Endangered species and timber harvesting: the case of red-cockaded woodpeckers.
Zhang, Daowei
I. INTRODUCTION
The issue of differentiating legitimate public regulation of
private property from regulatory takings has become important and
controversial in the United States. The Endangered Species Act (ESA),
probably the most powerful environmental regulation ever enacted in the
United States, is in the center of this controversy. The modern version
of the ESA was enacted in 1973, and it has been amended several times
since. The ESA is intended to protect species from becoming extinct. The
ESA creates two main processes: the designation of species and their
critical habitats through listing, and protection. Souder (1995) shows
that listing is important because it triggers the four major provisions
of the ESA, which are to conserve listed species, avoid jeopardizing
them, avoid destruction of critical habitat, and avoid taking them.
Under the ESA, no person may take endangered or threatened species.
In the ESA, "the term 'take' means to harass, harm,
pursue, hunt, shoot, wound, kill, trap, capture, collect, or attempt to
engage in any such conduct" (16 USC Section 1532 [19]).
Furthermore, the U.S. Department of the Interior has defined the
statutory term harm as "an act which actually kills or injures
wildlife, including significant habitat modification or degradation
where it actually kills or injures wildlife by significantly impairing
essential behavioral patterns, including breeding, feeding, or
sheltering" (50 CFR Section 17.3 [1995]). This regulatory
definition has been upheld by the U.S. Supreme Court (Sweet Home v.
Babbitt, II S.Ct. 714 [1995]), and it is the fulcrum on which the
government levers regulation of private land. Because habitat
modification may be a "take," Flick et al. (1996) indicate
that the normal forestry activities of landowners fall within the
purview of the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service on lands with endangered
or threatened species.
U.S. Government Accounting Office (1995) shows that more than 80%
of listed endangered species have some habitat on private lands that are
mostly used for forestry or agricultural purposes. Furthermore, the list
of endangered or threatened species is growing continually with no limit
in sight. Because the ESA prescribes behavior and extracts use rights
from the bundle purchased or inherited by private landowners, its
potential reach over private land is very large yet uncertain. Few
publicly provided incentive programs have been offered to private
landowners for protection and enhancement of endangered species until
very recently. (1)
Because of this "stick" approach to public policy
regarding endangered species, the usual presumption is that, other
things being equal, landowners will avoid management activities that
might attract endangered species onto their lands and possibly develop
their lands early. (2) This belief continues to produce advocates for
protection of private property rights, not only from private landowner
organizations but also from public agencies and some environmental
groups. Recently, the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, with the support
of the Environmental Defense Fund, designed and implemented the Safe
Harbor Program, No Surprise Policy, and No Take Regulation, as noted by
Zhang (1999). These policies were in part designed to mitigate the
existing incentives to manage against endangered species on private
lands. On the other hand, individuals and groups who want to stop
development, construction, or logging may latch onto the ESA as a tool
to do so, with little or no concern in fact for listed species.
"Not in my back yard" and other motives are served well by the
strong ESA as currently formulated. As such, these individuals and
groups who can be labeled as bootleggers are no doubt supportive of the
current ESA. (3)
However, with the exception of Lueck and Michael (2003), there is
little empirical evidence in support of the view that weakness in the
current endangered species-related regulations impedes good management
and stewardship of forest resources. That is, the influence of
endangered species induced regulatory uncertainty or weakening of
private property rights on landowner behavior has been a subject of much
speculation but very little empirical study. There have been a number of
theoretical and policy studies of the relationship between private right
security and landowner behavior and performance, such as Zhang and
Pearse (1996; 1997), Innes (1997), and Polasky and Doremus (1998); some
isolated case studies of the ESA, such as Mann and Plummer (1995); and
studies on the impacts of endangered species on public lands, as in Hyde
(1989). Lacking quantitative studies on the influence of endangered
species-related regulation on landowner behavior is partly due to its
controversial nature and the requirements of strict confidentiality of
many landowners who have endangered species on their lands.
This article presents the results of an initial attempt to measure
directly the influence of endangered species induced regulatory
uncertainty on landowner timber harvesting behavior. The study differs
from other investigations of this question insofar as it is based on the
classical Faustmann model and an econometric analysis of recorded timber
harvesting activities under two different regulatory conditions,
utilizing a large sample of data on an important endangered species, the
red-cockaded woodpecker (RCW). The primary finding is that regulatory
uncertainty and lack of positive economic incentives alter landowner
timber harvesting behavior and hinder endangered species conservation on
private lands. This article begins in the next section by describing the
RCW and the theoretical framework and econometric methods adopted. This
is followed by a discussion of the data used in this study. The
remaining sections present empirical findings and conclusions and policy
implications.
II. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
The Birds and the Regulation
The RCW was listed as an endangered species in 1970. The RCW
chisels out its den cavity in live mature pine trees, a task that may
take as long as four years. The RCW prefers mature pine trees that have
been infected with red heart fungus, which tends to weaken the heartwood and make the birds' excavation somewhat easier. In addition, the
RCW prefers open, parklike stands containing little understory and
usually forages for insects on mature pine trees near its den. If the
pine stands are open and hardwood competition grows up in the
understory, the birds will abandon the site. Intentionally controlled
(prescribed) burning can control the undergrowth, preventing this cause
of nest abandonment.
The RCW is one of the most controversial endangered species in the
country. The economic significance of the RCW is that without human
assistance (such as an artificial nest box) and under currently
available habitat alternatives, it prefers to use medium to large-size
tracts of mature southern pine forests as its habitat. Southern pines
are the most important commercial species in the South. Because the
South accounts for approximately 65% of timber harvests in the country
and because 90% of Southern timberlands are privately owned (Smith et
al. [2001]), protecting the RCW likely will alter some private forest
management activities. Therefore, protecting the RCW may have larger
economic impacts among landowners than any other currently listed
species, except the northern spotted owls.
The U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service (1992) specifies regulations
applicable to private forest with RCW, restricting private
landowners' forest management activities. For example, the manual
specifies that no trees greater than 10 inch in dbh (diameter at breast
height or at 1.3 m height) should be cut, no pesticide should be used,
and no road should be built without permission within a 200-foot radius
(2.9 acres) surrounding a cavity tree. In addition, a minimum of 60
acres of foraging habitat within a half mile of the cavity tree, and a
minimum of 3000 square feet of pine basal area (a cross-section area of
all trees measured at dbh) in trees 10 inches dbh or larger should be
maintained. A half-mile radius covers 502 acres, so landowners can do
some timber harvesting if they or other landowners maintain enough
foraging habitats within one half-mile of the cavity tree.
Unlike the northern spotted owls, the RCW is a territorial bird,
meaning that it usually only has a few mile migratory range and does not
move far away from its primary habitat in search for food. The
biological attributes of the RCW, its significant economic impacts on
private forest management, and the presence of a government guideline for managing private forests where the RCW resides all provide a unique
opportunity to study the impact of ESA-related regulatory uncertainty on
landowner behavior.
