Tracking customer search to price discriminate.
Deck, Cary A. ; Wilson, Bart J.
Suppose that every time you walked around the mall, somebody put a
bar code on your shoulder and, as you walked into the shops in the mall,
someone came up and scanned your shoulder and got the number ... went to
a database, saying, "Ah, yes, that's Lesley who visited the
shop next door 15 minutes ago." That's the level of
surveillance that's going on on the Internet.
--Internet entrepreneur Jason Catlett in a 60 Minutes interview
with Lesley Stahl ("Not As Private As You Think," aired
November 28, 1999)
I. INTRODUCTION
Transaction mechanisms in an electronic marketplace can be much
different from those used in traditional markets. Predominantly,
"brick and mortar" markets are described as sellers posting
single offer prices that buyers either accept or reject through their
purchase decisions. Without necessarily holding everything else
constant, two buyers, each making concurrent purchases in the same
store, pay the same posted price for an identical item. (1) In
particular, a buyer that has visited multiple rival stores receives the
same price as a buyer that impulsively purchases without comparing any
prices.
In contrast, a combination of Internet technologies makes it
possible to identify the search history of potential customers. Online
retailers generally make use of a standard programming device that
produces electronic files to tag individual customers with a unique
identification. Commonly referred to as cookies, these small computer
files are stored on the hard drive of the customer's computer.
Developers created cookies so that a Web site could maintain state even
though the HTTP protocol is stateless. This allows a Web site to
recognize an individual and accommodate multiple-item purchases from an
Internet retailer. (2) An unintended consequence of this technology is
that other Web sites, namely rival sellers, could use a second Internet
device called a Web bug to retrieve the identity of the Internet domain
that placed a cookie, even though the specific information content of
the cookie is typically encrypted. Two different types of Web bugs can
ascertain the search history of a customer. A Web bug is a
graphic--typically, one pixel by one pixel in size--on a Web page, and
it is designed to monitor who is reading the Web page. Web bugs are
virtually invisible because they are uncolored and so small. One type,
an executable Web bug, is a file that monitors a machine's traffic
and hard drive and periodically sends the information back to the Web
site that planted the bug on the machine. The second type is not
physically located on the machine and uses a technology called scripts
(e.g., JavaScript, ActiveX, and Perl) to scan a hard drive searching for
files. (3,4)
Because the process of identifying a customer and posting an offer
price is electronic and immediate, sellers on the Internet can use this
technology to post dynamic, customer-specific prices. (5) However, the
major contributions to the rich literature on consumer search consider
only models in which firms post a single price regardless of how
informed the customer may be. For example, Braverman (1980), Varian
(1980), Stiglitz (1979), and Salop and Stiglitz (1977) assume that a
consumer is either fully informed or completely unaware of other
stores' prices and that each firm posts a single price to any
customer. Other work considers sequential consumer search, but again
each firm posts a single price regardless of how informed the customer
may be--see, for example, Stahl (1989), Stiglitz (1987), Rob (1985),
Burdett and Judd (1983), Carlson and McAfee (1983), and Wilde and
Schwartz (1979). (6) This article explores the fundamental changes to
traditional sequential customer search in posted offer markets when
firms have the ability to track customers and price discriminate accordingly.
Using controlled experimental markets, we investigate how the
ability to track customers and offer differentially informed customers
different prices affects the prices that buyers receive in aggregate. We
can also readily identify the level to which customers are informed, and
we can ascertain the distribution of prices that these well-defined
customer segments receive. Within the confines of the laboratory, we can
control such variable factors as whether customers can be tracked, the
degree to which customers compare prices, seller competition, customer
preferences, and seller costs. As a control group, we also study markets
in which buyers cannot be tracked, thereby forcing sellers to post a
single price regardless of how well informed a customer may be.
We conducted a laboratory experiment for two reasons. First, even
in the rather straightforward analytical framework that we employ, there
is an inherent problem in attaining a theoretical solution without
making auxiliary assumptions. Thus, our experiment provides insight into
a new market phenomenon, price discrimination of differentially informed
customers. Second, a field study is problematic because of the
difficulty in finding naturally occurring data. The nature of Internet
transactions makes it difficult to collect data from consumers on the
distribution of prices for heterogeneous segments of price searchers.
Furthermore, Internet firms would naturally be reluctant to release
information if indeed they are discriminating based on tracking data,
because customers may become peeved ex post on learning that they paid
more than what other customers paid for the same item. (7)
As a preview of the results, we find that consumers, on average,
face the same prices when sellers have the ability to track customers
and price discriminate as when sellers post a single price for all
buyers. However, different types of buyers are affected differently by
tracking. Informed buyers receive lower prices when sellers can detect
buyer search, whereas uninformed buyers receive lower prices when firms
cannot track customers.
The outline of the chapter is as follows. Section II describes our
experimental design for comparing markets with and without customer
tracking. In section III we discuss the results of the market
experiment, and in section IV we offer our concluding remarks.
II. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN AND PROCEDURES
To explore how tracking buyers affects the performance of markets,
we conducted a series of experimental markets. Each computerized
experimental session consisted of undergraduates at the University of
Arizona. Many of our participants had experience in various unrelated
economic experiments; however, for some this was their first experiment.
In each session, four participants competed as sellers of a
fictitious good in a posted offer market. Buyers in the market were
fully revealing automated robots; that is, if a seller posted a price
below the buyer's value for the good, the agents completed a
transaction in experimental dollars. Every three seconds, which we refer
to as a period, a new computerized buyer would enter the market with a
randomly drawn value v for one unit of the good drawn from a uniform
distribution with support [[v.bar],[bar.v].] The number of periods was
fixed at 1,200 but was unknown to the participants. Each buyer also had
a randomly drawn order over which to query prices from the sellers, and
each buyer was randomly assigned the number of sellers that the buyer
would query. We refer to a buyer who searches i sellers as a type i
buyer. It is public information that fraction [[omega].sub.i] > 0 of
the buyers are of type i with
[n=4.summation over (i=1)] [[omega].sub.i] = 1.
As the number of sellers that the buyer visits increases, the buyer
can be considered more informed. (8) In the event that multiple sellers
offered the same lowest price to a buyer, the buyer randomly determined
from which of the tied low-price sellers to consider a purchase.
