Ask prices, offers, and time to sale in an online exchange.
Farmer, Amy ; Stango, Victor
I. INTRODUCTION
In this article, we consider the role served by the ask price
posted by sellers in an online exchange for used computers. The
functional role served by the ask price in this exchange is similar to
that in other bilateral exchange settings: the ask price is not binding
and essentially serves as a starting point for negotiations.
Furthermore, every offer that we observe by buyers lies well below the
ask price. This type of bargaining institution is common in online
marketplaces and also in markets for used cars, housing, and goods sold
through want ads placed in newspapers.
The general finding of empirical literature examining these other
markets is that ask prices convey information. A high ask price may
indicate a desire by the seller to hold out for a higher offer. In such
a setting, ask price dispersion may arise if sellers trade off higher
prices against the likelihood of making a sale. High ask prices will
then lead to higher sale prices on average but longer time on the
market. The standard justification for the inverse relationship between
ask prices and time on the market is that a seller asking a high price
will receive fewer offers if search by buyers is costly. Most of the
existing findings in support of this view have focused on real estate
markets.
As an empirical matter, it is not clear that ask prices should play
a similar role in the online setting that we examine. Although the
notion that sellers have differing reservation prices seems plausible,
if the market is characterized by perfect information and costless
search, then ask prices will serve no functional role. This is important
because there is a general anecdotal view that online markets serve as
sufficiently effective mechanisms for information transmission that
search is costless. In such a setting, an initial ask price posted by
the seller would be irrelevant.
One caveat to this view is that although information is readily
available online, it may be costly to process. The used computers sold
on this exchange are complex products that differ on a number of
dimensions. Viewing the large amount of information available and
forming an estimate of willingness to pay in such a situation is a
nontrivial task. Though the cost in terms of time and effort required to
process this information does not fall as neatly within the imperfect information paradigm as does the housing market, it is clearly
analogous. The search costs involved in visiting and walking through a
house for sale are substantial, but relative to the value of the house
they may be no larger than the costs of viewing and assessing the
characteristics of a used computer. It is possible then that the
immediate access to information online may not eliminate search costs.
One contribution of our research, therefore, is an assessment of the
extent to which online markets can be thought of as search markets. Our
approach is to see whether the relationship between ask prices, offers,
and time to sale on the exchange is similar to that in other markets
characterized by costly search.
Our data differ in some key ways from that available in more
traditional settings. For example, data regarding the number of offers a
given property receives are rarely available in housing markets. Nor, in
many cases, is the sequence of offers for a given property observable.
In our case, we observe the number of offers made and the level of each
offer. A disadvantage of our data is that we do not observe final
transaction prices, because once computers are sold they are removed
from the publicly available listings on the exchange. Thus we cannot
directly estimate the relationship between ask prices and sale prices.
We can, however, estimate the relationship between the ask price and the
level of the highest outstanding (i.e., rejected) offer that the
computer received. This allows us to test the implication that sellers
with high ask prices are more likely to reject offers of a given level.
This prediction has not been tested in previous work because rejected
offers are rarely recorded.
An advantage of our data relative to that used in other studies is
that in many bilateral exchange markets there are characteristics of the
good that are observed by both parties to the transaction but would be
unobservable to an econometrician investigating the transaction. Again,
this is a common problem in housing markets, in which the
characteristics of the house are typically unknown or may be too
qualitative to permit an econometric analysis. In contrast to these
other settings, we view listings on the online computer exchange exactly
as buyers view them. Thus the standard omitted variable concern that
arises in this type of analysis is greatly reduced.
We conduct the empirical analysis by outlining a standard set of
hypothesis tests regarding the relationship between ask prices, offers,
and time to sale in search models. In general, the search models predict
that higher ask prices should indicate a willingness on the part of the
seller to hold out for a higher offer. In such a setting, sellers with
high ask prices will reject higher offers than sellers with low ask
prices; thus, the ask price will be positively correlated with the
highest outstanding offer at any given point in time. The search models
also predict that a higher ask price should lead to fewer offers and a
longer time to sale. If search is costly, buyers will be deterred from
making offers on goods with high ask prices because they expect a low
probability of sale. A corollary of these models is that the gains from
pursuing a high ask price strategy are likely to be greater in markets
in which the variance of buyers' willingness to pay is greater. We
proxy for this variance by using an independent assessment of market
strength for each computer under the supposition that buyers'
tastes are more idiosyncratic in thinner (weaker) market segments. Our
view that thinner segments have a greater variance in buyers'
willingness to pay is borne out by the data; the variance of offers is
higher in lower-strength segments, holding computers' values
constant.
The empirical section of the article first examines the incidence
of offers for our sample of computers and assesses whether the level of
the ask price affects the number of offers that a computer receives.
Because computers have heterogeneous values, we normalize the ask price
by an independent measure of the resale value of the computer. This
allows us to compare computers with different values based on the
relative magnitude of their ask prices. We find that computers with high
ask prices (relative to their value) receive fewer offers. This result
is consistent with the search model. We also find that this result is
stronger in thinner market segments, suggesting that segments with
idiosyncratic buyer tastes are more likely to display the patterns
predicted by the search model.
The next part of the article examines the relationship between the
ask price for a given computer, and the level of the highest offer
outstanding when we observe it. Essentially this involves estimating a
hedonic pricing equation for computers and testing for an independent
effect of the ask price on offers. We find that in thinner (i.e., more
idiosyncratic) markets, there is a positive relationship between ask
prices and outstanding offers. The relationship is weak or nonexistent in thicker market segments. This suggests that sellers with high ask
prices are more likely to reject offers of a given level.
We then examine the relationship between the ask/value ratio and
time to sale. Our data limit the scope of this inquiry, because
computers disappear from the exchange once they are sold. Thus we can
only infer time to sale by asking whether a computer is more or less
likely to remain on the exchange during our sample period as a function
of the ask/value ratio. Using these data, we find that high ask prices
extend time to sale and that the relationship is stronger in thinner
market segments.
Our conclusion is that despite the prevalence of information in the
market, ask prices play a role consistent with the predictions of search
models. The results of this article highlight the importance of
information processing costs, even in online markets that appear quite
transparent. We discuss this point further in the conclusion.
II. THE ONLINE COMPUTER EXCHANGE
We take our data from the United Computer Exchange (UCE), an online
exchange between buyers and sellers of used computers. The UCE serves
two functions: It facilitates bilateral exchange, and it provides a form
of quality certification. (1)
Listing a computer and making offers are free. Sellers register to
list their computer and complete a form listing the characteristics of
the computer. There are 17 fields in which sellers may list
characteristics. Some of these may take on roughly continuous values
(such as memory and hard drive space), whereas others are more discrete
or qualitative (such as the existence of an Ethernet card). When the
listing is created, the seller also submits an "ask price."
The ask price is not binding and is typically high relative to any
objective assessment of the value of the computer. In our data, the
average ask price is more than twice as high as the average highest
offer for a computer. This ratio is larger than that we would see in
housing or used car markets.
