"New" public investment and/or public capital maintenance for growth? The Canadian experience.
Kalaitzidakis, Pantelis ; Kalyvitis, Sarantis
I. INTRODUCTION
In search of the determinants of long-run growth, a strand of the
relevant literature has focused on the growth impact of public
productive expenditures. The theoretical work of Barro (1990), Barro and
Sala-i-Martin (1992), and others and the empirical evidence by several
studies (surveyed by Gemmel and Kneller 2001) have stressed the role of
government productive activities as key determinants of long-run growth.
The impact of public expenditures typically takes the form of
positive production externalities that enhance private sector
productivity via private firms' production function either as a
flow (government productive services) or as a stock (public or
infrastructural capital). (1) The adoption of this framework embeds two
central assumptions on the nature of public capital expenditures. First,
all expenditures related to the public capital accumulation process of
the economy are oriented to the formation of "new" public
capital through investment. Second, public capital deterioration is
considered as an exogenously given technical relationship. Hence, this
approach neglects a crucial choice concerning the implementation of
public investment decisions, namely, the choice between investing in new
public capital and extending the durability of the existing public
capital stock. The cost paid for the latter option is usually called
"maintenance expenditures for public capital" and, strictly
speaking, should be classified under the budgetary term "public
investment" because it fulfills two basic criteria: (1) It is
financed by taxation or government borrowing and (2) it does not result
in public consumption expenditures, but instead increases the public
capital stock available in the economy. (2)
Despite the intuitive consensus on the crucial weight of
maintenance expenditures in public capital and the trade-off with
expenditures in new public investment, there have been few systematic
attempts to investigate their macroeconomic impact. An attempt to
analyze this trade-off has been recently made by Rioja (2003), who sets
up a growth model where domestic tax revenues finance maintenance
expenditures for public capital, whereas public infrastructure is
financed solely by foreign donors. The author shows that the optimal
maintenance level as a share of output depends on various parameters and
presents calibration results from Latin American countries that confirm
the importance of maintenance for the pattern of growth in these
countries. Along this line, Kalaitzidakis and Kalyvitis (2004) extend
Rioja's model by concentrating on the implications of maintenance
expenditures for public capital formation on growth. In their model,
both types of expenditures are financed by a tax on output; by altering
their allocation, the government can use the share of maintenance as a
policy instrument and raise the shadow value of private capital, thus
leading the economy to a higher growth rate. An appealing implication is
that the growth-maximizing share of taxation is higher than the
elasticity of public capital in the production function (which reverses
a standard argument put forward by, among others, Barro 1990; Glomm and
Ravikumar 1994; Devarajan et al. 1998), as the additional positive
effect of maintenance expenditure on the accumulation of public capital
raises the benefits of taxation compared to the standard models.
Although theoretically sound, these relationships do not translate
easily into operational guidelines for policy makers on the growth
effects of maintenance and new public capital expenditures. (3) Ideally,
one would like to test these implications in the context of a wide
cross-country data set consisting of data on each of the two components
of public expenditures. Unfortunately, published data on maintenance are
very scarce, involving only a handful of private activities due to
inherent problems in the measurement of this type of expenditures.
McGrattan and Schmitz (1999) describe the difficulties in constructing
aggregate measures of maintenance and repair; the authors point out
that, for instance, in the United States maintenance activities are
largely carried out outside the market and, thus, recorded transactions
are usually incomplete. When such transactions exist, there is no
systematic data collection, except for some scanty manufacturing data.
(4)
Globally, there has been only one source of long-run data on
maintenance expenditures, namely the Canadian survey on Capital and
Repair Expenditures, which contains evidence on maintenance expenditures
of both private firms and government organizations. The figures show
that total private and public maintenance and repair expenditures in
Canada amounted on average to around 6.3% of gross domestic product
(GDP) for the period 1956-93. (5) This figure was roughly equal to
one-third of spending on new investments and, when compared to other
so-called engines of growth, was somewhat lower than education spending
(6.8% of GDP), but far above the average spending on research and
development (1.4% of GDP). Regarding public sector expenditures in
maintenance, 21% of total public capital spending went to maintenance
and repair expenditures, but with considerable variations across sectors
of public activity (which in Canada consists of government-owned
enterprises, government institutions-housing, and government
departments).
The purpose of the current article is to shed some light on the
empirical relationship between maintenance expenditures in public
capital, new public investment, and growth. In particular, we use this
unexploited Canadian data set to test the impact of total public capital
expenditures and their components on growth. We place emphasis on the
growth rate because given the importance of economic growth in improving
living standards, modern growth theory has shown particular interest in
growth-enhancing policies. The understanding of the forces of economic
growth, which covers the theoretical and empirical analysis of the
growth-driving factors and policies, is crucial to identify the relative
merits, synergies, and impacts of government interventions in areas like
the formation and allocation of public infrastructure that is examined
here. Moreover, the growth rate is usually one of the main measurable
objectives of governments, and hence it is useful to know the
contribution of the components of public expenditures aiming at public
capital formation (see also Devarajan et al. 1996).
Our empirical results indicate that the Canadian economy would
benefit from a fall in total expenditures on both new capital and
maintenance and that the aggregate share of maintenance in total
expenditures should be lower over the period under consideration.
Moreover, the disaggregation of these expenditures by sector of public
economic activity yields interesting policy insights on the allocation
among sectors. The evidence shows that the decrease in total
expenditures should come mainly from expenditures in government-owned
enterprises and government departments. Of interest is also the
allocation between new capital and maintenance expenditures at the
sectoral level. According to the evidence, the suggested decrease of the
maintenance share should come mainly from maintenance expenditures in
government-owned enterprises.
We think that the results of the article highlight another possible
classification of public expenditures in accordance to the spirit of the
empirical work by Devarajan et al. (1996), Kneller et al. (1999), and
Bleaney et al. (2001). All these authors classified public investment
expenditures in two broad categories, namely, productive and
unproductive expenditures, and confirmed that their growth impact
differs dramatically, with productive expenditures exerting a positive
influence on growth, whereas unproductive ones have virtually no impact.
Albeit confined to a single economy (Canada), the evidence of the
current article shows that the growth impacts of public capital
expenditures in new capital and maintenance are likely to display
substantial discrepancies depending on their absolute size and their
relative share, thus opening a new route for further empirical
explorations on the growth effect of fiscal categories.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section II
outlines the anticipated growth impact of maintenance expenditures in
public capital versus new public investment. Section III describes
briefly the Canadian survey on capital and repair expenditures. Section
IV outlines the empirical specifications, and section V provides
empirical evidence on the impact of aggregated and disaggregated expenditures and of the corresponding maintenance shares on Canadian
growth. Section VI concludes.
II. THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS OF THE GROWTH IMPACT OF MAINTENANCE IN
PUBLIC CAPITAL
Maintenance expenditures can be broadly defined as the
"employment of resources [...] that preserve the operative state of
capital" (Bitros 1976, p. 919). Although several studies have
attempted during the past decades to investigate various aspects and
impacts of capital maintenance expenditures, few have concentrated on
their growth impact (see also the discussion in the previous section).
Here we describe more analytically the various channels through which
this type of public expenditures is anticipated to affect growth, as
they have been pinpointed by the theoretical literature so far.
The first study that underlined the macroeconomic importance of
maintenance expenditures in public capital was Rioja (2003), where the
author constructs an endogenous growth model in which the depreciation
rate of infrastructure is endogenous and depends on maintenance and
usage. Maintenance enhances the productivity of private capital by
increasing the level of public capital. In Rioja's model,
maintenance of public capital is financed by taxation; in contrast, new
investment is financed solely by foreign donors.
The author is then able to analyze the tradeoff between new
investment and maintenance expenditures. Intuitively, if aid-financed
new investment as a share of the existing infrastructure stock rises,
the optimal maintenance expenditure should decrease. In this setup, the
government cares about the overall size of the public capital stock,
which affects output and welfare. Hence, as donors fund more new
investment, which adds to the existing public capital stock, it is
optimal to decrease tax-financed maintenance. A welfare-improving option
in this setup is to reallocate a portion of aid-financed new investment
toward maintenance. Indeed, the calibration results presented by Rioja
(2003) confirm that reallocating some of the donor aid away from new
investments and toward maintenance can have positive effects on GDP of
Latin American countries.
To extend the concept of maintenance put forward by Rioja (2003) to
a more generalized setup, Kalaitzidakis and Kalyvitis (2004) develop an
infrastructure-led two-sector endogenous growth model in which the
private and the public capital stocks enter directly in the production
function. Following Rioja (2003), the authors then assume that the
depreciation rate of public capital and consequently its accumulation
rate are determined by public expenditures on maintenance. A rise in
maintenance expenditures as a ratio of output (where output can be
considered as a measure of the burden on public infrastructure) raises
the durability of public capital. At the same time, the second component
of public capital expenditures, namely, new public investment, adds
directly to public capital. Here, following Barro (1990), both types of
public expenditures are financed by a proportional tax on the aggregate
gross output.
The authors perform comparative statics to examine first whether
the economy can benefit from a reallocation between new investment and
maintenance at the given taxation rate. A shortage of (or excess in)
public capital can be eliminated by the change in allocation between
these two components and the subsequent accumulation of infrastructure.
In particular, under given total expenditures, if maintenance is at a
low (high) level relative to new investment, a shift in the mix toward
(from) maintenance reduces (increases) expenditures for new investment.
The economy is now able to accumulate public capital at a faster rate by
using the same amount of total public expenditures resources, because
the improved reallocation triggers a rise in public capital
accumulation. Hence, by accumulating more infrastructure, the economy
can take advantage of the existing private capital stock. The shadow
price of private capital and the growth rate rise as the economy moves
toward the new composition between new investment and maintenance.
Therefore, the government can improve the growth rate of the economy by
altering the share of maintenance expenditures in total expenditures,
because at the given government size the economy more efficiently uses
the existing private capital stock. The opposite picture emerges when
there is a lack of new investment relative to maintenance expenditures.
The dynamic relationship between growth and the ratio of maintenance to
new investment is depicted in Figure 1.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Notice that under this setting, maintenance and new investment are
not perfect substitutes, because one unit of the latter adds directly to
the public capital stock, whereas the same amount of expenditures on
maintenance affects the public capital accumulation rate indirectly
through the depreciation rate. An immediate implication is that the
implied relationship between growth and the allocation between the two
components of public capital expenditures is expected to be nonlinear depending, among other things, on the functional specification of the
endogenous depreciation function.
A similar exercise can be performed if, for a given composition
between new investment and maintenance, the government changes the level
of total public expenditures. The decline (rise) in taxation when the
economy is in excess (short of) tax revenues induces (reduces) private
capital accumulation as after-tax profits are higher (lower), but at the
same time reduces (raises) public capital accumulation as there are less
(more) resources for financing new investment and maintenance at the
given proportion. The fall (rise) of public infrastructure renders
private capital less (more) profitable and its accumulation rate falls
(rises) gradually until it reaches the corresponding one of public
capital. As a result, the new equilibrium is characterized by higher
growth. Hence, the new state of the economy depends on the initial level
of the tax rate where the inverse U-shaped tax rate effect, popularized
by Barro (1990), is confirmed and intensified by the impact of
maintenance expenditures in public capital (see also Barro and
Sala-I-Martin 1995, figure 4.1).
The previous analysis highlights the importance of maintenance
expenditures in public capital for the growth path of the economy at the
theoretical level. In particular, two broad conclusions can be drawn.
First, public expenditures in new capital and maintenance should both be
examined when analyzing the growth impact of public capital
expenditures. Second, the allocation between these two components of
public capital expenditures is likely to matter for the growth
performance of the economy. Third, the (possibly nnonlinear)
relationship between these types of expenditures and growth can go
either way because it depends on the current size of these expenditures.
III. THE CANADIAN CAPITAL AND REPAIR EXPENDITURES SURVEY: NATURE OF
DATA AND DEFINITIONS
As mentioned in section I, the only available data set worldwide on
this type of expenditures is the Canadian survey on Capital and Repair
Expenditures. In this section we give a brief description of this data
set that will be used later on; for more details the reader is referred
to McGrattan and Schmitz (1999).
Private firms, households, and government organizations in Canada
were asked in an annual survey over the period 1956-93 about their
capital and repair expenditures on equipment and structures. In
particular, capital expenditures cover spending devoted to new
investment, in accordance to the broad definition given earlier. These
include expenditures on (1) fixed assets (such as new buildings,
engineering, machinery, and equipment); (2) modifications, additions,
major renovations, and work in progress; (3) feasibility studies and
general fees; (4) work by own labor force. On the other hand, repair
expenditures cover spending devoted to maintenance cost, again in
accordance to the broad definition given earlier. These expenditures
cover (1) maintenance and repair of nonresidential buildings, other
structures, machinery, and equipment; (2) building maintenance; (3)
equipment maintenance (vehicles, etc.); (4) repair work by own and
outside labor force. Here, we pay particular attention to capital and
repair expenditures by the extended public sector (where the government
controls more than 50% of the voting rights); apart from
"pure" public services, such as departments or their
equivalents, this definition also covers other organizations, which
operate more independently.
