Price competition under cost uncertainty: a laboratory analysis.
Abbink, Klaus ; Brandts, Jordi
I. INTRODUCTION
In markets with posted price competition sellers independently
choose prices, which are publicly communicated to buyers on a
take-it-or-leave-it basis. Such posted pricing is common in retail
markets as well as in industries in which regulatory agencies require
that prices be filed with them and that discounts not be granted. This
type of competition has been studied both theoretically and
experimentally. The theoretical work by Bertrand (1883) gave rise to
what is known as the Bertrand paradox: If marginal costs are constant,
then two firms are enough for equilibrium prices to equal marginal cost;
beyond monopoly, there is no inverse relation between prices and the
number of firms in the market. Subsequent theoretical work has consisted
in proposing price competition models that "resolved" this
paradox. Vives (1999) discusses the theoretical work on price
competition in detail.
The experimental work in the area--surveyed in Holt (1995)--has
contributed data about behavior in various price competition
environments. Early experimental studies on posted prices, like those of
Williams (1973) and Plott and Smith (1978), were not based on formal
models of price competition. Instead, they took the Walrasian outcome as
the natural benchmark for evaluating behavior. More recently, a number
of experimental studies have investigated price competition on the basis
of designs more closely connected to theoretical models.
Davis and Holt (1994) and Kruse et al. (1994) study price
competition in environments in which the equilibrium prediction involves
a price distribution with average prices above marginal cost in the
spirit of the first theoretical resolution of the Bertrand paradox
proposed by Edgeworth (1925). Both studies find price dispersion distinct but qualitatively similar to those predicted by Nash
equilibrium. The study by Morgan et al. (2001) experimentally examines a
model on price competition with informed and uninformed consumers.
Informed consumers search for the best price, but uninformed consumers
are captive to a firm. As a result, pure strategy equilibria do not
exist. The authors find observed price distributions to be different
from the prediction but the comparative statics of the strategic
equilibrium to be supported.
Some studies deal with how the number of firms affects prices.
Dufwenberg and Gneezy (2000) address this question in what can be seen
as the first direct test of the Bertrand paradox as such. They study the
effects of market concentration in a one-shot price competition
framework with constant marginal cost and inelastic demand. In their
experiments, price is above marginal cost for the case of two firms but
equal to that cost for three and four firms. (1) In their results, two
firms are not enough to get prices down to marginal cost, but three
firms are. In a sense, the Bernard paradox remains, because the
experimental results do not exhibit the intuitively expected negative
relation between the number of firms and the price-cost margin.
Selten and Apesteguia (2002) experimentally study price competition
in a model of spatial competition. Their setting involves positive
profit margins in the Cournot equilibrium, but these margins are
constant in the number of firms. In line with this prediction, they find
very little difference in average prices across their treatments with
three, four, and five firms, and average prices are close to but
slightly above those chosen in equilibrium. In the spatial competition
game experimentally studied by Orzen and Sefton (2003), pure strategy
equilibria do not exist. Predictions for the expected price involve
decreasing prices for increasing firm numbers; a prediction that is met
in the experimental data.
Abbink and Brandts (2002) examine the effects of the number of
firms in an experimental design in which price competition can lead to
positive equilibrium price-cost margins. Their design is based on the
theoretical model by Dastidar (1995) in which there are multiple
equilibria in pure strategies, compatible with price-cost margins being
decreasing in the number of firms. Firms operate under decreasing
returns to scale and have to serve the whole market. The experimental
results are that average prices tend to decrease with the number of
firms, but this is mainly due to less collusion in larger oligopolies.
Numerous studies report results on related issues from quantity
competition environments. Huck et al. (1999, 2004) provide results and a
recent survey of work on the effects of market concentration under
repeated quantity competition. (2) Their conclusion is that duopolists
sometimes manage to collude, but in markets with more than three firms
collusion is difficult. With exactly three firms, Offerman et al. (2002)
observe that market outcomes depend on the information environment:
Firms collude when they are provided with information on individual
quantities but not individual profits. In many instances, total average
output exceeds the Nash prediction, and furthermore, these deviations
are increasing in the number of firms. The price-cost margins found in
experimental repeated quantity competition are, hence, qualitatively
consistent with the Cournot prediction for the static game.
We present an experimental study based on another theoretical
proposal to resolve the Bertrand paradox. Spulber (1995) analyzes an
extension of the standard Bertrand model in which marginal costs are not
common knowledge among the competitors. (3) Rather, they are, for each
firm independently, drawn from a distribution and private information
for the individual firms. This is an a priori very appealing model,
because it is quite natural to consider that firms only have approximate
information about rivals' costs.
This incomplete information about costs changes the equilibrium
prediction dramatically: Prices are now set substantially above marginal
costs. The realized market prices will depend on the random draws, but
in expectation prices decrease with the number of firms so that a
sufficient increase of the number of firms implies a prediction of lower
prices. The equilibrium prediction is in pure, not in mixed strategies.
With our work we wish to contribute to delineating a more complete
picture of price competition from an experimental viewpoint. In
particular, we are interested in what price and efficiency levels arise
and how they depend on the number of firms. With respect to price levels
we are interested in finding out whether prices remain above Walrasian
levels with three or four firms.
