The value of life: estimates with risks by occupation and industry.
Viscusi, W. Kip
I. INTRODUCTION
Economic values of a statistical life are now part of generally
accepted economic methodology. The theoretical foundations dating back
to Adam Smith's (1776) theory of compensating differentials are
widely accepted. For roughly a quarter century, economists have
developed empirical estimates of the trade-off between wages and
fatality risks, which continue to dominate the value-of-life literature.
The magnitude of the value-of-life estimates is of considerable
policy importance as well. For the past two decades, U.S. federal
agencies have used labor market estimates of the value of statistical
life to assess the benefits of health, safety, and environmental
regulations. These benefit values are critical inputs to the policy
because the benefits from reducing risks to life are often the dominant
benefit component, and the magnitude of these benefits is consequential given the increased reliance on benefit-cost tests for policy
assessment.
Notwithstanding the widespread use of value-of-life estimates,
empirical estimates of the value of life remain an object of
considerable controversy. A prominent area of concern stems from the
nature of the job risk variable used in the wage equation. Ideally, one
would want a measure of the worker's subjective assessment of the
fatality risk, (1) or at the very least an objective risk measure that
captures the variation in risk by both occupation and industry. Most
studies in the literature use a measure of industry death risks; the
remainder use a measure of occupational fatality risks. This procedure,
which is employed in studies using data from the United States as well
as other countries, (2) consequently never incorporates the variation in
job risks by both occupation and industry.
These deficiencies in the job risk variable create four potentially
serious problems. First, failure to recognize the variation in job risks
by occupation and industry creates a familiar situation of errors in
variables. However, there is no a priori reason to assume that the
measurement error is random so that the direction of the bias in the
value-of-life estimates in not known. (3)
Second, because the industry-based job risk variable is not
pertinent to workers in relatively safe positions, full-sample estimates
often fail to yield significant estimates of wage premiums for risk.
Researchers have attempted to cope with this problem by restricting the
wage equation estimates to blue-collar workers or male blue-collar
workers. That approach may yield significant fatality risk coefficients,
but the empirical magnitudes are biased. The job risk variable is
calculated based on the total fatalities in the industry divided by
total employment in the industry. If all fatalities are incurred by
blue-collar workers or blue-collar male workers, use of the total
employment denominator will lead to an understatement of the
worker's job risk for the blue-collar subsample used for the
analysis, biasing the estimated job risk coefficient upward.
A third consequence of the job risk data shortcomings has been the
failure of most studies to capture the influence of nonfatal job risks
and workers' compensation on worker wages. There are only two
studies that have included a measure of workers' compensation
benefits and nonfatal job risks in a wage equation estimating
wage-fatality risk trade-offs. [See Moore and Viscusi (1990) and
Kniesner and Leeth (1991).] The main practical consequence is that
observed wage premiums for fatality risks may also be capturing the
influence of these two omitted risk-related variables rather than being
a measure of the trade-off between wages and fatality risk alone.
A fourth limitation of studies using existing job risk data stems
from the construction of the risk variable. In the absence of
information on the worker's own job risk, researchers have matched
job risk data by occupation or industry to the worker based on the
worker's reported job. All workers in the same industry or
occupational group receive the same value for the job risk variable; as
a consequence, the estimated residuals will be correlated and standard
errors will be underestimated. This article is the first study of
estimates of the value of life that explicitly accounts for this aspect
of the fatality risk variable.
This analysis uses job fatality data by industry and occupation to
construct a fatality risk variable that will make it possible to obtain
more refined estimates of the value of life. Section II describes the
mortality risk data and how the fatality frequencies were constructed
for this article. After reviewing the hedonic wage model approach in
section III, I report estimates based on occupation and industry risk in
section IV and compare these to industry-level risk results using the
same data in section V. These estimates show significant premiums for
job fatality risks for a wide range of specifications and subsamples,
including both male and female workers. The concluding section VI
summarizes the differences arising from the aggregation of the fatality
risk variable by occupation and industry, which can affect the estimates
of the value of life by a factor of two.
II. FATALITY RISKS BY OCCUPATION AND INDUSTRY
The critical input to sound estimation of wage-fatality risk
trade-offs is to have an accurate measure of the risk of the
worker's job. The health and safety risk lottery associated with a
job consists of various adverse health outcomes and their associated
probabilities. Based on the constraints of available data, the analysis
here focuses on the risks of fatality and injuries severe enough to lead
to the loss of at least a day of work. The primary risk variable of
interest will be the probability of death associated with the job. The
analysis will also control for the job's probability of injury and
expected workers' compensation benefits to distinguish the
influence of fatality risk from other hazards on the job.
The two main approaches to establishing values for the fatality
risk variable have been to use measures of occupational risk, ignoring
variations by industry, and measures of industry risk, ignoring
variations by occupation. Many early studies used the occupational risk
approach, but the greater availability of detailed industry risk
measures has contributed to the greater reliance on industry risk
variables. Some
early studies of the value of life, such as Thaler and Rosen (1976)
and Brown (1980), used occupational risk measures based on data from the
Society of Actuaries. These risk estimates were for overall mortality of
people in different occupations, as opposed to the mortality risk
specifically attributable to job exposures. The variable also did not
capture differences in occupational risks across industries. Estimates
generated using these data tended to yield comparatively low values of
life (in year 2000 dollars) of $1.1 million for Thaler and Rosen (1976)
and $2.1 million for Brown (1980). The average worker risk levels
implied by these data were 0.001, so that the comparatively low values
of life are consistent with workers who are more willing to bear risk
self-selecting themselves into high-risk jobs.
Most studies in the literature have relied on industry-based
fatality data. The first set of industry data used was that developed by
the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Researchers match objective
death risk measures to workers based on their broad industry group SIC
code. Both the BLS and the Society of Actuaries data used in these
studies are measured at the one-digit or two-digit-SIC level, so there
are usually no more than 30 different values that the death risk
variable has for a given sample. Two early studies using BLS data are by
Smith (1976) and Viscusi (1979), who found implicit values of life of
$6.6 million and $5.9 million, respectively (year 2000 $). The average
risk levels for these studies of 0.0001 was an order of magnitude smaller than that using the actuarial occupational risk.
A second, more recent set of industry fatality risk data is that
generated by the National Institute of Occupational Safety and
Health's National Traumatic Occupational Fatality Project (NTOF).
Unlike the BLS data that used a partial sample to project death risks,
these data are based on a census of all occupational fatalities using
information reported on death certificates. However, notwithstanding the
data's designation as pertaining to "occupational"
fatalities, the data used in past studies have only been by industry and
state, not occupation. Using these fatality data where the industry
level of aggregation is at the one-digit SIC level, Moore and Viscusi
(1990) estimated an average value of life of $10.4 million (year 2000
$), where the worker's average risk level was 0.0001. To the extent
that the BLS measure has more random measurement error than does the
NTOF data, one would have expected that the estimated values of life
would be greater with the NTOF data than with the BLS data. (4) That was
in fact the case, as the value-of-life estimate using the BLS risk
measure was $3.6 million (year 2000 $) based on a direct comparison of
the results using the same underlying employment data.