In turn, total public expenditures are disaggregated into
expenditures by (1) government-owned enterprises, (2) government
institutions and housing, and (3) government departments. (6) Table 1
gives a synoptic presentation of the data for the various categories of
the public sector. We also report for comparison purposes the
corresponding figures for the private sector (which consists of business
and private institutions-housing sectors). The general picture shows
that total public expenditures in new investment and maintenance
amounted to 7.4% of GDP with the average maintenance share covering 21%
(1.5% of GDP). However, there are substantial differences between
sectors. In particular, the bulk of public capital expenditures were
concentrated in the government-owned enterprises and government
departments sectors (90% of total). Also, the average share of
maintenance was relatively high in these sectors (23.4% and 20.4% of
total expenditures, respectively), whereas in contrast the share of
maintenance in the institutions-housing sector was only 14.8% of total
capital expenditures. (7)
IV. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION
We attempt to quantify empirically the direction of the growth
impact of public capital expenditures by using the Canadian survey on
public expenditures in new capital and maintenance and developing an
empirical framework that relates these components of public capital
expenditures to Canadian growth. More specifically, the anticipated
results involve testing for the links between public expenditures for
capital formation, the share of maintenance, and the growth rate of the
economy. For instance, a positive effect of the share of maintenance on
growth implies that a reallocation of government expenditures toward
maintenance will increase the growth rate of the economy. Or, according
to Devarajan et al. (1996), maintenance is "productive," and
infrastructure investment is "unproductive" at the current
allocation of total government expenditure. To this extent, estimation of growth equations, which include the share of maintenance as a key
explanatory variable, could reveal whether an economy directs adequate
resources toward maintenance. In a similar vein, a positive (negative)
impact of total expenditures devoted to new investment and maintenance
on the growth rate indicates that a rise (fall) of total expenditures as
a fraction of GDP would ceteris paribus enhance (reduce) growth.
There is by now a large body of literature on the empirical impact
of public policies on growth, which can be broadly classified into three
categories depending on the adopted econometric approach: cross-section,
time-series, and pooled cross-section regressions. All studies emphasize
the potential importance of various forms of governmental actions
(expenditures, taxation, etc.) on the growth pattern of the economy. In
our case, to isolate empirically the effect of public infrastructure on
growth and private capital in Canada it is essential to take into
account all factors that are likely to be of importance.
Therefore, given (1) the theoretical predictions developed in
section II, (2) the consideration of the existing empirical literature,
and (3) the data set consisting of a single country time-series, the
testing strategy involves the following approach. After having adopted
the classification of the data for Canada reported previously, the aim
is to estimate the effect on growth of (1) the level of total public
capital and repair expenditures (the total public capital expenditures
effect) and (2) the ratio of maintenance to total public capital and
repair expenditures (the maintenance effect).
To this extent, we opt for a general empirical specification of the
form growth rate of Canada = f(control variables, total capital
expenditures, maintenance), where control variables indicates a set of
other variables that are expected to affect the growth rate of the
economy and will be determined later. In this framework, a positive
(negative) impact of the share of maintenance on growth would signal
that a reallocation of total government expenditures in favor of
maintenance (new investment) would be beneficial for the growth rate of
the economy. Similarly, the total public capital expenditures effect can
be investigated by testing whether aggregate public expenditures in new
capital formation and maintenance affect (positively or negatively) the
growth rate of the economy.
In general, total public capital expenditures, as a ratio to
output, and the share of maintenance in these expenditures are expected
to be positively related to growth when they are low, but the
relationship will become negative when they get relatively large. Thus,
one anticipates a nonlinear impact of total expenditures and the share
of maintenance on growth. Accordingly, a nonlinear empirical
specification is adopted with higher-order terms of aggregate
expenditures (as GDP%) and the maintenance share included as explanatory
variables. The estimated equation takes the following parametric form:
(1) [g.sup.CANf.sub.y] = f(control) + [k.summation over (j=1)]
[[alpha].sub.j] x [([G + M]/Y).sup.j] + [l.summation over (j=1)]
[[beta].sub.j] x [(M/[G + M]).sup.j],
where [g.sup.CANf.sub.y] denotes the Canadian three-year forward
moving average growth rate (for a more detailed discussion see later); G
and M denote new public investment and maintenance expenditures in
public capital, respectively; and Y denotes output. Hence, (G + M)/Y
denotes total (new and maintenance) public capital expenditures as a
share of GDP, and M/(G + M) denotes the share of maintenance
expenditures in total public expenditures. The order k and l of the two
variables of interest is assumed to be unknown and will be determined by
the properties of the data. In general, a nonlinear impact (i.e., an
order [greater than or equal to] 2) is predicted, according to the
models developed earlier.
The marginal effect of (G + M)/Y and M/(G + M) on growth can then
be captured by the partial derivatives evaluated at the mean. Hence, the
tested hypotheses on the total expenditure effect are:
(Null A) [[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/[differential]([G +
M]/Y)] = 0
(total public capital expenditures are not over- or underprovided);
(Alternative A1)
[[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/[differential]([G + M]/Y)] < 0
(total public capital expenditures are overprovided); and
(Alternative a2)
[[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/[differential]([G + M]/Y)] > 0
(total public capital expenditures are underprovided).
In an analogous manner, the corresponding tested hypotheses on the
marginal growth effect maintenance take the form:
(Null B) [[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/[differential](M/[G +
M])] = 0
(maintenance is not over- or underprovided);
(Alternative B1) [[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/
[differential](M/[G + M])]
< 0
(maintenance is overprovided); and
(Alternative B2) [[differential][g.sup.CANf.sub.y])/
[differential](M/[G + M])] > 0
(maintenance is underprovided).
This framework allows inference about the growth impact of total
public capital expenditures (Null A) and the share of maintenance in
total expenditures (Null B). In turn, the rejection of these null
hypotheses in either way provides us with evidence on the under- or
overprovision of these expenditures. (8)
Furthermore, to refine the analysis and estimate different effects
on growth of the different components of capital and repair
expenditures, we can use the sectoral survey data on public capital
expenditures and maintenance. This exploration at the sectoral level may
help us extract all the information reliably contained in the data. So,
a similar exercise can be performed using the disaggregated data
described in the previous section by estimating an equation that takes
the parametric form:
(2) [g.sup.CANf.sub.y] = f(control) + [m.summation over (j=1)]
[3.summation over (i=1)] [[[gamma].sub.i,j] x [([[G +
M].sub.i]/Y).sup.j]] + [n.summation over (j=1)] [3.summation over (i=1)]
[[[delta].sub.i,j] x [([M.sub.i]/[[G + M].sub.i]).sup.j]].
Again, the estimated coefficients for (2) have the same
interpretation as those of equation (1), but now refer to the sectoral
components, whereas the order m and n of the sectoral variables is
assumed to be unknown and will be determined by the properties of the
data on hand. Also, the hypotheses A and B and the corresponding
alternatives can be interpreted in the same manner with reference to the
related sectors.