Our results show that in accordance with Spulber (1995), market
prices indeed decrease significantly with the number of firms but--on
average--always stay above marginal costs. In this sense, our results
back the theoretical resolution of the Bertrand paradox. However,
compared to the equilibrium prediction, prices tend to be lower in all
treatments. This is good news for consumers, but it does not lift total
surplus beyond the level that would result from equilibrium play.
Rather, observed surplus and predicted total surplus are very close to
one another. The reason is that efficiency gains from closer to marginal
cost pricing are canceled out by occasional displacements, that is, by
quantities produced by firms other than the one with the lowest costs.
In relation to the highest possible surplus the actual surplus increases
with the number of firms.
The findings of this experiment also contribute to the literature
on experimental auctions. The model has a striking similarity to a
conventional sealed-bid first-price auction, in which buyers make bids
for a single item, the private valuations of which are drawn from
independent distributions (for an overview see Kagel 1995). However,
there are important differences. First, in most experiments on
first-price sealed-bid auctions, the bidders are buyers rather than
sellers. (4) Second, and more important, this is the first experiment on
this type of auction that employs an endogenous demand depending on the
bids. This feature, as remarked by Hansen (1988), has significant
efficiency implications. In a sealed-bid auction with a fixed quantity,
any outcome is efficient as long as the auction is won by the buyer with
the highest valuation (or the seller with the lowest costs,
respectively). In an auction with endogenous demand efficiency is also
affected by the resulting price.
II. THE MODEL AND THE EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN
The Model
In our experimental markets the demand function is linear with a
slope of 1, to choose the simplest formulation of such a function. We
chose an inverse demand function
p = 99 - Q
for our study, where Q is the total quantity demanded. (5) Each
firm i's cost function is linear with constant marginal costs
[c.sub.i], where the level of [c.sub.i] is randomly drawn from a uniform
distribution on the interval [0, 99] and is only known by that firm. The
interval covers the entire range from zero to the prohibitive price. By
choosing such a wide range, we focus on an environment in which the
effect of cost uncertainty is most pronounced. The random draws for each
firm are independent from one another. There are no fixed costs.
Firms set their prices simultaneously. Therefore, no firm knows the
choice of any other firm when setting its own price. As in the standard
Bertrand model, only firms setting the lowest price produce. If one firm
sets the lowest price alone, it serves all demand at that price, if two
or more firms set a common lowest price, each of them sells an equal
share of that demand. There are no capacity constraints, each firm can
(and must) always serve its entire demand.
A firm's strategy assigns a price to any possible realization
of the cost parameter. In equilibrium, firms set prices increasing in
their cost parameters and substantially above marginal costs. The reason
why price competition does not drive equilibrium prices down to marginal
costs is intuitive: Upward deviations from the firm's marginal
costs will not necessarily result in the loss of all demand, Because it
is possible that the competitors' costs and prices are higher than
the own ones. Rather, the firm faces a trade-off: By increasing its
mark-up on its marginal costs, it will increase its profit in the case
that its price is still the lowest. The probability of winning the
market, on the other hand, becomes smaller the higher the firm sets its
mark-up. The strategic situation is similar to that faced by a bidder in
a first-price auction with independent private values: In such an
auction, bidders' values for an item on auction are independently
drawn from a common distribution, where only the own valuation is known
to a bidder when making his or her bid. Spulber (1995) makes extensive
use of this analogy and characterizes the equilibria of Bertrand
competition with private cost information using techniques developed for
auction theory.
Spulber (1995) analyzes the properties of the equilibrium
prediction for a very general model of this kind. Although the general
case involves some complexity, the equilibrium price functions for the
symmetric case with linear demand are straightforward to compute. (6) A
firm maximizes its expected profit by setting the price p as a linear
function of the cost parameter c as
p(c) = (99 + nc)/(1 + n).
For a given n, the equilibrium price function is linear in the cost
parameter but not proportional to it. If the costs are zero, the firm
will charge a high mark-up to maximize its expected profit. If the costs
are maximal, however, the firm sets a price equal to its marginal costs.
Figure 1 depicts the equilibrium price functions for n = 2, n = 3, and n
= 4.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The Conduct of the Experiment
The experiment was conducted at the Centre for Decision Research
and Experimental Economics (CeDEx) of the University of Nottingham. The
software for the experiment was developed using the Ratlmage programming
package (Abbink and Sadrieh 1995). Subjects were recruited by email from
a database of students who had previously registered at CeDEx to express
their willingness in participating in experiments. Each subject was
allowed to participate in only one session, and no subject had
participated in experiments similar to the present one. The subjects
were undergraduate students from a wide range of disciplines.
In our experimental sessions, subjects interacted in fixed groups
of two, three, or four for 50 identical rounds. At the beginning of the
round, the unit cost parameter was drawn randomly, visualized by a
"one-armed bandit" on the terminal's computer screen. The
computer drew random numbers for each round and each individual
independently; we did not use controlled lottery outcomes. Because the
treatments involve a different number of firms and thus a different
number of random draws in each round, it is not possible to use the same
set of realizations for all treatments. The use of completely
independent draws creates some sampling variation, as subjects in
different treatments observe different samples of cost parameters.