The set of information available to the buyer therefore consists of
the listed characteristics of the computer, the date on which the
computer was listed, the ask price, and the date and level of any
previous offers submitted. Potential buyers may view listings on the UCE
Web page and submit offers for any computers they find desirable. Buyers
may submit an unlimited number of offers for any number of computers
they desire. Once an offer has been submitted, it appears on the Web
page of the computer for which the offer stands. A seller may view
offers at any time by visiting the UCE web page. The fact that the
seller has viewed the offer is noted on the Web page. The fact that an
offer has been viewed but not accepted constitutes a signal that that
offer has been rejected. (2)
The process of negotiation is often quite drawn out, and commitment
occurs late in the process. A computer in our data set may have been on
the exchange for a few months when observed and may have received only
one offer several weeks after it was listed. Sellers need not accept any
bids, and they face no time limit after which they must sell the
computer. Even after a seller notifies a buyer of acceptance of an
offer, the buyer has an opportunity to retract it.
Despite the late and bilateral nature of commitment, once it has
been made it is extremely costly for either party to cancel the
transaction. Once both parties have agreed to the transaction, the
seller pays to ship the computer to UCE, which performs a simple set of
diagnostic tests. If the computer is in working order, it is then mailed
to the buyer at the buyer's expense. After receiving the computer,
the buyer can still cancel the transaction if goods are not as promised.
In this event, the buyer pays the costs of returning the computer to
UCE. At that point, the seller may relist the computer or pay shipping
costs to have the computer returned to the seller's residence. (3)
If, after receiving the computer, the buyer agrees to the
transaction, a check goes to UCE. UCE takes 5% from the buyer's
total. Sellers pay a sliding scale fee for the service based on the
transaction price of the computer that they sell. (4) UCE then mails the
remainder of the transaction price to the seller. Once the transaction
is complete, the listing is removed.
It is worth emphasizing at this point that this exchange is not an
auction. There is no commitment to buy or sell until late in the
process. The ask price is not a binding reservation price. There is no
time limit before which a transaction must occur. Thus, although many
other online auctions exist (e.g., eBay), we should view the UCE as
closest to a centralized forum for bilateral exchange. This motivates
our theoretical discussion of search models.
III. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ASK PRICES, OFFERS, AND TIME TO SALE
In this section we discuss some models that explain a functional
role for ask prices. We outline the empirical predictions of these
models, discuss their applicability to an online exchange, and contrast
them with some alternative explanations regarding the role of ask
prices.
We should note first that in a perfect information setting with
costless search, ask prices will play no functional role. Even if ask
prices were correlated with sellers' reservation prices, sellers
would have no economic incentive to list different ask prices because
buyers would disregard them. (5) For the ask price to play a functional
role, buyer behavior must be affected by the ask price. This will only
occur if "search" is costly for buyers (we will outline an
interpretation of search in this online setting later).
Models of Search and Ask Prices
The standard search framework assumes that there is imperfect
information regarding some component of buyers' valuations for the
good being offered by sellers. (6) Many models also incorporate some
imperfect information regarding sellers' reservation prices. In
such a setting, the typical approach is to model the market as one in
which the imperfect information problem is resolved only after one
party, typically the buyer, pays some search cost. (7) In the simplest
formulation of these models, all buyers must pay the same search cost;
marginal search costs may also increase in the number of searches,
although this is not essential. Search is sequential; buyers
"visit" each seller and must then choose to purchase from the
current seller or visit another. The derivation of equilibrium in these
models often involves the construction of a stopping rule for buyers, in
which buyers trade the expected surplus from continued search against
the costs of continued search.
Models that incorporate ask prices into the search framework
typically take two approaches, both of which involve justifying a
negative relationship between the ask price and the arrival rate of
buyers. One approach is to simply assert that the ask price affects the
arrival rate of buyers, based on an intuitive appeal regarding
buyers' interpretation of the ask price. (8) This will occur, for
example, if buyers believe that the ask price is correlated with the
seller's (unobserved) reservation price. A second, more formal
approach assumes that although the final transaction price will be the
outcome of bargaining and will therefore vary, the ask price is a
commitment by the seller to an upper bound on the transaction price. (9)
Thus the ask price bounds the surplus received by the buyer at some
minimum value. Buyers facing different ask prices will therefore choose
to visit the sellers with lower ask prices first, holding the cost of
search constant. Sellers with lower ask prices will obtain a higher
arrival rate of buyers and receive more offers). (10) Whether or not the
relationship between arrival rates and ask prices is formally modeled,
all of these models imply a negative relationship between ask prices and
the arrival rate. (11) Because any buyer who "arrives" makes
an offer, this also implies that higher ask prices will lead to fewer
offers.
These models can motivate variation in ask prices for identical
goods in two ways. First, if sellers differ on some dimension--the most
tractable dimension is typically the discount rate--then they will find
different selling strategies optimal. Sellers who are patient will ask
higher prices and hold out for a high-valuation buyer. As a consequence
of this strategy, sellers with high ask prices will receive fewer offers
because they will deter low-valuation buyers from inspecting their good.
They will also have longer time on the market. (12)
Search models also predict a relationship between ask prices,
offers, and transaction prices. High-reservation price sellers will
reject higher offers than will low-reservation price sellers. This has
two implications. First, higher ask prices will be associated with
higher transaction prices. Second, given equal offers for identical
computers, those on computers with high ask prices should be more likely
to be rejected by sellers. Thus, if we observe a snapshot of the market,
higher ask prices should be associated with higher outstanding offers.
Another source of equilibrium ask price dispersion arises in models
with many sellers. (13) Sellers with identical goods may choose
different ask prices, trading off a higher expected selling price
against a longer expected time to sale. Even if sellers are themselves
identical and face the same outside option, price dispersion can be
sustained through the imposition of a zero-profit constraint. The
zero-profit constraint requires that the gains from raising the ask
price (higher offers and a higher final transaction price) must be
exactly offset by the losses (a lower probability of sale today).
Although these models are set up slightly differently from those in the
previous paragraph, they yield the same empirical implications. High ask
prices will be associated with higher outstanding offers but will
receive fewer offers and have a longer time to sale.
A final result of certain search models is that the variance of
buyers' valuations will affect seller strategies. These models find
that a higher variance of buyers' valuations leads to higher ask
prices, because the profitability of the high ask price strategy grows.
(14) In addition, the models predict that a higher variance of
valuations will lead to longer time on the market, as sellers have more
to gain by holding out for a high offer. (15) As a general empirical
matter, we would expect that in settings with high variance in
buyers' willingness to pay, the predictions of the search model
would be more strongly supported. (16)
Existing Empirical Work
Most of the existing literature testing the predictions regarding
search behavior and ask prices uses data from housing markets. Yavas and
Yang (1995) find that higher ask prices deter potential buyers and will
result in a longer time to sale. (17) Genesove and Mayer (1997) also
find that houses with higher ask prices receive higher final prices and
remain on the market longer. Glower et al. (1998) find that a more
motivated seller (for example, someone who has already purchased another
home) will ask less, sell faster, and for a lower price. The general
conclusions of this literature are fairly consistent, and provide strong
support for the predictions of search theory in these markets. One
limitation of the work already mentioned is that it does not examine
offers made by buyers that are rejected; in most housing markets, such
data typically are not recorded. One exception to this is recent work by
Ortalo-Magne and Merlo (2000), which contains observations for both
offers and transaction prices.