Turning to the variables at hand, the growth rate for Canada is
given by the annual GDP per capita growth rate. To avoid potential
endogeneity problems we use as a dependent variable the three-year
forward moving average growth rate, in the spirit of Devarajan et al.
(1996). (9) This definition also dampens down the business cycle effect
on the growth rate. Regarding growth determinants in Canada, most
previous studies have placed emphasis on the export-led character of the
economy and have paid less attention to domestic factors, like private
and public investment expenditures. Following the work of Aschauer
(1989), some authors have attempted to investigate the effects of
private and public investment on output in Canada. Serletis (1994, 1996)
reports that the private and public investment to output ratio is found
to be nonstationary. This finding contrasts the prediction of the
standard neoclassical growth model and can be considered as favorable for endogenous growth models, where permanent investment policies lead
to permanent changes in the growth pattern of the economy. Bodman (1998)
stresses the importance of public capital by finding that government
infrastructural capital has a significant impact on growth. Wylie (1995,
1996) has found that public infrastructure plays an important in
enhancing productivity in Canada with an elasticity that is comparable
to the one reported for the United States by Aschauer (1989).
In the current approach, to capture these impacts and verify the
robustness of the results we have used several conditioning variables to
account mainly for the impact of external shocks, domestic policies, and
competitiveness. So we use alternative empirical specifications with the
inflation rate, the budget deficit, and the terms of trade growth rate
as "control variables" (for a detailed description of all
variables see the appendix). (10) More specifically, the inflation rate
is always included to capture the well-known negative relationship
between inflation and growth. We also include the budget deficit (as a
share of output) as a measure of the domestic fiscal stance, which is
likely to affect the growth effects of public capital expenditures as
Ricardian equivalence might eliminate or mitigate their impact. Finally,
the open character of the Canadian economy and the associated influence
of international competitiveness additionally justify the inclusion of
the terms of trade growth rate, which is a standard variable in growth
regressions.
V. RESULTS
In this section we present the results derived by the empirical
specifications developed earlier. We start with the specification for
aggregated public capital expenditures, and then we move on to report
estimates for sectoral expenditures.
Aggregate Expenditures
We begin the presentation of the empirical results by postulating
coefficients of second order for the variables of interest. The
empirical results for various forms of this specification are displayed
in Table 2. The estimated equations have a high explanatory power of
total Canadian growth variability ranging from 78% to 82%. The inflation
rate enters with expected negative sign and is significant in all
specifications. The remaining two control variables enter with
insignificant signs; however, the general picture remains unaltered with
respect to the variables of interest, namely, the share of total public
capital expenditures in output and the maintenance share in these
expenditures.
Specifically, the impact of the latter variables is investigated by
equations (1.1) to (1.4) by assuming first- and second-order effects on
growth. Turning first to the impact of total public capital
expenditures, they enter in all specifications with statistically
significant (at the 1% level) positive coefficients for the first-order
effect and negative ones for the second-order effect. This evidence
implies an inverse U-shaped relationship between growth and these
expenditures, which corroborates the expected theoretical nexus
developed in section II. The dynamics of the maintenance share are,
however, found to be more complicated. Although the variable enters with
statistically significant signs in almost all cases in specifications
(1.1) to (1.4), the first-order effect is negative and statistically
significant, whereas the second-order effect is positive or
statistically insignificant. This implies either a U-shaped curve for
the relationship between the maintenance share and the growth rate or
more complicated dynamics involving higher-order nonlinearities in the
relationship between aggregate maintenance allocation and growth due,
for instance, to technical needs requiring an effective (upper or lower)
bound in the share of these expenditures.
The second part (specifications [1.5] to [1.8]) of Table 2 attempts
to explore these issues further by including a third-order effect for
the share of maintenance expenditures. (11) The third-order effect is
found to be significant in all specifications and improves the
statistical significance of the remaining coefficients of the
maintenance share, without substantially affecting the results on the
coefficients of the control variables or total public capital
expenditures. In general, this third-order relationship implies that
there are two turning points in the relationship between growth and the
share of maintenance, and therefore that the inverse U-shaped
relationship holds, but only for a region of the share of maintenance
expenditures. A potential explanation for this finding may be related to
the aggregated nature of the data at hand. As explained in section III,
the broad definition of aggregated expenditures covers various public
sector activities, which may operate in the opposite direction regarding
their growth effects. Absent any further aggregate evidence related to
this finding, we postpone its investigation for the following
subsection, where sectoral estimates are examined.
To assess the marginal impact of aggregate public capital
expenditures according to hypotheses A and B, we calculate the
corresponding derivates at the mean and we use a standard Wald test to
investigate the various hypotheses about the sign of the effects. (12)
The results for the aggregate specification are tabulated in the upper
part of Table 3. Total capital and repair expenditures are found to have
in all specifications a negative marginal impact on growth, which is
significant at the 1% significance level. An important policy conclusion
obtained by these results is that total expenditures on new capital and
maintenance (amounting on average to 7.4% of GDP) have been overprovided
for the period under investigation. Moreover, a negative marginal growth
impact is found for the share of maintenance in these expenditures
(which amount on average to 21% of total public capital expenditures),
indicating that the Canadian economy could benefit from a reallocation
between maintenance and new investment expenditures in favor of the
latter. Therefore, the overall conclusion is that for the period under
consideration the Canadian economy would benefit from a fall in
expenditures for public capital formation, which should largely come
from a reduction in the share of maintenance expenditure.
An interesting conjecture derived by the aforementioned results
regards the growth-maximizing shares of, first, the total public capital
expenditures in output and, second, maintenance expenditures. In
particular, the estimated coefficients imply that an increase in total
public capital expenditures is productive (enhances growth) until these
expenditures reach a critical level of 6.7%-7.0% of GDP depending on the
specification used and reduce growth thereafter. Similarly, according to
the implied shape of the growth-maintenance share relationship, the
inferred turning point (corresponding to the maximum in Figure 1) is in
the region of 14.1%-14.6% of total expenditures depending on the
specification used. (13)
We close this section by noting that at first glance, these results
appear to be in contradiction with the usual finding of a positive
impact of expenditures for public capital formation in Canada and other
developed economies. However, taking into account the budgetary
restriction, it is likely that these expenditures have been far above
the desired level, generating persistent deficits in the post- 1974
period, which have been inadequate in fostering long-term growth.
Another potential explanation for the negative impact of total
expenditures in public capital formation on growth may be that previous
studies have failed to take into account maintenance expenditures
(because their estimates were based solely on the impact of public
investment recorded in national accounts). This may have led to an
underestimation of the size of aggregate public expenditures and the
consequent distortions in the economy.