However, because we conducted sessions with 50 rounds and a large number
of independent markets, such effects do not affect the comparability of
our treatments substantially.
Once the cost parameter was drawn, each subject had to choose a
price between 0 and 99 talers (the fictitious experimental currency) per
unit. For convenience, cost parameters and price choices were restricted
to integers. After each round each subject was informed about the prices
chosen by each of the other subjects in the market as well as about all
subjects' sales quantities. As in actual markets prices are
typically publicly announced, but cost information is kept private, we
did not inform subjects about their competitors' cost parameters
even after the round. Consequently, subjects were told only their own
revenue, costs, and profit.
The same subjects played in the same market throughout the session
to reflect the repeated game character of actual oligopoly markets.
Thus, our setting can be seen as a stylized model of an oligopoly in
which firms face strong fluctuations of costs, for example, caused by
changing natural factors. Hansen (1988) observed that such a sequence of
pricing rounds describes quite well the groping of market forces to
react to an ever-changing equilibrium. Subjects were not told with whom
of the other participants they were in the same group.
To accommodate some losses, subjects were granted a capital balance
of 3,000 talers at the outset of each session. (7) The total earnings of
a subject from participating in this experiment were equal to his or her
capital balance plus the sum of all the profits made during the
experiment minus the sum of his losses. A session lasted for about 75
minutes (this includes the time spent to read the instructions). At the
end of the experiment, subjects were paid their total earnings
anonymously in cash, at a conversion rate of 1 British pound for 2,000
(n = 2), 1,250 (n = 3), and 1,000 (n = 4) talers. Subjects earned
between 6.13 [pounds sterling] and 21.20 [pounds sterling] with an
average of 11.26 [pounds sterling], which is considerably more than
students' regular wage in Nottingham. (8) At the time of the
experiment, the exchange rate to other major currencies was
approximately US$1.50 and 1.50 [pounds sterling] for 1 [pounds
sterling].
We conducted two sessions with 10 and 14 subjects for n = 2, two
sessions with 12 and 15 subjects for n = 3, and three sessions with 20,
16, and 16 subjects for n = 4. (9) Subjects interact with each other
within groups but not across groups, so that each group can be
considered a statistically independent observation. Thus, we gathered 12
independent observations for n = 2, 9 independent observations for n =
3, and 11 independent observations for n = 4.
Our analysis primarily consists of nonparametric tests performed on
these data points. Most analyses are made up of pairwise comparisons of
the treatments. For these we use Fisher's two-sample randomization test, applied to test statistics (e.g., average prices or surplus
levels) from the independent observations. (10) In some occasions we
also apply tests to statistics within one sample, for example, as when
comparing our observations to the equilibrium prediction. In this case,
we use the nonparametric binomial test.
III. RESULTS
Average Prices and the Number of Firms
The three treatments of our experiment allow us to study the effect
of market concentration on market outcomes. In particular, we can
analyze whether an increase in the number of competitors results in
lower transaction or market prices. Table 1 indicates that on average,
this is the case. The table shows average market prices, that is, the
lowest of chosen prices, for the different groups over the 50 rounds of
the experiment, ordered from the lowest to the highest for each value of
n. Average prices are decreasing in the number of firms. Fisher's
two-sample randomization test rejects the null hypothesis of equal
average prices at a significance level of [alpha] = 0.005 (two-sided)
for all pairwise comparisons of treatments. Therefore, our results
provide qualitative support for the equilibrium prediction of expected
prices decreasing with n. (11)
One may ask whether prices tend to increase or decrease over the 50
rounds of the experiment. Figure 2 shows the evolution of average prices
for each round averaged over all markets within a treatment. Visually,
the diagram does not strongly suggest any tendency in either direction.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
To test for trends statistically, we use the following method. For
each session separately we compute nonparametric Spearman rank
correlation coefficients between the market price and the round number.
Using these as summary statistics, we apply the binomial test to detect
a systematic tendency to rising or falling prices. The binomial test
rejects the null hypothesis at a one-sided 5% level if at least 10 out
of 12 observations for duopolies, 8 out of 9 observations for
triopolies, and 9 out of 11 observations for tetrapolies point in the
same direction. Table 2 shows the outcome of this analysis. In none of
the treatments, the null hypothesis of no trend can be rejected. (12)
Asking Prices
The aforementioned results clearly indicate that average prices
tend to decrease with the number of firms. There are two possible causes
for this effect. First, more aggressive pricing behavior could be
prevalent in larger markets. This would naturally lead to lower average
market prices. However, even if price setting behavior were the same
across treatments, we would observe the phenomenon of decreasing market
prices. This is because the market price is the minimum of the n asking
prices. Given identical price functions, the lowest of four asking
prices would be lower on average than the lowest of three or two asking
prices.
Table 3 shows average asking prices, that is, the average of all
chosen prices, for the different groups over the 50 rounds of the
experiment, ordered from the lowest to the highest for each value of n.
The table shows that duopolists ask for considerably higher prices than
both triopolists and tetrapolists, but the difference between triopolies
and tetrapolies is only marginal. In fact, Fisher's two-sample
randomization test rejects the null hypothesis of equal average asking
prices for the comparison of both n = 2 versus n = 3 and n = 2 versus n
= 4 at a significance level of [alpha] = 0.005 (one-sided), whereas the
comparison of n = 3 versus n = 4 is not significant (one-tail p = 0.29).