In theory, forest landowners have an economic incentive (to protect
or enhance the existing value of their property) to harvest early,
before the RCW comes to their lands and otherwise manage in ways that
minimize the suitability of their forests for RCW habitat, analogous to
anticipatory buying before a hurricane or anticipatory production before
a labor strike, as in Warren-Boulton (1977). With the exception of Lueck
and Michael (2003), previous analyses of this predicted behavioral
impact are focused primarily on numerical calculation of the impacts of
the guideline on timber harvesting revenue and cost, as in Cleaves et
al. (1994) and Meyers et al. (1996), or forest conditions and timber
production possibilities when the RCW is present (Roise et al. [1990]).
This study adopts an analytical and econometric approach to explore the
impact of ESA-induced regulatory uncertainty on private landowner
behavior.
A Model of Forest Landowners Facing Regulatory Uncertainly Induced
by an Endangered Species
Similar to Innes (1997) and Polasky and Doremus (1998), Zhang
(2001) shows landowners facing the prospect of an endangered species on
their lands and ESA regulation may behave differently from other
landowners in terms of their timber harvesting behavior. These
behavioral implications are derived from a simple forest production
model. To illustrate the main point of the analysis, I take the
perspective of stand-level optimization. I assume the following:
1. A landowner can borrow and lend at a known real interest, r.
2. Stumpage prices, P, are constant;
3. Timber yield, Q(t,I) is a function of stand age, t, and
silvicultural investment, I, where [Q.sub.i] = [delta]Q/[[delta.sub.i]
> 0; [Q.sub.ii] < 0 for i = t, I.
4. If no endangered species are present, the landowner has a secure
property right to his forest, and the probability of losing any portion
of the forest is zero. There is a nonzero ([delta]) probability of
losing a portion ([alpha], 0 < [alpha] < 1) of the forest if an
endangered species moves into the forest and ESA applies. The value of
[alpha] depends on the characteristics of the landowner's own as
well as surrounding forests. For simplicity, I assume [alpha] is
exogenous (as I do not know the characteristics of forest other than the
landowner's own in the empirical study). (4) This is a case of
"partial regulatory taking" where regulations restrict a
landowner's management activity without any compensation.
5. The probability of losing a portion of his forest ([delta]) is
an increasing function of time (i.e., the stand age). (5) This is
because the longer the landowner waits before harvesting, the more
likely he will lose a portion of the forest because an RCW prefers to
reside in old pine forests.
The analysis is considerably clearer and more intuitive if one
simply considers a model in which the planning horizon runs through one
rotation. The landowner maximizes net return, V, to the fixed factor,
land, over time t. Zhang (2001) demonstrates that restating the problem
to allow either land purchase at the beginning of the timber rotation
and land sale at harvest time or continuous replacement of timber
harvests leaves the relevant predictions unchanged.
In the case of simply focusing on one rotation, the objective is to
maximize the expected present value of future cash flow considering
regulatory uncertainty. If the landowner does not lose any portion of
his forest to regulation (i.e., [alpha] = 0), the expected value of the
forest can be expressed as
(1) [V.sub.1] = P Q(t, I)[e.sup.-rt] - I.
If the landowner does lose a portion ([alpha]) of his forest to
regulation (i.e., [delta] = 1), the expected value of the forest can be
expressed as
(2) [V.sub.2] = (1 - [alpha])P Q(t, I)[e.sup.-rt] - I.
Thus the expected value of the forest under regulatory uncertainty
is
(3) V(t,l) = [1 - [delta](t)][PQ(t,I)[e.sup.-rt] - I] +
[delta](t)[(1 - [alpha])PQ(t, I)[e.sup.-rt] - I].
The landowner's objective is to maximize V(t, I). This is the
well-known one-rotation Faustmann formula, as in Gane (1968), with the
addition of a stochastic uncertainty factor. It is equivalent to
maximizing the difference between gross revenues and total costs, where
revenues are harvest receipts and costs are the annual opportunity costs of forest land use and silvicultural investment under regulatory
uncertainty. The model has a weakness in that it treats the landowner as
risk-neutral. However, if the result shows that a risk-neutral landowner
responds negatively to policy uncertainty, risk-averse landowners will
respond negatively to policy uncertainty as well.
Equation (3) can be simplified as
(4) V(t, E) = [1 - [alpha] [delta](t)]PQ(t, I)[e.sup.-rt] - I.
First-order conditions for a maximum require that
(5) [delta]V/[delta]t = {[1 - [alpha] [delta](t)](P[Q.sub.t] - rPQ)
- [alpha] [[delta].sub.t]PQ}[e.sup.-rt] = O,
which can be simplified as
(6) Qt - [alpha] [[delta].sub.t]Q/[1 - [alpha] [delta](t)] = rQ
or
(7) Qt/Q = r + [alpha][[delta].sub.t] / [1 - [alpha][delta](t)].
The optimal condition (6) can be interpreted easily. On the right
is the interest forgone by postponing harvesting the timber stand for
one period. On the left is the gain from postponing the harvest one
period, consisting of the value of timber growth over the period minus
the portion of timber that the landowner might not be able to harvest
due to the ESA during the period. For optimality, the marginal gain from
postponing the harvest one period must equal the marginal loss of
postponement. (6)
Because [delta] and [1 - [alpha] [delta](t)] are greater than zero,
the second term in equation (7) is positive. In the absence of
regulatory uncertainty, [delta](t) =0, equation (7) simply reduces to
the well-known result that a forest stand should be harvested when its
rate of growth equals the discount rate if stumpage price is assumed to
be constant and opportunity cost of the land is ignored (single
rotation). With regulatory uncertainty, the forest should be harvested
when the rate of growth is greater than the discount rate. In other
words, the policy uncertainty has the same impact as an increase in
discount rate in the Faustmann formula. Hyde (1980) and Chang (1983)
show that in general an increase in the discount rate leads to earlier
harvesting. Therefore, everything else being equal, landowners who face
possible invasions of endangered species to their forests (and thus ESA
regulation) will cut timber earlier than those who do not have to face
such regulation.
Although the analytical model is continuous (age at harvest), the
dependent variables (probability of timber harvesting and harvesting
method) used in this empirical analysis are dichotomous. The connection
between them lies in the fact that the probability of observing harvest
during a given period of time (ten years in this study) is negatively
related to the optimal harvesting age. In other words, landowners who
cut timber at a shorter rotation age--whether it is due to regulatory
uncertainty or to other factors--have a correspondingly higher
probability of harvest in the given period of time.
Other things equal, stands near existing RCW clusters are more
likely to be colonized than stands far away. Figure 1 illustrates the
location relationship among stands that have RCW habitats and that face
possible occupation of the RCW. Lands in zone one are active RCW
habitats and therefore are subject to the ESA. Lands in zone two are
adjacent to or very close (say, within one mile) to the active RCW
habitats, and there is a higher possibility of the RCW moving to these
lands if suitable habitats are provided. These lands will be subject to
the ESA if the RCW does come. Lands in zone three are farther away from
the active RCW habitats and relatively safe from RCW occupation.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The closer a mature stand is to an active RCW cluster, the more
likely the RCW will come if the stand is not harvested. Everything else
being equal, I hypothesize that landowners who have stands close to an
active RCW habitat will be more likely to harvest their forests than
landowners whose forests are distant from the RCW. Furthermore,
landowners' decisions to harvest or not to harvest in a given
period of time are influenced by the expected total stumpage revenue of
the timber stand (which is determined by price and timber volume in
various products categories). Third, the biological characteristics
(especially those that influence growth rate) of the timber stand affect
landowners' harvesting decisions, as shown in Dennis (1989).