The fatal injury data that provides the basis for the mortality
risk measure used here is the U.S. BLS Census of Fatal Occupational
Injuries (CFOI) (available on CD-ROM from the BLS). The BLS has gathered
the CFOI mortality data since 1992, and these statistics are the most
comprehensive tallies of occupational deaths available. The sources of
information for the mortality data include death certificates,
workers' compensation reports, medical examiner reports, and
reports by the Occupational Safety and Health Administration. The agency
uses source documents and follow-up questionnaires to ensure that the
deaths are work-related. The number of deaths based on these data was
6238 in 1997. By way of comparison, the BLS reported only 3750
occupational fatalities in 1984, and the NTOF measure recorded 6901
average annual fatalities for 1980-84 (See Moore and Viscusi [1990],
73.). The key time period for analysis in this article will be 1997,
which is the year of individual employment data that will be matched to
the job risk estimates.
Though the BLS reports the total number of fatalities for different
categories of workers, it does not calculate the fatality rate for
occupational industry groups. The incidence rate of fatalities is the
ratio of the fatalities in any occupation-industry group to that
group's employment in that time period. In calculating the
incidence rate for these different cells, I divided occupation-industry
groups into 720 possible categories consisting of 72 two-digit SIC code
industries by 10 one-digit occupational groups. The employment data are
based on BLS estimates for that category. (5) Some occupation-industry
cells were not viable, because there were no reported employment levels
for those cells. For the 1992-97 period, there were 13 such categories,
such as transportation employees in nondepository credit institutions.
In addition, my analysis excludes agricultural workers and those on
active duty in the armed forces.
Evidence presented in Mellow and Sider (1983) indicated that there
is measurement error in the reporting of the individual's industry
and occupation. These errors were greater for occupational categories
than for industries. For this reason, the death risk variable is
constructed based on occupational groups that are less narrowly defined
than the industry breakdowns, which should diminish this problem to some
extent.
Because fatalities are relatively rare events, two approaches were
used to construct the fatality risk data. First, fatality risk estimates
were constructed using 1997 fatality data, coupled with 1997 employment
data. Focusing on only a single year leads to 290 cells out of the 720
occupation-industry categories with no reported worker deaths. To reduce
this problem, I constructed a second fatality risk measure based on an
average of fatalities for each group from 1992 to 1997. Using this
six-year average of deaths for each occupation-industry cell leads to a
more precise measure of the underlying fatality risk. This approach
reduces the number of occupation-industry cells with zero fatality risk
from 290 to 90. This averaging process is likely to be consistent with
the overall riskiness of jobs in 1997, as there were 6217 worker
fatalities in 1992, which is just below the level of 6238 in 1997. (6)
Thus there were no major trends in fatality rates during this period
that are likely to distort the measure of job riskiness.
The overall fatality rate implied by the CFOI data was 0.00004. By
way of comparison, the fatality rate for most previous studies using
industry fatality data historically has been approximately 0.0001, but
some more recent studies report lower risks that nevertheless are a bit
higher than these CFOI estimates. (7) A somewhat lower risk level is to
be expected for the recent period covered by the CFOI data because of
the decreased incidence of occupational fatalities over the past quarter
century during which labor market value-of-life estimates have been
generated. There are also differences in reporting and mortality
attribution that may enter.
Table 1 presents a grid of the mortality risk probabilities, where
panel A presents the results using 1997 fatality data and panel B is
based on average fatalities from 1992 to 1997. The ten different
occupational groups make up the rows of Table 1. This listing
consequently reflects the complete level of occupational aggregation
used in constructing the fatality risk measure. To make the industry
groups a more manageable size for summarizing in this table, the 72
industry groups have been collapsed into 9 major categories. The risk
estimates for panel A and panel B are reasonably similar. The most
noteworthy difference is the presence of five occupation-industry
categories with zero risk in panel A, whereas there are no such
categories in panel B. Overall average risks by industry and occupation
are of fairly comparable magnitude even though the component risks
differ to a greater extent.
The importance of analyzing risk variations by both occupation and
industry is apparent from the patterns in Table 1. Consider the
implications of the longer-term fatality estimates in panel B. The
fatality risks by industry, which have been the principal reference
points for previous studies, vary from 1.36 per 100,000 workers for
finance, insurance, and real estate to 25.99 per 100,000 workers for
mining. In every instance, including the lower-risk industry groups,
there is considerable heterogeneity in the risks by occupation.
Administrative support occupations are always the lowest risk, with an
annual fatality rate ranging from 0.44 per 100,000 workers for finance,
insurance, and real estate to 1.41 per 100,000 workers for
transportation and public utilities. However, even within the safest
industry groups, such as services and public administration, there are
substantial mortality risks exceeding 10 per 100,000 employees for
occupational categories such as transportation and material moving
occupations and handlers, equipment cleaners, helpers, and laborers. The
greatest occupational variations in riskiness occur in the most
dangerous industries, as the fatality risks vary by almost two orders of
magnitude for different mining occupations. The empirical estimates to
follow will capture the substantial variation in risk associated with
workers' jobs across both occupation and industry.
III. THE HEDONIC WAGE EQUATIONS
The empirical framework used for estimation will be based on the
standard hedonic wage framework and, as a consequence, will only be
summarized briefly. (8) The outer envelope of the individual firm curves
for wages as a function of job risk comprises the market opportunities
curve. Workers, who would rather be healthy than not, select their most
preferred wage-job risk combination from the market opportunities curve.
The resulting estimates of the wage-risk locus traces out the average
pattern of these market decisions but does not have a structural
interpretation in terms of either demand or supply influences
individually.
The hedonic wage equations that I estimate will be of the standard
semi-logarithmic form:
(1) 1n([Wage.sub.i]) = [X.sub.i][beta] + [[gamma].sub.i] [Death
Risk.sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.2] [Injury Risk.sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.3]
[Injury Risk.sub.i] x [Replacement Rate.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i],
where [Wage.sub.i] is worker i's hourly wage rate, [X.sub.i]
is a vector of personal characteristics and job characteristics for
worker i, the Death [Risk.sub.i] variable is matched to the worker based
on worker i's occupation and industry, [Injury Risk.sub.i] is the
lost workday injury and illness rate for worker i's industry, (9)
and [Injury Risk.sub.i] x [Replacement Rate.sub.i] is the worker's
expected workers' compensation replacement rate. A simple linear
wage equation will also be estimated.
The variables included have several distinctive features. The CFOI
death risk will be included by occupation-industry group and, in
separate regressions, by industry alone, making it possible to examine
the effect of abstracting from occupational differences. To the extent
that measurement error is random, one would expect that recognition of
occupational differences would boost the estimated value of a
statistical life given by [delta]Wage/[delta]Death Risk (converted to an
annual basis) and also shrink the standard errors. Though section V will
report estimates aggregating fatality risks by industry, my efforts to
derive similar estimates with the job risk variable based solely on the
worker's occupation, excluding industry differences, failed to
yield stable results. The fatality risk variable in these equations
often yielded insignificant effects of varying sign. The weak
performance of fatality risks based solely on occupation possibly arose
because of the relatively high degree of aggregation by occupation type
for the job risk measure.