Thus, increasing the number of firms from two to three induces
significantly more aggressive pricing behavior, but increasing the
number of competitors further to four firms has no significant effect on
the mark-ups charged by the firms. The effect on prices, therefore, then
stems from the effect that the minimum of the competitors' unit
costs tends to be lower with more firms.
An additional perspective on different pricing behavior across
treatments can be obtained in the following way. Estimate a linear
regression for each subject's pricing function. Then take the
resulting intercepts and focus on the comparison of the distributions of
the intercepts across treatments. Figure 3 shows the three corresponding
cumulative distributions and one can see that the differences between n
= 2 and the other two cases are quite substantial, whereas the two
distributions for n = 3 and n = 4 are rather alike.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Pricing Behavior as Compared with the Theoretical Prediction
The bottom rows of Tables 1 and 3 indicate the equilibrium
prediction of market prices and asking prices. The comparison of
observed averages with the equilibrium averages already suggests that
experimental firms tend to price more aggressively than predicted in
equilibrium. Figure 4 shows all the prices that have been asked in the
three treatments, plotted against the corresponding unit costs. In
addition, two benchmarks have been drawn into the figures: The diagonal
line depicts Walrasian prices, equal to marginal (unit) costs, which
lead to zero profits for the firm serving the market. The second line,
above the zero-profit line, is the equilibrium prediction for the case
of risk-neutrality.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
It can be seen that in fact the majority of asking prices are in
between the equilibrium prediction and the marginal cost pricing line.
The prices charged by the firms do contain a mark-up on the marginal
costs, but this mark-up is substantially lower than predicted in
equilibrium. This is reminiscent of a phenomenon observed in independent
private value auction experiments (see Kagel 1995). In that context
buyers were observed to bid above the equilibrium prediction for
risk-neutrality, which corresponds to below-equilibrium pricing in our
model. Several explanations of this fact have been suggested, among them
risk aversion, nonlinear probability weighting, and buyers enjoying the
fact of winning as such. These explanations may also account for the
relatively aggressive pricing we observe in our data. Like in
first-price auctions, risk-averse firms would attempt to increase the
probability of winning at the expense of lower profit margins, and
therefore set lower prices.
Table 4 shows the number of asking prices that are above, equal to,
and below the equilibrium prediction. The table indicates that the
underpricing, as compared to equilibrium, is less pronounced in
duopolies than in the markets with more firms. Broken down to individual
markets, we can observe more asking prices below than above the
equilibrium prediction in all 9 markets with three and all 11 markets
with four firms. For duopolies, this is the case for only 8 of the 12
markets, whereas in 4 markets more prices above than below equilibrium
can be observed. (13) A possible explanation is that with two firms,
participants may attempt to collude to establish higher and more
profitable prices. This seems relatively easier in duopolies than in
larger markets, as coordination requirements are less. However, it is
generally hard to establish successful cooperation in the present model.
Firms can only observe the prices set by their competitors, but not the
costs. The competitors' prices, however, will depend on their
costs, such that attempts to signal one's willingness to cooperate
are hard to transmit, as the prices are difficult to interpret in that
way. As a result, pricing is still quite aggressive even in duopolies.
(14)
With more firms, the equilibrium pricing function comes closer to
the zero profit line. Prices in our experiment tend to be in between the
two lines, an effect that is more pronounced in the larger oligopolies.
Of course we can only speculate about what kind of pricing behavior we
would expect in very large markets. Our findings would suggest that
large markets would show a clustering of prices close to the zero-profit
line, with profit margins disappearing as the number of firms grows.
Figure 4 seems to suggest that the below-equilibrium pricing is
less pronounced for lower draws of the cost parameter. To test this, we
have included a separate analysis for costs from the range of 0 to 10 in
Table 4. Indeed, the predominance of lower-than-equilibrium prices is
less extreme for all treatments. In duopolies prices below and above
equilibrium look quite balanced. The binomial test, applied to the
number of below- and above-equilibrium prices in the individual
independent markets, does not reject the null hypothesis of equal
likelihood at any significant level for this treatment. For the larger
oligopolies, however, there is a strong and statistically significant
tendency toward prices lower than equilibrium across the entire range of
cost parameters.
Figure 4 shows a small number of instances in which firms set
prices below costs, which can be interpreted as a mistake. We observe
seven such errors (0.58%) in n = 2, five (0.37%) in n = 3, and three
(0.14%) in n = 4. These figures may suggest that the likelihood of
errors decreases with the number of firms. However, the frequencies are
far too small to apply meaningful statistical tests. Note, furthermore,
that the figure for n = 4 does not include the two markets with
bankruptcies, which are caused by at least one fatal mistake.
Efficiency
The three treatments of our experiment enable us to compare
efficiency levels for different degrees of market concentration. Here we
present information on both absolute and relative efficiency. The
measure for efficiency we look at is the total surplus, conventionally
defined as the sum of consumer and producer surplus. This would be
maximized if (1) the good is produced by the firm with the lowest unit
costs, and (2) the market price equals the unit costs of this firm. (15)
Table 5 shows average total surplus--in talers--for the different groups
over the 50 rounds of the experiment, ordered from the lowest to the
highest for each value of n.