Some of the work also tests the hypothesis that the variance of
buyers' willingness to pay will affect ask prices, offers, and time
to sale. Glower et al. (1998) hypothesize that houses with
"atypical" features should be ones for which buyer's
valuations have a higher variance. Their empirical work shows that
atypicality is associate with higher list prices, higher sale prices,
and longer time on the market. Haurin (1988) also finds that atypical
houses are longer on the market and have higher list prices relative to
their selling price. Thus there is also some support for the prediction
of search theory regarding the variance of buyers' willingness to
pay.
Our work has both advantages and disadvantages relative to these
other articles. As we noted in the introduction, a disadvantage is that
we do not observe final transaction prices. We do observe the sequence
of offers, which is rare in the context of previous work. This allows us
to test whether higher ask prices actually deter buyers from making
offers. It also allows us to test whether sellers with higher ask prices
are more likely to reject offers of a given level, by examining the
highest offer outstanding when the computer is observed. Data concerning
the number of bids also allows the role of market strength to be
examined in this context.
Applying Search Theory to an Online Exchange
At this point it is worthwhile to discuss the applicability of
these models to the online computer exchange. For the models to apply,
we need to view the online exchange as a market in which buyers have
uncertain valuations of the computers for sale. Buyers would also need
to engage in costly search to determine their willingness to pay and
place an offer.
It may seem counterintuitive to view this market as one in which
buyers have different valuations that are uncertain before they engage
in search. However, we should note that the goods for sale--used
computers--are multidimensional goods that can vary in complex ways. As
we noted, there are 17 listed characteristics for each computer, and
each characteristic can take on a host of values. (18) When variations
in these characteristics are taken into account, very few computers on
the exchange are identical to any other. (19) Moreover, there is no
clear quality increment on which we can index computers of a given model
type; one computer may have more memory and less hard drive space (or a
slower modem) than another. It is almost surely the case that buyers
value different bundles of characteristics differently. (20)
Given that buyers have different valuations and that computers are
so heterogeneous, we can think of the search cost associated with making
an offer as the time and effort for the buyer to sort through the
complex bundle of attributes and arrive at a valuation for the computer.
One can see that it would take a nontrivial amount of time, for example,
to evaluate three or four computers of identical model type but
differing characteristics. Buyers would "visit" each computer
and then choose from the set of computers listed on the exchange the one
computer (or group of computers) that seems closest to their desired
bundle of characteristics; from this point, a buyer would engage in
detailed comparison. After engaging in this search, the buyer would be
in a position to submit an informed offer on each machine.
The role of the ask price in such a setting might be similar to
that in housing markets. Given limited time and a pool of eight or ten
computers of a given model type, the buyer might screen the computers
and examine only those four with the lowest ask prices. In fact, the
institutions of the exchange encourage this sort of screening. At the
outset of viewing the listings, the buyer is presented with a search
dialog that shows various major features of the computers, such as
processor speed, memory, and storage capacity. The buyer can select on
these feature to bring up a subset of the listings for detailed
examination. Importantly, one of these features on which the buyer can
screen is the ask price--thus a low-valuation buyer who used this
feature would automatically screen out more computers than a
high-valuation buyer.
As a theoretical matter it is difficult to say whether search costs
as we have outlined them here would be significant enough to lead to the
same patterns of ask prices, offers, and time to sale observed in other
search markets. Our approach is therefore to test the predictions of the
search model in this setting to assess empirically the role of ask
prices and the overall relevance of search models in this online
setting.
Competing Explanations for an Empirically Significant Ask Price
Before we move to the empirical tests, it is worth discussing some
alternative explanations regarding the role of ask prices. As we shall
see, the predictions of the search model are observationally distinct
from these competing explanations.
One might think that a natural alternative hypothesis would be that
ask prices serve as a signal of unobserved quality. It is possible to
construct models in which sellers with high ask prices convey positive
information regarding some unobservable component of quality. We should
note, however, that the features of the exchange are set up to mitigate such problems. Essentially, the UCE serves as a quality certification
device that ensures that all delivered machines are in working order.
Nonetheless, there are undoubtedly variations in working quality even
among all machines of minimum acceptable quality.
However, even if ask prices served as signals of unobserved
quality, the empirical predictions of the signaling model run counter to
the predictions of the search model. It is true that both models would
predict a positive relationship between ask prices and offers,
controlling for the observable characteristics of the computer. However,
the signaling model would also predict a positive correlation between
ask prices and the number of offers received. This would occur because
computers with higher ask prices would be more valuable than those with
lower ask prices, and the data indicate that high-value computers have
greater market strength. Of course, the data can only be instructive about the relationship between high-value observable characteristics and
market strength; although there is no guarantee that the market for
high-quality unobservable traits is also thicker, it seems as if this
would be a likely corollary. Note that this is in contrast to the
negative correlation predicted by the search model. Finally, for similar
reasons of market strength, the signaling model predicts a negative
relationship between the ask price and time to sale, whereas the search
model predicts a positive relationship. (21)
Another factor that could lead to an observed empirical
relationship between ask prices and offers are omitted variables. If
there were characteristics of computers that were unobservable to the
researchers observing a series of offers, but observable to both parties
to the exchange, then ask prices might reflect unobservable information
regarding the computer. (22) Again though, there are institutional
features of the market that argue against the existence of such
unobservables. Because the exchange occurs online, the exact set of
information observed by buyers is available. As with the signaling
explanation, the biases introduced by the presence of unobservables run
counter to the predictions of the search model. Though it is true that
higher ask prices would be associated with higher offers if ask prices
captured unobservables, it is also true that higher ask prices would be
positively correlated with number of offers and negatively correlated
with time to sale. The latter two relationships are opposite to those
predicted by the search model.
IV. THE DATA
Our data consist of listings, ask prices, and offers for a sample
of 301 Macintosh units. Each listing contains the date on which the
listing was created: these extend from 10 January 1998 to 10 May 1998.
Each observation also contains the date and amount of each offer. We
recorded listings and offers on 11 June 1998, and updated them on 28
June 1998.
We also obtained estimates of the market value and "market
strength" of each computer. This information is contained in a
quarterly report published by UCE. The report contains average national
values (prices) for used Macintosh units. The listed values are for
typical configurations for the most common Macintosh models. We will
discuss how we handle deviations from the typical configuration. The
market strength variable is a measure of national transaction volume for
the particular model, on a scale of 1 to 100. It is therefore a rough
measure of how thick the market is for each model. The summary is
readily available to buyers and sellers on the UCE Web site. In our
sample, the values and market strength figures are taken from the report
released on 10 March 1998. Thus our sample contains listings and ask
prices for the two months prior to and following the release of the
report.