Each seller quotes a single price p and receives a profit of p - c
if a buyer agrees to make a purchase, where c is the common-knowledge
constant marginal cost. In the event that two sellers quote the same
minimum price, the buyer randomly selects a seller to consider. The
buyer receives utility of v - [p.sub.L] if [p.sub.L] < v, as the
buyer is assumed to be completely rational and truthfully revealing. In
the event that the buyer makes no purchase, the buyer's utility is
0.
We conducted 16 experimental sessions, 4 under each treatment pair
in a 2 x 2 design. For the first treatment variable, participant sellers
participated in one of two buyer tracking institutions. Sellers in the
No Tracking treatment did not know the number of sellers visited by the
buyer. Each seller could set only a single price, which was described to
the participants as "Set price at [there does not exist],"
where the participants fill in the box. In contrast, a seller in the
Tracking treatment could determine the number of different sellers
visited by the buyer. More specifically, each participant chose a price
schedule described as "Price if visited 1st = [there does not
exist], Price if visited 2nd = [there does not exist], Price if visited
3rd = [there does not exist], and Price if visited 4th = [there does not
exist]," where participants filled in the boxes.
Participants maintained their single price or price schedule for 15
to 25 periods, with the exact number of periods randomly drawn from a
discrete uniform (15, 25) distribution each time a new pricing. (9)
Policy was implemented by the participant. When the required duration of
a pricing policy expired, participants could either maintain the current
pricing policy indefinitely or adopt a new one, the form of which
depended on the treatment (No Tracking or Tracking). While the current
price or price schedule was forced to remain unchanged for 15 to 25
periods, the subjects (1) knew the number of periods until they could
change their price or price schedule again and (2) could enter a new
pricing policy to implement at the first possible opportunity. We chose
to implement this procedure because we believe that a variable timing of
decision making better represents the naturally occurring (Internet)
economy than does the game of simultaneous moves.
The second treatment variable is the market environment. In all
sessions, buyer values were drawn from a uniform (25, 125) distribution.
However, the distribution of buyer types differed across treatments. In
the Low Search treatment, [[omega].sub.1] = .61 and [[omega].sub.2] =
[[omega].sub.3] = [[omega].sub.1] = .13, but in the High Search
treatment, the likelihood that a buyer will comparison shop increases
with [[omega].sub.1] = [[omega].sub.2] = [[omega].sub.3] =
[[omega].sub.4] = .25. In all sessions, c = 25 for each of the four
sellers. These market conditions were common knowledge among the
subjects.
After each period participants received feedback about the price
they quoted to the buyer if they were visited and their profit if they
made a sale. In the No Tracking treatment, sellers were given the prices
posted by their rivals last period, and in the Tracking treatment
subjects were given the price that their competitors would have quoted
to anyone who visited that competitor first. (10) At the conclusion of
the experiment the participants were paid their earnings over the entire
1,200 periods, which were converted into U.S. dollars at a rate of 1
dollar for 300 experimental dollars. Additionally, participants received
a fee of $5 for showing up on time. Table 1 provides the average payoff
by treatment for the 75-minute sessions, excluding the $5 show-up fee.
Reference Predictions
One potential reference prediction for the No Tracking treatment is
the competitive outcome, p = c, but as Varian (1980) shows, no pure
strategy equilibrium at any price exists in the stage game. For
([[omega].sub.1] > 0, [p.sub.m] strictly dominates the competitive
price. Given the repeated nature of this game and the unknown time
horizon, a second potential reference prediction is p = [p.sub.m].
The Varian model makes a prediction for the one-shot simultaneous
move game. To determine the symmetric mixed-strategy equilibrium in this
environment, we first calculate the seller's "security
profit," or the payoff that the seller can unilaterally achieve. In
this environment a monopolist receives profit [[pi].sub.m], which can be
calculated by maximizing with respect to p the monopolist's profit
function, [pi] = [([bar.v] - p)/([bar.v] - [v.bar])](p - c). As
described, p - c is the seller's profit from a sale. The first term
in the profit calculation is simply the probability that a buyer has a
value v > p. The profit-maximizing price is [p.sub.m] =
([bar.v]+c)/2, which generates [[pi].sub.m] = [([bar.v] -
c)[sup.2]/[4([bar.v] - [v.bar])]. In an n-seller environment, a seller
can act as a monopolist for a proportion [[omega].sub.1]/n of the
buyers, and therefore the seller's expected "security"
profit is ([[omega].sub.1][[pi].sub.m])/n.
Next we determine the probability that a buyer will consider a
purchase from a particular seller when the other sellers price according
to the cumulative density function F(p). First, we note that there are
[sub.n][C.sub.i] total groups of size i, and [sub.n - 1] [C.sub.i - 1]
possible groups of size i to which a seller can belong. Thus, for a type
i buyer, a particular seller will be one of a group sampled by a buyer
with probability [sub.n - 1][C.sub.i - 1]/[sub.n][C.sub.i] = i/n.
Second, that same seller will have a price less than i - 1 rivals with
probability [[1 - F(p)].sup.i-1]. Last, recall that with probability
[[omega].sub.i] the buyers are of type i. Hence, the overall probability
that a buyer will consider a purchase from a particular seller is
[n.summation over (i=1)] [[i[[omega].sub.i][1 - F(p)].sup.i-1]]/n
In a mixed-strategy equilibrium, the firm must be indifferent over
all possible pure strategies in the support; hence, equating the
security profit and the expected profit at a price p yields the equation
that determines the equilibrium cumulative distribution functions:
(1) [([bar.v] - p)/([bar.v] - [v.bar])](p - c)
x([n.summation over (i=1)] [[i[[omega].sub.i][1 - F(p)].sup.i-1]]/n
= ([[omega].sub.i][[pi].sub.m])/n.
With nonzero weights on all n [greater than or equal to] 3 buyer
types, no closed form solution for F(p) exists. However, one can
determine several key features of the resulting pattern of pricing
behavior. First, if [[omega].sub.1] = 1, then each seller should charge
a pure strategy equilibrium price of [p.sub.m] because there is no
competition among the sellers when the buyers do not search. However, if
[[omega].sub.1] = 0, then the unique equilibrium is for each firm to
charge a price of c, the Bertrand solution. (11) The upper bound of F(p)
is [p.sub.m] whereas the lower bound of the support, [p.sup.*], is
implicitly defined by setting F(p) = 0 in equation 1. Mass points do not
exist in a symmetric mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium, as the probability
of a tie would lead sellers to a lower price in an attempt to capture
more expected profit than would sharing the profit at the common price.
