Patents as a measure of technology shocks and the aggregate U.S. labor market.
Rossana, Robert J.
I. INTRODUCTION
One of the dominant approaches to macroeconomic research in the
past several decades has been the island paradigm of Friedman (1968) and
Phelps (1970). In this framework, economic agents operate under
incomplete information regarding relative and absolute prices when
making economic decisions. This paradigm is used in the rational
expectations literature (see McCallum 1980 and the references therein)
in a market-clearing framework to study, among other things, the effects
of fiscal and monetary policies in aggregate economic systems. This
market-clearing model is sufficiently popular that it is rare to find a
textbook treatment of macroeconomics that omits this "new
classical" model of the aggregate economy.
One component of this aggregate economic model is a labor market where nominal wages are flexible. (1) This approach to the labor market
was developed by Lucas and Rapping (1969); in their model, it is assumed
that labor suppliers operate under incomplete information about the
aggregate price level, thereby raising the possibility that output
produced in the economy will vary with the level of price expectations.
(2) Despite its central role in explaining economic fluctuations in a
popular model of the economy, there is surprisingly little evidence
available in previous research testing the implications of this model of
the labor market. One objective of the present study is to provide some
empirical evidence on this market-clearing model of the labor market.
In carrying out such a test, it will be necessary to provide an
explanation for the nonstationary nature of labor market series, such as
real wages and employment. One possible explanation for this apparent
nonstationarity would be the technology shocks frequently used in the
real business cycle literature (e.g., Long and Plosser 1983), where it
has often been assumed that these shocks are I(1) unobservable
stochastic processes. Thus these shocks to the production function may
be used as a way of explaining why macroeconomic time series are also
I(1). A similar mechanism involves the possibly nonstochastic scalar preceding the aggregate production function. In the economic growth
literature, this magnitude, called the Solow residual, measures the
growth in aggregate output that cannot be explained by the growth of
quality-adjusted factor inputs in production. This residual is sometimes
thought to be measured by the stock of knowledge used by economic agents
(Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995, p. 351). Increases in the stock of
knowledge enable the aggregate economy to produce more goods and/or new
goods from quality-adjusted resource levels when knowledge increases. If
the stock of knowledge is nonstationary, then so, too, would be output
and other magnitudes in an aggregate economy. (4) Thus the nonstationary
nature of aggregate data can be explained by a nonstationary element of
the aggregate production function (whether stochastic or deterministic),
however that variable is interpreted.
If the sources of the apparent nonstationarity in macroeconomic
data are assumed to be unobservable I(1) stochastic processes, an
implication of this fact is that the inability to measure technology
shocks renders it impossible to test the implications of economic models
that would arise if these shocks could be measured. For example, if
technology shocks are I(1), then optimizing behavior by households and
firms will result in cointegrating relationships between technology
shocks and choice variables set by the public. If it were possible to
measure shocks to the production function, one could test for these
long-run cointegrating relationships and the parameters of these
cointegrating vectors could be estimated. (5) In addition, it is
desirable to explicitly incorporate technical change into economic
models, if it could indeed be measured, because doing so may result in
more reliable estimates of structural parameters of economic interest,
and it may permit improved tests of economic hypotheses. For example,
structural changes can impair tests for unit roots in time series and
there is a substantial body of literature which develops tests for unit
roots in the presence of structural breaks in economic data. (6)
In this article, it will be assumed that technology shocks or the
stock of knowledge are a function of utility patent data. These data
measure patents issued to individuals and firms, and because
technological progress is at least in part a consequence of new
knowledge available to the public as a result of research and
development activities, this seems a sensible measure of increments to
the stock of knowledge. These data series have been used in previous
work to study the extent to which expenditures on research and
development are related to patents. (7) Here patents will be used as the
motivating force for the nonstationary or I(1) characteristics of labor
services and real wages in the aggregate labor market. As a result,
estimates of the structural parameters from the labor market will be
obtained from the long-run relationships arising in the labor market
between real wages, labor services, and patents.
There is measurement error associated with using patents to measure
the stock of knowledge in an aggregate economy or to justify the I(1)
characteristics of labor market data. (8) For example, the model used in
this article presumes that new patents lead to measurable increases in
output produced, yet not all patents lead to commercially viable
products. In addition, there are changes in the stock of knowledge that
are unrelated to new ideas and patents. The stock of knowledge may
expand through learning-by-doing and there is evidence that this occurs
(see Lucas 1993, pp. 259 62, and the references cited there). Efficiency
increases of this sort would seem to have little to do with patent
flows. But if patents are correlated with the stock of knowledge, then
this measure of new ideas should be a sensible measure of the impact of
new knowledge on the industrial composition of aggregate economies. At
least some of the observed changes in industrial structure are related
to the invention of new ideas, leading to the birth and death of firms
and the reorganization of existing industries. But it may also be true
that changes in the organizational structure of industries may be caused
by forces unrelated to the development of new knowledge.
An equilibrium model of the labor market implies that, if the shock
to technology is I(1), there will be two cointegrating vectors in a
trivariate vector autoregression (VAR) for real wages, labor services,
and the technology shock, and this implication will be tested using
aggregate U.S. data. The cointegrating vectors from the labor market
will be explicitly derived, and it will be seen that estimating the
elements of these cointegrating vectors delivers exactly identified
estimates of three structural parameters from the optimization problem solved by the representative firm, conditional on an assumed value for
the discount rate. These parameters measure the severity of the training
or adjustment costs attached to the labor force, the speed of adjustment
of labor, and the degree of diminishing returns in production. The labor
market model is built on the assumptions of diminishing returns in
production and rising marginal adjustment costs for labor; given these
assumptions, the adjustment speed for labor is between zero and unity.
The empirical estimates will thus enable us to determine if these
assumptions are evident in labor market data.
Regarding the empirical results herein, there are reasons
(discussed later) suggesting that patents may be subject to a structural
break associated with changes in the legal system, so unit root tests
are applied to the patent series with and without endogenous breaks in
the series. It is found that the patent series is indeed I(1), whether
or not a structural break is permitted in the patent series. Aggregate
data provides consistent evidence that technology shocks are
cointegrated with real wages and labor services and there is a
substantial amount of evidence that there are two cointegrating vectors
in the data. However, full-sample estimates of the elements of the
cointegrating vectors and their implied estimates of structural
parameters provide relatively little support for this model of the labor
market. Qualitative parameter assumptions from the model are quite
different from estimated values of various structural parameters and the
magnitudes of estimated parameters often appear implausible. But there
are at least two regime changes in the sample (the formation of the
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries [OPEC] cartel in October
1973 and the policy regime change by the Federal Reserve System in
October 1979) that render parameter estimation problematic, and so
subsample estimates are investigated to see if there is evidence of
instability in the rank of the cointegrating matrix or in estimated
parameters. The evidence observed is that the number of cointegrating
vectors is robust to the choice of sample, despite the fact that a
reduction in sample size should reduce the power of cointegration tests,
but there is clear evidence of parameter instability. Substantial
differences in some parameter estimates are apparent over various
subsamples. Thus it seems clear that although one source of possible
instability in empirical work has been accounted for by the use of a
measure of the stock of knowledge, there seem to be other forms of
structural or regime changes that may still contaminate parameter
estimates.
Furthermore, in all subsamples but one, the predictions of the
model are not supported by the data. However there is one subsample
where the model provides a good description of the market for labor. In
the period prior to the formation of OPEC, estimated structural
parameters match up quite well with the assumptions of the model. The
estimated speed of adjustment for labor is high, an intuitively
appealing result, and other structural parameter estimates are found to
be qualitatively consistent with the assumptions made on the demand side
of the labor market: in addition, estimated parameters other than the
speed of adjustment seem to be of plausible magnitude. The evidence
suggests that new forms of knowledge, as measured by the stock of
patents, do not provide a complete description of the source of
nonstationarity evident in macroeconomic data subsequent to the
formation of the oil cartel.