Finally, another potential source driving the negative impact of
maintenance expenditures on future growth may be reverse causality. (14)
In particular, a higher future growth rate may lessen the need for
expansionary demand-driven policies by use of new investment. Hence,
there may be more resources available to the government for maintenance
expenditures, thus generating an apparent positive correlation between
current maintenance expenditures and future growth, which may explain
the finding of maintenance over-provision.
Sectoral Expenditures
As discussed earlier, the composition of public capital
expenditures varies considerably across public sectors in Canada. So, to
further explore the sources of growth impacts, additional information
about can be gained by turning to sectoral estimates (reported in Table
4). The control variables enter with correctly signed but statistically
insignificant signs in the estimated specifications (2.1) to (2.4).
Nevertheless, the overall picture with respect to the variables of
interest seems again robust with respect to various alterations with the
explanatory power of the equations being again high (approximating 80%).
To capture the effects of the variables of interest (sectoral
expenditures and sectoral maintenance shares), their first- and
second-order effects are included in the estimated regressions. These
specifications are found to be adequate here, because higher-order
specifications did not yield statistically significant results. As in
the case of aggregate estimates, a direct picture on their marginal
growth effects of sectoral public capital expenditures can be obtained
by examining the statistical significance of the corresponding partial
derivates. These are tabulated in the second part of Table 3. According
to the evidence, the marginal growth impact of total capital
expenditures by government-owned enterprises is negative. This also
holds for the share devoted to maintenance expenditures, which is found
to exert a negative marginal impact on growth. These findings are
statistically significant at the 1% level and are consistent with the
high average level of public capital expenditures (3.4% of GDP) and the
high average share (23.4%) of maintenance expenditures in this sector.
The results are less conclusive for government departments, which
also have a relatively large average size (amounting to 3.2% of GDP over
the period under investigation), but appear to have exerted a negative
marginal impact on growth only in two out of four specifications. In
contrast, total expenditures in the government institutions-housing
(which amount only to 0.8% of GDP), as well as the shares of maintenance
in the government institutions-housing and government departments
sectors appear to have been at their growth-maximizing levels. (Recall
that the shares of maintenance in these sectors were 14.8% and 20.4% of
total expenditures, respectively.)
To sum up, the sectoral evidence points out that the reduction in
total public capital expenditures suggested in the previous subsection
should come from reductions in government-owned enterprises and
government departments sectors, which also have the largest sizes in
terms of output. Also, it appears that the average share of maintenance
expenditures in the government-owned enterprises sector, which is the
highest one among the three sectors, should be reduced to improve the
growth performance of the Canadian economy.
VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The main goal of the article was to highlight empirically the
growth aspects of a component of public expenditures, namely,
maintenance expenditures in public capital, which had been until now
unexplored. Along this line, we attempted to obtain some evidence on the
growth impact of public capital and maintenance expenditures in Canada.
Our empirical estimates give some interesting policy implications on the
size of total public capital expenditures and the impact of maintenance.
We therefore think that the article makes a persuasive case for a strong
link between maintenance expenditures, new investment, and growth. The
empirical findings support the view that maintenance expenditures in the
public sector are a crucial determinant of growth, whose impact should
be examined in conjunction with that of expenditures in new capital
formation advocated by standard growth models.
Although our results are confined to the Canadian economy, it is
confirmed that maintenance is an important source of expenditures on
public capital, whose impact has remained inadequately explored. Yet the
broad cross-country empirical testing of the relationships outlined in
the article is, at the present stage of data availability, not possible.
Maintenance traditionally appears under various categories in national
accounts systems, such as repairs or renovations. With the exception of
Canada, there has been no particular interest in collecting data on
maintenance expenditures in public capital, although scarce existing
evidence from other sectors of economic activity reveals that
maintenance in developed economies covers a substantial fraction of
total expenditures for capital formation. This lack of data is largely
due to the nature of maintenance expenditures: Because there is no
market and recorded transactions for maintenance, data collection
requires the planning of surveys in public organizations to obtain an
accurate estimate of maintenance expenditures and their effect on the
depreciation rate of public capital.
The article hopefully offers a rationale for several potential
extensions. On the theoretical side, the macroeconomic implications of
public capital and maintenance expenditures can be investigated in the
context of private and public sector cooperation, including the cost and
effectiveness of new public investment and maintenance expenditures. On
the empirical side, greater awareness and understanding of long-term
growth implications of public capital expenditures along with a greater
focus on setting more precise objectives to be pursued by government
organizations would facilitate better budgetary decision making and
enhance public reporting of the macroeconomic costs and benefits
regarding government productive activities. To this extent, data
collection in the public sector on these expenditures either by a
unified survey or by the inclusion of related questions in existing
surveys would yield valuable information for the conduct of efficient
public sector management.
Finally, further work on the impact of maintenance expenditures
could focus on the regional aspects of these activities. Several types
of infrastructure projects often involve small-scale interventions (like
public schools or hospitals), which are largely effective at the local
level, but whose impact may not appear equally powerful at the national
level. It would be therefore of interest for policy makers to know if
and by how much maintenance activities affect primarily the local
economy or display wider spillover effects. Attempting to answer this
open issue might provide an indication regarding the desired degree of
designation of the management of this type of expenditures to state or
local authorities.
DATA APPENDIX
The first part of the appendix gives the sources for public capital
and repair expenditures (for a general description of the variables, see
section IV).
1. Total public capital and repair expenditures: CANSIM variable
D843829.
2. Total public repair expenditures: CANSIM variable D843830.
3. Capital and repair expenditures by government-owned enterprises:
CANSIM variable D843808.
4. Repair expenditures by government-owned enterprises: CANSIM
variable D843809.
5. Capital and repair expenditures by government institutions and
housing: CANSIM variable D843812.
6. Repair expenditures by government-owned institutions and
housing: CANSIM variable D843813.
7. Capital and repair expenditures by government departments:
CANSIM variable D843816.
8. Repair expenditures by government departments: CANSIM variable
D843817.
The second part of the appendix describes the rest of the Canadian
variables.
1. GDP per capita growth rate: difference in growth rates of Canada
GDP (IFS variable 15699B.CZF ...) and Canada population (IFS variable
15699Z..ZF ...).
2. Inflation rate: percentage difference in Consumer Price Index
(IFS variable 15664 ... ZF ...).
3. Budget deficit as GDP percent (IFS variable 15680 ... ZF ...
divided by GDP as defined).
4. Terms of trade growth rate: ratio of export price index
(implicit price index for exports of goods and services, Datastream Code
CND20570) to import price index (implicit price index for imports of
goods and services, Datastream Code CND20573).