Figure 1 displays the symmetric Nash equilibrium mixing
distributions when sellers post a single price. Notice the clear
separation in the predicted distribution of prices, though both share
the same monopoly price [p.sub.m] of 75. The median of the Low Search
treatment is 46.5, approximately (and purposely not exactly) in the
middle of the interval (c, [p.sub.m]) = (25, 75), but the median in the
High Search treatment is 33.4, which is strictly below the lower bound
of the support for the Low Search treatment.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Varian's framework, however, becomes intractable for a
one-shot simultaneous move version of the game in the Tracking treatment
(and hence is the primary motivation for this experiment).
III. EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS
For each of the 19,200 simulated buyers (16 sessions x 1,200
periods/session x 1 buyer/period) in our experiment, our data include
the price schedule employed by each seller, the random draw of the
buyer's value, the buyer's type, and the order in which the
buyer visited the sellers. The data permit us to compare posted price
schedules, buyers' best-quoted prices, seller profitability, and
the distribution of total surplus for the four separate treatments: (No
Tracking, Tracking) x (Low Search, High Search).
We report our results as a series of five findings. As a control
for potential learning effects over the course of a session, our
analysis focuses exclusively on the last half of each session, a total
of 9,600 simulated buyers. We begin by comparing observed behavior to
the game-theoretic prediction for the static model in the No Tracking
environment. Even though our environment involves asynchronous moves,
the static model Nash equilibrium serves as a basis of comparison for
analyzing our results. (12)
Finding 1
When sellers set a single price for all buyer types because all
buyers are untrackable, the resulting distribution of prices is a
mean-preserving spread of the static symmetric Nash equilibrium mixing
distribution when sellers are competing in the Low Search treatment. In
contrast, the central tendencies of the price distribution for the No
Tracking-High Search treatment are considerably greater than the static
symmetric game-theoretic predictions.
Evidence
Figure 2 provides the qualitative support and Table 2, the
quantitative support. The median and mean of all prices aggregated
across all subjects and sessions in the No Tracking-Low Search treatment
are close to the static game-theoretic predictions. The Low Search
static symmetric game-theoretic predictions for the mean and median are
48.4 and 46.5, respectively, whereas the observed mean and median are
51.0 and 48.0, respectively. However, the observed mean and median for
the No Tracking-High Search treatment, 52.1, and 46.0, respectively, are
considerably greater than the static predictions, 37.2 and 33.4,
respectively. We employ a linear mixed-effects model for analyzing data
with repeated measures as the basis for quantitative support. (13) The
results from estimating this model for the median price (MedianP) and
mean price (MeanP) of the No Tracking sessions are reported in Table 2.
The treatment effect (Low Search versus High Search) is modeled as a
zero-one fixed effect, whereas the sessions are modeled as random
effects, [e.sub.i]. Each observation is a seller's median or mean
posted price for the last 600 buyers. We index sessions by i = 1, ....,
8 and sellers by j = 1, 2, 3, 4. Specifically, we estimate the model
(2) [Y.sub.ij] = [alpha] + [e.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.1][LowSearch.sub.i] + [[epsilon ].sub.ij],
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
where [e.sub.i] ~ N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.1]), [[epsilon].sub.ij] ~
N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2,i])and Y = MedianP or MeanP. The linear
mixed-effects model for repeated measures treats each session as one
degree of freedom with respect to the treatment. (14)
The mean and median prices for the No Tracking-High Search
treatment are significantly different from the static predictions (p
values = 0.0002 and 0.0000, respectively). The mean price for the No
Tracking-Low Search treatment ([??] + [[beta].sub.1] = 50.0) is not
statistically different from theoretical prediction 48.4 (p value =
0.6208); however, at a 90% confidence level, the median No Tracking-Low
Search price ([??] + [[??].sub.1] = 49.4) differs from the prediction of
46.5 (p value = 0.0757). As predicted by intuition and the static
theory, (15) the No Tracking-Low Search treatment median price is
greater than the No Tracking-High Search treatment median price (p value
= 0.0548), but the means are not statistically different (p value =
0.6933).
Finding 1 suggests that the model of sales organizes behavior in
such markets fairly well for the No Tracking-Low Search treatment, but
sellers in the No Tracking-High Search treatment clearly price less
competitively than what the static model predicts. Figure 2 illustrates
that the Search variable shifts the distribution of posted prices. From
the No Tracking-High Search to the No Tracking-Low Search treatment, the
distribution of prices shifts distinctly to the right, with the mode
shifting from 29 to 45, even though it is a mean-preserving shift. The
means are the same because the mode for the No Tracking-High Search
treatment of 29 is offset by increased frequency of prices greater than
or equal to the monopoly price, 75: 19% of the No Tracking-High Search
treatment prices are in the 75 or greater range, whereas just 10% of the
No Tracking-Low Search treatment prices are in this same range. One
hypothesis is that the extremely competitive environment of the No
Tracking-High Search treatment leads to more signaling than does the
less competitive environment of the No Tracking-Low Search. By setting
higher prices, subjects can signal a willingness to raise prices. Such
signaling is less costly in the more competitive environment due to the
lower expected profit margin. If subjects are signaling higher prices
for the purpose of mitigating the competitive pressure of comparison
shopping, then the signaling is apparently quite effective. Table 1
reports that the sellers in the No Tracking-High Search treatment earned
$10.75 on average as compared to the $6.25 predicted by the static
theory. The price signals in the High Search treatment appear to be an
intelligent response to a highly competitive environment. It is this
signaling that prevents a statistical separation of the results in Table
2 and Figure 2. Without the small tails above the monopoly price of 75,
the means and medians of these two treatments would be quite different,
as is graphically evident in the histograms in Figure 2. The observed
distributions appear to shift as the static predictions shift, but the
quantitative effect in aggregate and across-buyer types is minor (see
findings 2a and 2b). Morgan et al. (forthcoming) similarly find that
increasing the proportion of informed consumers decreases the prices
paid by informed and uninformed customers. Given our asynchronous
laboratory environment, we would expect, a priori, less of a pronounced
conformity with Varian's predictions. What is interesting is that
the differing levels of consumer search conform differently with his
model.