The article is organized as follows. The next section provides a
discussion of the demand and supply sides of the labor market model. The
labor market error-correction VAR is derived there, and its time-series
properties will be discussed. The cointegrating matrix is derived, and
it will also be shown that the cointegrating matrix does not contain
parameters from the stochastic process obeyed by any unobservable shocks
in the model. Section III provides diagnostic statistics for the patent
data, including tests for unit roots with and without structural breaks
in the patent data, to discover if the patent data are an I(1) series.
This section also presents the estimates of the elements of the
cointegrating vectors and structural parameters of the model over the
entire sample and various subsamples. Section IV offers concluding
remarks.
II. A MODEL OF THE LABOR MARKET
In this section, an equilibrium model of a labor market will be
formulated. The model is a version of one described in Rossana (1998,
pp. 437M2). (9) Functional forms are used that permit the derivation of
an error-correction VAR in labor services, real wages, and the stock of
knowledge. The model presumes that wages clear the market, and it is
simplified so that its implications may be obtained with a minimum of
economic detail. For example, constants are omitted throughout, and the
household choice problem is simplified so that the dynamics evident in
the VAR will come only from the demand side of the market. The objective
of the analysis will be to derive the long-run relationships for the
three time series in the VAR, which will serve as the basis for the
empirical work reported later.
The Behavior of the Firm
The firm is assumed to solve the following cash flow maximization
problem.
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
In (1), [gamma] is the discount rate (0 < [gamma] < 1),
[[zeta].sup.d] is a technology shock to the firm's production
function, w is the real wage rate (the firm's output price is
normalized to unity), n refers to labor services, and [[alpha].sub.i]
> 0[for all]i. [E.sub.0] is a conditional expectation operator where
expectations are formed at time zero. The firm produces a nonstorable
output using a technology that is a quadratic form. Payments to labor
are given by the product of the real wage and the flow of labor services
used in production. The last term in the cash flow expression measures
the training costs attached to changes in the level of labor services.
Because the parameters [[alpha].sub.0] and [[alpha].sub.1] are assumed
positive, the firm has diminishing returns in production associated with
its use of labor services and costs of adjustment, or the training costs
of labor, rise at the margin. Because of these adjustment costs, the
firm will have an incentive to gradually adjust its labor usage in
response to shifts in the determinants of labor use in production (see
later discussion). Regarding the technology shock, [[zeta].sup.d], it
will be assumed that [[zeta].sup.d] ~ I(1). Further discussion about the
stochastic process obeyed by this shock to the production function will
be provided later.
The optimal choice of labor services in production leads to the
Euler equation,
(2) [gamma][[alpha].sub.1][E.sub.t][n.sub.t+1] - [[alpha].sub.0] +
[gamma](1 + [[alpha].sub.1])][n.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.1][n.sub.t-1]
= [w.sub.t] - [[zeta].sup.d.sub.t].
The firm is assumed to have contemporaneous and lagged information
at its disposal when choosing the optimal level of labor services at
each instant of time. Thus the expectation operator is applied only to
[n.sub.t+1]. Using standard methods, it may be shown that (2) implies
that the expected discounted marginal product of labor will be set equal
to the marginal cost of labor, where the latter includes the wage rate
and the marginal cost of training an additional unit of labor.
The Behavior of the Household
Household behavior is very simple. The optimization problem to be
solved is
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where c refers to consumption, n is labor supply, [[zeta].sup.s] is
a preference shock, and [[mu].sub.i] > 0[for all]i. The relationship
between the household's sources and uses of income is given by
[c.sub.t] = [w.sub.t][n.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] where [D.sub.t] refers to an
exogenous dividend stream (saving is assumed fixed and is thus ignored).
Eliminating consumption from (3) by replacing it with the income of the
household from its labor supply and dividends leads to the Euler
equation,
(4) [[mu].sub.0][w.sub.t] - [[zeta].sup.s.sub.t] -
[[mu].sub.1][n.sub.t] = 0.
Because there are no lags appearing in the household's
objective function, this optimality condition is simply a static one.
This condition merely implies that the household sets the marginal rate
of substitution between consumption and labor supply equal to the real
wage rate.
The Labor Market VAR
The labor market vector autoregression may be derived by using the
Euler equations for the firm and household. Use (4) to eliminate the
wage rate from (2). Suppressing the expectation operator for
convenience, the resulting expression is
[n.sub.t+1] - ([[mu].sub.0][[alpha].sub.1](1 + [gamma]) +
[[alpha].sub.0]] - [[mu].sub.1]/[gamma][[alpha].sub.1][[mu].sub.0])[n.sub.t]
+ [[gamma].sup.-1][n.sub.t-1] =
([[mu].sup.-1.sub.0][[zeta].sup.s.sub.t] -
[[zeta].sup.d.sub.t])/[gamma][[alpha].sub.1],
This equation may be factored to give
(1 - [[lambda].sub.1]L)(1 - [[lambda].sub.2]L)[n.sub.t+1] =
([[mu].sup.-1.sub.0][[zeta].sup.s.sub.t] -
[[zeta].sup.d.sub.t])/[gamma][[alpha].sub.1],
where [[lambda].sub.1] and [[lambda].sub.2] are eigenvalues (0 <
[[lambda].sub.1] < 1, [[lambda].sub.2] > 0), and L is the lag
operator. Reintroducing the expectation operator and solving forward
with the unstable root, [[lambda].sub.2], gives
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Expression (5) displays the well-known property that quasi-fixed
state variables are determined by all future sequences of exogenous
variables, which in this model are the shocks to household preferences
and the technology of the firm. The parameter [[lambda].sub.1] gives the
speed of adjustment to equilibrium for labor services. This parameter is
between zero and unity because there are costs of adjustment attached to
labor which rise at the margin (which follows if [[alpha].sub.1] >
0).
The optimal investment demand schedule in (5) contains the expected
levels of the two exogenous variables in the model. To derive the labor
market VAR, a decision must be made about the manner in which agents
forecast these discounted series of shocks in the expression. Agents
will be assumed to forecast these shocks using the Weiner-Kolmogorov
prediction formula (Sargent 1978, p. 304), and for the preference shock
[[zeta].sup.s.], this is
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where [theta](L) is a polynomial in the lag operator appearing in
the stochastic process for [[zeta].sup.s]. To complete the derivation of
the labor market VAR, assumptions must be made about the time-series
processes obeyed by the shocks in (5). For the shock to household
preferences, [[zeta].sup.s], it will be assumed that [[zeta].sup.s] ~
iid(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.s]). Applying (6) to the discounted infinite
series for this shock causes the discounted infinite series to reduce to
[[zeta].sup.s.sub.t]. For the shock to the firm's production
function, [[zeta].sup.d.sub.t], it will be assumed that this is an
observable driftless random walk (measured by the stock of patents).
(10)
Applying the Weiner-Kolmogorov prediction formula yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Using the stochastic process for each shock and (6), I obtain
(7) [n.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.1][n.sub.t-1] +
[[[lambda].sub.1]/[[alpha].sub.1](1 -
[gamma][[lambda].sub.1])][[zeta].sup.d.sub.t] -
[[lambda].sub.1]/[[alpha].sub.1][[mu].sub.0]][[zeta].sup.s.sub.t],]
an expression that is one part of the labor market VAR.
The next step in constructing the VAR for the labor market is to
derive an expression for real wages. Using the Euler equations for the
firm and household and a procedure similar to the derivation of(5), I
can obtain the following expression for the real wage:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Using this result and (6) yields
(8) [w.sub.t] = -[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1] (1 + [gamma][1 -
[[lambda].sub.1]])][n.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.1][n.sub.t-1] + [(1 -
[gamma][[lambda].sub.1].sup.-1][[zeta].sup.d.sub.t] -
[gamma][[lambda].sub.1][[mu].sup.-1.sub.0][[zeta].sup.s.sub.t].