Table 1 presents summary statistics for our sample and for
subsamples stratified by market strength. Stratifying the sample in this
way is a preliminary attempt to see how patterns in the data might vary
as the thickness of the market segment for a particular model varies.
Our supposition is that thinner (weaker) market segments are more likely
to possess a high variance of buyer willingness to pay; we support this
claim later with data. As a first pass at the effects of market
strength, we classify market strengths below the median as
"low" and those above the median as "high." The
first row of the table shows the average number of days each computer
was on the exchange when it was first observed. Recall that this date is
four months after our earliest listing. For the sample of listings, the
average time on the exchange is roughly two months. This value is
essentially the same for high- and low-strength machines.
The second row shows the average value of all computers in the
sample and the average values for the low and high market strength
subsamples. Not surprisingly, the average value for a computer with high
market strength is much larger (by nearly three times) than that for a
computer with low market strength.
The next rows show data on the incidence of offers. The most
striking thing about these data is that relatively few offers are made.
For the sample as a whole, 43% of computers had not received any offers
by the observation date. Thirty-five percent had received only one
offer, and only 9% had received more than one offer. In general,
computers with higher market strength receive more offers. Only 29% of
computers with high market strength had received no offers, and 56% of
those with low market strength had received no offers. It seems most
correct based on these data to think of the markets in which these
computers are sold as being fairly thin. (23)
The next row shows the average log-difference between the ask price
and the computer's value. For the entire sample, this difference is
over 80%. Thus, the ask price is typically quite high relative to the
value of the computer. This difference is more pronounced for computers
with low market strength. For these machines, the log-difference between
the ask price and the value of the computer is over 100%. It is 60% for
the computers with high market strength. Thus the raw data seem to
suggest that sellers in thinner markets are more likely to purse a high
ask price strategy. (24)
The next row shows the average log-difference between the highest
offer received and the computer's value for the subset of computers
that received at least one offer. On average, the highest offer is quite
close to the computer's value; the log-difference is less than 8%
for the sample as a whole. There is a difference between computers with
high and low market strengths. The average log-difference between the
highest offer and the value is over 10% for the low-strength subsample,
whereas it is only 6% for the high-strength subsample.
Finally, we note that the offers for the low-strength subsample
vary considerable more than those for the high-strength, controlling for
the value of the computer. The coefficient of variation for the ratio of
the high offer to the computer's value is 0.37 for the
high-strength subsample and 0.78 for the low-strength subsample. (25)
This is important because our reason for focusing on market strength is
that we believe that in thinner (low-strength) markets, the variance of
buyers' willingness to pay is higher. The evidence here is
consistent with that assumption--the variance of offers made on
computers with low market strength is much higher than the variance of
offers on computers with high market strength.
The final row shows the percentage of the computers we observed
initially that were no longer on the exchange when we next recorded
data. Just over 40% of the computers observed initially were gone when
we recorded data 17 days later. This percentage is slightly higher for
computers with high market strength than for computers with low market
strength, and the direction of the difference seems intuitive. In the
empirical work, we will assume that all computers that are gone from the
exchange on our second observation date were sold rather than just
removed from the market. Although this may not be completely accurate,
it would only bias the results against our main empirical finding
regarding time to sale. (26)
V. ESTIMATING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ASK PRICES, OFFERS, AND TIME
TO SALE
In this section we conduct three sets of empirical tests. We first
examine the incidence of offers using the entire sample of computers.
Under the search hypothesis, higher ask prices should deter offers, and
this effect should be stronger in thinner markets. We then examine the
determinants of the highest outstanding offer for the subsample of
computers that received at least one offer. The search model predicts
that higher ask prices should be associated with higher offers, and that
this effect should be stronger in thinner markets. Finally, we examine
the determinants of time to sale. The search model predicts that higher
ask prices should be associated with longer time to sale, and that this
result should be stronger in thinner markets.
The Incidence of Offers
We model the number of offers received for a computer as the
outcome of a Poisson process, in which the data take on only whole
number values and the probability that an outcome is observed is:
(1) Pr[ y = [y.sub.i] =
([e.sup.-[[lambda].sub.i][[lambda.sup.[y.sub.i].sub.i]/[y.sub.i]!)], y =
0, 1, ...
The model is specified by assuming that
(2) In [[lambda].sub.i] ([[epsilon].sub.i) = [beta]*[Chars.sub.i] +
[PHI]*[Strength.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i].
This simple specification allows the number of offers to be a
function of observable characteristics of the computer and its market
strength. The set of characteristics includes the value of the computer.
This value variable captures most important features of the
computer--its processor type and speed, the number of expansion slots,
typical memory and hard drive sizes, and a standard bundle of video and
network/Internet capabilities. Including this variable rather than each
of the above-mentioned characteristics is advantageous because the value
of the computer is in all likelihood a complex nonlinear function of the
observable features. Estimation of this function would be problematic,
given these nonlinearities and the likely interaction effects between
various attributes of the computer. In any case, all else equal, we
would expect computers in thicker submarkets to receive more offers. It
is likely that the value of the computer reflects market thickness
because computers with higher values are typically newer and have a
wider range of practical uses. Also, value and market strength are
positively correlated in the data. Because computers differ from the
base specification with which their value is associated, in some
specifications we also include extra memory or hard drive space relative
to the mean for that model. To the extent that these characteristics
affect value, they might change the likelihood of an offer. In
preliminary estimates we also included a variety of other observable
characteristics of the computer; none of these other characteristics was
significant, so they are excluded from the results that we present. (27)
The set of characteristics also includes the length of time for
which the computer has been on the exchange. We would expect time on the
exchange to be positively correlated with the number of offers,
particularly given the assumption of most search models that buyers
arrive sequentially. Time on the exchange might be endogenous, however,
if there are unobserved variables that affect the number of buyers that
make offers. Dealing with this endogeneity is difficult because there
are no clear suitable instruments. In the empirical work we therefore
simply present results both including and excluding time on the exchange
to assess its impact on the coefficients of interest.
We also attempt to control for deviations from base configuration
by including other characteristics of the computer. In preliminary
estimates using the complete set of observable characteristics, only two
variables proved to affect offers significantly. We therefore include
only these two variables, which measure the deviation of the
computer's memory and hard drive space from the mean levels for
that model type.
To measure the effect of the ask price, we also include the
log-difference between the ask price and the independent assessment of
the computer's value as a right-hand-side variable: (28)
(3) In [[lambda.sub.i]([[epsilon].sub.i) = [beta]*[Chars.sub.i] +
[PHI]*[Strength.sub.i] + [gamma]*1n([Ask.sub.i]/[Value.sub.i]) +
[epsilon].sub.i].