Finally, landowners' management objectives and characteristics,
such as their financial need, attitude, and knowledge about forest
management, play a role in their timber harvesting decisions (Binkley
[1981]). Thus,
(8) HARVEST = f(ZONE, TR, [C.sub.f], USE, [C.sub.o]),
where
HARVEST is harvest or not (discretionary dependent variable);
ZONE is a measurement of proximity of a forest stand to a known or
perceived RCW habitat;
TR is the expected total stumpage revenue of the forest stand per
acre, which is determined by stumpage price and timber volume in each
products class;
[C.sub.f] is a vector of characteristics of the forest stand,
including basal area (a measure of density and tree size), species
composition, and size of the forest stand that influence its suitability
as RCW habitat;
USE is the landowner's primary use of the forest stand;
[C.sub.o] is a vector of characteristics of the landowner,
especially his education, income and length of forestland ownership.
Therefore, the primary linkage between the theoretic model and
empirical analysis is a measure of closeness of a forest stand (ZONE) to
a known or perceived RCW habitat. The other linkages include stumpage
price (which is assumed to be constant in the theoretic model), timber
volume (Q), and factors (biological characteristics of the stand)
influencing the growth rate ([Q.sub.t]) of timber volume. The
landowner's management objective and characteristics are factors
ignored in the theoretic model but need to be controlled for in
empirical analysis because they vary significantly.
The model only predicts when the forest should be harvested and
does not indicate which harvesting method should be chosen. The
frequently used harvesting methods include clear-cut, seed-tree,
shelterwood, and selection. Using harvesting methods other than
clear-cut will result in some large trees being left on the ground.
Because the RCW prefers open, park-like stands containing little
understory, using nonclear-cut harvesting methods may improve the
suitability of the forest stand as RCW habitat. Although not all
nonclearcut methods are equally desirable to the RCW, they are all
preferable to the RCW comparing to clear-cut method, and thus their use
or nonuse might be affected by the possible application of the ESA and
RCW regulations. Because clear-cut destroys or forecloses potential RCW
habitat quickly, I hypothesize that it will be more often used when the
possibility of the RCW's coming to the stand is high.
In the absence of regulatory uncertainty, landowners choose among
harvesting methods to maximize stumpage revenue (net of reforestation cost, if any) subject to constraints such as forest stand
characteristics (some stands are suitable for certain harvesting
methods), aesthetics, management objective, and tax liability.
Landowners can maximize revenue by using the clear-cut method, but they
usually have to make some reforestation investment shortly after
harvesting to ensure the productivity of the land and forest succession.
In addition, clear-cut lands usually lack aesthetic appeal, and large
clear-cut stands attract less wildlife, such as deer and turkey,
limiting landowners' opportunities for recreational use (hunting or
leasing for hunting rights) and potentially subjecting them to a higher
tax bracket. The other harvesting methods have the opposite effect
(relatively less revenue, but the resulting cutover lands have more
aesthetic appeal, attract more wildlife, and can ensure forest
succession based on natural regeneration). Thus, closeness to an RCW
habitat, stand characteristics, and landowners' management
objectives and characteristics are determinants of harvesting method:
(9) METHOD=f(ZONE, [C.sub.f], USE, [C.sub.o]),
where METHOD is the harvesting method (discretionary dependent
variable). (7)
III. DATA
The unit of observation for this study is the forest or timber
stand, which is a tract of forest with similar age, species composition,
location, and belonging to a single ownership. Here each stand is
treated as a homogeneous unit with respect to its stand characteristics,
location, and species composition. (8) Ideally, we would like to have a
random sample of timber stands in different zones. Such a forest stand
database was not available, so I had to rely on a survey of landowners.
The sampling strategy was to randomly select a group of landowners and
reveal their timber harvesting decisions in various stands for a given
period of time.
The study area covers 32 counties in the sandhills and coastal
areas of South Carolina and North Carolina (Figure 2). All of these
counties currently have active RCW populations. A mail survey designed
according to the total design method by Dillman (1978) and Salant and
Dillman (1994) was conducted in fall 1998. The survey contained 56
questions, focusing on timber harvesting activities (and the lack of
them) in the previous ten years. If timber harvests had been conducted,
the landowners were asked to provide location (the closeness to a known
or perceived RCW habitat), harvesting method used, and forest stand
characteristics for a maximum of (the last) three stands cut in the past
ten years. (9) They were then asked to provide the same information for
the oldest forest stand that had not been cut and was older than 35
years (because all known RCW cavity trees are older than 35 years and
the RCW prefers to reside in older pine forests). Those who had not cut
any timber were asked to provide information for the oldest forest
stand. Those who had not cut any timber in the past ten years and did
not have any forest stands old than 35 years were only asked to respond
to questions related to landowner characteristics. In other words,
landowners who cut trees less than 35 years old and who did not have
stands that are more than 35 years old were excluded from this study;
therefore, the heterogeneity of tree ages were controlled for.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
There are no current and comprehensive databases with information
on the location of known RCW habitat on private lands. The database
maintained by the National Heritage Foundation is based on historical
occurrence records, not periodic and systemic surveys. As such, the
quality of the database is questionable. For example, the South Carolina
database only has 51 known RCW occurrence records on private
forestlands, far less than the estimates by the U.S. Fish and Wildlife
Service. Furthermore, the RCW records on public forests in the database
do not match up well with those in the database maintained by the U.S.
Fish and Wildlife Service, which is based on periodic surveys. Thus the
U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service do not use the National Heritage
Foundation database even without an RCW location map of its own on
private land (not to mention a list of surrounding landowners). Note
that even if my measure of RCW proximity is not factually accurate, it
may give a better measure of landowners' perception of RCW
proximity than would a perfect GIS database. Harvesting decisions will
be influenced by what landowners know and think, not necessarily by what
is true.
Because some questions concerning the forest stand characteristics
were fairly detailed and technical, landowners who could not answer them
were asked to provide the names, addresses, and phone numbers of
assistance foresters they used or their timber buyers. Then a follow-up
telephone interview with these foresters or timber buyers was conducted
to recover this information.
The sampling procedure was designed to achieve a representative and
unbiased sample of relatively large nonindustrial private forest
landowners, as the chance of small landowners having RCW on their lands
is relatively remote. Industrial forest landowners were excluded from
this study primarily because they have the time (the marginal utility that can be generated from a particular stand at a given time is small),
space (planning can be done on large land base), and financial
flexibility that nonindustrial forest landowners rarely have. In
addition, some industrial forest landowners have signed "No Take
Agreements" with the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, which give
them assurance that they would not be challenged under the ESA since
1994. Finally, nonindustrial private owners own approximately 70% of
forest lands in the U.S. South, whereas industrial forest owners own
some 20%. Nonindustrial private forests are more important to various
endangered species, including the RCW. Nonetheless, excluding industrial
owners from this study does not mean that the ESA does not impact their
behavior, but that their behavior could be different from that of
nonindustrial private landowners.