Our next four findings examine the impact of buyer tracking with
the No Tracking environments serving as a baseline. Finding 2 pertains
to the prices quoted to buyers. Because the sellers in the Tracking
treatments choose a price schedule containing up to four different
prices depending on the order in which they are visited, we use the
metric of the best-quoted price to compare prices across the Tracking
and No Tracking treatments. Each buyer visits [n.sub.s] = 1, 2, 3, or 4
sellers dependent on type, receiving a quoted price potentially
dependent on the order visited. The best-quoted price is the minimum
price of the [n.sub.s] prices that the buyer observes. (16) For ease of
exposition, we break this finding into four parts.
Finding 2a
Buyers, when aggregated across types, do not receive statistically
different mean best-quoted prices from any of the primary or interaction
treatment effects.
Evidence
Table 3 reports the results of a mixed-effects model to determine
the primary and interaction effects of the treatments on the best-quoted
prices for the 9,600 best-quoted prices (16 sessions x 600
buyers/session). The treatment and interaction effects (No Tracking
versus Tracking, Low Search versus High Search) are modeled as fixed
effects, whereas the sessions are modeled as random effects, [e.sub.i].
The dependent variable for each observation is the best-quoted price for
the last 600 buyers in a session. Sessions are indexed by i = 1, ..., 16
and buyers by j = 1, ..., 600. Specifically, we estimate the model
(3) [BestQuotedPrice.sub.ij]
= [alpha] + [e.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.1][LowSearch.sub.i]
+ [[beta].sub.2][Tracking.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][Tracking.sub.i]
x [LowSearch.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.ij]
where [e.sub.i] ~ N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.1]), [[epsilon].sub.ij] ~
N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2,i]).
Because all of the primary and interaction effects are
statistically insignificant at conventional levels of significance, we
conclude that, overall, buyers receive the same best-quoted price
regardless of the level of search or the sellers' ability to track
buyers.
Initially, finding 2a may seem counterintuitive; buyers do not
receive lower best-quoted prices in more competitive environments.
However, finding 2a is based on prices aggregated across buyer types. As
the remainder of finding 2 demonstrates, a shopper's search pattern
significantly affects the best-quoted price. The insignificance of the
market characteristics at the aggregate level is due to offsetting price
movements across buyer types.
Having established that the treatments do not affect the
best-quoted prices that the buyers in aggregate receive, we focus now on
how the degree of buyer search affects best-quoted prices under the
various treatments. For quantitative support, we add the following
variables to the model in Table 3: the buyer's type (type m) and
the interaction of the buyer types with both treatment variables. We
first consider the primary effect of buyer search without tracking. This
is largely a calibration result, because buyers purchase from the
minimum price of the i sellers visited; hence, a greater search will
lead to a lower best-quoted price in expectation. (17) When buyers
cannot be tracked, buyers that visit fewer sellers receive higher
best-quoted prices than do more informed customers. Figures 3 and 4
report the observed densities of best-quoted prices by treatment and
buyer type and depict the story that the linear mixed-effects model
reports statistically in Table 4.
[FIGURES 3-4 OMITTED]
The type 4 buyers serve as the baseline type of buyer, and No
Tracking-High Search serves as the baseline treatment in Table 4. A
priori, in the No Tracking treatments we anticipate that the expected
values of the order statistics for the price distribution decrease as
the number of seller visits increase. The right panels of Figures 3 and
4 illustrate that the densities shift to the left as the number of
sellers visited by the buyer increases. This shift is particularly
noticeable in the No Tracking-High Search treatment. Statistically, we
find that the point estimates of the type variables increase as the
buyers search less ([[??].sub.3] = 1.64, [[??].sub.2] = 3.72, and
[[??].sub.1] = 12.1) and that all of these estimates are highly
statistically significant (p values = 0.0257, 0.0000, and 0.0000,
respectively). Furthermore, with a 95% confidence interval (10.4, 13.8),
the type 1 term is significantly greater than the type 2 and type 3
terms.
Finding 2b
With No Tracking, different buyer types do not receive
statistically different best-quoted prices in the Low and High Search
treatments, but with Tracking, there is a statistical difference.
Evidence
Using a likelihood ratio test of the estimates in Table 4, we test
the joint hypothesis that [[beta].sub.1] = [[phi].sub.1] = [[phi].sub.2]
= [[phi].sub.3] = 0 against the alternative that at least one buyer type
with No Tracking receives different prices in the Low Search treatment
than in the High Search treatment. Table 4 reports that we cannot reject
the null hypothesis that buyers of all types receive the same
best-quoted prices (p value = 0.5575). In contrast, we can reject the
corresponding null hypothesis in Tracking treatment, namely, that
[[beta].sub.3] = [[gamma].sub.1] = [[gamma].sub.2] = [[gamma].sub.3 ]= 0
(p value = 0.0000).
We now turn our attention to comparing the No Tracking and Tracking
treatments holding the search variable constant.
Finding 2c
Type 4 buyers in the Tracking-High Search treatment receive
statistically lower best-quoted prices than do type 4 buyers who are not
tracked in the High Search environment. Type 1 buyers in the
Tracking-High Search treatment, however, do not receive this same price
break.
Evidence
We refer again to the results reported in Table 4. Because the
Tracking x Type m variables control for the specified buyer types, the
Tracking term captures the effect that type 4 buyers in Tracking-High
Search markets receive a lower best-quoted price ([[beta].sub.2] =
-8.61, p value = 0.0700). However, not all buyer types received this
price break. The Tracking x Type 1 term is highly significant (p value =
0.0000), raising the best-quoted price for Tracking-High Search type 1
buyers by 5.71 experimental dollars.
Finding 2d
In addition to the effects discussed, buyers that visit fewer
sellers in the Low Search-Tracking treatment receive additionally higher
quoted prices.
Evidence
As reported in Table 4, all three Low x Type m interaction terms
are statistically significant, raising the best-quoted-price by
[[??].sub.3] = 3.23, [[??].sub.2] = 8.26, and [[??].sub.1] = 11.6 (p
values = 0.0600, 0.0000, and 0.0000, respectively). Figure 3 illustrates
the dramatic leftward shift in the density of best-quoted prices as the
buyer searches more in Tracking-Low Search treatment. The estimated
best-quoted price for a type 1 buyer in the Tracking-Low Search
treatment is 57.6 (= [??] = [[??].sub.1] + [[??].sub.2] + [[??].sub.3] +
[[??].sub.1] + [[??].sub.1] +([[??].sub.1] + [[??].sub.1]), whereas a
type 4 buyer receives a price of 30.1 (= [??]+ [[??].sub.1] +
[[??].sub.2] + [[??].sub.3]). Visiting three other sellers reduces a
buyer's price by 47.7%.