Finally, using (7)-(8) and the stochastic process for the
technology shock, I obtain the VAR for the labor market which can be
written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where [[kappa].sub.1t] = -[[lambda].sub.1][([[alpha].sub.1]
[[mu].sub.0]).sup.-1], [[kappa].sub.2t] = - [gamma][[lambda].sub.1
[([[alpha].sub.1][[mu].sub.0]).sup.-1][[zeta].sup.s.sub.t], and
[[kappa].sub.3t] is assumed to be a serially uncorrelated, iid
disturbance from the stochastic process obeyed by [[zeta].sup.d.sub.t].
It is further assumed that [[zeta].sup.s.sub.t] and [[kappa].sub.3t] are
mutually uncorrelated. Using the definitions
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
and [[??].sub.it] = [[GAMMA].sup.-1][[kappa].sub.it], this VAR may
be rewritten in its error-correction form as
(9) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where [[OMEGA].sub. = [[lambda].sub.1][[alpha].sub.0] -
[[alpha].sub.1] (1 - [gamma][[lambda]s.ub.1])(1 - [[lambda].sub.1]), and
[[OMEGA].sub.2] = 1/[[alpha].sub.1](1 - [gamma][[lambda].sub.1]) > 0.
It is clear that the matrix of coefficients attached to the lagged
levels of the series in the trivariate VAR has reduced rank. (11) The
time-series system is therefore cointegrated; as a result, the matrix of
coefficients preceding the lagged levels of time series can be written
as [PI] = [alpha][beta]' where [alpha] is known as the adjustment
matrix and [beta] is the cointegrating matrix.
The cointegrating matrix may be normalized by setting some of its
elements equal to unity, and this normalization causes the elements of
the adjustment matrix to have useful economic content (i.e., the
elements of the adjustment matrix contain parameters of economic
interest as a consequence of this normalizing transformation of the
cointegrating matrix). In optimizing models with one state variable,
such a normalization is arbitrary on statistical grounds, but on
economic grounds it only makes sense to attach a unit coefficient to the
state variable. Here, normalization is arbitrary on economic and
statistical grounds. The choice of normalizing transformation is a
matter of convenience, and it is easily shown that normalization has no
impact on the information revealed by estimates of the cointegrating
vectors. (12)
It is convenient to set the coefficients attached to labor services
to unity. Doing so gives the following adjustment and cointegrating
matrices:
(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Having obtained these matrices, one could proceed to estimate their
elements using any of the available estimation methods. Before doing so,
it is instructive to consider the determinants of the lag length in (9).
This lag length is just one with no lagged difference terms
appearing in (9), and this single lag is a consequence of assuming, in
the typical manner, that there are costs of adjustment attached to labor
services. (13) Estimation of this VAR with data at monthly frequency, as
will be done shortly, will almost certainly yield lag lengths exceeding
one with statistically significant lagged difference terms. The question
then arises as to how one might rationalize the discrepancy between the
lag length implied by the model and the lag length uncovered empirically
when this VAR is estimated. In the context of this model, two
possibilities can be given to explain these empirical lag lengths.
One is that there may be lagged difference terms in the time-series
process obeyed by the technology shock experienced by the firm.
Univariate methods are used below to test this series for unit roots,
and it was found that the lag length for this series was greater than
one. A second possibility is that the unobservable shock to household
preferences may obey a time-series process containing autoregressive
terms, thereby displaying serial persistence. For example, suppose that
the household preference shock obeys the stochastic process
[phi](L)[[zeta].sup.s.sub.t] = [[kappa].sub.4t] where [phi](L) is a
finite-order polynomial in the lag operator with all of its roots
outside the unit circle and [[kappa].sub.4t] is an lid error term with
mean zero and constant variance. Then it may be shown that the
adjustment matrix will be
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
illustrating the fact that the adjustment matrix now contains both
structural parameters and parameters from the autoregressive polynomial
attached to the shock to household preferences. Thus estimation of the
elements of the adjustment matrix does not directly yield estimates of
structural parameters. But the cointegrating matrix does not contain the
parameters in [phi](L), so this matrix can be estimated even when long
lags are found in the estimated VAR, thereby providing estimates of
structural parameters of interest. (14) In the context of the model, the
only way to explain long lags for real wages and labor services within
the estimated VAR is that preference shocks are serially correlated and
lags beyond one are apparent in the estimated VAR (see later
discussion). As a result, estimates of the elements of the adjustment
matrix will not be given because these estimates would not deliver
information on structural parameters of economic interest.
Finally, conditional on an assumed value for the discount rate,
three structural parameters ([[lambda].sub.1], [[alpha].sub.0],
[[alpha].sub.1]) are exactly identified from estimation of the elements
of the cointegrating matrix so that an estimate of this parameter matrix
yields estimates of these underlying structural parameters from the
demand side of the labor market. The parameter [[alpha].sub.0]
determines if there are diminishing returns in production associated
with the use of labor. This parameter is important in part for its role
in determining the sufficiency of intertemporal optimality criteria
because sufficiency depends on the curvature of the technology and other
functions within the economic model. The parameter [[alpha].sub.1]
determines if there is partial adjustment of labor services in
production for adjustment costs must rise at the margin to provide an
incentive for the firm to adjust its labor inputs slowly over time. If
there are adjustment costs rising at the margin, then [[lambda].sub.1]
must lie between zero and unity because partial adjustment of the labor
force is optimal for the firm when adjustment costs rise at the margin.
Thus, if the model is a good description of the labor market, the
estimated values of these latter two parameters should be consistent; a
finding of a positive estimated value for [[alpha].sub.1] should be
associated with a value of [[lambda].sub.1], reflecting partial
adjustment of the labor force in each period.
III. TESTING THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE LABOR MARKET MODEL
Data and Tests for Unit Roots
The data used to test the labor market model were obtained from two
U.S. government agencies, and these data are publicly available. Labor
services are measured by man-hours of production workers in the private
sector. Data on average weekly hours and the number of production
workers were obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The same
agency provided the data on average hourly earnings of production
workers and the Consumer Price Index for all urban workers, series used
to construct a measure of the real wage rate. Data on utility patents
issued was provided by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office. The data
are unadjusted for seasonality, they are measured in natural logs at
monthly frequency, and they cover the period 1964:1 to 1998:12.
The stock of knowledge will be measured by the cumulative sum of
patents granted by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office. (15)
If knowledge does not depreciate and if the initial stock of
patents is zero, then knowledge in any time period is given by
k(t) = [t.summation over([tau]=1)]p([tau]),
where k denotes the stock of knowledge and p prefers to the flow of
patents. The empirical work to follow uses the stock of knowledge in the
estimated VAR but the analysis of this section examines the time series
characteristics of the flow of patents. The reason for doing so is that
there is reason to believe (see note 18) that there has been a
structural change in the environment in which patents are granted. This
structural instability is most easily seen in the patent flow series
(see Figure 1) and is obscured in the stock series because the
cumulative sum of the patent flow series yields a stock series that is
very smooth. Because a unit root cannot be rejected in either the stock
or flow series using standard Dickey-Fuller tests (more will be said
later on unit root testing of the stock data), it is useful to use the
flow series in this context because it permits us to address the
possible effects of structural change on tests for unit roots.
The utility patent data measures the monthly flow of patents issued
in the United States; it includes patents issued to individuals and
corporations, both foreign and domestic. Patents must be filed in
whatever country individuals or firms wish to receive patent protection.
The industrial structure in the United States can be affected by new
ideas developed domestically or in foreign countries, so it does not
seem reasonable to distinguish between foreign and domestic patents.
(16)This monthly patent data (not measured in logs) has a sample mean of
about 6245, with a standard error of approximately 1735. Figure 1
contains a plot of this patent data in natural logs over the estimation
period. It seems clear on the basis of this graph that the series does
not have a constant mean; it appears that the last decade has seen
patents granted per year at an increasing rate as compared to earlier
years in the sample Indeed, an unprecedented increase in the rate at
which patents are issued has been documented elsewhere (see Kortum and
Lerner 1998). (17)
Test results, indicating that real wages and labor services are
I(1), may be found elsewhere. (18) The patent data must be tested for
nonstationarity. The presence of a unit root in this patent data is the
motivating force that explains the presence of unit roots in real wages
and labor services. Table 1 provides a variety of diagnostic statistics
that reveal information on the stationarity of the data. The table
contains sample autocorrelations and partial autocorrelations, denoted
respectively by [[rho].sub.l] and [r.sub.l] where l denotes lag length.