The names and addresses of all forest landowners who owned more
than 100 acres of forestland in these counties were collected from
individual county tax assessors. Seven counties only provided a list of
owners of farm and forestlands over 100 acres. After deleting all known
industrial forest landowners, a sample of I out of 10 landowners (and 1
out of every 15 for the seven counties with combined lists of
landowners) in each county was then selected for the survey. The final
mailing list comprised 1742 randomly selected landowners.
The final survey sample had 1696 landowners because 48 surveys (3%)
were returned unopened. Five hundred eight of the surveys were completed
and returned, representing a response rate of 30%. (10) A follow-up
telephone survey of a randomly selected sample of 50 (3%) of the
nonrespondents reveals that nonresponding is not correlated to the size
of ownership, income, education, age, and state origins. Some 190
respondents that did not cut any timber in the past 10 years and had no
forest stands older than 35 years were excluded from this study, leaving
318 respondents. Excluding respondents who reported hardwood stands,
which is not a good habitat for the RCW and is not relevant to this
study, leaves 252 respondents and 522 timber stands (as some respondents
reported more than one stand). However, information on characteristics
of 206 stands was not available because some landowners did not respond
to the questions and did not provide the name of their assistance
foresters or timber buyers. The final number of timber stands useful for
this study is 316, of which 230 were harvested in the last 10 years and
86 remain standing. Clear-cutting was used in 164 of the 230 harvested
stands, and other methods, including seed-tree, shelterwood, selection,
and thinning, were used on the remaining 66 stands. Sixty-seven
landowners provided information on both stand(s) they cut and their
oldest remaining stands. These 134 stands comprise the sample used in
the timber harvesting model. (11)
Table 1 provides the definitions of variables used in the
statistical analysis, their mean values, and standard deviation. The
mean values and standard deviations of the variables used in the
harvesting method model are not much different from these in the
harvesting model and are not reported here. Tables 2 and 3 present the
corresponding information for each zone. Though the means for HARVEST
and METHOD are 0.50 and 0.71, respectively, for all observations (Table
1), they differ between zones (Tables 2 and 3). However, any conclusions
regarding the effect of ZONE on harvesting decisions can only be firmly
drawn after additional econometric analysis is conducted, because other
factors differ between zones as well.
Of the independent variables in the two regressions, that for the
location, ZONE, is of special interest in this study. ZONE was assigned
a value of one if the stand was (or was perceived to be) adjacent to or
within one mile of a known or perceived RCW habitat and zero otherwise
(i.e., if the stand was more than one mile away from a known RCW habitat
or the owner did not know or was not sure how far the stand was from an
RCW habitat). (12) Because proximity to existing habitat increases the
odds of colonization, which would bring the ESA regulation into force,
the coefficient for this variable was expected to have a positive sign
in both harvesting and harvesting method models.
The expected or potential total revenue (per acre) variable, TR, is
included in equation (8) to capture variations among stands in the
amount of money an owner could get from each stand at some given set of
prices. It is calculated as
(10) TR = [SIGMA]([P.sub.i] * [V.sub.i])/CPI
where [P.sub.i] and [V.sub.i] are stumpage prices and harvested
volume of product i (i includes pine products--pole, sawtimber,
chip-n-saw, and pulpwood--and hardwood sawtimber and hardwood pulpwood),
and CPI is the Consumer Price Index (1997 = 100). Stumpage price data
were from Timber-Mart South (1999) and were tied to the date (quarter of
the year) of harvesting. When the stand is not cut, the total revenue is
calculated as of the fourth quarter of 1998. The coefficient of TR was
expected to be positive for the harvesting model as landowners harvest
when the expected total revenue is high.
The stand characteristics include BA (basal area), SPECIES, and
SIZE. The coefficient of BA was expected to be positive in the
harvesting model because high basal area means that the stand is dense
and that doing nothing to the stand will reduce its biological growth
rate. Its sign was also predicted to be positive in the harvesting
method model because dense forests make selective cutting more difficult
to conduct without damaging trees intended to be left. The variable
SPECIES was used to control for the predominant species in the stand.
Longleaf pine is known to be a preferred species for the RCW. However,
longleaf typically matures later than other pine species, and,
everything else being equal, landowners will cut it later than other
species. Therefore, the sign of the SPECIES variable could only be
determined empirically. The variable SIZE was expected to have a
negative sign in both models because, everything else being equal,
cutting too much timber within a year could make landowners jump to a
higher tax bracket and pay more income taxes. (13)
The variable USE represents the primary management objective of
landowners. It was expected to be negative for the harvesting model and
positive for the method model. If landowners have a primary objective
other than timber production (such as hunting and other recreation,
hunting lease, pine straw harvesting, farm or domestic use, and land
investment), they will delay timber harvesting, making the USE variable
have a negative sign in the harvesting model and use other aesthetically
appealing harvesting methods if they decide to cut some timber (which
will make the USE variable have a positive sign in the harvesting method
model).
A variable FIRE was used in the harvesting method model to control
for the "cleanness" of forest stands on harvesting method. It
was expected to have a negative sign for three reasons. First, the
forest stands will be clean if fire is frequently used, making
nonclear-cut harvesting methods applicable. Second, fire promotes
natural regeneration, and harvesting methods other than clear-cutting
protect young tree seedlings better. Finally, fire promotes park-like
stands with little understory, which is preferred by the RCW. Thus,
those who use clear-cut method to reduce the likelihood of regulatory
taking due to the RCW would tend not to burn. Since FIRE and SPECIES are
highly correlated (r = 0.79), the variable SPECIES was dropped from
equation (9) to avoid multicollinearity. The high level of correlation
between these two variables reflects the fact that longleaf pine forests
are fire-dependent. In other words, longleaf pine forests could easily
be converted to other forests in a few years without natural or
controlled fires.
Finally, three variables were used to control for characteristics
of landowners. FINCOME was expected to be positive in both models, as
landowners with a high portion of their income from forests tend to cut
more timber, either through timber harvesting or using clear-cut
methods. The variables LENGTH and EDUCATION were expected to be negative
in both models because highly educated and knowledgeable landowners with
long-time land ownership might be more appreciative of multiple forest
uses and have a longer-term perspective on forest management.
IV. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
Equations (8) and (9) were run using linear logistic regression.
Both models fit relatively well as the chi-squared statistics are
significant at the 0.01% level or better. Models in which the continuous
independent variables took logs were run as well. In both cases, the
simple linear model performed better. None of the variables used has
pair-wise correlation coefficients exceeding [+ or -] 0.35.
The results of the regression for equation (8) are presented in
Table 4, using only 134 observations (the last stands harvested in the
last ten years and the oldest timber stands that had not been cut, as
reported by the 67 landowners). Of the nine parameters estimated, five
are significant at the 10% level or better. All signs in estimated
models confirm my expectation, and most of the values, as indicated by
the marginal effect, appear reasonable. What is critical about this
analysis is that each landowner had at least two stands that were more
than 35 years old, of which one was harvested. The question is, did
proximity to RCW influence the landowner's choice of which one was
cut?