In sum, finding 2 shows that buyers in aggregate do not receive
higher best-quoted prices when sellers have the ability to track
customers and charge sequentially different prices. One buyer segment,
buyers who do not search but are in an environment where they can be
tracked, receives higher prices than their counterparts who are in an
environment without seller tracking. However, as Figures 3 and 4
markedly illustrate, this effect is offset because buyers who search
more receive correspondingly lower prices in an environment in which
they are tracked.
Our next three findings consider how the treatments influence
seller profit, total surplus, and the distribution of the surplus,
respectively.
Finding 3
The ability to track buyers does not affect seller profit in the
Low Search treatment, but the Tracking treatment does reduce seller
profit in the High Search treatment.
Evidence
Figure 5 and Table 3 provide the relevant support for this finding.
Figure 5 displays the individual seller profit in experimental dollars
for the last 600 buyers in the seller's market. The first two
clusters of markers show that the ability to track customers and price
sequentially has no discernable influence on the profitability of the
sellers under Low Search. In comparing across the four treatment cells,
notice that profits in the Low Search treatments are greater than
profits in the High Search treatments as predicted by the static model.
It is also apparent that the Tracking-High Search profits are markedly
lower (29% on average) than the No Tracking-High Search treatment. The
dependent variable Seller Profit in Table 3 is the individual profit for
each seller in experimental dollars. The estimates of the mixed-effects
model indicate that Low Search significantly increases seller profit by
547 experimental dollars (p value = 0.0399). With the No Tracking-High
Search treatment serving as the baseline, the inclusion of tracking
reduces seller profits by 664 experimental dollars (p value = 0.0407).
The interaction effect, Tracking x Low Search, is positive and
marginally significant and thus offsets the Tracing effect in the Low
Search sessions ([[??].sub.2] + [[??].sub.3] = 73.3, p value = 0.7994).
From this we can conclude that given the Low Search treatment, Tracking
has no affect on seller profits.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Two reasons explain why seller profits fall with buyer tracking in
the High Search environment but not in Low Search, even though we report
in finding 2a that the primary and interaction effects are mean
preserving. First, even though tracking raises type 1 buyer prices and
lowers type 4 buyer prices (findings 2b and 2d), there are more type 4
buyers (25% versus 13%) and fewer type 1 buyers (25% versus 61%) with
High Search than with Low Search. Second, prices are relatively higher
for the type I buyers who are tracked in the Low Search environment
(finding 2c), so the profit margin from type 1 buyers is higher.
Finding 4
Total surplus generated does not statistically differ across
treatments.
Evidence
To be parsimonious, we conducted the same analysis with total
surplus as the dependent variable as we did for seller profit. Total
surplus is calculated as the sum of seller profit and consumer surplus
generated by each seller in the experiment. As Table 3 reports, all
three primary and interaction effects are insignificant; that is, the
level of total surplus is unaffected by the treatment variables.
The intuition for this result can also be found in the price
distributions. For the Search treatment variable, Figure 2 illustrates
that the mode of the High Search distribution is shifted to the left
relative to the Low Search distribution, which would increase the total
number of trades and total surplus in the High Search treatment.
However, the greater weight of prices in the right tail of the High
Search treatment tends to decrease total surplus relative to the Low
Search treatment. Finding 4 indicates that these effects offset each
other. Similarly for the Tracking treatment variable, the increase in
total surplus due to lower prices for type 4 buyers is offset by the
higher prices incurred by type 1 buyers.
Finding 5
The ability to track customers does not alter consumer surplus as a
percentage of the total surplus when search is low. However, the
Tracking-High Search treatment increases consumer surplus as a
percentage of total surplus relative to the No Tracking-High Search
treatment.
Evidence
Figure 6 and Table 3 provide the relevant support for this finding.
By seller, Figure 6 displays the consumer surplus as a percentage of
total surplus generated for the last 600 buyers of a session. The first
two clusters of markers show that the ability to track customers has no
discernable influence on consumer surplus as a percentage of total
surplus when search is low. Comparing all four sets of markers, both Low
Search consumer surplus percentages are lower than in the High Search
treatments. It is also apparent that the Tracking-High Search consumer
surplus percentages are noticeably higher (8.1 percentage points on
average) than the No Tracking-High Search treatment. The estimates of
the mixed-effects model indicate that Low Search significantly lowers
the consumers' share of the surplus by 10.9 percentage points in
the absence of tracking (p value = 0.0010). With the No Tracking-High
Search treatment serving as the baseline, tracking increases the
consumer surplus as a percentage of total surplus by 10.4 percentage
points, holding the level of search constant (p value = 0.0006). The
interaction effect, Tracking x Low Search offsets the tracking effect in
the Tracking-Low Search sessions ([[??].sub.2] + [[??].sub.3] = -1.0, p
value = 0.7565), indicating that given the Low Search treatment,
tracking has no affect on consumer surplus as a percentage of total
surplus.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
IV. CONCLUSION
From an analytical standpoint, the features of an electronic
marketplace can be fundamentally different from those used in more
traditional markets. As the major contributions on buyer search theory
have assumed, a "brick and mortar" firm cannot readily
distinguish the informed customers from the uninformed. Such a firm
posts a single price, independent of the degree to which customers are
informed about competitors' prices. In contrast, the interactive
technologies of electronic markets allow a firm to identify the extent
to which customers may be informed about competitors' prices, and
with this information, the firm can then tailor a price for each
individual customer.
Using controlled experimental markets, we investigate how the
ability to track customers and price discriminate accordingly affects
the prices that buyers receive and the associated profits of the
sellers. For a baseline, we study markets in which buyers cannot be
tracked. We find that the sellers' ability to track customers and
implement search history-based pricing does not harm customers as a
group. However, tracking-based pricing affects distinct customer
segments differently. In particular, buyers who could be tracked and who
search several sellers receive lower prices than did buyers who could
not be tracked but who also search several sellers. In contrast,
uninformed buyers who could be tracked receive higher prices than did
uninformed buyers who could not be tracked. Thus, we find that buyers on
average do not receive higher prices in a tracking-based pricing
environment, because the buyers who searched more receive lower prices
and buyers who search less receive higher prices. Furthermore, aggregate
consumer surplus rises and seller profits fall when 75% of the buyers
search at least two sellers as opposed to when only 39% of the buyers
search in the tracking environment.