The table contains Bartlett (1946) standard errors for the sample
autocorrelations, derived from
var([[rho].sub.l]) = [T.sup.-1] [1+2[summation
over(j<l)][[rho].sup.2.sub.j],
where the sample size is denoted by T(T = 420). The standard error
for the partial autocorrelations is [T.sup.-1/2]. Ljung and Box (1978)
Q-statistics are also provided. Autocorrelations and partial
autocorrelations are contained in Table 1 for the patent data in levels
and for first and second differences of the data.
These statistics suggest that the levels data are nonstationary
because the autocorrelations are more than two standard errors away from
zero, even at 12 lags. This is also true when the data are differenced
once and even twice. The Q-statistics decisively reject the null
hypothesis that all 12 sample autocorrelations are zero. Similarly, the
partial autocorrelations are more than two standard errors away from
zero at all lags, irrespective of the degree of differencing. Similar
results can be observed at lag lengths considerably beyond 12. Thus I
would conclude from these diagnostic statistics that the patent data are
nonstationary, containing at least one unit root and possibly more.
Unit root tests must be applied to the patent data. In view of the
results from Table 1, it is reasonable to test for more than one unit
root in the data, especially because the methods in Johansen (1991) will
be used later, and these procedures are inappropriate to data that are
I(2). Consequently, the test of Dickey and Pantula (1987) will be used.
Their test requires estimating
(11) (1 - L)[y.sub.t] = [[theta].sub.0] +
[[theta].sub.1][y.sub.t-1] + [l.summation over (i=1)] [[zeta].sub.i] (1
- L)[y.sub.t-i] + [[phi].sub.t]
Assuming a maximum of three unit roots in the patent series, the
procedure requires testing sequentially for fewer unit roots until we
can no longer reject the null hypothesis [H.sub.0]:[[theta].sub.1] = 0.
Begin by defining [y.sub.t] to be the second difference of the patent
series and estimate (11), thereby testing for a third unit root. If the
null hypothesis is rejected using the t-statistic on [[theta].sub.1] and
the critical values for the [[tau].sub.[micro]] statistic in Fuller
(1976, p. 371), then repeat the test with [y.sub.t] as the first
difference of the patent series and so on. Table 1 reports the results
of these tests. The lag length l must be chosen and it was selected by
using the BIC criterion of Schwarz (1978). (19) This criterion selects l
= 9. At the 1% level, the test results indicate that three and two unit
roots are rejected by the data but one unit root cannot be rejected,
even at the 10% level. Thus I conclude, subject to one qualification,
that the patent data are I(1). (20)
That qualification concerns the possibility of structural breaks in
the patent data. There has been a considerable amount of research effort
devoted to the issue of tests for unit roots in the presence of
structural breaks. Perron (1989) argued that time series may be I(0),
having structural breaks either in their levels or growth rates, and
that time series may appear to be I(1), even if they are in fact I(0),
when using conventional Dickey-Fuller tests if these structural breaks
are ignored. Perron (1989) provides evidence that macroeconomic time
series appear to have these structural breaks and may be stationary,
given these exogenous breaks. His work uses exogenous breakpoints, and
there have been a number of studies developing tests for unit roots when
breakpoints are unknown, such as the test of Zivot and Andrews (1992).
It is reasonable to ask if these tests should be applied to the patent
data.
The analysis of section II treats technology shocks in the manner
of much of the economic growth literature, namely, that technical
progress is of the disembodied, exogenous type, unrelated to economic
events. Clearly this is not the case. New products are frequently
developed in response to movements in relative prices or perceived
profit opportunities. For example, it is plausible to argue that
energy-efficient products were developed in response to the increase in
the relative price of oil in October 1973. Research and development
activities leading to those new products may have generated new patents.
Thus the formation of the OPEC cartel could be viewed as a structural
break in the patent series. In addition, Kortum and Lerner (1998)
document institutional changes in the legal system that may have
increased the rate at which patents are issued. For these reasons, it
seems a good idea to apply unit root tests that permit the possibility
of a structural break in the patent data to determine if the series is
I(1) even if allowance is made for a structural break in the series. The
test of Zivot and Andrews (1992) (hereafter Z-A) will be used for this
purpose.
Structural breaks may occur in either the levels or growth rates of
a time series. Inspection of Figure 1 does not suggest any distinct
changes in the level of the patent series, but there seems to be the
possibility of a growth rate change in the neighborhood of 1984.
Therefore I use the version of the Z-A test that allows for a structural
break in the growth rate of the series that is being tested for unit
roots. To carry out this test, it is necessary to estimate
(12) [y.sub.t] = [[theta].sub.0] + [[theta].sub.1]t +
[[theta].sub.2][DT.sub.t]([omega]) + [[theta].sub.3][y.sub.t-1] +
[l.summation over (i=1)] [[zeta].sub.i](1 - L)[y.sub.t-i] +
[[phi].sub.t]
The circumflex indicates that a magnitude corresponds to the
estimated break fraction [omega]([omega] = [T.sub.B]|T where [T.sub.B]
refers to the breakpoint in the data. In (12), if [DT.sub.t]([omega]) =
t - T[omega] if t > T[omega], 0 otherwise. The testing strategy
proposed by Z-A involves using a conventional t-statistic to test
[H.sub.0]:[[theta].sub.3] = 1, choosing the breakpoint that yields a
value of the test statistic that is least favorable to the null
hypothesis. At each value of the break fraction [omega], the lag length
l must be chosen. Here I follow the model specification procedure used
by Perron (1989) and Z-A. Beginning with the maximum lag [l.sub.max] =
36 and working backward, choose the first value of l such that the
t-statistic on [[zeta].sub.1] is greater than or equal to 1.6 and where
the t-statistic on [[zeta].sub.m] for m < l was less than 1.6. (21)
Table 1 reports the statistic required for this test. The breakpoint,
chosen by the selection procedure, is 1982:6, the year in which
legislation was passed that is thought to have had a substantial impact
on the patent approval process. (22) Using critical values provided by
Z-A (p. 257), a unit root cannot be rejected at the 10% significance
level. Thus the patent series is I(1), whether or not I allow for the
possibility of structural change. Tests for cointegration may now be
conducted.
Cointegration Tests and Estimated Cointegrating Vectors
The maximal eigenvalue statistic of Johansen (1991) is used to test
for cointegration. (23) Critical values for the test are taken from
Hansen and Juselius (1995). The test statistic is adjusted by the
small-sample correction factor found in Boswijk and Franses (1992, 372).
(24) Centered seasonal dummies were included in the estimated VAR
because none of the time series in the system have been adjusted for
seasonality (real wages, for example, clearly contain seasonal
fluctuations due to the evident seasonal component in the Consumer Price
Index). Intercepts are included in each cointegrating vector, but for
the sake of brevity, estimates of these parameters are not provided.
(25) The lag length of the VAR must be determined prior to carrying out
the tests, and using the BIC criterion, this lag length was determined
to be l=4. This lag length is used in all estimated equations to follow.
The full-sample estimates suggest that it may be informative to
examine subsample parameter estimates. The subsamples contained in Table
2 were chosen because they have been repeatedly used in studies
concerned about the effects of structural change on parameter estimation
methods or hypothesis tests. (26) The first subsample concerns the
formation of the OPEC cartel in October 1973, raising the relative price
of energy, and it is one event that has been widely used in studies on
the effects of structural change. The second subsample is related to the
October 1979 change in the manner of conducting monetary policy, an
example of a monetary policy regime change. At this time, the Federal
Reserve switched from pegging the Federal Funds interest rate to a
policy of reserve targeting, resulting in more variability in interest
rates. Both of these break points will be used in examining the issue of
rank instability in the cointegrating matrix and parameter instability
in the estimated cointegrating vectors. Table 2 reports the results from
the cointegration tests over the entire sample and for these two
selected breakpoints in the data.