The variable for closeness to a known or perceived RCW habitat,
ZONE, is positive and significant at the 5% level. This is consistent
with the hypothesis that possible regulatory intervention induced by
proximity to a known or perceived RCW habitat has a significant positive
impact on landowners' decisions to harvest timber. These results
indicate that after allowing for other influences, the likelihood of
timber harvesting is higher when the stand is close to a known RCW
habitat. The marginal effect, as shown in Table 4, is quite large (about
25%). In other words, a landowner is 25% more likely to cut forests when
he or she knows or perceives that a RCW cluster is within a mile of the
land than otherwise.
The coefficient for total revenue per acre is positive and
significant at the 10% level, confirming the expectation that high
revenue increases the possibility of the stand being cut. Among other
significant influences on timber harvesting probability, the positive
coefficient for basal area suggests that dense stands tend to be
harvested earlier, as expected. The coefficients for the primary use and
education variables show that they, too, have significant impacts on
timber harvesting probability, both in a negative way. Other variables
for species composition, income from forestry, and length of ownership
are not significant. The marginal effects of all significant variables
are also significant.
The results of the regression for harvesting method equation (9)
are reported in Table 5. The variable ZONE is significant at 1%,
confirming that possible regulatory intervention has a positive impact
on landowners' decision to employ clear-cutting as their harvesting
method. The marginal effect of this variable is about 21%. The other
significant variables include use of prescribed fire, stand size,
percent of forestry income, and length of forest ownership. In this
model, the coefficient for the basal area is not significant at normal
levels. Dropping this variable did not have much impact on the estimates
of other variables.
Table 6 compares the predicted and actual outcomes for the two
models. This measures the performance of the models in predicting
landowners' timber harvesting behaviors. For example, in case of
the timber harvesting model, the model correctly predicts 95 (48 + 47)
of the 134 outcomes, an overall success rate of 71%. Comparing the two
specific outcomes, the model correctly predicts 72% of the "0 (no
harvesting)" and 70% of the "1 (harvesting)." However,
the model performs well in predicting the usage of clear-cut method but
not the usage of other harvesting methods. To demonstrate the
explanatory power of the model, another measure is presented in the
rightmost column of Table 6. The numbers in this column show the
randomly assigned ratios of 1 and 0 to the dependent variables. That is,
if there were no explanatory variables and outcomes were assigned
according to their ratios, 50% (67/134) will be correctly predicted as 0
and 1 in the timber harvesting model. Comparing these numbers to those
in the percent correct column demonstrates an increase in the
explanatory power of the model due to the inclusion of the independent
variables.
A Comparison with a Similar Study
The results of this article are similar to those presented in Lueck
and Michael (2003), who use quite similar logic and techniques. It is
striking that two similar studies were initiated independently at
roughly the same time and that the results reached support each other.
Nonetheless, there are differences in these studies. Data used in
these two studies are different. Lueck and Michael use secondary data
(U.S. Forest Service Forest Inventory Survey data and a North Carolina
State University survey data) in North Carolina alone. As such, they do
not control for landowner characteristics. In contrast, this study uses
primary data based on a survey of landowners in both North and South
Carolina. More important, the proximity to RCW is measured as actual
number of colonies within various (5, 10, 15, and 25 miles) distances to
a forest property in their study but as known or perceived existence of
RCW habitat (as defined by U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, an RCW
cluster area, which is the 200-foot-area surrounding a cavity tree, and
foraging habitat is a minimum of 60 acres within half a mile of the
cluster) within 1 mile to a forest property in this study. Consequently,
the magnitude of the marginal effect of this proximity variable in these
two studies is somewhat different and may not be directly compared.
Third, this study is able to control for forest characteristics, such as
basal area and tract size, whereas the other study has done better in
controlling for landowner objectives. Finally, this study is able to
cover another dimension of timber harvesting--harvesting method (and to
a much lesser degree, the use of controlled burning), and the other
study covers actual rotation age and industrial landowners.
Despite the use of different data, the basic conclusions reached in
these two studies are similar: the ESA regulations actually lead
landowners cut their timber sooner, to the detriment of the RCW, than
they otherwise would do. As a consequence, RCW habitats have been
reduced on private lands because of the ESA. In this case the ESA
imposes costs but does not generate conservation benefits. These
findings add substance to anecdotal claims of preemption and are
consistent with concerns of those who have noted that RCW populations
have been declining since it has been listed as an endangered species.
V. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The purpose of this study was to assess quantitatively the popular
notion that regulatory uncertainty induced by possible invasion of an
endangered species influences landowners' decisions to cut timber
quickly and to use a harvesting method that forecloses potential
endangered species habitat. The conventional logic is clear: without any
financial compensation for providing endangered species habitat but
facing more governmental regulatory limitation on their land use and
management if an endangered species comes onto their property,
landowners have no incentive to voluntarily provide additional habitat
for endangered species. Instead, landowners will act in ways that they
might not otherwise act--to cut timber and eliminate suitable habitat
and to do so before endangered species come onto their lands to protect
or enhance the existing value of their property. Furthermore, they have
an incentive to urge their neighbors to do the same, because the RCW on
neighboring land increases the vulnerability of them and other neighbors
as well.
The findings of this study support this general argument. To this
extent, they are broadly consistent with the conclusion of other studies
on property right security such as Epstein (1985), Feder et al. (1988),
and Zhang and Pearse (1996; 1997) and on the ESA in popular magazines
and books such as Mann and Plummer (1995) and Stroup (1995) and in
academic journals such as Stroup (1996) and Innes (1997). The results of
this article help verify with independent evidence the point made
earlier by others but supported empirically primarily by Lueck and
Michael (2003), that at least for the RCW, the ESA has a strong and
negative effect on habitat. More uniquely, the empirical findings
indicate that the magnitude of disincentive-induced destruction or
foreclosure of potential endangered species habitat may be substantial.
The implications of these findings are significant. Of the vast
majority of endangered species that have some or all of their habitats
on private lands, the likelihood of them thriving is not great if the
current policy is not changed. A full recovery of these species, as
mandated in the ESA, is even more remote because private landowners have
little incentive to provide additional habitat to endangered species but
much incentive to preclude them from coming onto their lands. Facing
isolation, some endangered species could eventually become extinct.
Moving all of these species onto public lands seems to be an impractical solution for most endangered or threatened species.
Having realized that perverse incentive could lead to undesirable
harvesting behavior, some environmental groups have started to lobby for
more flexible regulations and more programs that provide positive
incentives for landowners. (14) The Environmental Defense Fund (1995)
recommends cost-share programs and tax breaks for landowners who provide
habitat for endangered species. Stroup (1996) and Bourland and Stroup
(1996) call for compensation or rental payments to landowners who
provide endangered species habitat on their land. If implemented, a
compensation policy would provide economic incentives that induce
landowners to supply more endangered species habitat. However, Czech and
Krausman (1999) show that the political feasibility of this policy is
questionable. Furthermore, the transaction costs for implementing it
need to be studied.