Under the prediction of the search model, higher ask prices
(relative to value) should reduce the incidence of offers. A corollary
of this is that in thinner submarkets, the prediction of the model
should be stronger. We test this in two ways. We first estimate equation
(3) for both "high-strength" and "low-strength"
subsamples, where high and low are defined relative to the median market
strength (as in Table 1). (29)
The results of this model are presented in Table 2. For the sample
as a whole, we find that higher ask/value ratios reduce the number of
offers received for the computer. The magnitude of the coefficient implies that a one-standard-deviation increase in ask/value from its
mean reduces the expected number of offers by 0.25. Though not
excessively large, this is an economically significant result. As a
point of comparison, this effect is similar to either a $200 decrease in
value or an additional 28 days of time on the exchange. The coefficient
does not change significantly when time on the exchange is omitted.
The next sets of columns show results based on the stratification into high and low market strength. (30) The results are quite striking.
The coefficient on the ask price is close to zero and is not
statistically significant for the high-strength subsample. On the other
hand, in the low-strength subsample the coefficient is large and
statistically significant.
The magnitude of the coefficient implies that a
one-standard-deviation increase in the ask/ value ratio is associated
with roughly 0.50 fewer offers.
To conclude this section, we can note two features of the empirical
results regarding the incidence of offers. First, all else equal,
computers with high ask prices relative to their values receive fewer
offers for at least some of the observations. This constitutes a
rejection of a perfect information model in which ask price should be
irrelevant and is also inconsistent with the hypothesis that higher ask
prices reflect the presence of unobservable product characteristics.
Second, the pattern of results when we stratify the sample by market
strength is consistent with search models in which the variance of
offers affects the gains to pursuing a high ask price strategy. In the
next section we test the next set of predictions of the search model by
examining the relationship between the ask price and the level of the
highest outstanding offer.
Ask Prices and Offer Levels
Recall that the search models predict that higher ask prices should
be associated with higher offers for the computers that ultimately
receive offers. (31) In this section we test this prediction.
The most straightforward approach to estimating this relationship
is to include the ask price in a standard hedonic regression. We specify
this model as
(4) [Offer.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [delta]*[Spread.sub.i] +
[beta]*[Chars.sub.i] + [lambda]*[Strength.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i],
where the dependent variable is the highest offer outstanding for a
given computer when it is observed. (32) The right-hand-side variables
include the set of computer characteristics, including the
computer's value. We also include market strength; this may pick up
any components of value not captured by the value variable.
In the base specification, we measure the independent effect of the
ask price on offers by including the difference between the ask price
and the computer's value (the "spread") as an explanatory variable. (33) Under the search model, we would see a positive
relationship between this spread and the highest offer received for a
computer. We allow this relationship to vary based on market strength in
two ways. We estimate the model separately for the high- and
low-market-strength subsamples. We also include in some specifications
interaction terms between the spread and market strength:
(5) [Offer.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [delta]*[Spread.sub.i] +
[gamma]*[Spread.sub.i]*[Strength.sub.i] +
[beta]*[Chars.sub.i]+[lambda]*[Strength.sub.i] + [epsilon.sub.i].
Using this hedonic specification with offers as the dependent
variable raises two specification issues. The first is a standard sample
selection problem; the sample includes only those computers that have
received offers. This can be handled in a straightforward manner with
standard sample selection techniques. In the work that follows, we use a
standard two-step estimation technique that selects based on a binary variable indicating whether the computer has received at least one
offer. (34)
The second issue derives from the fact that computers depreciate fairly rapidly. This introduces temporal concerns, because ask prices,
computer values, and offers may have been submitted at different times
for the same computer. Consider two computers that are identical but
were listed on different dates. The newer machine is likely to have had
a lower value at the time of listing, due to depreciation. Thus it would
probably have both a lower ask price and lower offers--but these would
reflect differences in the true value of the computer. To deal with this
issue, we construct a variable measuring the time (in days) between the
listing of the computer and the date on which the offer was submitted.
We include this variable in the specification. We also include an
interaction between this time variable and the ask price, an interaction
between the time variable and the computer's value, and an
interaction between market strength and the computer's value.
Table 3 shows results of these models. The first column shows
results for the sample as a whole, and the second and third columns
segment the sample into computers with high and low market strength.
(35) The coefficient on the ask-value spread is positive and
statistically significant for the sample as a whole. This result masks
some differences across levels of market strength, however. For
high-strength computers, the coefficient is smaller and is not
statistically significant, whereas it is much larger and significant for
low-strength computers. The magnitude of the coefficient for the
low-strength subsample suggests that for each dollar that the ask price
exceeds the estimate of the computer's value, the highest offer for
that computer is higher by 36 cents. This is certainly significant in
economic terms.
The coefficient on the interaction term also suggests that the
impact of the ask price varies depending on market strength. For the
sample as a whole and the high-strength subsample the coefficient on the
interaction term is not statistically significant. However, for the
low-strength subsample it is negative and significant, suggesting that
the impact of the ask price is even greater in thinner markets.
The coefficient on market strength is also informative. It is
positive in the high-strength subsample and statistically significant
when the interaction term is included. This result seems intuitive--all
else equal, computers in stronger markets receive higher offers. On the
other hand, the coefficient on market strength for the low-strength
subsample is negative and significant in the specification that omits
the interaction term. This suggests that the highest outstanding offer
is negatively related to market strength. This is consistent with the
search model, in which the gain to holding out for a high price is
greater in a thinner market.
The coefficient on the computer's value is what one would
expect. In the high-strength subsample, the coefficient on the
computer's value is close to (and not significantly different from)
one. This suggests that for these computers, offers generally move
one-for-one with value. Additionally, the coefficients on extra memory
and hard drive space seem intuitive; all are positive, and in the
low-strength subsample both memory and hard drive space are
statistically significant.
The temporal variables also generally match expectations. The
variable measuring the time between the observation date and the offer
is positive and significant in most specification, suggesting that
offers made earlier in the sample period were higher. The interaction
term between the ask-value spread and the time since the offer is
negative and significant in most specifications. This suggests that for
computers that have been on the exchange longer when the offer is
submitted, the influence of the spread is smaller.
As a final point, we can note that the adjusted [R.sup.2] for the
high-strength subsample is much higher (0.80) than that for the
low-strength subsample (0.60). This accords with the notion that in the
low-strength subsample, buyers' valuations are more idiosyncratic.
It is therefore more difficult to "fit" their offers regarding
the observable characteristics of the computer.
Ask/Value Ratios and Time to Sale
In this section we assess the effect of the ask price on time to
sale. Unfortunately, as we mentioned earlier, we do not observe final
transactions and cannot observe time to sale directly. We do observe
whether the computer remains on the exchange in our second observation
date, and we use that to proxy for time to sale. Our assumption is that
all else equal, computers that are gone on our second observation date
have a quicker time to sale than those that remain. This is a slightly
noisy measure, because we cannot be sure that removal from the exchange
occurred because of a sale.