TABLE 1
Basic Statistics of Expenditures in "New" Capital and Maintenance
by Sector of Economic Activity: Canada, 1956-93
Mean SD Maximum Minimum
Public sector
New capital and maintenance 3.4 0.6 4.6 2.5
expenditures in government-owned
enterprises (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in 23.4 4.2 33.3 15.1
government-owned enterprises
(% of new capital and maintenance
expenditure)
New capital and maintenance 0.8 0.3 1.5 0.5
expenditure in government
institutions and housing (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in 14.8 7.8 30.7 6.2
government institutions and housing
(% of new capital and maintenance
expenditure)
New capital and maintenance 3.2 0.6 4.2 2.4
expenditures in government
departments (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in 20.4 2.8 25.3 15.0
government departments
(% of new capital and maintenance
expenditure)
Total public expenditures in new 7.4 1.1 9.5 5.5
capital and maintenance (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in public 1.5 0.2 1.2 1.9
sector (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in public 21.0 3.1 27.7 14.7
sector (% of new capital and
maintenance expenditure)
Private sector
Total private expenditures in new 19.7 1.6 23.8 16.2
capital and maintenance (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in private 4.8 0.5 3.7 5.7
sector (% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditures in private 24.3 2.1 28.1 22.4
sector (% of new capital and
maintenance expenditure)
Total (private + public)
Total expenditures in new capital 27.1 2.4 33.3 22.5
and maintenance (% of GDP)
Total maintenance expenditures 6.3 0.7 5.1 7.5
(% of GDP)
Maintenance expenditure (% of new 23.3 1.5 26.7 21.0
capital and maintenance
expenditure)
Source: CANSIM database, Statistics Canada.
TABLE 2
The Effects of Aggregated Public Expenditures in "New" Capital
and Maintenance on Canadian Growth: Nonlinear Effects
(Dependent Variable: Three-Year Forward Moving Average
of GDP per Capita Growth Rate)
Independent Variable Eq. (1.1) Eq. (1.2)
Constant 2.28 (20.47) 5.14 (20.05)
Inflation -0.35 (0.14) * -0.31 (0.14) *
Budget deficit -- -0.16 (0.17)
Terms of trade growth rate -- --
Aggregated public sector
Capital and repair 18.15 (5.33) ** 17.09 (5.33) **
expenditures
(Capital and repair -1.32 (0.34) ** -1.26 (0.34) **
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -4.02 (1.50) ** -3.84 (1.46) **
(Maintenance) (2) 0.07 (0.04) * 0.06 (0.03)
(Maintenance) (3) -- --
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.79 0.78
D-W 1.22 1.33
Independent Variable Eq. (1.3) Eq. (1.4)
Constant 2.62 (20.43) 5.11 (20.13)
Inflation -0.35 (0.14) * -0.30 (0.15) *
Budget deficit -- 0.18 (0.19)
Terms of trade growth rate 0.02 (0.10) 0.03 (0.11)
Aggregated public sector
Capital and repair 18.11 (5.31) ** 16.97 (5.36) **
expenditures
(Capital and repair -1.32 (0.34) ** -1.26 (0.34) **
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -4.05 (1.50) ** -3.77 (1.49) **
(Maintenance) (2) 0.07 (0.04) * 0.06 (0.04)
(Maintenance) (3) -- --
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.78 0.78
D-W 1.25 1.30
Independent Variable Eq. (1.5) Eq. (1.6)
Constant -167.36 (58.21) ** -173.54 (64.29) **
Inflation -0.37 (0.12) ** -0.38 (0.13) **
Budget deficit -- -0.03 (0.16)
Terms of trade growth rate -- --
Aggregated public sector
Capital and repair 21.08 (4.57) ** 21.41 (4.83) **
expenditures
(Capital and repair -1.50 (0.29) ** -1.52 (0.30) **
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance 19.44 (7.86) * 20.17 (8.46) *
(Maintenance) (2) -1.08 (0.38) ** -1.11 (0.41) **
(Maintenance) (3) 0.02 (0.01) ** 0.02 (0.01) *
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.82 0.82
D-W 1.62 1.61
Independent Variable Eq. (1.7) Eq. (1.8)
Constant -189.06 (63.00) ** -185.80 (65.89) **
Inflation -0.36 (0.12) ** -0.35 (0.13) **
Budget deficit -- -0.03 (0.17)
Terms of trade growth rate -0.09 (0.09) -0.09 (0.10)
Aggregated public sector
Capital and repair 21.57 (4.64) ** 21.35 (4.86) **
expenditures
(Capital and repair -1.54 (0.30) ** -1.52 (0.31) **
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance 22.37 (8.52) ** 22.01 (8.75) *
(Maintenance) (2) -1.22 (0.41) ** -1.20 (0.42) **
(Maintenance) (3) 0.02 (0.01) ** 0.02 (0.01) *
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.82 0.82
D-W 1.49 1.48
Notes: "Capital and repair expenditures" denotes total public
expenditures in new capital and maintenance (GDP%) and "Maintenance"
the share of maintenance in total public expenditure, respectively.
Estimation method is generalized method of means with correction for
second-order autocorrelation. SEs are in parentheses. An asterisk
denotes significance at the 5% level and two asterisks at the 1% level.
TABLE 3
Summarized Estimates of Nonlinear Impact on Canadian Growth based
on Tables 2 and 4
Aggregated
Eq. (1.1) Eq. (1.2)
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative ** Negative **
Aggregated
Eq. (1.3) Eq. (1.4)
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative ** Negative **
Aggregated
Eq. (1.5) Eq. (1.6)
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative ** Negative **
Aggregated
Eq. (1.7) Eq. (1.8)
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative** Negative **
Disaggregated
Eq. (2.1) Eq. (2.2)
Government-owned enterprises
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative ** Negative **
Government institutions and housing
Total capital and repair expenditures Zero Zero
Maintenance share Zero Zero
Government departments
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative * Zero
Maintenance share Zero Zero
Disaggregated
Eq. (2.3) Eq. (2.4)
Government-owned enterprises
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative ** Negative **
Maintenance share Negative ** Negative **
Government institutions and housing
Total capital and repair expenditures Zero Zero
Maintenance share Zero Zero
Government departments
Total capital and repair expenditures Negative * Zero
Maintenance share Zero Zero
Notes: The effects are estimated from a Wald statistic based on the
partial derivatives test (see section IV in text). An asterisk denotes
significance at the 5% level and two asterisks at the 1% level.