The equation also includes a measure of workers' compensation
benefits so that the results will control for these insurance payments.
The particular measure used is the expected workers' compensation
replacement rate. Thus the lost workday injury and illness rate is
interacted with the level of workers' compensation benefits for
that particular worker, divided by the worker's wage rate. Thus, if
the injury risk for the worker is zero, this variable drops out of the
analysis. The expected workers' compensation replacement rate is
given by
(2) Expected WC Replacement Rate = [Lost Workday Rate.sub.i] x
[Benefit Rate.sub.i] x [Wage.sub.i] (Adjusted for min, max) /(1 -
[t.sub.i]) [Wage.sub.i],
where [t.sub.i] is the average state and federal tax on the
worker's wages. (10)
The workers' compensation benefit amount is given by the
worker's weekly earnings (or spendable weekly earnings depending on
the state) multiplied by the state's benefit rate. The particular
benefits category used was that for temporary total disability. This
benefit category comprises about three-fourths of workers'
compensation claims. Permanent partial disability formulas are typically
almost identical except for differences in benefit duration that are not
captured in the measure used here. Though the benefit measure is not
free of error, it should be highly positively correlated with the
expected benefits from workers' compensation.
The workers' compensation variable is also distinctive from
almost all previous measures used in the literature in that it is
calculated on an individual worker basis using state benefit formulas
coupled with information on the individual worker rather than being
based on a statewide average. (11) Benefit levels were adjusted to
reflect state minimum and maximum allowed benefits. Because of the
favorable tax treatment accorded to workers' compensation benefits,
these benefit levels were inflated to reflect the fact that there are
state and federal taxes on wages but not on workers' compensation
benefits, leading to the (1 - [t.sub.i]) adjustment in the denominator.
Thus both wages and the expected workers' compensation replacement
rate are in comparable tax terms.
The expected replacement rate is a function of the worker's
wage rate when the benefit minimum and maximum values are binding. (12)
Thus it is potentially endogenous. Tests using instrumental variable
estimators for the expected replacement rate yielded statistically
significant instruments. The compensating differential estimates also
were very similar to those generated with ordinary least squares (OLS).
Pertinent Hausman tests implied that one could not reject the hypothesis
that the expected workers' compensation rate was not endogenous.
(13)
The death risk variable is distinctive in that it varies by
occupation and industry, but all workers in the same industry and
occupation category receive the same value for the death risk.
Similarly, the injury rate variable only varies by industry. The first
set of reported standard errors will be the White
heteroscedasticity-adjusted standard errors. This correction adjusts for
the fact that the error term [epsilon.sub.i] may have different values
by industry or occupation. In addition to adjusting for this group
heteroscedasticity, I also adjust for the influence of clustering as,
for example, workers in the same occupation-industry group may have
correlated residuals. Neglect of this clustering often leads to
underestimation of the standard errors. The robust and clustered
standard errors that are reported adjust for the within-group
correlation for the occupation-industry cells for the results in section
IV and for the correlations within the industry-based cells for the
results reported in section V. (14) To date, the only studies in the
hedonic wage risk literature that have made this adjustment have been
analyses of the implicit value of nonfatal job injuries by Hersch (1998)
and Viscusi and Hersch (2001). By failing to make this adjustment,
previous studies of the value of statistical life consequently may have
over-stated the statistical significance of the value-of-life estimates
by failing to account for this clustering.
The labor market data set to which the risk variables are merged
for this empirical analysis is the 1997 CPS merged outgoing rotation
group. The workers retained in the sample used for this study are
nonagricultural workers who are not in the armed forces. All regression runs focus on full-time workers (usual hours at least 35) age 18 to 65.
The hourly wage was calculated as weekly earnings divided by usual
weekly hours. (15) Workers whose wage was below the statutory minimum
wage of $4.75 (the minimum wage until September 1997) were excluded from
the sample. The principal worker background variables included in the
analysis were worker age, gender, dummy variables for racial groups
(black, Native American, Asian, Hispanic), being married, and education
in years. (16) The job characteristic variables in addition to those
related to risk were whether the worker was a union member or under a
union contract, was employed in public rather than private industry, and
a series of nine occupational dummy variables for the full-sample
results and four such variables for the blue-collar-sample results. Each
equation also included eight regional dummy variables as well as a
variable for whether the respondent lived in a standard metropolitan
statistical area.
Hersch's (1998) analysis of wage premiums for job injuries
indicated that it was more appropriate to estimate separate wage
equations for men and women. Not only does the influence of human
capital variables vary by gender, but preferences with respect to job
risks may differ as well. Whereas many previous studies found that only
blue-collar males received significant job risk premiums, Hersch (1998)
found significant positive premiums for females but not for males as a
group, though she did find effects for male blue-collar workers.
Pertinent F tests for the equations presented here indicate that pooling
males and females and allowing only for separate intercepts by gender is
not appropriate. (17) Although the discussion will report full-sample
findings including a female dummy variable to provide comparability with
much of the literature I will also report separate equations by gender.
IV. VALUE-OF-LIFE ESTIMATES: FATALITY RISKS BY OCCUPATION AND
INDUSTRY
The empirical analysis will consider a series of different
equations for five alternative samples of respondents: the full sample,
males, females, blue-collar males, and blue-collar females. The variants
to be considered will explore the robustness of the results with respect
to different specifications, many of which have proven to be problematic
in previous studies.
Table 2 reports representative 1n(Wage) equations for the full
sample, blue-collar males, and blue-collar females. Restricting the
sample to blue-collar male workers has been a common practice in past
studies because the industry death risk data were poor measures of the
risk in white-collar jobs, leading to insignificant wage premiums for
death risks in many studies. However, Hersch (1998) found that females
did in fact receive significant compensating differentials for nonfatal
risk measures. Whereas Hersch (1998) calculated gender-specific injury
risks, this article uses the same fatality risk measure for men and
women. The risk measures do, however, control for differences in
occupation and industry, which should account for most gender-related
variations in riskiness.
The nonrisk variable coefficients in Table 2 follow the expected
patterns, as wages increase with age but at a diminishing rate, are
lower for minorities and females, are higher for better educated
workers, and are higher for union members. The magnitudes of the effects
are also comparable to those in the literature, as one would expect from
a conventional wage equation with a widely used data set.
The death risk variable has a positive effect on wages, consistent
with the theory of compensating differentials. In all three samples
reported in Table 2, the death risk coefficients are statistically
significant at the 99% level, two-tailed test, based on the
heteroscedasticity-adjusted standard errors. However, the estimates
adjusted also for clustering have larger standard errors. Significance
levels remain at the 99% level for blue-collar males and blue-collar
females, but drop to the 90% level (two-tailed test) or 95% level
(one-tailed test) for the full sample. Higher job risks should
unambiguously raise wages, so a one-tailed test is warranted in this
instance. It is also the commonly used threshold in many previous
studies that included less demanding tests that never adjusted for
clustering and, in most instances, did not include a nonfatal job risk
variable. Moreover, as additional specifications summarized in Table 3
indicate, in instances in which the death risk variable is the only job
risk variable included in the full-sample equation, as in most previous
studies, the death risk coefficient is statistically significant at the
99% level even with the clustered standard errors. The lost workday
injury and illness variable and the expected workers' compensation
replacement rate also are strongly significant with the hypothesized
sign.