The absolute total surplus does not account for the fact that
larger markets exhibit a greater potential for generating surplus,
because the expected minimum costs are lower. Therefore, we also compute
relative total surplus as the ratio between attained and maximal total
surplus. The results appear in Table 6. The table shows that in all
treatments most of the possible surplus is extracted from the market,
where duopolies perform somewhat worse than oligopolies with more than
two firms. Moving from two to three firms induces a larger increase in
surplus extraction than increasing the number further from three to four
firms.
However, all differences including the latter are significant at
[alpha] = 0.01 (one-sided) or lower, according to Fisher's
two-sample randomization test. The fact that relative efficiency
increases with the number of firms indicates that the absolute
efficiency advantage of more firms is not only induced by the greater
potential of generating surplus, which stems from the fact that the
lowest unit cost is typically the lower the more firms there are in the
market. More aggressive bidding also contributes to higher efficiency.
It is striking that both absolute and relative efficiencies are
very close to the figures achieved in the theoretical equilibrium. The
binomial test, applied to the difference between observed and predicted
surplus in the individual sessions, cannot reject the null hypothesis of
no difference at any conventional level. It seems that the
efficiency-enhancing effect of more aggressive bidding is just canceled
out by the loss in cost efficiency. Notice that in equilibrium it is
always guaranteed that the firm(s) with the lowest costs serve all the
demand, whereas this is not always the case in the experimental markets.
In fact, in on average 5.25 out of 50 rounds (or 10.5%) in duopolies,
6.33 rounds (12.7%) in triopolies, and 6.72 rounds (13.4%) in
tetrapolies at least one firms that does not have the lowest costs
produces positive quantities. (16) Thus, although most of the time the
most cost efficient firm(s) serve all the demand, occasional
displacements reduce efficiency to the extent that similar surplus
levels as in equilibrium are observed, though firms tend to price more
aggressively.
The question arises whether these displacements are a temporary
phenomenon occurring mainly in early rounds of the game, when
participants are less experienced and their behavior may be more
erratic. We therefore look at the number of displacements in the first
and the second half of the experiment separately. Table 7 shows the
number of markets in which we observe an increasing, decreasing, and
constant number of displacement from the first to the second 25 rounds
of the experiment.
Indeed, in all treatments we observe that the number of markets
with more displacements in earlier rounds is greater than the number of
markets exhibiting the opposite trend. However, this is statistically
significant only for the n = 4 treatment, for which the binomial test
rejects the null hypothesis of equal likelihood of positive and negative
trends at a (weak) significance level of at [alpha] 0.10 (one-sided). If
we pool the data from all treatments, the test rejects the null
hypothesis at a one-sided significance level of [alpha] = 0.05. Thus,
production efficiency in our experimental oligopolies tends to increase
over time.
Profits
To conclude the presentation of our experimental data, we look at
the implications of our findings for firms' profits. Table 8 shows
average round profits for the different groups over the 50 rounds of the
experiment, ordered from the lowest to the highest for each value of n.
The table shows average round profits decreasing with the number of
firms. For all pairwise comparisons, Fisher's two-sample
randomization test rejects the null hypothesis of equal average round
profits at a significance level lower than [alpha] = 0.001 (one-sided).
Thus, our data exhibit a clear and strong tendency toward profits
decreasing with n. (17)
Because experimental firms tend to charge prices with lower profit
margins than predicted by the theoretical equilibrium, profits are
considerably lower than would result from equilibrium play.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
We report on an experiment examining price levels and the relation
between these levels and the number of firms in a price competition
environment with uncertainty about competitors' costs. Our results
show that average market prices are decreasing and that total surplus is
increasing in the number of firms; in addition, average market prices
stay above marginal cost for different numbers of firms. To this extent,
our experimental data back the model proposed by Spulber (1995) as a
satisfactory resolution of the Bertrand paradox.
Our experimental data show that if one relaxes the assumption of
complete information on rivals' costs, pricing behavior appears
more intuitive than the one in the standard Bertrand game: We observe
positive profits, which are the higher the fewer competitors there are.
Competition is still strong, because pricing tends to be even more
aggressive than in the strategic equilibrium. This improves
consumers' situation, but it does so at a twofold price for
producers: They suffer from lower profit margins and, in addition, from
occasional displacements when the producing firm is not the most
cost-efficient. With respect to total surplus, consumer benefits and
producer losses--as compared with equilibrium--just cancel each other
out.
Of course, our results cannot be a conclusive investigation of
pricing behavior in oligopolies with cost uncertainty. To keep things
simple, we started with a symmetric framework that does not take
differences in the individual firms' characteristics into account.
In the wider world, structural asymmetries between firms are common, but
they add substantial complexity to the model. Furthermore, we model cost
uncertainty in the very stylized way, as random draws independent for
each firm and every round. Uncertainty about competitors' costs
seems a very natural assumption for real-life oligopolies, but, because
costs are determined by factors like technology or input prices, changes
may not affect the individual firms in a completely independent manner,
neither may they be completely uncorrelated over time. A richer model of
price competition under cost uncertainty therefore should allow for cost
levels evolving dynamically, and for competitors' costs to be
affiliated. We do believe, however, that the insights from this simple
setting can contribute to a broader research agenda on oligopolistic
competition under uncertainty.