Our specification is a probit model, in which the dependent
variable indicates whether the machine was gone when we conducted our
second observation. The right-hand-side variable of interest is the
log-difference between the ask price and the computer's value. The
other right-hand-side variables are time on the exchange, the
computer's value, its market strength, and extra memory and hard
drive space. Again, we stratify the sample by market strength and also
include an interaction term between the ask price term and market
strength.
Table 4 shows results of these models. For the sample as a whole,
the coefficient on ln(Ask/Value) is negative and statistically
significant, indicating that computers with higher ask prices are more
likely to remain on the exchange between our observation dates. At the
means, the magnitude of the coefficient suggests that a
one-standard-deviation increase in the log-difference between the ask
price and the computer's value is associated with a
nine-percentage-point fall in the probability that it remains on the
exchange. Although there is no way to directly impute the increase in
time on the exchange associated with this figure, it seems economically
significant given that for the sample as a whole over 60% of computers
remain on the exchange between our observation dates.
Once again, the results are nonexistent in the high-strength
subsample and stronger for the low-strength subsample. The coefficient
on the log-difference between the ask price and the computer's
value is significant in the specification without the interaction term.
In the specification with the interaction term, the interaction term is
negative and significant, indicating that the effect of the ask price on
the probability of sale increases in thinner markets.
VI. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
Our results show that the relationship between ask prices, offers,
and time to sale in the online computer exchange is consistent with
search models. We find that higher ask prices are associated with higher
outstanding offers at the time of observation. This implies that sellers
with higher ask prices are more likely to reject equivalent offers, and
by extension implies that higher ask prices are associated with higher
final transaction prices. We also find that higher ask prices reduce the
probability of sale between our observation dates, suggesting that high
ask prices extend time to sale. Finally, we find that higher ask prices
are associated with fewer offers. This implies that high ask prices
deter buyers from making offers, suggesting that search or information
processing for buyers is costly. These results are more pronounced for
thinner markets in which buyers' preferences are idiosyncratic.
Thicker markets tend to demonstrate characteristics closer to that of a
competitive market in which ask prices have little effect.
It may seem surprising that despite the large amount of information
available at low cost in this market, buyer and seller behavior fits the
pattern predicted by search models. In prima facie terms this market
possesses price information of very high quality; in fact, the exchange
itself serves as an information transmission device by providing
estimates of each computer's value. It would also seem that the
costs of placing an offer are quite low.
It seems that the complexity of the good--a personal computer,
which is a bundle of characteristics that may interact with each other
in highly nonlinear ways--creates information processing costs that are
significant. These costs may seem fairly small, especially compared to
the time costs of visiting a house and inspecting it thoroughly.
However, it is important to remember that the typical price of a used
computer is also very small relative to the price of a house. In
relative terms, the time costs of evaluating two computers that differ
slightly on many dimensions may be high enough to deter consumers from
undertaking many such comparisons.
The general intuition suggested by this work is that the wealth of
information on the Internet may not guarantee frictionless outcomes.
This notion is consistent with some recent empirical work examining
e-commerce. Brynjolfsson (2000) finds, for example, that online book
retailers (such as Amazon.com) may enjoy a price advantage of as much as
10% for repeat customers. Brynjolfsson and Smith (2000) find that
despite extremely low search costs, there still exists substantial price
dispersion in Internet book and CD markets; Internet prices for these
goods differ by 25%, on average. They conclude that "branding,
awareness and trust remain important sources of heterogeneity among
Internet retailers." We would add to this the notion that if
information is costly for consumers to process, a market may perform in
a manner akin to one with costly search in the more classical sense.
TABLE 1 Descriptive Statistics for the Computer Sample
Market Strength
All High Low
Days on exchange 61 57 65
when observed (32) (29) (34)
Value 407 593 226
(285) (266) (160)
Percent with
No offers 0.43 0.29 0.56
One offer 0.35 0.42 0.29
More than one offer 0.09 0.10 0.08
Log(ask/value) 0.83 0.60 1.05
(0.59) (0.29) (0.72)
Log(high offer/value) 0.077 0.06 0.103
(0.464) (0.384) (0.570)
Percent gone on second 0.43 0.45 0.4
observation date
N 301 150 151
Notes: Figures are mean. Standard deviations are shown in parentheses
below means. "High" and "Low" market strengths are relative to median.
TABLE 2
Offer Incidence
Market Strength
Variable All
Log(ask price/value) -0.699 ** -0.473 **
(0.172) (0.159)
Value 0.0016 ** 0.0018 **
(0.0003) (0.0003)
Time on exchange 0.009 **
(0.002)
Extra RAM 0.002 -0.001
(0.002) (0.002)
Extra HD space 0.047 0.031
(0.081) (0.079)
Market strength -0.009 -0.011 *
(0.006) (0.006)
N 301
Market Strength
Variable High
Log(ask price/value) -0.146 -0.024
(0.324) (0.303)
Value 0.0013 ** 0.0014 **
(0.0004) (0.004)
Time on exchange 0.003 0.015 **
(0.003) (0.003)
Extra RAM -0.003 -0.004
(0.003) (0.003)
Extra HD space 0.047 0.040
(0.089) (0.088)
Market strength 0.008 0.007
(0.011) (0.011)
N 150
Market Strength
Variable Low
Log(ask price/value) -1.102 ** -0.872 **
(0.270) (0.258)
Value 0.0033 ** 0.0027 **
(0.0011) (0.0011)
Time on exchange
Extra RAM 0.009 * 0.012 **
(0.005) (0.005)
Extra HD space 0.026 0.075
(0.245) (0.209)
Market strength -0.038 ** -0.040 **
(0.013) (0.013)
N 151
Notes: Poisson regression. Dependent variable is number of offers
received. "High" and "Low" market strengths are relative to median
(66). Extra RAM and HD space are measured as (positive or negative)
deviation from mean for given model.
* Significant at 10%.