The general magnitude of the premiums is plausible. Evaluated at
the mean values of the variables, death risks raise worker wages by an
average of $0.095 per hour for the full sample, $0.324 per hour for
blue-collar males, and $0.123 an hour for blue-collar females. On an
annual basis, assuming 2000 hours worked per year, these levels of
compensation are $190 for the full sample, $648 for blue-collar males,
and $246 for blue-collar females. These values are for fatality risks
controlling for nonfatal job injury risk and workers' compensation
benefits.
The lost workday injury and illness variable commands a significant
wage premium as well, in addition to the premiums for mortality risk. At
the mean risk level, the nonfatal job risk accounts for $0.151 in higher
wages per hour for the full sample, $0.251 for the blue-collar male
subsample, and $0.534 for the blue-collar female sample. On an annual
basis, this contribution is $302 for the full sample, $502 for the
blue-collar male sample, and $1068 for the blue-collar female sample.
Total premiums for fatal and nonfatal job risks consequently are $492
for the full sample, $1150 for blue-collar male workers, and $1314 for
blue-collar female workers.
The final risk variable is the expected workers' compensation
replacement rate, which has a significant negative effect on wages. As
with the few previous studies that have included a workers'
compensation variable in a wage equation estimating the value of life,
there is a wage offset that workers are willing to incur in return for
insurance coverage of the income loss associated with hazardous jobs.
(18) This result is also consistent with the theory of compensating
differentials.
As is shown in Moore and Viscusi (1990, 39), if the insurance
loading parameter is h, p is the risk of job injury, w is the wage rate,
and b is the benefit level, the optimal level of workers'
compensation benefits satisfies
(3) dw/db = -ph/(1 - p).
If there were no administrative costs, the trade-off rate would be
p/(1 -p). Thus, with actuarially fair insurance, it is optimal to accept
lower wages in response to higher benefits so that the trade-off rate is
p/(1 - p), which is simply the odds of being injured divided by the
probability of no injury. In insurance contexts this ratio often is
viewed as a measure of the price of insurance, and it emerges as an
implication of actuarially fair insurance pricing. (19)
On a theoretical basis the wage offset workers are willing to
accept in return for an additional dollar of insurance benefits is given
by (Injury Rate)/(1 - Injury Rate), which for this sample is 0.032 for
the full sample, 0.043 for blue-collar males, and 0.037 for blue-collar
females. With a rate of insurance loading h of approximately 1.25, (20)
the wage offset for an additional dollar of benefits should be h(Injury
Rate)/(1 - Injury Rate), which is 0.040 for the full sample, 0.054 for
blue-collar males, and 0.046 for blue-collar females. The actual wage
effect for an additional dollar of weekly workers' compensation
benefits implied by the results in Table 2 is -0.032 for the full
sample, -0.034 for blue-collar males, and -0.015 for blue-collar
females. The marginal wage offset falls short of the wage reduction that
would imply an optimal level of benefits. Taken at face value, these
estimates would imply that the level of workers' compensation
benefits is above the efficient insurance amount. Moore and Viscusi
(1990) found a somewhat higher rate of trade-off, implying that
workers' compensation was more than self-financing. (21) However,
those results reflect a different era of workers' compensation.
Beginning in the late 1980s, many states enacted reforms that altered
the structure of benefits and also reduced workers' compensation
costs from $31 billion in premiums written in 1990 to $22 billion in
1999. (22)
Table 3 summarizes the risk coefficients from a series of
specifications using alternative fatality risk measures. Other variables
included in the analysis are the same as in Table 2. The implicit value
of life based on equation (1) is
(4) Implicit Value of Life = [delta]Wage/[delta]Death Rate =
Wage[[gamma].sub.1]. (23)
The first row reports coefficients from the full sample in Table 2.
The implied value of life based on these estimates is $4.7 million. The
value-of-life estimates are net of the value of income support provided
through workers' compensation so that the value of fatal injuries
would be greater in the absence of social insurance. Similarly, the
implicit value of a job injury is $9570 for the full sample and $12,226
for blue-collar males. These estimates fall near the low end of the
range of estimates of the implicit value of injury in the literature.
(24) However, most of these studies of nonfatal risk premiums omitted
the fatality risk variable from the wage equation, thus boosting the
estimated injury coefficient.
The second row of full sample estimates in panel A of Table 3 omits
the two nonfatal risk variables and includes only the fatality rate.
Doing so boosts the estimated value of life to $8.9 million. (25) This
equation is more comparable to that used in previous studies in that the
only job risk variable included pertains to fatalities.
The second set of results in panel A of Table 3 parallels those in
the upper part of the table except that the fatality risk variable is
based solely on fatalities that occurred in 1997. The subsequent
imprecision in the risk variable will lead to lower estimated values of
life if the error in the variable is random. The consequence is somewhat
lower estimated coefficients for fatality risk, thus reducing the
estimated value of life.
Panel B in Table 3 reports estimates for which the worker's
wage is the dependent variable rather than its natural log. The
value-of-life estimates for the full sample are $2.6 million with the
full set of risk variables and $7.8 million when only the fatality risk
is included.
For each of these sets of results, Table 3 also includes comparable
estimates for various male and female subsamples. Males as a group have
estimated implicit values of life ranging from $2.7 million to $4.9
million for equations including injury variables, and $6.3 million to
$9.1 million for the fatality risk only specification. However, these
estimates are sometimes not statistically significant at the 95% level
based on the robust and clustered standard errors.
The estimates for blue-collar males are of particular interest
because these are the first estimates for such a subsample in which the
job risk variable has been constructed to be pertinent to blue-collar
workers rather than being a measure of overall industry risk for all
workers. The results for blue-collar males are consistently significant
at the 99% level, and they yield higher estimated values of life.
Estimates for the blue-collar male subsample reported in Table 3 range
from $4.9 million to $7.0 million for equations including all
risk-related variables. With only the fatality risk variable included,
the implicit values of life for the blue-collar male samples range from
$7.8 million to $9.7 million.
Somewhat surprisingly, the implicit value of life estimates are
more evident for blue-collar males than the full sample of males even
though the risk measures reflect both the worker's occupation and
industry. On a theoretical basis, more affluent workers should exhibit
higher wage-risk trade-offs, but empirically it may be that workers in
risky white-collar jobs are less productive or have other
characteristics that make it difficult to disentangle such effects.
Estimates for the white-collar male subsample, which are not reported,
yield negative coefficients for the fatality risk variable. Because
these estimates focus on only male workers, gender differences do not
account for the effect. Moreover, the implicit values of lost workday
job injuries for the full male sample are only marginally greater than
the values for the blue-collar male subsample, whereas one might have
expected greater valuations. Both the fatality risk variable and the
lost workday risk variable generate results that reflect a similar
departure from theoretical predictions in this regard.
Estimates for the female subsamples are remarkably similar to those
for the males. The full sample females results do not yield positive and
statistically significant premiums for fatality risks, but there are
significant premiums for lost workday injuries, as in Hersch (1998).