TABLE 4
The Effects of Sectoral Public Expenditures in "New" Capital and
Maintenance on Canadian Growth (Dependent Variable: Three-Year
Forward Moving Average of GDP per Capita Growth Rate)
Independent Variable Eq. (2.1) Eq. (2.2)
Constant 89.16 (44.99) * 67.05 (46.27)
Inflation -0.07 (0.15) -0.07 (0.18)
Budget deficit -- -0.39 (0.28)
Terms of trade growth rate -- --
Government-owned enterprises
Capital and repair expenditures -11.87 (11.31) -8.24 (11.41)
(Capital and repair 0.84 (1.48) 0.32 (1.50)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -1.96 (0.90) * -2.08 (0.89) *
(Maintenance) (2) 0.02 (0.02) 0.03 (0.02)
Government institutions and
housing
Capital and repair expenditures 19.37 (14.82) 22.31 (14.81)
(Capital and repair -7.27 (6.40) -9.55 (6.55)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance 1.43 (0.52) ** 0.94 (0.61)
(Maintenance) (2) -0.05 (0.01) ** -0.04 (0.01) *
Government departments
Capital and repair expenditures -7.29 (15.40) -3.49 (15.24)
(Capital and repair 0.62 (2.26) 0.13 (2.23)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -1.70 (1.59) -0.64 (1.69)
(Maintenance) (2) 0.03 (0.04) 0.01 (0.04)
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.80 0.80
D-W 1.72 1.65
Independent Variable Eq. (2.3) Eq. (2.4)
Constant 89.27 (44.98) * 66.28 (46.23)
Inflation -0.09 (0.18) 0.04 (0.19)
Budget deficit -- -0.40 (0.28)
Terms of trade growth rate 0.02 (0.11) 0.04 (0.11)
Government-owned enterprises
Capital and repair expenditures -12.33 (11.82) -9.24 (11.77)
(Capital and repair 0.92 (1.58) 0.49 (1.58)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -1.95 (0.90) * -2.06 (0.89) *
(Maintenance) (2) 0.02 (0.02) 0.03 (0.02)
Government institutions and
housing
Capital and repair expenditures 19.45 (14.77) 22.64 (14.71)
(Capital and repair -7.25 (6.39) -9.62 (6.50)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance 1.45 (0.52) ** 0.97 (0.61)
(Maintenance) (2) -0.05 (0.01) ** -0.04 (0.01) *
Government departments
Capital and repair expenditures -6.73 (15.72) -1.91 (15.62)
(Capital and repair 0.54 (2.32) -0.11 (2.29)
expenditures) (2)
Maintenance -1.76 (1.62) -0.75 (1.70)
(Maintenance) (2) 0.03 (0.04) 0.01 (0.04)
[R.sup.2] adjusted 0.79 0.80
D-W 1.74 1.69
Notes: "Capital and repair expenditures" denotes sectoral public
expenditures in new capital and maintenance (GDP%) and "Maintenance"
the share of maintenance in sectoral expenditure, respectively.
Estimation method is generalized method of means with correction for
second-order autocorrelation. SEs are in parentheses. An asterisk
denotes significance at the 5% level and two asterisks at the 1% level.
(1.) For the rest of the article, the terms public capital stock
and infrastructure shall be used interchangeably.
(2.) The issue of capital maintenance is not new in the literature.
In a series of papers during the 1970s, several authors investigated the
private firm's problem between optimal maintenance level and the
maintenance dependent depreciation rate; see, among others, Schmalensee
(1974), Feldstein and Rothschild (1974), Su (1975), and Parks (1979).
Subsequent empirical studies found that although decaying constant rates
of depreciation often provide a reasonable approximation at a given
point in time, there is mounting evidence that capital deterioration is
endogenous and, in particular, associated with maintenance expenditure;
for a brief survey of related empirical findings, see Nelson and Caputo
(1997). More recent strands of the theoretical literature investigate
the role of private maintenance in aggregate models of the business
cycle (Collard and Kollintzas 2000), on capital utilitization at the
firm level (Licandro and Puch 2000) or at the aggregate level
(Aznar-Marquez and Ruiz-Tamarit 2001; Licandro et al. 2001), and the
complementarity or substitutability between maintenance and investment
(Boucekkine and Ruiz-Tamarit, 2003).
(3.) Existing work on maintenance expenditures in public capital is
usually performed in the context of cost-benefit analysis and is
primarily concerned with road damage and optimal user charges, which
rely on required repairs and their timing; see Newbery (1988). Another
type of project-based analysis is conducted in terms of
'recurrent' expenditures, which are the "operations and
maintenance expenditures needed to run the project at a level consistent
with its expected use, and to maintain the capacity of the investment
during its expected lifetime" (Hood et al. 2002).
(4.) One such source for manufacturing is the Survey of
Business" Plans for New Plants and Equipment utilized by Feldstein
and Foot (1971) and Eisner (1972). According to the figures quoted in
these papers, replacement expenditure in the United States amounted to
around 60% of planned investment in manufacturing for the 1949-68
period.
(5.) The private sector consists of the business sector and the
private institutions-housing sector.
(6.) The classification follows that of Statistics Canada for the
Capital and Repair Expenditures survey. There are 19 government
departments (and ministries of state) in Canada and more than 100
government institutions, including among others health services, science
and research centers, transportation agencies, cultural boards, and
financial-economic authorities (like Statistics Canada or the Bank of
Canada).
(7.) Interestingly, the government institutions and housing sector
has exhibited the largest variability. We shall not address issues like
the relationship between maintenance variability, depreciation, and
business cycle fluctuations. For a related paper, see Collard and
Kollintzas (2000).
(8.) In a similar vein, Karras (1996) has used growth accounting to
test for the optimal size of the government sector in various economies,
as suggested by the standard Barro (1990) model.
(9.) Due to the presence of overlapping observations and the serial
correlation of the residuals, estimation is carried via generalized
method of moments with a correction for second-order moving-average
autocorrelation. We also experimented with the percentage change between
t + 3 and t + 1 growth rate as the dependent variable with no
substantial changes in the results.
(10.) We also experimented with other candidate control variables,
such as the U.S. growth rate, the degree of openness of the economy
(given by the ratio of exports and imports to GDP), the real exchange
rate, private investment, and private capital and repair expenditure
from the same Canadian survey, but none of these variables yielded
plausible or statistically significant coefficients for the
corresponding variables. More important, the inclusion of these
variables did not alter the significance and magnitude of the
coefficients of the public capital expenditures' regressors.
(11.) We also experimented with other potential specifications,
like multiplicative terms or a third-order effect in total public
capital expenditures, but no statistically significant results were
obtained.
(12.) Notice that the test statistic is not affected by the
presence of the stochastic explanatory variables; see, for example,
Greene (2000).
(13.) As suggested by a referee, an alternative route to derive an
indication about the implied impact in these relationships could rely on
the search of a threshold effect (see, e.g., Khan and Senhadji 2001).
Preliminary evidence (available on request) indeed confirmed that the
within-sample inflexion point occurs at a low level of total public
capital expenditures, which was at the region of 6.6%-6.7% of GDP and is
very close to the implied growth-maximizing share given in the text.