The exploratory nature of this article raises both theoretical and
empirical questions for future work. First, how would customer search
patterns react to tracking by sellers? Customers may not become price
searchers en masse, because the more that buyers as a group search, the
lower the prices for the uninformed customers; that is, there is an
opportunity to free-ride off the searching of other buyers. Second, the
evolution of customer search patterns may affect the degree to which
sellers adopt tracking technology. Also, incorporating the ability
afforded by the Internet to closely monitor individual rivals, firms may
be able to further tailor customer prices based on the specific firms
that a potential customer has visited. Hence, this study really provides
only an initial foray into the effects of customer tracking in an
electronic marketplace.
REFERENCES
Baye, M., and J. Morgan. "Revisiting Bertrand's
Competition: Paradox Lost or Paradox Found?" Mimeo, Indiana
University, 1996.
Braverman, A. "Consumer Search and Alternative Market
Equilibria." Review of Economic Studies, 47, 1980, 487-502.
Burdett, K., and K. Judd. "Equilibrium Price Dispersion."
Econometrica, 51, 1983, 955-70.
Carlson, J., and R. P. McAfee. "Discrete Equilibrium Price
Dispersion." Journal of Political Economy, 91, 1983, 480-93.
Cason, T., and D. Friedman. "Buyer Search and Price
Dispersion: A Laboratory Study." Journal of Economic Theory,
112(3), 2003, 232-60.
Davis, D., and C. Holt. "Consumer Search Costs and Market
Performance." Economic Inquiry, 34, 1996, 133-51.
Davis, D., and B. J. Wilson. "Firm-Specific Cost Savings and
Market Power." Economic Theory, 16(3), 2000, 545-65.
Deck, C. A., and B. J. Wilson. "Automated Pricing Rules in
Electronic Posted Offer Markets." Economic Inquiry, 41, 2003,
208-23.
Kruse, J., S. Rassenti, S. Reynolds, and V. Smith.
"Bertrand-Edgeworth Competition in Experimental Markets."
Econometrica, 62, 1994, 343-71.
Longford, N. T. Random Coefficient Models. New York: Oxford
University Press, 1993.
Morgan, J., H. Orzen, and M. Sefton. "An Experimental Study of
Price Dispersion." Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming.
Morgan, J., and M. Sefton. "A Model of Sales: Comment."
Mimeo, 2000.
Olsen, S. "New Tools Hatch for Sniffing Out Web Bugs"
CNET News.com, 5 March 2001, http://news.cnet.
com/news/0-1005-200-5008849.html.
Rob, R. "Equilibrium Price Distributions." Review of
Economic Studies, 52, 1985, 457-504.
Rodgers, A. "Checking for Bugs." Smart Computing, 12(7),
2001, 92-95, http://www.smartcomputing.
com/editorial/article.asp?article=articles/2001/s1207/ 35s07/35s07.asp.
Salop, S., and J. Stiglitz. "Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of
Monopolistically Competitive Price Dispersion." Review of Economic
Studies, 44, 1977, 493-510.
Smith, V. "Microeconomics as an Experimental Science."
American Economic Review, 72(5), 1982, 923-55.
Stahl, D. "Oligopolistic Pricing with Sequential Consumer
Search." American Economic Review, 79, 1989, 700-712.
Stiglitz, J. "Equilibrium in Product Markets with Imperfect Information." American Economic Review, 69, 1979, 339-45.
--. "Competition and the Number of Firms in a Market: Are
Duopolies More Competitive Than Atomistic Markets?" Journal of
Political Economy, 95, 1987, 1041-61.
Streitfeld, D. "On the Web, Price Tags Blues." Washington
Post, 27 September 2000, Sec. A, p. 1.
Sullivan, B. "Pop-Ups Prove Profitable, Persistent,"
MSNBC.com, 20 November 2003, http://www.msnbc. com/news/995180.asp.
Varian, H. "A Model of Sales." American Economic Review,
70(4), 1980, 651-59.
Weber, T. "The Man Who Baked the First Web Cookies Chews Over
Their Fate," Wall Street Journal, 28 February 2000, Sec. B, p. 1.
Wilde, L., and A. Schwartz. "Equilibrium Comparison
Shopping." Review of Economic Studies, 46, 1979, 543-53.
Wolverton, T. "MP3 Player 'Sale' Exposes
Amazon's Flexible Prices." CNET News.com, 17 May 2000a,
http://news.cnet.com/news/0-1007-200-1889854.html.
--. "Now Showing: Random DVD Prices on Amazon," CNET
News.com, 5 September 2000b, http://
news.cnet.com/news/0-1007-200-2703210.html.
(1.) Exceptions include various traditional forms of price
discrimination, such as coupons or quantity discounts.
(2.) Weber (2000) reports that Web sites were initially designed to
process each information requests one by one. Thus, without cookies, an
individual customer would have to purchase each item separately.
Netscape designed the original browser specifications so that a Web site
could access only its own cookies.
(3.) See, for example, Olsen (2001) and Rodgers (2001). In an
article on the technology of spyware, adware, and popup ads, Sullivan
(2003) reports, '"When are people going to get it, that every
time they look at something they are being watched?' said one
industry watcher, who asked not to be named. [Keith Smith CEO of
180Solutions] and others in the adware side of the industry insist there
is no privacy invasion when consumers are watched anonymously. To the
contrary, consumers enjoy having the chance to do last-minute comparison
shopping before they finish the checkout procedure at an e-commerce
site, he said. 'I would challenge anyone to make the case that
giving consumers more options at the point of sale is bad,' he
said."
(4.) Another way for Web sites to track customers is to exploit
flaws in new versions of browsers that to permit a Web site to gain
access to the cookies placed by a second Web site. Even when patches are
developed and posted to fix these glitches, the diffusion of these
patches is unlikely to be complete, leaving some people trackable.
(5.) Two instances of cookie-specific pricing (but without Web
bugs), have recently transpired, both involving Amazon.com. Amazon
customers learned in an online discussion forum that the price of
several DVDs differed among buyers, depending on whether or not they had
cached cookies--see Streitfeld (2000) and Wolverton (2000b). Streitfeld
(2000) and Wolverton (2000a) also report that customers discovered that
Amazon was offering "random" prices on an MP3 player (up to
$51 less than the regular $233.95 price). Amazon defended the random
pricing as market research.
(6.) See Davis and Holt (1996) and Cason and Friedman (2003) for
examples of experimental studies on costly buyer search and price
dispersion. The sellers in their designs could not price discriminate to
informed and uninformed buyers.