Because few white-collar females are exposed to fatality risks, the
blue-collar female results are more instructive. In every instance,
blue-collar females exhibit positive and significant premiums for fatal
and nonfatal risks of the job. Interestingly, the point estimates of the
magnitudes of the wage-risk trade-offs are higher for female blue-collar
workers than their male counterparts, as is evidenced by the somewhat
higher implicit values of life and implicit values of injury for the
blue-collar females. For the equations including all three risk-related
variables, female blue-collar workers have implicit values of life
ranging from $7.0 million to $12.2 million; with the injury-related
variables excluded, the estimates range from $8.8 million to $15.5
million. The degree to which females exhibit a higher implicit value for
lost workday injuries, as compared to their male blue-collar
counterparts, is even greater than the implicit value of life disparity.
V. VALUE-OF-LIFE ESTIMATES: FATALITY RISKS BY INDUSTRY
To provide a comparable reference point for the consequences of
moving from an industry level of aggregation for fatality risk data to
data that are available by both occupation and industry, I will use the
same CPS data set except that the fatality risk measure will not be
permitted to vary by occupation. Thus the job risk measure will be
comparable to the marginal values along the bottom row in the panels in
Table 1 except that the level of aggregation is for 72 industries rather
than only 9 industries.
The value-of-life estimates by occupation and industry provide a
more precise match to the actual risk of a worker's job than if
only the influence of the worker's industry was considered. Using
the CFOI data taking into account only the worker's industry makes
it possible to examine the incremental effect of considering
occupational variations in job riskiness. If the errors-in-variables
problem arising from moving to the industry level of aggregation
involves random errors, the industry-based value-of-life estimates
should be lower. The results do not indicate such a relationship,
implying that taking into account occupational differences may have
important systematic effects as well.
Table 4 summarizes empirical estimates that follow the same
structure as did those in Table 3 except for the use of the
industry-based fatality rate. Here the clustered standard errors reflect
clustering only by industry rather than by industry and occupation. The
estimated value of life for the full sample with all the risk variables
included is $10.0 million with the log wage equation and $8.3 million
with the wage equation. If the nonfatal risk and workers'
compensation variables are omitted, these values rise to $14.5 million
for log wage and $13.7 million for the wage equation. Thus these
estimates are greater than those generated by fatality risks by
occupation and industry.
Because the industry-based measure excludes occupational
differences, one might have expected the results for the overall male
and female samples to be less consistently significant. However, the
fatality risk coefficients in Table 4 display higher levels of
statistical significance for most of the male sample results as well as
positive effects that are often significant for the female sample, where
levels of significance vary depending on the type of standard error. In
contrast, the statistical significance of the results in Table 4 for
blue-collar females is consistently lower with the industry-based
measure. Recognition of occupational differences in job risks is most
pertinent to the context in which female workers are exposed to fatality
risks, which is blue-collar jobs.
Estimated values of life for the full equation for blue-collar
males are $9.3 million (semi-logarithmic form) and $8.6 million (linear
wage equation). Including only the fatality risk measure of the three
risk-related variables boosts the value of life to $12.7 million and
$12.6 million, respectively. The comparable estimates for female
blue-collar workers for the full equation are $6.7 million
(semi-logarithmic form) and $11.5 million (linear form). Restricting the
risk variable to only the fatality risk variable leads to values of
$12.8 million and $18.8 million for these two sets of results.
The lower portions of panels A and B of Table 4 report the results
including only fatalities from 1997 in the fatality rate variable. These
estimates yield very similar estimates of the value of life compared to
the results for which the risk variable is calculated using fatalities
from 1992 to 1997.
VI. CONCLUSION
Estimates of the value of life vary considerably once differences
in occupational risk within industry are recognized. For the full sample
log wage equations, the value of life is $4.7 million (or $5.0 million
in year 2000 dollars) based on occupation and industry risk and $10.0
million (or $10.7 million in year 2000 dollars) based solely on industry
risk. Blue-collar males have higher values in each instance, of $7.0
million (or $7.5 million in year 2000 dollars) for occupation-industry
risks and $9.3 million (or $10.0 million in year 2000 dollars) for
industry risks. Blue-collar females likewise receive significant
premiums for fatality risk, with a value of life of $8.5 million (or
$9.1 million in year 2000 dollars) for occupation-industry risks and
$6.7 million (or $7.2 million in year 2000 dollars) for industry risks.
The measurement error due to industry level aggregation does not
appear to be random. The value-of-life estimates tend to be reduced by
recognizing occupational variations in job riskiness. Estimating the
value of life using only CFOI data by worker industry roughly doubles
the estimated value of life for the full sample, implying that the
errors arising from occupational aggregation are not the classical
random errors.
The occupation-industry risk variable proved to be especially
influential in making it possible to estimate significant fatality risk
coefficients for female blue-collar workers. Previous studies have often
restricted the sample to male blue-collar workers, with a notable
exception being the analysis of nonfatal injuries by Hersch (1998). More
refined risk measures yield significant fatality risk premiums for women
as well as men, where the magnitude of the wage-risk trade-offs are
comparable.
However, notwithstanding the greater refinement of the
occupational-industry risk measure, estimates for the full sample of
male workers and female workers did not perform as satisfactorily in two
respects. First, particularly for females, the fatality risk
coefficients had mixed signs and were not statistically significant.
Second, even for males, the wage-risk trade-offs for the full male
subsample were not higher than the implicit values for blue-collar
workers, whereas in theory workers self-selecting into blue-collar jobs
should have a lower value of life.
The additional refinement made possible by use of the CFOI
mortality data yields job risk measures more pertinent to the
worker's job and yielded more consistently significant
value-of-life estimates than in the previous literature. Results
remained statistically significant across different specifications of
the wage equations. These equations also included statistically
significant coefficients for both the nonfatal lost workday injury and
illness rate and the expected workers' compensation replacement
rate. Even with the inclusion of these variables, the fatality risk
variable remained statistically significant even when judged using
standard errors that recognize the effects of the clustering of the risk
measure at the occupation and industry level. What these results suggest
is that the lack of robustness of evidence of compensating differentials
for job risks may have stemmed in part from deficiencies in the job risk
measure rather than underlying shortcomings of the economic theory.