However, the corresponding within-sample threshold for the share of
maintenance was at 18.6%-18.8% of total expenditures and is higher than
the growth-maximizing one implied by the approach adopted here. Absent a
strict theoretical formulation leading to a precise parametric
specification where the growth-maximizing levels can be directly
identified and estimated, we consider this evidence as an overall
confirmation of the findings reported in Table 3 and of the associated
policy implications.
(14.) We thank a referee for pointing this potential explanation to
us.
REFERENCES
Aznar-Marquez, J., and J. R. Ruiz-Tamarit. "Endogenous Growth,
Capital Utilitization and Depreciation." IRES Discussion Paper
2001-37, 2001.
Aschauer, D. "Is Public Expenditure Productive?" Journal
of Monetary Economics, 23(2), 1989, 177-200.
Barro, R. "Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous
Growth." Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1990, 103-25.
Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. "Public Finance in Models of
Economic Growth." Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 1992, 645-61.
--. Economic Growth. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1995.
Bitros, G. "A Statistical Theory of Expenditures in Capital
Maintenance and Repair." Journal of Political Economy, 84(5), 1976,
917-36.
Bleaney, M., N. Gemmell, and R. Kneller. "Testing the
Endogenous Growth Model: Public Expenditure, Taxation and Growth over
the Long Run." Canadian Journal of Economics, 34(1), 2001, 36-57.
Bodman, P. "A Contribution on the Empirics of Trade, Migration
and Economic Growth for Australia and Canada." International
Economic Journal, 12(3), 1998, 41-62.
Boucekkine, R., and R. Ruiz-Tamarit. "Capital Investment and
Maintenance: Complements or Substitutes?" Journal of Economics,
78(1), 2003, 1-28.
Collard, F., and T. Kollintzas. "Maintenance, Utilization, and
Depreciation along the Business Cycle." CEPR Discussion Paper 2477,
2000.
Devarajan, S., V. Swaroop, and H. Zou. "The Composition of
Public Expenditure and Economic Growth." Journal of Monetary
Economics, 37(2), 1996, 313-44.
Eisner, R. "Components of Capital Expenditures: Replacement
and Modernization versus Expansion." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 54(3), 1972, 297-305.
Feldstein, M., and D. Foot. "The Other Half of Gross
Investment: Replacement and Modernization Expenditures." Review of
Economics and Statistics, 53(1), 1971, 49-58.
Feldstein, M., and M. Rothschild. "Towards an Economic Theory
of Replacement Investment." Econometrica, 42(3), 1974, 393-423.
Gemmell, N., and R. Kneller. "The Impact of Fiscal Policy on
Long-Run Growth." European Economy, 1, 2001, 97-129.
Greene, W. Econometric Analysis, 4th ed. New Jersey: Prentice Hall,
2000.
Glomm, G., and B. Ravikamar. "Public investment in
infrastructure in a simple growth model." Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 18(6), 1994, 1173-1187.
Hood, R., D. Husband, and F. Yu. "Recurrent Expenditure
Requirements of Capital Projects: Estimation for Budget Purposes."
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2938, 2002.
Kalaitzidakis, P., and S. Kalyvitis. "On the Macroeconomic
Implications of Maintenance in Public Capital." Journal of
Public" Economics, 88(3-4), 2004, 695-712.
Karras, G. "The Optimal Government Size: Further International
Evidence on the Productivity of Government Services."
Economic" Inquiry, 34(2), 1996, 193-203.
Khan, M., and A. Senhadji. "Threshold Effects in the
Relationship between Inflation and Growth." IMF Staff Papers,
48(1), 2001, 1-21.
Kneller, R., M. Bleaney, and N. Gemmell. "Public Policy and
Government Budget Constraint: Evidence from the OECD." Journal of
Public" Economics, 74(2), 1999, 171-90.
Licandro, O., and L. A. Puch. "Capital Utilization,
Maintenance Costs and the Business Cycle." Annales d'Economie
et de Statistique, 58, 2000, 143-64.
Licandro, O., L. A. Puch, and J. R. Ruiz-Tamarit. "Optimal
Growth under Endogenous Depreciation, Capital Utilization and
Maintenance Costs." Investigagiones Economicas, 25(3), 2001,
543-59.
McGrattan, E., and J. Schmitz. "Maintenance and Repair: Too
Big to Ignore." Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review, 23(4), 1999, 2-13.
Nelson, R., and M. Caputo. "Price Changes, Maintenance, and
the Rate of Depreciation." Review of Economics and Statistics,
79(3), 1997, 422-30.
Newbery, D. "Road Damage Externalities and Road User
Charges." Econometrica, 56(2), 1988, 295-316.
Parks, R. "Durability, Maintenance and the Price of Used
Assets." Economic Inquiry, 17(2), 1979, 197-217.
Rioja, F. "Filling Potholes: Macroeconomic Effects of
Maintenance vs. New Investment in Public Infrastructure." Journal
of Public Economics, 87(9-10), 2003, 2281-304.
Schmalensee, R. "Market Structure, Durability, and Maintenance
Effort." Review of Economic Studies, 41(2), 1974, 277-87.
Serletis, A. "Testing the Long-Run Implications of the
Neoclassical Growth Model for Canada." Journal of Macroeconomics,
16(2), 1994, 329-46.
--. "Government Activities and Tests of the Long-Run
Implications of the Neoclassical Growth Model for Canada." Canadian
Journal of Economics, 29(3), 1996, 635-42.
Su, T. "Durability of Consumption Goods Reconsidered."
American Economic Review, 65(1), 1975, 148-57.
Wylie, P. "Infrastructure and Canadian Economic Growth."
Canadian Business Economics, 3(2), 1995, 40-52.
--. "Infrastructure and Canadian Economic Growth
1946-1991." Canadian Journal of Economics, 29, 1996, S350-55.
PANTELIS KALAITZIDAKIS and SARANTIS KALYVITIS *
* We have benefited from discussions with G. Bitros, G. Karras, P.
Koundouri, K. Kyriazidou, T. Mamuneas, K. Panopoulou, and A.
Philippopoulos, and by comments and suggestions by participants at
various conferences and seminars. We also thank two anonymous referees
for helpful comments and suggestions. Kalyvitis acknowledges financial
assistance by the Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade
of Canada through the Canadian Studies Program. The usual disclaimer
applies.
Kalaitzidakis: University of Crete, Department of Economics,
Rethymno 74100, Greece. Phone 30-2831077408, Fax 30-2831077406, E-mail
kalaitz@econ.soc.uoc.gr
Kalyvitis: Athens University of Economics and Business, Department
of International and European Economic Studies, Patision 76 Str., Athens
10434, Greece. Phone 30-2108203273, Fax 30-202108221011, E-mail
skalyvitis@aueb.gr