Let r denote the number of cointegrating vectors. The maximal
eigenvalue test is a test of [H.sub.0]: r = [r.sub.0] against [H.sub.A]:
r = [r.sub.0] + 1 and I begin with [r.sub.0] = 0, testing sequentially
until the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. For the entire data
sample, the null that r = 0 can be rejected at the 90%, significance
level. One cointegrating vector is also rejected by the test statistic
at the same significance level. As for the presence of two cointegrating
vectors, the null cannot be rejected at the 90% level in the entire
sample. Thus it seems to be the case that the data provide fairly strong
support for the idea that endogenous labor market variables are
cointegrated with unit root technology shocks, measured here by the
stock of patents. This aspect of the evidence provides support for this
model of the labor market.
Estimates of the elements of the two cointegrating vectors evident
in the data are given in Table 2 using the maximum likelihood estimator
provided in Johansen (1991). As stated earlier, normalization of the
cointegrating vectors is arbitrary in the context of a model of the
labor market, but this choice has no impact on the information about
structural parameters that can be obtained from estimated elements of
the cointegrating vectors. In what follows, parameters associated with
labor services will be normalized to unity. For convenience, the
cointegrating matrix from (10) is restated here, conditional on this
normalizing transformation.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In the above matrix, [[lambda].sub.1] is the parameter that may be
used to infer the speed at which labor services approach their
equilibrium level, [[omega].sub.1] = [[lambda].sub.1][[alpha].sub.0] -
[[alpha].sub.1] (1 - [gamma][[lambda].sub.1]) (1 - [[lambda].sub.1]),
and [[omega].sub.2] = 1/[[alpha].sub.1](1 - [gamma][[lambda].sub.1])
> 0. Inspection of these results shows that once the elements of the
cointegrating vectors are estimated, it is possible to uniquely recover
estimates of the structural parameters ([[lambda].sub.1],
[[alpha].sub.0], [[alpha].sub.]), given a value for the discount rate
[gamma]. It will be assumed that the discount rate is 2% per year,
converted to a monthly value. The precise value for the discount rate
can be varied with little effect.
Inspection of the results in Table 2 reveals that full sample
estimates of the cointegrating vectors provide little support for this
equilibrium model of the labor market. Among the parameters where
qualitative predictions arise from the model, only the estimated value
of [[alpha].sub.0] has the qualitative sign assumed in the labor market
model (it implies that there are diminishing returns in production), but
its magnitude is implausibly large. The estimated value of
[[alpha].sub.1] implies that there are costs of adjustment that decline
at the margin, a result implying that there is no well-defined finite investment demand schedule for labor. The estimated value of
[[lambda].sub.1] is particularly poor, with a negative value that is
smaller than -1. In the presence of adjustment costs, this parameter is
expected to be positive and lie between zero and unity. Overall these
parameter estimates provide little support for an equilibrium model of
the labor market. But a difficulty with these results is that there are
at least two structural regime changes in the sample, rendering
hypothesis testing and parameter estimation problematic. For this
reason, subsample estimates using these two breakpoints will now be
examined.
Across subsamples of the data, there could be changes in the number
of cointegrating vectors apparent in the data and/or there may be
changes in parameter values contained within the cointegrating vectors.
The Johansen (1991) test was applied to all of the subsamples with the
appropriate correction factor applied to the test statistics. The
results consistently show that there are two cointegrating vectors in
all subsamples. Thus there is no evidence of changes in the number of
cointegrating vectors in the VAR in any subsample, despite the presumed
loss of power in the test due to declining sample size, which could
conceivably alter the implications of the test statistic. Rank
instability in the cointegrating matrix does not seem to be a major
concern in these results.
However the subsample results do provide striking evidence of
substantial changes in parameter estimates in various subsamples.
Consider estimates of the parameter [[lambda].sub.1], the parameter that
can be used to infer the speed of adjustment for labor. This parameter
is between zero and unity in the model of the labor market, and this is
found to be the case for the subsample preceding the formation of the
OPEC cartel. This parameter estimate is particularly plausible, for it
implies that labor is adjusted relatively rapidly to its equilibrium
level, a result that is intuitively appealing because the marginal
training costs of labor should be much lower than marginal installation
costs attached to quasi-fixed inputs, such as capital goods. (27) But
note how different the estimates of this parameter are within other
subsamples. For example, the period subsequent to the formation of the
OPEC cartel yields an estimate that is very strange. The estimated value
is negative, contrary to the labor market model, and it is of enormous
size and thus totally implausible. In other subsamples, we observe
equally different results. Prior to the policy regime change by the
Federal Reserve, the estimated value of this parameter implies very
rapid adjustment of labor to its equilibrium level within the month.
Adjustment is complete within the month. The data subsequent to the
regime change by the Fed produces another parameter estimate of no
intuitive appeal; the parameter estimate is far above unity, and it
implies unstable behavior in the market for labor. Viewed from the
perspective of this parameter estimate, an equilibrium model of the
labor market provides a good description of the aggregate U.S. labor
market only in one historical period, namely, that preceding the
formation of OPEC.
Much the same story is observed in other parameter estimates. The
parameters [[alpha].sub.0] and [[alpha].sub.1] are structural parameters
from the optimization problem solved by the firm. These parameters are
assumed positive in the model so that the firm's technology
displays diminishing returns to labor services and to ensure that there
are costs of adjustment attached to labor that rise at the margin.
Comparing subsample results, estimated values of these parameters often
vary enormously. Estimates of [[alpha].sub.0] are consistent in the
sense that in three of four subsamples the estimated value for this
parameter is qualitatively consistent with the assumption of diminishing
returns in production. But the subsample results reveal enormous
fluctuations in the estimated magnitude of this parameter. Over the
entire sample and in the subsample after the formation of OPEC,
estimates of this parameter are implausibly large. Regarding estimates
of [[alpha].sub.1], we observe estimates that are often qualitatively
different from what is assumed in the labor model (note the subsamples
before and after the period of the Federal Reserve policy regime change)
or they have estimated values of enormous size (see the period prior to
the Fed policy change for the most extreme example) and thus offer
little economic appeal. But prior to the formation of the OPEC cartel,
the estimated values of these parameters are qualitatively consistent
with the labor market model. Strictly speaking, it is only prior to the
OPEC shock that this model is valid because it is only in this period
when the estimated value of [[alpha].sub.1] is consistent with
adjustment costs rising at the margin. Elsewhere, training costs are
falling at the margin so that labor should not be regarded as
quasi-fixed. Rather, it should be assumed to be a variable factor input
in production. Overall, these parameter estimates provide little support
for an equilibrium view of the aggregate labor market, but once again,
that conclusion seems to be conditional on the choice of the data
sample.
There is also the possibility of model misspecification here. As
already stated, the labor market model is constructed so that the
dynamics in the labor market come entirely from labor demand. This
occurs because the labor supply optimization model had no lags appearing
in the objective function used by the household. That simplification
does prevent supply-side parameters, contained in the household's
objective function, from appearing in the estimated VAR, and this
omission may have a role to play in the empirical performance of this
labor market model.
As already stated, the period prior to the formation of OPEC is the
only subsample where the model is found to be valid because it is the
only in this sample data where we find that there are diminishing
returns in production ([[alpha].sub.0] > 0), costs of adjustment rise
at the margin ([[alpha].sub.1] > 0), and where the speed of
adjustment for labor is empirically found within the bounds implied by
the model (0 < [[lambda].sub.1] < 1). It is interesting to note
that the adjustment cost literature was developed in the 1960s as an
attempt to explain the serial persistence in investment data, and the
evidence in this article indicates that this is indeed a plausible way
to explain data up through the early 1970s. It is also the subsample
closest to the time period originally used by Lucas and Rapping (1969),
who first advocated a market-clearing model of the labor market.