ABBREVIATIONS
BLS: Bureau of Labor Statistics
CFOI: Census of Fatal Occupational Injuries
CPS: Current Population Survey
NTOF: National Traumatic Occupational Fatality Project
TABLE 1
Incidence of Fatality by Major Occupation and Industry (Fatalities per
100,000 employees)
Industry
Major Occupation Group Mining Construction Manufacturing
A: Estimates using
fatalities, 1997
Executive, administrative, 4.35 6.12 1.73
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 11.76 3.16 0.98
occupations
Technicians and related 8.00 11.11 2.47
support occupations
Sales occupations 10.00 1.39 3.82
Administrative support 0.00 0.24 0.59
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 0.00 2.86 2.24
Precision production, 37.55 11.24 4.27
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 20.83 39.18 1.99
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 37.62 22.04 16.01
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 45.83 38.91 7.12
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 24.64 13.62 3.01
B: Estimates using average
fatalities, 1992-97
Executive. administrative, 5.80 4.89 1.84
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 6.86 2.64 1.20
occupations
Technicians and related 10.67 15.19 2.49
support occupations
Sales occupations 5.00 4.86 3.54
Administrative support 0.51 0.98 0.56
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 22.22 4.76 5.66
Precision production, 38.54 11.38 3.63
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 24.31 30.41 2.15
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 42.90 20.88 15.79
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 45.83 31.41 7.57
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 25.99 12.62 3.02
Industry
Transportation
& Public Wholesale Retail
Major Occupation Group Utilities Trade Trade
A: Estimates using
fatalities, 1997
Executive, administrative, 1.87 3.06 3.96
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 2.84 1.82 1.41
occupations
Technicians and related 17.06 4.17 0.00
support occupations
Sales occupations 2.11 2.39 3.57
Administrative support 1.31 0.81 0.61
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 4.00 5.45 1.49
Precision production, 7.80 6.44 3.58
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 8.27 10.53 1.52
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 32.72 16.73 12.17
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 13.56 8.91 2.65
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 11.51 4.83 3.00
B: Estimates using average
fatalities, 1992-97
Executive. administrative, 2.22 3.34 4.77
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 2.72 2.88 1.80
occupations
Technicians and related 21.03 3.82 0.87
support occupations
Sales occupations 2.23 3.26 3.87
Administrative support 1.41 0.63 0.59
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 6.06 5.45 1.69
Precision production, 7.48 7.82 3.11
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 6.64 9.90 1.43
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 28.82 14.97 11.86
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 12.93 10.09 3.60
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 10.75 5.19 3.29
Industry
Finance,
Insurance, & Public
Major Occupation Group Real Estate Services Administration
A: Estimates using
fatalities, 1997
Executive, administrative, 1.52 1.48 1.79
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 0.33 1.09 2.79
occupations
Technicians and related 1.32 2.01 5.41
support occupations
Sales occupations 1.15 1.24 3.13
Administrative support 0.40 0.39 0.69
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 4.56 1.59 11.73
Precision production, 3.98 5.06 11.05
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 0.00 1.53 8.00
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 0.00 13.27 27.66
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 7.41 12.40 26.47
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 1.19 1.66 5.40
B: Estimates using average
fatalities, 1992-97
Executive. administrative, 1.67 1.56 2.60
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 0.71 1.13 2.72
occupations
Technicians and related 0.77 1.74 7.88
support occupations
Sales occupations 1.45 2.11 2.60
Administrative support 0.44 0.47 0.97
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 5.21 1.90 11.26
Precision production, 3.13 5.43 11.58
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 4.17 2.33 14.67
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 10.61 12.02 25.89
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 12.35 10.40 42.65
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 1.36 1.76 5.72
Industry
Occupation
Major Occupation Group Total
A: Estimates using
fatalities, 1997
Executive, administrative, 2.22
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 1.26
occupations
Technicians and related 3.56
support occupations
Sales occupations 2.90
Administrative support 0.58
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 2.63
Precision production, 7.69
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 2.71
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 23.48
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 13.00
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 4.00
B: Estimates using average
fatalities, 1992-97
Executive. administrative, 2.38
and managerial occupations
Professional specialty 1.30
occupations
Technicians and related 3.92
support occupations
Sales occupations 3.30
Administrative support 0.66
occupations, including
clerical
Service occupations 2.92
Precision production, 7.59
craft, and repair
occupations
Machine operators, 2.81
assemblers, and inspectors
Transportation and 21.47
material moving
occupations
Handlers, equipment 12.02
cleaners, helpers, and
laborers
Industry total 4.02
TABLE 2
Regression Estimates for ln(Wage) Equations for Occupation-Industry
Death Risk Measure
Coefficients
(Robust SE)
[Robust and Clustered SE]
Blue-Collar Blue-Collar
Full Sample Male Sample Female Sample
Age 0.0417 0.0384 0.0274
(0.0007) (a) (0.0012) (a) (0.0018) (a)
[0.0016] (a) [0.0017] (a) [0.0030] (a)
Age squared -0.0432 -0.0396 -0.0296
(0.0009) (a) (0.0015) (a) (0.0022) (a)
[0.0020] (a) [0.0020] (a) [0.0034] (a)
Black -0.0960 -0.1164 -0.0714
(0.0040) (a) (0.0073) (a) (0.0092) (a)
[0.0069] (a) [0.0078] (a) [0.0103] (a)
Native American -0.0306 -0.0268 0.0012
(0.0116) (a) (0.0193) (0.0285)
[0.0137] (b) [0.0197] [0.0414]
Asian -0.0744 -0.1246 -0.0671
(0.0064) (a) (0.0132) (a) (0.0169) (a)
[0.0103] (a) [0.0169] (a) [0.0184] (a)
Hispanic -0.1050 -0.1373 -0.1294
(0.0045) (a) (0.0072) (a) (0.0118) (a)
[0.0081] (a) [0.0095] (a) [0.0151] (a)
Female -0.1453
(0.0026) (a)
[0.0110] (a)
Education 0.0469 0.0324 0.0436
(0.0007) (a) (0.0016) (a) (0.0027) (a)
[0.0024] (a) [0.0019] (a) [0.0029] (a)
Married 0.0115 0.0361 -0.0108
(0.0025) (a) (0.0046) (a) (0.0071)
[0.0045] (b) [0.0054] (a) [0.0086]
Union 0.1400 0.2022 0.1821
(0.0032) (a) (0.0048) (a) (0.0103) (a)
[0.0128] (a) [0.0102] (a) [0.0211] (a)
Death risk 0.0017 0.0027 0.0047
(0.0002) (a) (0.0003) (a) (0.0013) (a)
[0.0010] (c) [0.0007] (a) [0.0015] (a)
Injury and illness 0.2702 0.2300 0.1321
rate, lost workday (0.0025) (a) (0.0038) (a) (0.0108) (a)
cases [0.0157] (a) [0.0141] (a) [0.0172] (a)
Expected workers' -0.3811 -0.3173 -0.1584
compensation (0.0034) (a) (0.0050) (a) (0.0142) (a)
replacement rate [0.0212] (a) [0.0202] (a) [0.0236] (a)
[R.sup.2] 0.49 0.44 0.23
Observations 99,033 28,060 9902
(a) Indicates statistical significance at the 99% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(b) Indicates statistical significance at the 95% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(c) Indicates statistical significance at the 90% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
Notes. The full-sample equation also includes variables for public
employment, SMSA, nine occupational groups, eight regions, and a
constant term. The blue-collar male and blue-collar female equations
also include variables for public employment, SMSA, four occupational
groups, eight regions, and a constant term.