APPENDIX: THE WRITTEN INSTRUCTIONS
Instructions for n = 4; other treatments analogous.
General Information
We thank you for coming to the experiment. The purpose of this
session is to study how people make decisions in a particular situation.
During the session it is not permitted to talk or communicate with the
other participants. If you have a question, please raise your hand and
one of us will come to your desk to answer it. During the session you
will earn money. At the end of the session the amount you have earned
will be paid to you in cash. Payments are confidential, we will not
inform any of the other participants of the amount you have earned. In
the following, all amounts of money are denominated in talers, the
experimental currency unit.
In the experiment you take the role of a firm producing a good.
There are four firms serving the market. One firm is you, the other
three firms are three other participants you are matched with. You will
be matched with the same participants throughout the experiment. In
every round, all firms post a price they ask per unit of the good.
The experiment consists of 50 rounds, each structured as follows.
Demand
The buyers of the good are simulated by the computer. Their
behaviour is as follows.
All customers buy only from a firm that offers the lowest price. If
two firms ask different prices, they do not buy anything from the firm
asking for the higher price.
The buyers are willing to buy the more units the lower the price
is. At a price of 99 talers per unit or higher, no units can be sold.
For each taler that the price is lower than 99, the demand for the good
increases by one unit. Thus, at a price of zero talers, buyers are
willing to buy 99 units of the good.
The demand is allocated to the firm(s) offering the lowest price.
If more than one firm asks the same price, all firms asking the lowest
price are allocated equal shares of the demand for that price.
Costs
Each unit a firm produces causes a cost to the firm. The cost per
unit varies from round to round and is likely to be different for each
firm. In particular, the unit costs are drawn randomly at the start of
each round, independently for each firm, from all integer numbers
between 0 and 99 inclusively, where all numbers are equally likely.
Your total costs are the number of units you produce and sell times
the unit costs. There are no fixed costs.
Decisions
In each round you and the other participants that you are matched
to will each separately make a decision. This decision will consist in
choosing a price between 0 and 99. When you have decided on a price
please enter it into the computer.
Earnings
After each round, buyers' demand is computed according to the
pattern described above, i.e. the market demand, in units, is 99 minus
the lowest price. The firm asking the lowest price produces and sells
the market demand. If two or more firms ask the same lowest price, the
market demand is shared equally among these firms.
Your revenue is the number of units you sell times the price you
have asked. Your total costs are the number of units you sell times the
unit cost that have been drawn randomly for that round. Your round
profit is your revenue minus your total costs. Notice that you can make
a loss if you ask a price that is lower than your unit costs.
Firms whose price has not been the lowest make a profit of zero.
Payments
At the beginning of the experiment each of you will receive 3000
talers credited to your talers account. After each round, your round
payoffs are credited to your talers account. At any moment during the
experiment you will be able to check your talers account on the screen.
Should you accumulate losses such that your taler account is
negative, you are bankrupt and cannot continue participating in this
experiment.
At the end of the experiment your total payoff in your talers
account will be converted into Sterling at the exchange rate of 1
[pounds sterling] for every 1000 talers.
TABLE 1
Average Market Prices
Group No. n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
1 35.80 29.58 25.02
2 40.40 32.26 25.52
3 42.80 33.16 26.28
4 42.88 34.94 26.52
5 49.20 35.14 27.68
6 51.08 36.64 28.66
7 51.24 37.26 29.08
8 51.38 37.88 33.56
9 51.64 38.68 33.72
10 51.64 35.10
11 57.28 35.48
12 57.82
Average 48.60 35.06 29.69
Equilibrium 53.70 43.02 35.87
TABLE 2
Correlation between Round Number and
Market Price
Treatment
Spearman Rank
Correlation Coefficient n = 2 n = 3 n = 4 Total
Positive 7 3 6 16
Negative 5 6 5 16
Total 12 9 11 32
TABLE 3
Average Asking Prices
Group No. n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
1 53.69 51.55 48.08
2 56.07 53.19 51.35
3 57.31 55.66 51.49
4 57.83 55.89 53.01
5 62.30 55.99 55.31
6 62.48 57.14 55.37
7 63.42 57.17 55.47
8 63.49 58.44 58.14
9 63.74 58.89 58.29
10 64.93 59.90
11 65.68 60.14
12 68.61
Average 61.63 55.99 55.14
Equilibrium 65.25 61.45 59.19
TABLE 4
Asking Prices Compared to the Equilibrium
Prediction (Percent)
Treatment
Asking Price as Compared
to Equilibrium n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
All costs
Above equilibrium 30.4 14.9 17.8
As in equilibrium 3.6 2.6 2.0
Below equilibrium 66.0 82.5 80.1
Costs [member of] {10, ..., 10}
Above equilibrium 43.1 27.8 25.2
As in equilibrium 3.5 2.1 2.7
Below equilibrium 53.5 70.1 72.1
TABLE 5
Average Total Surplus in the Individual
Markets
Group No. n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