Some individuals and groups do not want to make any changes to the
ESA, and that's why the ESA has been mired in congressional
grid-lock since its authorization expired in 1992. Those who want to use
the ESA as a tool to stop development, construction, and logging
certainly do not want to weaken the ESA provisions on private or public
lands. "Not in my back yard" motives are also served by the
strong ESA as currently formulated, while listed species seems to be
quite badly served. When considering ESA reauthorization, it would be
wonderful if policy makers can identify the noise made from these
bootleggers and look at hard empirical evidences.
Public lands can be affected in the same way by the ESA as private
lands. For example, if U.S. Department of Defense uses land (such as
Fort Benning, GA, and Fort Bragg, NC, which both have RCW colonies) for
military exercises and such land use is threatened if listed species are
found thereon, their commanders may, to protect their military missions,
engage in habitat modifications to the same end as private landowners
and with the same negative results for habitat. At another extreme, four
firefighters lost their lives in Okanogan National Forest in Winthrop,
Washington, in July 2001 because delays in granting permission for
fire-fighting helicopters to use water from nearby streams and rivers
protected by the ESA (Fox News [2001]). More likely, because the
managers of public lands have a weak ownership of the land, they are not
expected to alter land use to preempt the ESA. Thus the ESA will be more
successful in preserving habitat on public land. But the current ESA
could still provide incentives to public land managers to either act
like private landowners or stick to the ESA overzealously.
The problem with the ESA is not an artifact of private property or
market operation as difficulty with implementing it exists in private as
well as public lands. Rather, it reflects the tunnel vision by those
seeking to serve their own mission--whether it is saving species or
other goals--at unlimited expense of other missions. Why else would land
use restrictions emanating from the ESA not be considered as in the case
of public lands or be paid for as in the case of private lands,
regardless of their cost?
The broad policy implications of this study are twofold. First, the
ESA is not working well on private lands because it does not provide
adequate incentive for landowners to conserve endangered species and
enhance habitat. Any attempt to make ESA more effective will have to
accommodate the need of private landowners and provide them with
positive incentives for endangered species conservation. More
flexibility in the application of the ESA, such as the Safe Harbor
Program, is a step toward correcting misguided incentives. However, it
is not enough to attract many small, nonindustrial landowners who do not
have the necessary time, space, and financial resources that large and
industrial landowners possess. Second, many environmental regulations
have unintended consequences with respect to producer and consumer
behavior, such as creating additional harm to the environment that the
regulations were intended to protect. Future reforms to these
regulations need to eliminate or reduce the regulation-induced behavior
by providing positive incentives to producers and consumers. In other
words, regulations can work or work better only when there is incentive
compatibility.
ABBREVIATIONS
ESA: Endangered Species Act
RCW: Red-Cockaded Woodpecker
TABLE 1
Variable Definitions and Sample Statistics
Variable Definition Mean SD
HARVEST Whether or not harvest occurred 0.500 0.502
(dummy: 1 if timber harvesting occurred
in the last 10 years, 0 otherwise)
METHOD Harvesting method 0.713 0.453
(dummy: 1 if clear-cut, 0 otherwise)
ZONE Proximity to a known or perceived RCW 0.306 0.463
habitat (dummy: 1 if adjacent or within
1 mile of a known RCW habitat, 0
otherwise)
TR Expected or potential total stumpage 23.668 10.591
revenue of mature forest products
per acre, in constant 1997 $ (100)
BA Basal area in square feet 75.097 24.479
SPECIES Predominant species 0.269 0.445
(dummy variable: 1 if longleaf pine, 0
otherwise)
SIZE Number of acres of the stand 200.246 550.615
USE Primary use (dummy: 1 if primarily used 0.515 0.502
for anything other than timber
production, 0 if for timber production)
FIRE Use of prescribed burning 0.410 0.493
(dummy: 1 if prescribed burning is used
for every 7 years or less, 0 otherwise)
FINCOME Percent of forestry income in the 0.418 0.495
family's total annual income in the
last 5 years (dummy: 1 if more than
10%, 0 otherwise)
LENGTH Years of forest land ownership 29.119 22.102
EDUCATION Owner's level of education 0.821 0.385
(dummy: 1 if college or postgraduate
degree, 0 otherwise)
TABLE 2
Sample Statistics of the Explanatory
Variables by Zones for Timber
harvesting
ZONE = 1 ZONE = 0
Variable Mean SD Mean SD
HARVEST 0.707 0.461 0.409 0.494
TR (100 in 1997$) 26.965 12.070 22.214 9.583
BA 83.829 23.091 71.247 24.196
SPECIES 0.195 0.401 0.301 0.461
SIZE 196.829 771.190 201.753 423.912
USE 0.488 0.506 0.527 0.502
FINCOME 0.439 0.502 0.409 0.494
LENGTH 28.073 17.338 29.581 23.974
EDUCATION 0.829 0.381 0.817 0.389
No. of observations 41 93
TABLE 3
Sample Statistics of the Explanatory
Variables by Zones for Timber
Harvesting Method
ZONE = 1 ZONE = 0
Variable Mean SD Mean SD
METHOD 0.786 0.412 0.654 0.478
TR (100 in 1997$) 27.722 9.606 29.014 13.268
BA 82.942 19.225 84.354 22.193
SIZE 140.835 168.385 97.724 144.684
USE 0.466 0.501 0.386 0.489
FIRE 0.350 0.479 0.386 0.489
FINCOME 0.466 0.501 0.488 0.502
LENGTH 40.952 41.166 30.465 22.316
EDUCATION 0.806 0.398 0.835 0.373
No. of observations 103 127
TABLE 4
Results of Logistic Regression on Timber Harvesting Model
Marginal
Variable Coefficient t-Ratio Effect
ZONE (proximity to a 1.002 2.189 * 0.250
RCW habitat)
TR (potential total 0.040 1.689 * 0.010
stumpage revenue)
BA (basal area) 0.019 1.785 * 0.005
SPECIES (predominant 0.184 0.388 0.046
species)
SIZE (acreage of the -0.001 -0.859 0.000
stand)
USE (primary use) -1.266 -2.788 * -0.316
FINCOME (share of 0.016 0.036 0.004
forestry income)
LENGTH (years of -0.010 -1.014 -0.002
ownership)
EDUCATION (level of -0.979 -1.747 * -0.244
education)
INTERCEPT -0.786 -0.820 -0.196
Log-likelihood -73.913
function
Restricted log- -92.882
likelihood function
Chi-squared (df=8) 37.938
No. of observations 134
Variable t-Ratio
ZONE (proximity to a 2.183 *
RCW habitat)
TR (potential total 1.688 *
stumpage revenue)
BA (basal area) 1.784 *
SPECIES (predominant 0.388
species)
SIZE (acreage of the -0.863
stand)
USE (primary use) -2.787 *
FINCOME (share of 0.036
forestry income)
LENGTH (years of -1.014
ownership)
EDUCATION (level of -1.747 *
education)
INTERCEPT -0.820
* Significant at the 10% level.