TABLE 3
Regression Results for Occupation-Industry Death Risk Measure
Coefficients
(Robust SE)
[Robust and Clustered SE]
Expected Workers'
Injury and Compensation
Death Risk Illness Rate Replacement Rate
A: ln(Wage)
equation results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0017 0.2702 -0.3811
(0.0002) (a) (0.0025) (a) (0.0034) (a)
[0.0010] (c) [0.0157] (a) [0.0212] (a)
0.0032
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0009] (a)
Male sample 0.0016 0.2626 -0.3797
(0.0003) (a) (0.0029) (a) (0.0040) (a)
[0.0008] (c) [0.0139] (a) [0.0194] (a)
0.0030
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0007] (a)
Female sample -0.0007 0.2851 -0.3899
(0.0008) (0.0047) (a) (0.0064) (a)
[0.0029] [0.0280] (a) [0.0367] (a)
0.0006
(0.0008) -- --
[0.0031]
Blue-collar 0.0027 0.2300 -0.3173
male sample (0.0003) (a) (0.0038) (a) (0.0050) (a)
[0.0007] (a) [0.0141] (a) [0.0202] (a)
0.0037
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0006] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0047 0.1321 -0.1584
female sample (0.0013) (a) (0.0108) (a) (0.0142) (a)
[0.0015] (a) [0.0172] (a) [0.0236] (a)
0.0061
(0.0014) (a) -- --
[0.0016] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0015 0.2704 -0.3813
(0.0002) (a) (0.0025) (a) (0.0034) (a)
[0.0008] (c) [0.0157] (a) [0.0212] (a)
0.0026
(0.0002) (a) -- --
[0.0007] (a)
Male sample 0.0014 0.2627 -0.3799
(0.0002) (a) (0.0029) (a) (0.0040) (a)
[0.0007] (b) [0.0139] (a) [0.0194] (a)
0.0024
(0.0002) (a) -- --
[0.0006] (a)
Female sample 0.0004 0.2849 -0.3899
(0.0007) (0.0047) (a) (0.0064) (a)
[0.0022] [0.0279] (a) [0.0367] (a)
0.0011
(0.0007) -- --
[0.0023]
Blue-collar 0.0022 0.2301 -0.3178
male sample (0.0002) (a) (0.0038) (a) (0.0050) (a)
[0.0006] (a) [0.0141] (a) [0.0202] (a)
0.0030
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0006] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0039 0.1332 -0.1595
female sample (0.0010) (a) (0.0107) (a) (0.0142) (a)
[0.0012] (a) [0.0173] (a) [0.0237] (a)
0.0049
(0.0011) (a) -- --
[0.0014] (a)
B: Wage equation
results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0130 5.1024 -7.2595
(0.0034) (a) (0.0471) (a) (0.0645) (a)
[0.0119] [0.2932] (a) [0.4044] (a)
0.0392
(0.0039) (a) -- --
[0.0112] (a)
Male sample 0.0150 4.9624 -7.2360
(0.0036) (a) (0.0550) (a) (0.0758) (a)
[0.0105] [0.2559] (a) [0.3670] (a)
0.0396
(0.0042) (a) -- --
[0.0092] (a)
Female sample -0.0103 5.3050 -7.3212
(0.0100) (0.0885) (a) (0.1217) (a)
[0.0316] [0.5492] (a) [0.7330] (a)
0.0095
(0.0108) -- --
[0.0369]
Blue-collar 0.0311 4.0809 -5.6948
male sample (0.0034) (a) (0.0692) (a) (0.0938) (a)
[0.0083] (a) [0.2756] (a) [0.4000] (a)
0.0485
(0.0040) (a) -- --
[0.0081] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0610 2.0362 -2.5713
female sample (0.0147) (a) (0.1559) (a) (0.2087) (a)
[0.0162] (a) [0.2725] (a) [0.3681] (a)
0.0774
(0.0160) (a) -- --
[0.0180] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0123 5.1029 -7.2608
(0.0029) (a) (0.0471) (a) (0.0645) (a)
[0.0097] [0.2933] (a) [0.4045] (a)
0.0316
(0.0033) (a) -- --
[0.0093] (a)
Male sample 0.0134 4.9630 -7.2376
(0.0031) (a) (0.0551) (a) (0.0758) (a)
[0.0089] [0.2560] (a) [0.3670] (a)
0.0317
(0.0036) (a) -- --
[0.0082] (a)
Female sample 0.0030 5.3021 -7.3209
(0.0083) (0.0885) (a) (0.1217) (a)
[0.0238] [0.5489] (a) [0.7330] (a)
0.0136
(0.0085) -- --
[0.0273]
Blue-collar 0.0243 4.0830 -5.7004
male sample (0.0031) (a) (0.0693) (a) (0.0938) (a)
[0.0075] (a) [0.2760] (a) [0.3996] (a)
0.0389
(0.0036) (a) -- --
[0.0076] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0488 2.0511 -2.5862
female sample (0.0122) (a) (0.1560) (a) (0.2089) (a)
[0.0140] (a) [0.2738] (a) [0.3699] (a)
0.0613
(0.0132) (a) -- --
[0.0155] (a)
Coefficients
(Robust SE)
[Robust and Clustered SE]
Value of Value of
Life Injury or
Death Risk ($ millions) Illness ($)
A: ln(Wage)
equation results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0017 4.7 9570
(0.0002) (a)
[0.0010] (c)
0.0032 8.9
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0009] (a)
Male sample 0.0016 4.9 13,379
(0.0003) (a)
[0.0008] (c)
0.0030 9.1
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0007] (a)
Female sample -0.0007 -1.7 10,921
(0.0008)
[0.0029]
0.0006 1.5
(0.0008) --
[0.0031]
Blue-collar 0.0027 7.0 12,226
male sample (0.0003) (a)
[0.0007] (a)
0.0037 9.6
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0006] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0047 8.5 29,642
female sample (0.0013) (a)
[0.0015] (a)
0.0061 11.0
(0.0014) (a) --
[0.0016] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0015 4.2 9737
(0.0002) (a)
[0.0008] (c)
0.0026 7.3
(0.0002) (a) --
[0.0007] (a)
Male sample 0.0014 4.3 13,270
(0.0002) (a)
[0.0007] (b)
0.0024 7.3
(0.0002) (a) --
[0.0006] (a)
Female sample 0.0004 1.0 10,422
(0.0007)
[0.0022]
0.0011 2.7
(0.0007) --
[0.0023]
Blue-collar 0.0022 5.7 11,566
male sample (0.0002) (a)
[0.0006] (a)
0.0030 7.8
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0006] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0039 7.0 30,177
female sample (0.0010) (a)
[0.0012] (a)
0.0049 8.8
(0.0011) (a) --
[0.0014] (a)
B: Wage equation
results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0130 2.6 4150
(0.0034) (a)
[0.0119]
0.0392 7.8
(0.0039) (a) --
[0.0112] (a)
Male sample 0.0150 3.0 8384
(0.0036) (a)
[0.0105]
0.0396 7.9
(0.0042) (a) --
[0.0092] (a)
Female sample -0.0103 -2.1 6747
(0.0100)
[0.0316]
0.0095 1.9
(0.0108) --
[0.0369]
Blue-collar 0.0311 6.2 7518
male sample (0.0034) (a)
[0.0083] (a)
0.0485 9.7
(0.0040) (a) --
[0.0081] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0610 12.2 31,830
female sample (0.0147) (a)
[0.0162] (a)
0.0774 15.5
(0.0160) (a) --