1 1,856 2,596 2,752
2 2,045 2,634 2,800
3 2,154 2,713 2,861
4 2,215 2,714 2,896
5 2,229 2,795 3,043
6 2,240 2,813 3,149
7 2,376 2,910 3,242
8 2,392 2,965 3,295
9 2,443 3,235 3,342
10 2,525 3,405
11 2,622 3,420
12 2,657
Average 2,313 2,819 3,109
Equilibrium 2,289 2,790 3,109
TABLE 6
Average Relative Total Surplus in the
Individual Markets (Percent)
Group No. n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
1 82.37 91.68 93.83
2 82.51 92.14 95.00
3 86.84 92.48 95.67
4 87.56 94.20 95.85
5 87.73 94.85 96.43
6 88.07 95.76 96.75
7 90.25 95.89 97.00
8 91.26 96.02 97.21
9 92.19 97.51 97.32
10 93.65 98.06
11 96.59 98.23
12 98.89
Average 89.83 94.50 96.48
Equilibrium 89.09 93.67 95.99
TABLE 7
Number of Displacements over Time
Treatment
Number of
Displacements n = 2 n = 3 n = 4 Total
Greater in first half 5 6 8 19
Equal in both halves 5 0 1 6
Lower in first half 2 3 2 8
Total 12 9 11 32
TABLE 8
Average Profit per Round
Group No. n = 2 n = 3 n = 4
1 210.9 180.3 123.2
2 321.1 180.6 128.0
3 362.2 191.0 138.3
4 367.6 198.0 148.2
5 385.4 231.6 151.0
6 456.5 235.3 155.4
7 460.9 246.2 161.8
8 472.6 246.8 163.7
9 484.6 258.0 164.5
10 517.8 175.2
11 572.9 198.2
12 580.7
Average 432.8 218.6 155.2
Equilibrium 572.5 373.7 259.5
(1.) With duopolies, Dufwenberg et al. (2002) find that the
introduction of price floors (the minimum feasible price is above
marginal costs) lead to lower average prices compared to the standard
Bertrand game. Thus, the exception for the two-firm case is weakened
when price floors are introduced.
(2.) Huck et al. (2002) study market outcomes when the number of
firms decreases through mergers. They find that merged firms produce
significantly more than firms without a merger history.
(3.) Hansen (1988) earlier presented a very similar model in the
context of auctions. He compares sealed-bid and open auctions in the
presence of a downward-sloping demand and finds the former being more
efficient.
(4.) Radner and Schotter (1989) find some asymmetries in the
bidding of buyers and sellers in their experimental study of the
sealed-bid mechanism.
(5.) The intercept of 99 was chosen for practical reasons. In the
experiment, subjects only needed to choose between all numbers with up
to two digits.
(6.) See Wolfstetter (1997, pp. 407-8). When using the term
equilibrium, we always refer to the equilibrium prediction for
risk-neutral firms.
(7.) If this capital balance was used up, the participant was
"bankrupt," and the remaining subjects in that market played
in a smaller market. Because this creates a very different market
environment, we did not use observations with bankruptcies in our data
analysis. Overall, two participants went bankrupt. Losses can occur if
subjects charge prices below their unit costs.
(8.) These figures do not include the two participants who went
bankrupt. They received a show-up fee of 3 [pounds sterling].
(9.) The show-up rate for the sessions was quite erratic.
Therefore, the number of participants was different across sessions.
(10.) This test can be seen as a nonparametric variant of the
t-test, with which differences in the mean of two samples can be
detected. For a discussion of the power of this test see Moir (1998).
(11.) In all of the following analysis, the equilibrium predictions
we note are based on the unit costs actually drawn in the experiment.
(12.) The detection of trends is relatively difficult in our
experiment, because unit costs vary much over time. Thus prices are
naturally very volatile. There is no straightforward way to normalize the prices, because mark-ups on them are not independent from cost
levels either. However, because our analysis entails 50 rounds, even
weak trends in a market should make it likely that a positive or
negative Spearman rank correlation coefficient would show up. Notice
that our method does not require the individual coefficients to be
significant, as they are only used as summary statistics for the
binomial test.
(13.) If we test the null hypothesis that deviations in both
directions are equally likely, the binomial test rejects the null
hypothesis for both the n = 3 and the n = 4 treatment at a significance
level of [alpha] = 0.005 (one-sided), whereas for duopolies the effect
is not significant.
(14.) The observation that duopolists tend to collude while firms
in larger markets do less so has been found in a number of oligopoly
experiments on different models, for example, Huck et al. (2001) or
Abbink and Brandts (2002).
(15.) In some sense, these calculations are hypothetical, for
consumers were not represented by real subjects. If only the payoffs of
real subjects are considered, efficiency--then the sum of all
firms' profit--is maximized if the lowest-cost firm alone produces
and it charges the monopoly price given its unit costs.
(16.) The difference between treatments is weakly significant (p =
0.07 one-sided) for the comparison between n = 2 and n = 4. All other
pairwise comparisons do not yield a significant result.
(17.) Part of this effect can be attributed to the fact that a firm
will sell fewer times in larger markets. The average profit in case that
the firm does make a nonzero profit is 852.0 in duopolies, 656.4 in
triopolies, and 615.9 in tetrapolies. The difference between n = 2 and
either of n = 3 and n = 4 is significant at [alpha] = 0.01 (one-sided),
the difference between n = 3 and n = 4 is not significant.