** Significant at 5%.
TABLE 3
Effect of Ask Price on Offers
Market Strength
Variable All
Value 0.852 ** 0.853 **
(0.105) (0.105)
Ask-value 0.340 ** 0.292
spread (0.087) (0.247)
Ask-value spread * 0.001
market strength (0.003)
Value * time since 0.006 ** 0.006 **
offer (0.001) (0.001)
Ask-value spread * -0.004 ** -0.004 **
Time since offer (0.001) (0.001)
Time since offer 1.603 ** 1.645 **
(0.688) (0.718)
Extra RAM 0.001 0.05
(0.587) (0.636
Extra HD space 38.99 ** 39.90 **
(18.31) (19.04)
Market strength 1.418 1.317
(1.382) (1.481)
Inverse Mill's 64.16 107.47
ratio (66.69) (84.60)
N 165
Adj. [R.sup.2] 0.83 0.83
Market Strength
Variable High
Value 0.863 ** 0.850 **
(0.247) (0.231)
Ask-value 0.126 0.463
spread (0.220) (0.863)
Ask-value spread * -0.004
market strength (0.009)
Value * time since 0.006 * 0.006 **
offer (0.003) (0.003)
Ask-value spread * -0.003 -0.003
Time since offer (0.002) (0.002)
Time since offer 1.334 0.958
(2.458) (2.377)
Extra RAM 0.037 -0.159
(1.523) (1.458)
Extra HD space 59.44 58.61
(55.33) (50.73)
Market strength 11.99 13.21 *
(7.79) (7.84)
Inverse Mill's 518.67 469.39
ratio (407.68) (392.78)
N 92
Adj. [R.sup.2] 0.81 0.81
Market Strength
Variable Low
Value 0.648 ** 0.488 **
(0.170) (0.165)
Ask-value 0.362 ** 1.010 **
spread (0.151) (0.298)
Ask-value spread * -0.012 **
market strength (0.005)
Value * time since 0.008 ** 0.007 **
offer (0.002) (0.002)
Ask-value spread * -0.007 ** -0.007 **
Time since offer (0.002) (0.002)
Time since offer 1.749 ** 1.337 *
(0.801) (0.752)
Extra RAM 2.588 ** 2.294 **
(1.254) (1.134)
Extra HD space 60.97 * 38.69
36.20) (34.53)
Market strength -4.016 ** 0.950
(2.007) (2.436)
Inverse Mill's 139.44 * 124.35
ratio (74.79) (92.69)
N 73
Adj. [R.sup.2] 0.6 0.6
Notes: Sample selection model. Dependent variable is level of highest
outstanding offer. First-stage model is probit with dependent variable
equal to one if computer received at least one offer. "High" and "Low"
market strengths are relative to median (66). Extra RAM and HD space
are measured as (positive or negative) deviation from mean for given
model.
* Significant at 10%.
** Significant at 5%.
TABLE 4
Time to Sale
Market Strength
Variable All
Log(ask price/value) -0.371 ** -0.077
(0.164) (0.385)
Log(ask price/value) * -0.007
market strength (0.008)
Value 0.0006 0.0004
(0.0005) (0.0005)
Extra RAM 0.005 0.005
(0.003) (0.003)
Extra HD space 0.218 * 0.229 *
(0.122) (0.124)
Market strength -0.008 -0.001
(0.007) (0.012)
N 301
Market Strength
Variable High
Log(ask price/value) -0.288 4.833
(0.416) (3.34)
Log(ask price/value) * -0.066
market strength (0.043)
Value 0.0006 0.0004
(0.0006) (0.0006)
Extra RAM 0.005 0.005
(0.004) (0.004)
Extra HD space 0.169 0.172
(0.145) (0.147)
Market strength 0.001 0.043
(0.013) (0.031)
N 150
Market Strength
Variable Low
Log(ask price/value) -0.444 * 0.544
(0.233) (0.557)
Log(ask price/value) * -0.027 *
market strength (0.014)
Value 0.0005 -0.0009
(0.0012) (0.0014)
Extra RAM 0.004 0.006
(0.007) (0.008)
Extra HD space 0.366 * 0.417 *
(0.212) (0.218)
Market strength -0.005 0.031
(0.013) (0.023)
N 151
Notes: Dependent variable is dummy variable equal to one if computer is
gone on second observation date. "High" and "Low" market strengths are
relative to median (66). Extra RAM and HD space are measured as
(positive or negative) deviation from mean for given model.
* Significant at 10%.
** Significant at 5%.
(1.) Since we collected our data, the exchange discontinued person-to-person operations and is now a business-to-business
clearinghouse. The details that follow pertain to the person-to-person
business as it existed in 1998.
(2.) Though the rejection is not binding, we would imagine that
after some period of time elapses (a few weeks, at the most), a buyer
will interpret a "seen" offer as a rejected offer.
(3.) UCE's construction o f the transaction process seems
designed to mitigate the problems inherent in online sales of used
goods: adverse selection and hold-up. Forcing sellers to pay costs of
shipping to UCE before the initial quality check deters (at least some)
sellers with lemons. Though the UCE quality certification process is
minimal, the exchange grants buyers a right of refusal even after a
machine has passed the initial test. At this point, however, buyers
rejecting machines must also incur a sunk cost of rejection. This seems
designed to deter hold-up. We are grateful to a referee for making this
point. These issues seem particularly important given the importance of
trust and reputation in many online settings; see, for example, Jin and
Kato (2002), Houser and Wooders (2000), Melnick and Alto (2002), and
Resnick and Zeckhauser (2002) for more on these issues.
(4.) During the time period of our sample, sellers paid 15% of the
transaction price for computers sold for less than $1500 ($60 minimum),
12% for computers sold for $1500-$3000, and 10% for computers sold for
more than $3000. This is in addition to the buyer's fee.
(5.) If sellers (irrationally) persisted in setting ask prices that
were correlated with their reservation prices, then we would see a
positive correlation between ask prices and the highest outstanding
offer for a given computer. We might also see a positive correlation
between ask prices and time to sale. We would not see an inverse
relationship between ask prices and the number of offers that a computer
received, because buyers would not be deterred from (costlessly) making
offers on computers with high ask prices, no matter how small the
probability of making a transaction.
(6.) It may be the case that sellers do not know buyers'
reservation prices or that neither buyers nor sellers know the
willingness to pay of a particular buyer for a particular good.
(7.) In Yavas and Yang (1995) buyers and sellers each know their
reservation price but not that of the other party. This does not change
the intuition of the model.
(8.) Green and Vandell (1994) take this approach in considering a
seller's choice of the optimal list price.
(9.) This is the approach in Arnold (1999), Chen and Resenthal
(1996), and Yavas and Yang (1995).
(10.) Quan and Quigley (1991) develop a search model in which ask
prices are completely binding. The same result--that higher offers deter
buyers--occurs in their model.
(11.) The Chen and Rosenthal (1996), Yavas (1992), Yavas and Yang
(1995), and Arnold (1999) models all examine the case of a single seller
of a unique good. These models all yield a unique ask price for a given
set of model parameters. They also yield an inverse relationship between
ask prices and arrival rates in equilibrium.
(12.) Glower et al. (1998) use comparative statics to show that an
increase in the seller's discount rate leads to a higher list
price, a higher expected sale price, and longer time on the market.
(13.) This arises in the Quan and Quigley (1991) model. In their
model, ask prices are binding, but the intuition would still apply as
long as setting a higher ask price deterred low-valuation buyers from
making offers.
(14.) See Read (1988) for a model that allows the variance of
buyers' valuations to change.
(15.) See Haurin (1988) for a search model with this feature.
(16.) Consider the limiting case in which buyers' valuations
are known with certainty. The search model would no longer apply, and
ask prices would be irrelevant.
(17.) They find that this is true for mid-priced houses but is not
true for high- and low-priced houses.
(18.) Though the amount of memory and hard drive space is easily
quantifiable, other attributes are less so. For example, the model
category itself represents a bundle of characteristics (number of
expansion slots, standard video adapter, etc.) that is fairly complex
and would certainly have heterogeneous value for buyers.
(19.) Of the 300 computers for which we have data, only 16 are
functionally identical to another on the exchange.