Furthermore, this subsample data excludes the period of the 1980s, a
period when the personal computer was developed and when there were many
reorganizations of industries due to mergers and acquisitions. (28) It
also excludes the acceleration in technical progress in the 1990s as
documented by Basu et al. (2001).
This subsample also excludes any innovations in technology that
arose in response to the increase in the relative price of oil. One way
to interpret the subsample findings is that the patent data ceases to be
an adequate measure of technical progress at some point in the data
sample, possibly because it is a poor measure of technical progress in
relation to the OPEC cartel and the industrial reorganizations of the
1980s.
To summarize, the empirical results provide support for the idea
that I(1) technology shocks are at least one reason why economic time
series are also I(1) and that these technology shocks are cointegrated
with choice variables set by economic agents. But it also evident that
there is substantial parameter variability in the data, which may be due
to other forms of structural change that are not adequately captured by
increments to the stock of knowledge.
IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS
New classical models of the economy are frequently used in
macroeconomic research, and a component of these models is a labor
market where money wages are flexible. There is little evidence testing
this model of the labor market, and one purpose of this article is to
provide some empirical evidence on the suitability of this model as a
description of the aggregate U.S. labor market.
In doing this test, one issue that must be confronted is the
nonstationary nature of labor market time series, and an explanation
must be provided for this nonstationarity. Technology shocks are often a
component of macroeconomic models, and these shocks are frequently
assumed to be unobservable I(1) stochastic processes. Although this
assumption does explain why other economic magnitudes are I(1), a
consequence is that it is impossible to test economic hypotheses that
could be tested if shocks to the production function could be measured.
However one possible interpretation of these shocks is that they are
measured by the stock of knowledge available to the public, so that
increases in knowledge enable the economy to produce more and/or new
goods from a given resource base. Under this interpretation, there is a
measure of new knowledge that can be used for testing economic
hypotheses.
In this article, increments to the stock of knowledge are assumed
to be measurable by the number of utility patents granted by the U.S.
government. Patents are a reasonable measure of innovations that lead to
new products in the market and, if patents are I(1), then economic
theory implies that they will be cointegrated with choice variables set
by firms and households. Within an equilibrium model of a labor market,
this exogenous nonstationary process will be the cause of the apparent
unit roots in labor market series, such as labor services and real
wages. It is shown that an error-correction VAR for labor services, real
wages, and the technology shock will arise in this market, and there
will be two cointegrating vectors within the cointegrating matrix
describing the long-run relationship between the endogenous labor market
series (labor services and real wages) and the exogenous I(1) process
measured by the stock of utility patents. This implication is tested
using aggregate U.S. labor market series. Unit root tests are applied to
patent data and the series is found to be I(1), whether or not an
endogenous structural break is allowed in the patent series. There is a
substantial body of evidence provided that there are two cointegrating
vectors in a trivariate time-series system containing man-hours, real
wages, and patents issued.
Estimation of the cointegrating vectors permits estimation of
structural parameters arising from the demand side of the labor market,
given an assumed value for the real interest rate. One of these
parameters determines whether there are training costs attached to labor
services and how severe these costs are to the firm. Parameter estimates
provide little support for this model of the labor market over the
entire data sample, but there are at least two regime changes in the
sample data (the formation of the OPEC cartel and the switch in
operating procedures by the Federal Reserve) that may account for the
poor performance of the model. Subsample estimates using these
structural breakpoints are examined. The number of cointegrating vectors
apparent in the data is found to be quite robust to the data sample
chosen, but substantial differences in estimated structural parameters
are observed in different subsamples. One subsample (prior to October
1973) provides strong empirical support for the market-clearing model.
The performance of the model deteriorates after the early 1970s.
Thus it may be useful to consider extensions to the analysis that might
improve the performance of the model. One possible extension would be to
assume that producers use intermediate materials, such as energy, in the
production of output, thereby incorporating energy prices into the VAR
arising in the labor market. This extension would have the advantage of
explicitly incorporating the relative price of energy, measuring the
effects of the formation of the OPEC cartel, directly into the labor
market model. A second possible extension would be to permit labor
market dynamics to emerge from the labor supply decision by allowing
lagged labor supply to enter into the utility maximization of the
household. Although these extensions may be attractive on theoretical
grounds, they will also introduce additional structural parameters into
the cointegrating matrix, thus complicating the identification of
structural parameters from estimation of the elements of the
cointegrating vectors. These extensions are left for future
investigation.
ABBREVIATIONS
VAR: Vector Autoregression
OPEC: Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
TABLE 1
Diagnostic Statistics for Utility Patent Data
Autocorrelations
[[rho].sub.1] [[rho].sub.2] [[rho].sub.3]
d = 0 0.698 0.676 0.722
SE 0.049 0.069 0.083
d = 1 -0.491 -0.100 0.318
SE 0.049 0.060 0.060
d = 2 -0.628 -0.127 0.346
SE 0.049 0.065 0.065
Partial autocorrelations
[r.sub.1] [r.sub.2] [r.sub.3]
d = 0 0.698 0.369 0.376
d = 1 -0.491 -0.449 0.045
d = 2 -0.628 -0.673 -0.273
SE 0.049 0.049 0.049
Tests for unit roots without structural breaks
[H.sub.0] d = 3 -13.369 *
Test for a unit root with a structural break
Autocorrelations
[[rho].sub.4] [[rho].sub.5] [[rho].sub.6] [[rho].sub.7]
d = 0 0.574 0.602 0.611 0.505
SE 0.097 0.105 0.113 0.120
d = 1 -0.292 0.038 0.177 -0.258
SE 0.064 0.067 0.067 0.068
d = 2 -0.315 0.061 0.195 -0.252
SE 0.070 0.073 0.073 0.074
Partial autocorrelations
[r.sub.4] [r.sub.5] [r.sub.6] [r.sub.7]
d = 0 -0.114 0.113 0.105 -0.061
d = 1 -0.152 -0.152 0.006 -0.146
d = 2 -0.229 -0.308 -0.111 -0.072
SE 0.049 0.049 0.049 0.049
Tests for unit roots without structural breaks
[H.sub.0]: d = 2 -8.881 *
Test for a unit root with a structural break
[H.sub.0]: d = 1 -2.509
Autocorrelations
[[rho].sub.8] [[rho].sub.9] [[rho].sub.10]
d = 0 0.556 0.579 0.442
SE 0.125 0.131 0.137
d = 1 0.061 0.260 -0.350
SE 0.070 0.071 0.073
d = 2 0.037 0.274 -0.364
SE 0.076 0.076 0.079
Partial autocorrelations
[r.sub.8] [r.sub.9] [r.sub.10]
d = 0 0.097 0.155 -0.174
d = 1 -0.204 0.145 -0.087
d = 2 -0.349 -0.050 -0.021
SE 0.049 0.049 0.049
Tests for unit roots without structural breaks
[H.sub.0]: d = 1
Test for a unit root with a structural break
Autocorrelations
[[rho].sub.11] [[rho].sub.12] Q(12)
d = 0 0.519 0.527 1784.3
SE 0.140 0.145
d = 1 0.123 0.198 334.44
SE 0.077 0.077
d = 2 0.132 0.209 420.08
SE 0.083 0.083
Partial autocorrelations
[r.sub.11] [r.sub.12]
d = 0 0.087 0.107
d = 1 -0.128 0.083
d = 2 -0.197 0.005
SE 0.049 0.049
Tests for unit roots without structural breaks
-1.628
Test for a unit root with a structural break
N.B. Standard errors are denoted by SE, d refer to the degree of
differencing, and Q(12) is the statistic of Ljung and Box (1978)
testing the null that all 12 autocorrelations are zero. Tests for
unit roots with no structural breaks are the test statistics proposed
by Dickey and Pantula (1987). The unit root test with a structural
break is that of Zivot and Andrews (1992). An asterisk (*) indicates
rejection of the null hypothes at the 1% level.