(7.) See Wolverton (2000b). In reference to the variable DVD
prices, one customer at DVD Talk Forum posted the message, "Okay
quick solution for Amazon's little dishonest pricing scam,"
and another customer wrote, "Sounds like illegal price
descrimination [sic]." A hard copy of the forum discussion is
available upon request. In addition, Internet retailers are likely to be
wary of drawing regulatory attention.
(8.) Following Braverman (1980), Varian (1980), Stiglitz (1979),
and Salop and Stiglitz (1977), we treat consumer search as being
exogenously determined. In these works buyers are either completely
informed of prices or are uninformed, dependent on personal
characteristics, essentially the buyers of Type 1 or Type n. We
generalize this by allowing buyers to be of Types 2, ..., n - 1. This is
consistent with certain shoppers having preferences for or knowledge of
some subset of the retail outlets.
(9.) The model described in section II assumes simultaneous
decision making in a one-shot environment, two assumptions that are
unrealistic in the naturally occurring electronic economy. As we are
conducting a heuristic experiment in the vein discussed by Smith (1982),
we choose to implement the pricing game in an asynchronous repeated-play
environment.
(10.) The same technology that allows a firm to determine the price
that competitors quote to a customer when visited first could also be
used to determine the competitor's entire price schedule; however,
we believed that providing information on 12 other prices every three
seconds (plus the four prices in one's own schedule) would be an
overwhelming amount of information for the participants to handle.
Moreover, this keeps the amount of price feedback similar across the
Tracking and No Tracking treatments.
(11.) Baye and Morgan (2000) discuss the conditions under which the
only Nash equilibrium of a price setting game is the Bertrand solution.
(12.) Deck and Wilson (2003), Davis and Wilson (2000), and Kruse et
al. (1994) have found that the central moment of the static Nash
equilibrium mixed strategy captures behavior in a repeated pricing game
quite well.
(13.) See Longford (1993) for a description of this technique that
is commonly employed in experimental sciences. It is well known that
dummy variables such as LowSearch are not identifiable in a model with a
full set of session fixed effects, because a and LowSearch are a perfect
linear combination of the eight session fixed effects.
(14.) Hence, with two parameters, the degrees of freedom for the
estimate of the Search treatment fixed effect are 6 = 8 sessions - 2
parameters. We also accommodate sessionwise heteroskedastic errors when
estimating the model via maximum likelihood.
(15.) Morgan and Sefton (2000) show that in Varian's model of
sales (1980), an increase in the number of uninformed consumers raises
informed customers' expected price.
(16.) The analysis of transaction prices closely resembles the
results reported for best-quoted prices and is hence not reported. A
transaction did not occur if the best-quoted price exceeded the
buyer's reservation value.
(17.) It is not necessarily the case that increased buyer search
will lead to lower prices in the tracking environment, as sellers could
use pricing distributions for comparison shoppers that are greater than,
in a first-order stochastic dominance sense, the distribution employed
for buyers making an initial inquiry. Recall that the agents are allowed
to make decisions in an unrestricted action space. Finding 2b is thus a
calibration, as it identifies a baseline by which to evaluate the
treatment effect of tracking on consumers who search.
CARY A. DECK and BART J. WILSON, We thank two anonymous referees
for their comments that have improved this paper. The paper has also
benefitted from conversations with Gundoz Caginalp, Raja Kali, Dan
Kovenock, Vernon Smith and Ferenc Szidarovsky and from seminars at
Florida State University, Purdue University, the University of
Mississippi, the University of Massachusetts, Virginia Commonwealth
University and the Meetings of the Southern Economic Association. The
data and a sample copy of the instructions are available upon request.
We thank Jia Jing Liu, Prashanth Murthy, and Ben Toff for excellent
research assistance in running these experiments. The authors gratefully
acknowledge financial support from the International Foundation for
Research in Experimental Economics.
Deck: Department of Economics, Walton College of Business,
University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR 72701. Phone 1-479-575-6226,
Fax 1-479-575-3241, E-mail cdeck@walton.uark.edu
Wilson: Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science, George Mason
University, 4400 University Drive, MSN 1B2, Fairfax, VA 22030-4444.
Phone 1-703993-4845, Fax 1-703-993-4851, E-mail bwilson3@ gmu.edu
TABLE 1
Average Payoffs (US$) by Algorithm
Game theoretic--Low Search 15.25
Game theoretic--High Search 6.25
No Tracking--Low Search 15.25
No Tracking--High Search 10.75
Tracking Low Search 15.75
Tracking-High Search 10.00
Note: These payoffs do not include the
$5 payment for showing up on time.
TABLE 2
Estimates of the Linear Mixed-Effects Model
for the No Tracking Treatment [Y.sub.ij] = [alpha] +
[[e.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.1] [LowSearch.sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.ij], where [[e.sub.i] ~ N (0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.1],
~ N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2,i]
Y Estimate Std. Degrees
Error of
Freedom *
MedianP
[alpha] 45.4 1.47 24
LowSearch 4.00 2.13 6
MeanP
[alpha] 52.6 3.48 24
LowSearch -2.56 4.80 6
Y [H.sub.a] t P Value
Statistic
MedianP
[alpha] [alpha] 8.19 0.0000
[not equal to]
33.4 *
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] 1.88 0.0548
> 0
[alpha] + 1.86 0.0757
[[beta].sub.1]
[not equal to]
MeanP 46.5 *
[alpha] [alpha] 4.42 0.0002
[not equal to]
37.2 *
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] -0.53 0.6933
> 0
[alpha] + 0.50 0.6208
[[beta].sub.1]
[not equal to]
48.4 *
Note: The linear mixed-effects model for repeated measures
treats each session as one degree of freedom with respect to
the Low versus High treatments. Hence, the degrees of freedom
for the estimates of this fixed effect is 6 = 8 sessions - 2
parameters. Each linear mixed-effects model is fit by
maximum likelihood with 32 observations and 8 sessions.
For brevity, the session random effects are not included
in the table.
* Theoretical prediction.
TABLE 3
Estimates of the Linear Mixed-Effects Model
[Y.sub.ij] = [alpha] + [e.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.1][LowSearch.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.2][Tracking.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][[Tracking].sub.i]
x [LowSearch.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.ij], where [e.sub.i] ~
N (0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.1], [[epsilon].sub.ij] ~ N
(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.2,i].