(20.) A simple way in which these valuations would differ, for
example, is in buyers' relative valuations of the presence of a
modem versus a network card, depending on their Internet use and access
to a direct (e.g., T1) Internet connection.
(21.) Note that if we do not assume that market strength for
unobserved quality mimics that of observed quality traits, the signaling
model would offer no predictions concerning the number of offers or the
time to sale. This still differs from the search models, which provide
clear predictions. The quality signaling model also has no implication
regarding the variance of buyers' willingness to pay.
(22.) This problem plagues studies of real estate transactions. For
example, Glower et al. (1998) must construct a "predicted sale
price" for houses that they observe, because actual sale prices
might reflect omitted variables.
(23.) Of course, the exchange is not the only option for sellers;
nonetheless it is clear that this market is not one in which buyers are
continuously outbidding each other (as in, for example, many Internet
auctions).
(24.) It is also possible that older computers with low market
strength are more likely to have additional memory, hard drive space, or
other features that will inflate their values above that for the base
configuration. We control for this possibility in the estimates that
follow.
(25.) The coefficient of variation is the standard deviation
divided by the mean. For the high-strength subsample, the mean of (high
offer/ask) is 1.14, and the standard deviation is 0.42. For the
low-strength subsample, the mean of (high offer/ask) is 1.32, and the
standard deviation is 1.04.
(26.) To see this, suppose a seller with a high ask price has a
high reservation price, because he or she has a good outside option or
is inclined to keep the computer. All else equal, such a seller would be
more likely to remove his or her computer from the exchange than one
with a lower ask price. We find that the opposite is true.
(27.) The other characteristics were a set of dummy variables
representing the presence of features superior to that in the base
configuration. There were six such dummies, one each indicating the
presence of extra features for graphics or audio, one indicating the
presence of a modem, one indicating the presence of a network card, and
two indicating the presence of extra storage devices. None of the
coefficients on these variables were significant either jointly or
individually.
(28.) Using the ratio of the ask price to value (without logs)
yielded qualitatively identical results.
(29.) In unreported results, we also estimate a pooled
specification that allows for the impact of market strength using a
linear interaction term. The interaction term is not significant and
leaves the other coefficients unchanged.
(30.) An alternative way of specifying the relationship between
market strength and the effect of the ask/value ratio would be to
construct an interaction term. In unreported estimates, we find that a
simple linear interaction term is not significant. It is possible that
the relationship between market strength and the ask/value coefficient
is highly nonlinear.
(31.) Our test explicitly examines the effect of the ask price on
the highest outstanding offer and therefore tests whether offers are
more likely to be rejected by high-ask price sellers. But it also
implicitly tests whether computers with high ask prices ultimately
receive higher transaction prices, under the assumption that final
transaction prices are correlated with higher outstanding offers.
(32.) In fact, if high ask prices deter low-valuation buyers, we
would expect that the distribution of received offers (not just the
highest) would be higher for computers with high ask prices. Though we
do not report the results of this model, this is in fact the case. A
specification that includes the average offer yields a positive and
statistically coefficient on the ask-value spread. Nor is this
coefficient statistically different from that on the ask-value spread
when only the highest offer on each computer is included in the model.
(33.) Our specification assumes that if the ask price affects
offers, its marginal effects are identical in dollar terms across all
computers. One could instead allow the ask price to enter the model
using the percentage markup of the ask price over the computer's
value, but this would create problems of interpretation given that the
dependent variable is in dollars.
(34.) We do not report these results, but the model includes a set
of right-hand-side variables identical to those in the Poisson model
reported in Table 2. Their results are qualitatively the same as the
Poisson results.
(35.) Note that segmenting the sample into high and low market
strengths no longer divides the sample evenly, as the median market
strength of the entire sample differs from the median market strength
for the subsample of computers that received at least one offer.
REFERENCES
Arnold, M. "Search, Bargaining and Optimal Asking
Prices." Real Estate Economics, 27(3), 1999, 453-81.
Brynjolfsson, E. "The Great Equalizer? Consumer Choice
Behavior at Internet Shopbots." Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology, Sloan School of Management, 2000.
Brynjolfsson, E., and M. Smith. "Frictionless Commerce? A
Comparison of Internet and Conventional Retailers." Management
Science, 46(4), 2000, 563-85.
Chen, Y., and R. Rosenthal. "On the Use of Ceiling-Price
Commitments by Monopolists." RAND Journal of Economics, 27(2),
1996, 207-20.
Genesove, D., and C. J. Mayer. "Equity and Time to Sale in the
Real Estate Market." American Economic Review, 87(3), 1997, 255-69.
Glower, M., D. Haurin, and P. Hendershott. "Selling Time and
Selling Price: The Influence of Seller Motivation." Real Estate
Economics, 26(4), 1998, 719-40.
Green, R., and K. Vandell. "Optimal Ask Price and Bid
Strategies for Residential Sales." Working Paper, University of
Wisconsin, 1994.
Haurin, D. "The Duration of Marketing Time of Residential
Housing." Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association, 16(4), 1988, 351-68.
Houser, D., and J. Wooders. "Reputation in Auctions: Theory,
and Evidence from eBay." Working Paper 00-12, University of
Arizona, 2000.
Jin, G., and A. Kato. "Blind Trust Online: Experimental
Evidence from Baseball Cards." Working Paper, University of
Maryland, 2002.
Melnick, M. I., and J. Alm. "Does a Seller's eCommerce
Reputation Matter?" Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(3), 2002,
337-49.
Ortalo-Magne, F., and A. Merlo. "Bargaining over Residential
Real Estate: Evidence from England." Working Paper, 2000.
Quan, D. C., and J. M. Quigley. "Price Formation and the
Appraisal Function in Real Estate Markets." Journal of Real Estate
Finance and Economics, 4, 1991, 127-46.
Read, C. "Price Strategies for Idiosyncratic Goods--The Case
of Housing." Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban
Economies Association, 16(4), 1988, 379-95.
Resnick, P., and R. Zeckhauser. "Trust among Strangers in
Internet Transactions: Empirical Analysis of eBay's Reputation
System," in The Economics of the Internet and E-Commerce. edited by
Michael R. Baye. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 2002.
Yavas, A. "A Simple Search and Bargaining Model of Real Estate
Markets." Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association, 20(4), 1992, 533-48.
Yavas, A., and S. Yang. "The Strategic Role of Listing Price
in Marketing Real Estate: Theory and Evidence." Real Estate
Economics, 23(3), 1995, 347-68.
AMY FARMER and VICTOR STANGO *
* We thank Richard Cox for helpful data entry and the anonymous
referees for their comments. All errors are our own.
Farmer: Professor, Department of Economics, Walton College of
Business, University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR 72701. Phone
1-479-575-6093, Fax 1-479-575-3241, E-mail afarmer@walton.uark.edu
Stango: Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 230 S.
LaSalle St., Chicago, IL 60604. E-mail victor.stango@chi.frb.org