TABLE 2
Cointegration Tests and Estimated Cointegrating Vectors
1964:1-1998:12 1964:1-1973:9
Cointegration test statistics
[H.sub.0]: r = 0 35.47 [H.sub.0]: r = 0 34.42
[H.sub.0]: r = 1 14.62 [H.sub.0]: r = 1 21.14
[H.sub.0]: r = 2 3.45 * [H.sub.0]: r = 2 6.82 *
Parameter estimates
[[OMEGA].sub.1] -0.474 [[OMEGA].sub.1] -0.122
[[OMEGA].sub.2] -0.642 [[OMEGA].sub.2] 1.032
[[alpha].sub.0] 41.840 [[alpha].sub.0] 0.052
[[alpha].sub.1] -1.547 [[alpha].sub.1] 0.968
[[lambda].sub.1] -4.570 [[lambda].sub.1] 0.066
1973:10-1998:12 1964:1-1979:9
Cointegration test statistics
[H.sub.0]: r = 0 21.28 [H.sub.0]: r = 0 23.99
[H.sub.0]: r = 1 21.17 [H.sub.0]: r = 1 11.62
[H.sub.0]: r = 2 3.06 * [H.sub.0]: r = 2 3.57 *
Parameter estimates
[[OMEGA].sub.1] -1.236 [[OMEGA].sub.1] 1.922
[[OMEGA].sub.2] -0.543 [[OMEGA].sub.2] -0.228
[[alpha].sub.0] 2578.5 [[alpha].sub.0] 0.061
[[alpha].sub.1] -1.736 [[alpha].sub.1] -4.389
[[lambda].sub.1] -36.59 [[lambda].sub.1] -0.023
1979:10-1998:12
Cointegration test statistics
[H.sub.0]: r = 0 25.46
[H.sub.0]: r = 1 10.29
[H.sub.0]: r = 2 2.29 *
Parameter estimates
[[OMEGA].sub.1] -1.684
[[OMEGA].sub.2] -0.514
[[alpha].sub.0] -0.746
[[alpha].sub.1] -1.951
[[lambda].sub.1] 1.630
The maximal eigenvalue test statistic for cointegration, as well as
the maximum likelihood estimator for cointegrating vectors, are
obtained from Johansen (1991). Test statistics are adjusted by the
correction factor in Boswijk and Franses (1992). An asterisk (*)
indicates that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected at the 90%
significance level.
(1.) See McCallum (I980, p. 720) for an explicit derivation showing
that the famed Lucas supply function, a critical component of rational
expectations models, can be derived from a labor market with flexible
wages when labor suppliers operate under incomplete information about
the price level.
(2.) Variants of this model may be found in Sargent (1978, pp. 472
78), Kennan (1988), and Rossana (1998). Many would be skeptical that
market clearing occurs in the labor market, but there is some evidence
showing that nominal wages are more flexible than might be commonly
believed. See McLaughlin (1994) for evidence on money wage flexibility.
(3.) Kennan (1988) provides estimates of structural parameters
arising from this type of labor market model but does not address the
issue of unit roots in labor market data. The present study will provide
estimates of long-run equilibrium relationships obeyed by real wages and
employment using an explicit measure of technical progress as the source
of the unit roots in the labor market.
(4.) A third possibility would be mergers and acquisitions of
firms, activities that would cause permanent changes in the levels of
factor inputs used in production.
(5.) If there are I(l) unobservable shocks in economic models,
these shocks would appear in the disturbance vector of any VAR derived
from an economic model containing these shocks (thus the covariance
matrix for such a model would no longer be finite as the sample size
tends to infinity). As a result, linear combinations of observable
economic magnitudes would not be I(0). Rather they would be I(1). See
Rossana (1995, p. 10) for more on this point.
(6.) See Perron (1989), Zivot and Andrews (1992), and other studies
in the July 1992 issue of the Journal of Business & Economic
Statistics for examples of research dealing with statistical inference in the presence of structural change.
(7.) See Griliches (1990) for further discussion of patent data and
its uses. In addition, Gardner and Joutz (1996) use patent data in a
model of economic growth.
(8.) Measurement error does not necessarily invalidate the
asymptotic validity of the statistical methods used if the errors are
uncorrelated with the time series used in the analysis.
(9.) The version of this model in Rossana (1998) was not
empirically tested, and no discussion was provided of the connection
between I(1) technology shocks and labor market time series. The
discussion in this earlier study focused on the issue of normalizalion
within the cointegrating matrix.
(10.) There is no loss of generality in assuming that the
stochastic process for the technology shock is simply a driftless random
walk because the focus of the analysis will be on long-run relationships
between patents and labor market magnitudes. Let the technology shock
obey a finite order ARI(p, 1) process [zeta](L)(1 -
L)[[zeta].sup.d.sub.t] = [[kappa].sub.3t] where [zeta](L) has all of its
roots outside the unit circle and [[kappa].sub.3t] is an iid
disturbance. All of the parameters in the autoregressive polynomial
[zeta](L) would appear in the error-correction VAR, but they would only
appear in the lagged difference terms in that VAR. Such autoregressive
parameters would not be present ill the parameter matrix attached to the
lagged levels of the time series in the system, which is the parameter
matrix of interest for investigating cointegrating relationships.
Intuitively, the reason for this is that the autoregressive polynomial
has an impact on the transitory dynamics of the time-series system. It
does not influence the long-run relationships maintained by the series
in the error-correction VAR. An explicit analysis, illustrating the fact
that the cointegrating matrix is independent of the parameters in such
an autoregrcssive polynomial, may be found in Rossana (1998, pp. 430
32).
(11.) It has rank two as long as [[lambda].sub.1] [not equal to],
which is the case in this model.
(12.) In models with one state variable, economic theory indicates
that state variables are functions of exogenous parameters in
equilibrium. Thus it is quite natural to normalize the coefficient
attached to the state variable to unity. In a market context, theory
does not indicate how to normalize within the cointegrating matrix, but
as long as a structural model is available to be used in interpreting
parameter estimates, there is no danger that misleading inferences will
be drawn from estimated cointegrating vectors. Rossana (1998) provides
further discussion on these issues.
(13.) It is also possible that adjustment costs affect cash flow
for more than one period, an assumption that would be plausible with
high-frequency data. If this is true, then there would be additional
lagged levels of labor appearing in the error-correction VAR.
(14.) Put differently, the transient effects of serial correlation
in unobservable disturbances do not affect estimates of the
cointegrating matrix because this matrix describes the long-run
equilibrium of the market for labor. See Rossana (1998, pp. 433-34) for
more on this point. It should also be noted that strictly speaking, the
speed of adjustment is not a structural parameter because it is well
known that this is an eigenvalue that is a function of exogenous
variables in the model.
(15.) Gardner and Joutz (1996) use patent applications in their
study of economic growth because data on patents granted were
unavailable. Patents granted, rather than patent applications, would
seem to be a better measure of increments to the stock of knowledge
because there has been at least some attempt to screen patent
applications for legitimacy by a disinterested agency.
(16.) In practice, the distinction between a domestic and foreign
patent does not reveal the location where the research leading to the
patent was actually done. The patent holder can generally assign the
patent to a U.S. subsidiary or its foreign parent firm as it wishes.
(17.) The study by Kortum and Lerner(1998) attempts to determine
why this structural change (or trend break) occurred. There is an
interesting discussion contained there documenting institutional changes
in the U.S. legal system that seem to account for the increase in the
rate at which patents have been issued.
(18.) Rossana and Seater (1992) show that real wages cannot reject
a unit root null hypothesis using standard Dickey-Fuller tests. Unit
root tests were, in fact, used on the real wage and labor services
series, and although not reported, these test results generally do not
reject the unit root null hypothesis that they are I(1). Furthermore,
the testing strategy of Dickey and Pantula (1987) was carried out and
the results indicate that these series are not 1(2) or 1(3). Finally,
neither series appears to contain a unit root at lag one and at the
seasonal lag using the test statistics of Hasza and Fuller (1982).