Degrees of
Y Estimate Std. Error Freedom *
Best Quoted Price (a)
[alpha] 43.6 2.99 9,584
LowSearch 4.30 4.22 12
Tracking -7.06 4.22 12
Tracking x LowSearch 8.36 5.97 12
SellerProfit (b)
[alpha] 1763 207.4 48
LowSearch 547.1 285.9 12
Tracking -663.8 289.5 12
Tracking x LowSearch 737.1 404.2 12
TotalSurplus % (b)
[alpha] 6901 565.2 48
LowSearch 269.2 774.3 12
Tracking 513.4 974.2 12
Tracking x LowSearch -760.9 1140.6 12
ConsumerSurplus% (b)
[alpha] 73.8 1.82 48
LowSearch -10.9 2.52 12
Tracking 10.4 2.26 12
Tracking x LowSearch -11.4 3.85 12
Y [H.sub.a] t Statistic
Best Quoted Price (a)
[alpha] [alpha] [not equal to] 37.2 2.13
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] > 0 1.01
Tracking [[beta].sub.2] [not equal to] 0 -1.67
Tracking x LowSearch [[beta].sub.3] [not equal to] 0 1.40
[alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] 0.18
[not equal to] 48.4
SellerProfit (b)
[alpha] [alpha] [not equal to] 937.5 * 3.98
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] > 0 1.91
Tracking [[beta].sub.2] [not equal to] 0 -2.29
Tracking x LowSearch [[beta].sub.3] [not equal to] 0 1.82
[alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] 0.12
[not equal to] 2287.5 *
[[beta].sub.2] + [[beta].sub.3] 0.26
[not equal to] 0
TotalSurplus % (b)
[alpha] [alpha] [not equal to] 0 12.2
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] < 0 0.34
Tracking [[beta].sub.2] [not equal to] 0 0.53
Tracking x LowSearch [[beta].sub.3] [not equal to] 0 -0.66
ConsumerSurplus% (b)
[alpha] [alpha] [not equal to] 0 40.6
LowSearch [[beta].sub.1] [not equal to] 0 -4.32
Tracking [[beta].sub.2] [not equal to] 0 4.60
Tracking x LowSearch [[beta].sub.3] [not equal to] 0 -2.95
[[beta].sub.2] + [[beta].sub.3] -0.32
[not equal to] 0
Y p Value
Best Quoted Price (a)
[alpha] 0.0333
LowSearch 0.1642
Tracking 0.1202
Tracking x LowSearch 0.1868
0.8545
SellerProfit (b)
[alpha] 0.0002
LowSearch 0.0399
Tracking 0.0407
Tracking x LowSearch 0.0932
0.9083
0.7994
TotalSurplus % (b)
[alpha] 0.0000
LowSearch 0.6330
Tracking 0.6078
Tracking x LowSearch 0.5173
ConsumerSurplus% (b)
[alpha] 0.0000
LowSearch 0.0010
Tracking 0.0006
Tracking x LowSearch 0.0119
0.7565
kNote: The linear mixed-effects model for repeated measures treats
each session as one degree of freedom with respect to the treatments
in the 2 x 2 design: Low, Tracking, and Low x Tracking variables.
Hence, the degrees of freedom for the estimates of these fixed
effects are 12 = 16 sessions - 4 parameters. The linear mixed-effects
model is fit by maximum likelihood with 16 groups. For brevity, the
session random effects are not included in the table.
* Theoretical prediction.
(a) 9,600 observations.
(b) 64 observations.
TABLE 4
Estimates of the Linear Mixed-Effects Model for the Best-Quoted Prices
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Degrees of
Best Quoted Prices Estimate Std. Error Freedom *
[alpha] 39.1 3.08 9572
Low 2.05 4.37 12
Tracking -8.61 4.33 12
Tracking x LowSearch -2.49 6.16 12
Type 1 12.1 0.83 9572
Type 2 3.72 0.83 9572
Type 3 1.64 0.84 9572
LowSearch x Type 1 -1.84 1.16 9572
LowSearch x Type 2 -1.35 1.32 9572
LowSearch x Type 3 -0.53 1.34 9572
Tracking x Type 1 5.71 1.02 9572
Tracking x Type 2 1.25 1.02 9572
Tracking x Type 3 -0.41 1.03 9572
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 111.6 1.51 9572
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 28.26 1.74 9572
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 33.23 1.77 9572
Best Quoted Prices [H.sub.a]
[alpha] [alpha] [not qual to] 0
Low [[beta].sub.1] > 0
Tracking [[beta].sub.2] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x LowSearch [[beta].sub.3] [not qual to] 0
Type 1 [[delta].sub.1] > 0
Type 2 [[delta].sub.2] > 0
Type 3 [[delta].sub.3] > 0
LowSearch x Type 1 [[phi].sub.1] [not qual to] 0
LowSearch x Type 2 [[phi].sub.2] [not qual to] 0
LowSearch x Type 3 [[phi].sub.3] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x Type 1 [[phi].sub.1] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x Type 2 [[phi].sub.2] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x Type 3 [[phi].sub.3] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x LowSearch x Type [[gamma].sub.1] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x LowSearch x Type [[gamma].sub.2] [not qual to] 0
Tracking x LowSearch x Type [[gamma].sub.3] [not qual to] 0
Best Quoted Prices t Statistic p Value
[alpha] 12.7 0.0000
Low 0.47 0.3236
Tracking -1.99 0.0700
Tracking x LowSearch -0.40 0.6937
Type 1 14.5 0.0000
Type 2 4.47 0.0000
Type 3 1.95 0.0257
LowSearch x Type 1 -1.58 0.1134
LowSearch x Type 2 -1.02 0.3071
LowSearch x Type 3 -0.40 0.6876
Tracking x Type 1 5.59 0.0000
Tracking x Type 2 1.26 0.2166
Tracking x Type 3 -0.40 0.6910
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 7.70 0.0000
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 4.76 0.0000
Tracking x LowSearch x Type 1.83 0.0671
[H.sub.0]: [[beta].sub.1] = [[phi].sub.1] =
[[phi].sub.2] = [[phi].sub.3] = 0 LR = 3.00 0.5575
[H.sub.0]: [[beta].sub.3] = [[gamma].sub.1] =
[[gamma].sub.2] = [[gamma].sub.3] = 0 LR = 67.73 0.0000
Note: 9,600 observations.
LR = likelihood ratio.