TABLE 5
Results of Logistic Regression on Timber Harvesting Method Model
Marginal
Variable Coefficient t-Ratio Effect
ZONE (proximity to a 1.084 3.058 *** 0.207
RCW habitat)
BA (basal area) 0.001 0.016 0.001
FIRE (use of -0.521 -1.610 * -0.099
prescribed fire)
SIZE (acreage of the -0.002 -2.353 ** -0.001
stand)
USE (primary use) 0.135 0.398 0.026
FINCOME (share of 1.280 3.525 *** 0.244
forestry income)
LENGTH (years of -0.013 -2.605 *** -0.002
ownership)
EDUCATION (level of -0.259 -0.586 -0.049
education)
INTERCEPT 1.056 1.398 * 0.201
Log-likelihood -122.166
function
Restricted log- -137.863
likelihood function
Chi-squared (df=8) 31.393
No. of observations 230
Variable t-Ratio
ZONE (proximity to a 3.156 ***
RCW habitat)
BA (basal area) 0.016
FIRE (use of -1.620 *
prescribed fire)
SIZE (acreage of the -2.340 **
stand)
USE (primary use) 0.398
FINCOME (share of 3.659 ***
forestry income)
LENGTH (years of -2.646 ***
ownership)
EDUCATION (level of -0.586
education)
INTERCEPT 1.428 *
* Significant at the 20% level.
** Significant at the 5% level.
*** Significant at the 1% level.
TABLE 6
Predicted versus Actual Outcomes of
Timber Harvesting and Harvesting
Method Models
Predicted
Random
Actual 0 1 Total % Correct Assignment (%)
Timber harvesting model
0 48 19 67 72 50
1 20 47 67 70 50
Total 68 66 134
Harvesting method model
0 24 42 66 36 29
1 7 157 164 87 71
Total 31 199 230
(1.) See Eisner et al. (1995) and Zhang and Flick (2001) for
habitat creation with positive incentive. However, it might take giant
incentives to overcome the threat of large and direct losses with the
current command-and-control powers inherent in the current ESA programs.
On the other hand, absent of those draconian (potential rather than
inevitable) penalties, small positive incentives might bring forth much
habitat protection now being preemptively reduced or destroyed and
habitat creation.
(2.) See Innes (1997) and Polasky and Doremus (1998). Both articles
use game theoretic models and show that private landowners have
incentive to develop their property early when facing potential ESA
regulation. Although this study can be thought of as an empirical test
of these models, I use the traditional Faustmann forest rotation model
to study timber harvesting.
(3.) Yandle (1989) labels "Baptists" as those who promote
any public or private interest by attaching it to other issues that have
broad public support (such as protecting the environment), while
"bootleggers" are characterized as those who would support the
same interest without attaching it to any public issue.
(4.) The value of [alpha] varies according to the landowner's
own stand size and characteristics as well as those of his
neighbor's and the number of RCW clusters. When a varies, the
predicted result in equation (7) changes only in magnitude, not in
direction.
5. More precisely in this study, [delta](t) is an increasing
function of time after pine trees reach 35 years because all known RCW
cavity trees are more than 35 years old. I excluded less than 35 years
old stands in the empirical analysis (see data section).
(6.) Zhang and Flick (2001) show that optimal silvicultural
investment varies dependent whether or not the ESA applies. Because this
article is focused on timber harvesting, the optimal condition of the
investment variable is not derived.
(7.) It is widely known to foresters and some landowners that the
RCW will go away if no prescribed burning is used for a period of seven
to ten years and the understory hardwood grows high enough to reach the
RCW cavity holes. I have run a model similar to equation (9) and found a
negative but statistically insignificant relationship between prescribed
burning and closeness to a known or perceived RCW habitat. I understand
that several key variables (such as closeness of a stand to a city or
township and the attitude and experience of landowners with fire) are
missing in the model. Further research could be done in this area.
(8.) It is possible that one large stand could become two stands if
the landowner conducts two separate timber harvesting or harvests a
portion of it and leaves the rest intact.
(9.) I wanted to take a snapshot at timber harvesting behavior of
random-selected landowners using a window of ten years. All landowners
we surveyed had the opportunity of providing information on their last
timber harvest. If they cut more than one stand, they were asked to
provide information on the second and third last timber stands
harvested. I did not include other timber stands harvested in the survey
for two reasons--landowners might not have the information on these
harvests and, more important, putting too many questions in one survey
questionnaire would reduce response rate. I only asked the oldest
standing timber stand. The logic for not asking more standing timber
stands is simple--everything else being equal, the oldest stand should
get cut first. Therefore, if a landowner cuts a 45-year-old timber stand
but keeps a 55-year-old timber stand, there must be a reason. In
searching for the reason, we do not need to ask information on another
40- or 50-year old stand.
(10.) The primary appeals for landowners to respond to our survey
are the importance of the issue under this study and the promise of
sending them papers coming out of the research.
(11.) The reason for using this partitioned data in timber
harvesting model is to control for the possible nonrandomness of the
survey as landowners might have cut more than three stands and have more
than one remaining stands. In this case, all 67 landowners having two
(or more) stands chose to cut one and leave the other(s) intact. This
approach is similar to a controlled experiment on the same landowners
who harvest one mature stand and leave the other(s) intact. Another
approach is to augment the sample by including landowners who only cut
one or more stands but do not have any remaining stand and who only have
one or more remaining stands but did not cut any. The results using this
augmented sample (227 observations) are similar to those reported in
Table 4, although the coefficient (1.272) and marginal effect (0.287) of
the ZONE variable (both are significant at the 1% level) using the
augmented sample are slightly larger.
(12.) The choices for this distance question (how far is the stand
from the closest RCW habitat) are within the habitat, adjacent to the
habitat, not adjacent to but within 1 mile of the habitat, 1-5 miles
from the habitat, 6-18 miles from the habitat, more than 18 miles from
the habitat, and do not know or is not sure. Scientific evidence shows
that the RCW rarely goes beyond 1-5 miles from its habitat in search for
food, and no RCW has been found more than 18 miles from its cavity trees
under normal conditions. See Kulhavy et al. (1995). My preliminary
analysis indicates that landowners change their behavior when they know
or perceive that RCW is within one mile of their timber stand. About 26%
of respondents indicated that they did not know or were not sure how far
their stands were from an RCW habitat. Excluding these landowners
generates results similar to those reported here.
(13.) Landowners can cut a portion of a large stand to avoid paying
high tax. In this case, the stand size will be smaller than the whole
stand. See note 8.
(14.) The Safe Harbor Program is invented for this purpose. Safe
Harbor is a voluntary agreement between landowners and U.S. Fish and
Wildlife Service. Under the agreement, landowners commit actions that
are expected to benefit endangered species. In return, they receive
assurances that they can "undo" these actions in the future.
The agreement applies to landowners with or without an endangered
species on their lands. In either case, a preagreement baseline
population of endangered species (which may be zero) is established, and
landowners are required to maintain this population unless unforeseeable natural events destroy endangered species habitats.