(19.) Hall (1994) shows that the augmented Dickey-Fuller test retains its validity when data-based procedures, such as the BIC
criterion, are used to choose the lag l, in (11). There can be a
substantial gain in the power of this unit root test when the data are
used to choose this lag length.
(20.) There is also no evidence of a unit root at the seasonal lag
in this series using the test procedures of Hasza and Fuller (1982).
Standard augmented Dickey-Fuller test results for the stock of patents
are as follows: for d = 2, the test statistic is -6.532 and, for d = 1,
the test statistic is -1.634 using lag lengths chosen by the Schwarz
criterion. The null hypothesis of double unit roots is rejected, but a
single unit root cannot be rejected.
(21.) This manner of choosing the lag length for computing the test
statistic produces lag lengths that are much greater than those selected
by use of the BIC criterion. Whereas the conclusions drawn from the
Dickey and Pantula (1987) test are unaffected by the precise value of
the lag length, the results from the Z-A test are much more sensitive to
the precise value of the lag length chosen.
(22.) This is the year in which the Federal Courts Improvement Act
was passed, consolidating all patent appeals cases into a newly created
appeals court with jurisdiction over all such cases. This appellate
court is believed to have caused an increase in the rate of patent
approvals, and the formation of this court can be viewed as a structural
change that streamlined the patent approval process. See Kortum and
Lerner (1998) for further details.
(23.) Version 4.31 of RATS (Doan 1996) and the CATS procedure of
Hansen and Juselius (1995) were used to carry out the computations in
this paper. Johansen (1991) also provides a trace statistic for
cointegration testing. This test statistic generates identical results
regarding the number of cointegrating vectors in the data.
(24.) The Johansen (1991) statistic is adjusted by the correction
factor (T- (n + 1)l)/T where n refers to the dimensionality of the time
series system (n = 3). There is evidence in Gregory (1994) that this
cointegration test lacks power in sample sizes ranging from T = 50 to T
= 200, far below the sample size used in this article for the entire
sample, where T = 420. Subsample sizes used below are closer in size to
those in Gregory (1994).
(25.) It seems reasonable to include intercepts in virtually any
cointegrated time series system because economic models would generally
have constant terms in their long-run equilibrium relationships unless
an explicit decision has been made to use functional forms that might
rule them out. Although the elimination of constant terms may be
convenient for theoretical work, there seems little justification for
omitting intercepts from an applied point of view.
(26.) I also looked at subsample parameter estimates using the
1982:6 breakpoint chosen by the Z-A test for a unit root. The parameter
estimates from this subsample are quite similar to the results using the
October 1979 Fed breakpoint, so these estimates are not given for the
sake of brevity.
(27.) The speed of adjustment of any state variable is defined in
the adjustment cost literature to be the partial derivative of the
change in the state variable with respect to its own level within an
optimal investment demand relationship. Thus the adjustment speed can be
measured by merely subtracting one from the estimated value of
[[lambda].sub.1].
(28.) See Kaplan and Stein (1993) for some evidence on the
acceleration of merger and acquisition activity in the 1980s.
REFERENCES
Barro, R. J., and X. Sala-i-Martin. Economic Growth. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1995.
Bartlett. M. "On the Theoretical Specification of Sampling
Properties of Autocorrelated Time Series." Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series B, 8(1), 1946, 27-41.
Basu, S., J. G. Fernald, and M. D. Shapiro. "Productivity
Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment?"
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8359, 2001.
Boswijk, P., and P. H. Franses. "Dynamic Specification and
Cointegration." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 54(3),
1992, 369-81.
Dickey, D. A., and S. G. Pantula. "Determining the Order of
Differencing in Autoregressive Models." Journal of Business &
Economic Statistics, 5(4), 1987, 455-61.
Doan. T. A. RATS. Evanston: Estima, 1996.
Friedman, M. "The Role of Monetary Policy." American
Economic Review, 58(1), 1968, 1-17.
Fuller. W. A. Introduction to Statistical Time Series. New York:
Wiley, 1976.
Gardner, T. A., and F. L. Joutz. "Economic Growth. Energy
Prices, and Technological Innovation." Southern Economic Journal,
62(3), 1996, 653-66.
Gregory, A. W. "Testing for Cointegration in Linear Quadratic Models." Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 12(3),
1994, 347-60.
Griliches. Z. "Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A
Survey." Journal of Economic Literature, 28(4), 1990, 1661-707.
Hall, A. R. "Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series with
Pretest Data-Based Model Selection." Journal of Business &
Economic Statistics. 12(4), 1994, 461-70.
Hansen, H., and K. Juselius. CATS in RATS. Evanston: Estima, 1995.
Hasza, D. P., and W. A. Fuller. "Testing for Nonstationary
Parameter Specifications in Seasonal Time Series Models." Annals of
Statistics, 10(4), 1982, 1209-16.
Johansen, S. "Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models."
Econometrica, 59(6), 1991, 1551-80.
Kaplan, S. N., and J. C. Stem. "The Evolution of Buyout Pricing and Financial Structure in the 1980s." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 108(2), 1993, 313-57.
Kennan, J. "An Econometric Analysis of Fluctuations in Labor
Supply and Demand." Econometrica, 56(3), 1988, 317-33.
Kortum, S., and J. Lerner. "Stronger Protection or
Technological Revolution: What Is Behind the Recent Surge in
Patenting?" Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
48, 1998, 247-304.
Ljung, G., and G. E. P. Box. "On a Measure of Lack of Fit in
Time Series Models." Biometrika, 65(2), 1978, 297-303.
Long, J. B., and C. I. Plosser. "Real Business Cycles."
Journal of Political Economy, 91 (1), 1983, 39-69.
Lucas, R. E. "Making a Miracle." Econometrica, 61(1),
1993, 251-72.
Lucas, R. E., and L. A. Rapping. "Real Wages, Employment, and
Inflation." Journal of Political Economy, 77(5), 1969, 721-54.
McCallum, B. T. "Rational Expectations and Macroeconomic
Stabilization Policy: An Overview." Journal of 'Money. Credit,
and Banking, 12(4, Part 2), 1980, 716-46.
McLaughlin, K. J. "Rigid Wages?" Journal of Monetary
Economics, 34(3), 1994, 383-414.
Perron, P. "The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock, and the Unit
Root Hypothesis." Econometrica, 57(6), 1989, 1361-401.
Phelps, E. S. Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation
Theory. New York: Norton, 1970.
Rossana, R. J. "Technology Shocks and Cointegration in
Quadratic Models of the Firm." International Economic Review,
36(1), 1995, 5-17.
--. "On the Adjustment Matrix in Error Correction
Models." Journal of Monetary Economics, 42(2), 1998, 427-44.
Rossana, R. J., and J. J. Seater. "Aggregation, Unit Roots,
and the Time Series Properties of Manufacturing Real Wages."
International Economic Review, 33(1), 1992, 159-79.
Sargent, T. J. Macroeconomic Theory, New York: Academic Press,
1987.
Schwarz, G. "Estimating the Dimension of a Model." Annals
of Statistics, 6(2), 1978, 461-64.
Zivot, E., and D. W. K. Andrews. "Further Evidence on the
Great Crash, the Oil-Price Shock, and the Unit Root Hypothesis."
Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 10(3), 1992, 251-70.
* My thanks to Jim Hirobayashi of the U.S. Patent and Trademark
Office for providing the utility patent data used in this article and
for helpful information about its characteristics. I am grateful to
David A. Dickey, Adrian R. Fleissig, and Alastair R. Hall for comments
and useful discussions. Two anonymous referees provided many valuable
suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies regarding responsibility for
errors and omissions.
Rossana: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, 2074
F/AB, Wayne State University, Detroit, MI 48202. Phone 1-313-577-3760,
Fax 1-313-577-9564, E-mail r.j.rossana@wayne.edu