REFERENCES
Abbink, K., and J. Brandts. "24." CeDEx Discussion Paper,
University of Nottingham, September 2003.
Abbink, K., and A. Sadrieh. "RatImage---Research Assistance
Toolbox for Computer-Aided Human Behaviour Experiments." SFB Discussion Paper B-325, University of Bonn, 1995.
Bertrand, J. "Theorie Mathematique de la Richesse
Sociale." Journal des Savants, 67, 1883, 499-508.
Dastidar, K. G. "On the Existence of Pure Strategy Bertrand
Equilibrium." Economic Theory, 5, 1995, 19-32.
Davis, D., and C. Holt. "Market Power and Mergers in
Laboratory Markets with Posted Prices." RAND Journal of Economics,
25, 1994, 467 87.
Dufwenberg, M., and U. Gneezy. "Price Competition and Market
Concentration: An Experimental Study." International Journal of
Industrial Organization, 18, 2000, 7-22.
Dufwenberg, M., U. Gneezy, J. Goeree, and R. Nagel. "Price
Floors and Competition." Working Paper, Stockholm University, 2002.
Edgeworth, F. "The Pure Theory of Monopoly." Papers
Relating to Political Economy, 1, 1925, 111-42.
Hansen, R. G. "Auctions with Endogenous Quantity," RAND
Journal of Economics, 19, 1988, 44-58.
Holt, C. "Industrial Organization: A Survey of Laboratory
Research," in The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by J.
Kagel and A. Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995,
347-443.
Huck, S., K. Konrad, W. Muller, and H. T. Normann. "Mergers
and the Perception of Market Power: An Experimental Study." Working
Paper, University College London, 2002.
Huck, S., H. T. Normann, and J. Oechssler. "Learning in
Cournot Oligopoly An Experiment." Economic Journal, 109, 1999,
C80-95.
--. "Two Are Few and Four Are Many: On Number Effects in
Experimental Oligopolies." Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 53, 2004, 435-46.
Kagel, J. "Auctions: A Survey of Experimental Research,"
in The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by J. Kagel and A.
Roth. Princeton, N J: Princeton University Press, 1995, 499-585.
Kruse, J., S. Rassenti, S. Reynolds, and V. Smith.
"Bertrand-Edgeworth Competition in Experimental Markets."
Econometrica, 62, 1994, 343-72.
Moir, R. "A Monte Carlo Analysis of the Fisher Randomization
Technique: Reviving Randomization for Experimental Economists."
Experimental Economics, 1, 1998, 87-100.
Morgan, J., H. Orzen, and M. Sefton. "An Experimental Study of
Price Dispersion." CeDEx Working Paper, University of Nottingham,
2001.
Offerman, T., J. Potters, and J. Sonnemans. "Imitation and
Belief Learning in an Oligopoly Experiment." Review of Economic
Studies 69, 2002, 973-97.
Orzen, H., and M. Sefton. "Mixed Pricing in Oligopoly: An
Experiment." CeDEx Discussion Paper 2003 6, University of
Nottingham, 2003.
Plott, C., and V. Smith. "An Experimental Examination of Two
Exchange Institutions." Review of Economic Studies, 45, 1978,
133-53.
Radner, R., and A. Schotter "The Sealed Bid Mechanism. An
Experimental Study." Journal of Economic Theory, 48, 1989, 179-220.
Selten, R., and J. Apesteguia. "Experimentally Observed
Imitation and Cooperation in Price Competition on the Circle."
BonnEcon Discussion Paper 19/2002, University of Bonn, 2002.
Spulber, D. F. "Bertrand Competition when Rivals' Costs
Are Unknown." Journal of Industrial Economics, 43, 1995, 1-11.
Vives, X. Oligopoly Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1999.
Williams, F. "The Effect of Market Organization on Competitive
Equilibrium: The Multi-Unit Case." Review of Economic Studies, 40,
1973, 97-113.
Wolfstetter, E. "Auctions: An Introduction." Journal of
Economic Surveys, 10, 1997, 367-420.
KLAUS ABBINK and JORDI BRANDTS *
* We thank Dennis W. Jansen, an anonymous referee, and seminar
participants in Amsterdam, Boston, Erfurt, and Lancaster for helpful
comments and suggestions. Financial support by the European Union
through the TMR research network ENDEAR (FMRX-CT98-0238), the Spanish
Ministerio de Educacion y Cultura, the Generalitat de Catalunya, the
University of Nottingham and the Barcelona Economics programme of CREA is gratefully acknowledged. Part of this research was carried out while
Abbink was a visitor at the Institut d'Analisi Economica (CSIC),
Barcelona. He gratefully acknowledges the hospitality and support from
that institution.
Abbink: Lecturer, School of Economics, University of Nottingham,
University Park, Nottingham NG7 2RD, United Kingdom. Phone
44-11-59514768, Fax 44-11-59514159, E-mail klaus.abbink@nottingham.ac.uk
Brandts: Professor, Institut d'Analisi Economica (CSIC),
Campus UAB, 08193 Bellaterra, Spain. Phone 34-93-5806612, Fax
34-93-5801452, E-mail jordi.brandts@ uab.es