REFERENCES
Binkley, C. S. Timber Supply from Nonindustrial Forests. Bulletin
No. 92. Yale University School of Forestry and Environmental Studies,
New Haven, CT, 1981.
Bourland T. R., and R. L. Stroup. "Rent Payment as
Incentive." Journal of Forestry, 93(4), 1996, 18-21.
Chang, S. J. "Rotation Age, Management Intensity, and the
Economic Factors of Timber Production: Do Changes in Stumpage Price,
Interest Rate, Regeneration Cost and Forest Taxation Matter?"
Forest Science, 29(2), 1983, 267-78.
Cleaves, D., R. Busby, B. Doherty, and J. Martel. "Cost of
Protecting Red-Cockaded Woodpecker Habitat: Interaction of Parcel and
Cluster Size," in Proceeding of the 24th Annual Southern Forest
Economics Workshop, edited by D. Newman. Athens, GA: University of
Georgia, 1994.
Czech, B., and P. R. Krausman. "Public Opinion on Endangered
Species Conservation and Policy." Society and Natural Resources,
12, 1999, 469-79.
Dennis, D. F. "An Economic Analysis of Harvesting Behavior:
Integrating Forest and Ownership Characteristics." Forest Science,
35(4), 1989, 1088-104.
Dillman, D. A. Mail and Telephone Surveys: The Total Design Method.
New York: Wiley, 1978.
Eisner, T., J. Lubchenco, E. O. Wilson, D. S. Wilcove, and M. J.
Bean. "Building a Scientifically Sound Policy for Protecting
Endangered Species." Science, 268, 1995, 1231-32.
Epstein, R. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent
Domain. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1985.
Environmental Defense Fund. "Incentives for Endangered Species
Conservation Opportunities in the Sandhills of North Carolina." A
Report to the Bernice Barbour, Beneficia, Unerhill, and the National
Fish and Wildlife Foundations, 1995.
Feder, G., T. Onchan, Y. Chalamwong, and C. Hongladarom. Land
Policy and Farm Productivity in Thailand. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
University Press, 1988.
Flick, W., R. Tufts, and D. Zhang. "Sweet Home as Forest
Policy." Journal of Forestry, 94(4), 1996, 4-8.
Fox News. "Endangered Fish Policy May Have Cost
Firefighters' Lives." 1 August 2001. Online document available
at www.foxnews.com/story/0,2922,31019,00.html.
Gane, M., ed. "Martin Faustmann and the Evolution of
Discounted Cash Flow: Two Articles from the Original German of
1849," trans. W. Linnard. Commonwealth Forestry Institute,
University of Oxford, Institute Paper 42, 1968.
Government Accounting Office. Endangered Species Act: Information
on Species Protection on Nonfederal Lands. GAO/RCED-95-16, Washington,
DC, 1995.
Hyde, W. F. Timber Supply, Land Allocation and Economic Efficiency.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1980.
--. "Marginal Costs of Managing Endangered Species: The Case
of the Red-Cockaded Woodpecker." Journal of Agricultural Economic
Research, 41(2), 1989, 12-19.
Innes, R. "Takings, Compensation and Equal Treatment of Owners
of Developed and Undeveloped Property." Journal o fLaw and
Economics, 40(2), 1997, 403-32.
Kulhavy, D. L., R. G. Hooper, and R. Costa. Red-Cockaded
Woodpecker: Recovery, Ecology, and Management. Nacogdoches, TX: Stephen
F. Austin State University Press, 1995.
Lueck, D., and J. Michael. "Preemptive Habitat Destruction under the Endangered Species Act." Journal of Law and Economics,
46, 2003.
Mann C. C., and M. L. Plummer. Noah's Choice: The Future of
Endangered Species. New York: Knopf, 1995.
Meyers, S. P., W. Flick, and R. Meldahl. "The Economics of
Private Forestry: The Opportunity Cost of the Red-Cockaded Woodpecker
Management," in Proceeding of the 26th Annual Southern Forest
Economics Workshop, edited by J. Caulfield and S. Bullard. Mississippi
State University, 1996.
Polasky, S., and H. Doremus. "When the Truth Hurts: Endangered
Species Policy on Private Land with Imperfect Information." Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management, 35(1), 1998, 22-47.
Roise, J. P., J. Chung, R. Lancia, and M. Lennartz.
"Red-Cockaded Woodpecker Habitat and Timber Management Production
Possibilities." Southern Journal of Applied Forestry, 14(1), 1990,
6-12.
Salant, P., and D. A. Dillman. How to Conduct Your Own Survey. New
York: Wiley, 1994.
Smith, W. B., J. S. Vissage, D. R. Darr, and R. M. Sheffield.
Forest Resources of the United States, 1997. General Technical Report
NC-219, St. Paul, MN, U.S. Forest Service North Central Research
Station, 2001.
Souder, J. A. "Chasing Armadillos down Yellow Lines: Economics
in the Endangered Species Act." Natural Resources Journal, 33,
1995, 1096-139.
Stroup, R. L. The Endangered Species Act: Making Innocent Species
the Enemy. Policy Series PS-3. Bozeman, MT: Political Economy Research
Center. 1995.
--. "The Economics of Compensating Property Owners."
Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 1996, 55-65.
Timber-Mart South. Quarterly Report of the Market Prices for Timber
Products of the South. Athens, GA: Warnell School of Forest Resources,
University of Georgia, 1999.
U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service. Red-Cockaded Woodpecker Procedures
Manual for Private Lands. Released with a cover letter by John R. Eadie,
Acting Regional Director, Fish and Wildlife Service, Atlanta, GA, 1992.
Warren-Boulton, F. "Vertical Control by Labor Unions."
American Economic Review, 67(3), 1977, 309-22.
Yandle, B. The Political Limits of Environmental Regulation:
Tacking the Unicorn. New York: Quorum Books, 1989.
Zhang, D. "Endangered Species Conservation on Private Lands:
Some New Initiatives." Forest Landowner, 58(3), 1999, 12-15.
--. "Faustmann in an Uncertain Policy Environment."
Forest Policy and Economics, 2, 2001, 203-10.
Zhang, D., and W. Flick. "Sticks, Carrots, and Reforestation
Investment." Land Economics, 77(3), 2001,443-56.
Zhang, D., and P. H. Pearse. "Differences in Silvicultural
Investment under Various Types of Forest Tenure in British
Columbia." Forest Science, 44 (4), 1996, 442-49.
--. "The Influence of the Form of Tenure on Reforestation in
British Columbia." Forest Ecology and Management, 98, 1997, 239-50.
DAOWEI ZHANG, This research is funded in part by USDA National
Research Initiative Competitive Grant # 96-354400-3749. I thank Ralph
Costa and Sayeed Mehmood for their help in data collection and David
Laband, Roger Brown, Robert Ekelund, Warren Flick, Changyou Sun, and two
anonymous referees and the editor of this journal for their comments on
an earlier version of this article. All remaining errors, of course, are
my own.
Zhang: Professor, School of Forestry and Wildlife Sciences. Auburn
University, Auburn, AL 368495418. Phone 1-334-844-1067, Fax
1-334-826-0374, E-mail zhangdw@auburn.edu