[0.0180] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0123 2.5 4068
(0.0029) (a)
[0.0097]
0.0316 6.3
(0.0033) (a) --
[0.0093] (a)
Male sample 0.0134 2.7 8286
(0.0031) (a)
[0.0089]
0.0317 6.3
(0.0036) (a) --
[0.0082] (a)
Female sample 0.0030 0.6 6210
(0.0083)
[0.0238]
0.0136 2.7
(0.0085) --
[0.0273]
Blue-collar 0.0243 4.9 7143
male sample (0.0031) (a)
[0.0075] (a)
0.0389 7.8
(0.0036) (a)
[0.0076] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0488 9.8 32,635
female sample (0.0122) (a)
[0.0140] (a)
0.0613 12.3
(0.0132) (a) --
[0.0155] (a)
(a) Indicates statistical significance at the 99% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(b) Indicates statistical significance at the 95% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(c) Indicates statistical significance at the 90% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
TABLE 4
Regression Results for Industry Death Risk Measure
Coefficients
(Robust SE)
[Robust and Clustered SE]
Expected Workers'
Injury and Compensation
Death Risk Illness Rate Replacement Rate
A: ln(Wage)
equation results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0036 0.2677 -0.3806
(0.0003) (a) (0.0025) (a) (0.0034) (a)
[0.0011] (a) [0.0265] (a) [0.0381] (a)
0.0052
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0014] (a)
Male sample 0.0032 0.2603 -0.3793
(0.0003) (a) (0.0029) (a) (0.0040) (a)
[0.0010] (a) [0.0255] (a) [0.0382] (a)
0.0048
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0012] (a)
Female sample 0.0035 0.2825 -0.3897
(0.0005) (a) (0.0047) (a) (0.0064) (a)
[0.0022] [0.0327] (a) [0.0448] (a)
0.0041
(0.0006) (a) -- --
[0.0022] (c)
Blue collar 0.0036 0.2283 -0.3178
male sample (0.0003) (a) (0.0038) (a) (0.0050) (a)
[0.0009] (a) [0.0184] (a) [0.0267] (a)
0.0049
(0.0004) (a) -- --
[0.0009] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0037 0.1323 -0.1599
female sample (0.0014) (a) (0.0108) (a) (0.0142) (a)
[0.0025] [0.0177] (a) [0.0240] (a)
0.0071
(0.0014) (a) -- --
[0.0026] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0035 0.2676 -0.3806
(0.0002) (a) (0.0025) (a) (0.0034) (a)
[0.0011] (a) [0.0264] (a) [0.0381] (a)
0.0050
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0015] (a)
Male sample 0.0032 0.2601 -0.3794
(0.0003) (a) (0.0029) (a) (0.0040) (a)
[0.0009] (a) [0.0253] (a) [0.0383] (a)
0.0046
(0.0003) (a) -- --
[0.0012] (a)
Female sample 0.0034 0.2824 -0.3896
(0.0005) (a) (0.0047) (a) (0.0064) (a)
[0.0021] [0.0328] (a) [0.0448] (a)
0.0041
(0.0005) (a) -- --
[0.0022] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0037 0.2282 -0.3180
male sample (0.0003) (a) (0.0038) (a) (0.0050) (a)
[0.0008] (a) [0.0182] (a) [0.0266] (a)
0.0048
(0.0004) (a) -- --
[0.0009] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0042 0.1318 -0.1596
female sample (0.0014) (a) (0.0108) (a) (0.0142) (a)
[0.0023] (c) [0.0176] [0.0240] (a)
0.0075
(0.0014) (a) -- --
[0.0024] (a)
B: Wage equation
results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0413 5.0682 -7.2501
(0.0036) (a) (0.0472) (a) (0.0643) (a)
[0.0138] (a) [0.4992] (a) [0.7161] (a)
0.0687
(0.0044) (a) -- --
[0.0206] (a)
Male sample 0.0371 4.9325 -7.2288
(0.0042) (a) (0.0552) (a) (0.0756) (a)
[0.0128] (a) [0.4774] (a) [0.7156] (a)
0.0647
(0.0052) (a) -- --
[0.0189] (a)
Female sample 0.0495 5.2676 -7.3176
(0.0072) (a) (0.0884) (a) (0.1216) (a)
[0.0247] (a) [0.6456] (a) [0.8839] (a)
0.0553
(0.0080) (a) -- --
[0.0279] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0430 4.0599 -5.6993
male sample (0.0046) (a) (0.0696) (a) (0.0939) (a)
[0.0110] (a) [0.3485] (a) [0.5070] (a)
0.0632
(0.0056) (a) -- --
[0.0124] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0573 2.0302 -2.5846
female sample (0.0175) (a) (0.1563) (a) (0.2089) (a)
[0.0284] (b) [0.2758] (a) [0.3744] (a)
0.0941
(0.0180) (a) -- --
[0.0284] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0399 5.0680 -7.2509
(0.0036) (a) (0.0472) (a) (0.0643) (a)
[0.0140] (a) [0.4984] (a) [0.7163] (a)
0.0650
(0.0042) (a) -- --
[0.0215] (a)
Male sample 0.0366 4.9315 -7.2295
(0.0042) (a) (0.0552) (a) (0.0756) (a)
[0.0129] (a) [0.4756] (a) [0.7156] (a)
0.0614
(0.0050) (a) -- --
[0.0199] (a)
Female sample 0.0471 5.2677 -7.3172
(0.0069) (a) (0.0884) (a) (0.1215) (a)
[0.0242] (c) [0.6464] (a) [0.8842] (a)
0.0532
(0.0076) (a) -- --
[0.0275] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0434 4.0590 -5.7015
male sample (0.0046) (a) (0.0694) (a) (0.0938) (a)
[1.0106] (a) [0.3461] (a) [0.5068] (a)
0.0607
(0.0054) (a) -- --
[0.0134] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0604 2.0258 -2.5830
female sample (0.0166) (a) (0.1563) (a) (0.2090) (a)
[0.0273] (b) [0.2749] (a) [0.3743] (a)
0.0958
(0.0169) (a) -- --
[0.0274] (a)
Coefficients
(Robust SE)
[Robust and Clustered SE]
Value of Value of
Life Injury or
Death Risk ($ millions) Illness ($)
A: ln(Wage)
equation results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0036 10.0 3571
(0.0003) (a)
[0.0011] (a)
0.0052 14.5
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0014] (a)
Male sample 0.0032 9.7 7218
(0.0003) (a)
[0.0010] (a)
0.0048 14.6
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0012] (a)
Female sample 0.0035 8.7 4786
(0.0005) (a)
[0.0022]
0.0041 10.2
(0.0006) (a) --
[0.0022] (c)
Blue collar 0.0036 9.3 6900
male sample (0.0003) (a)
[0.0009] (a)
0.0049 12.7
(0.0004) (a) --
[0.0009] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0037 6.7 28,031
female sample (0.0014) (a)
[0.0025]
0.0071 12.8
(0.0014) (a) --
[0.0026] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0035 9.8 3292
(0.0002) (a)
[0.0011] (a)
0.0050 14.0
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0015] (a)
Male sample 0.0032 9.7 6404
(0.0003) (a)
[0.0009] (a)
0.0046 14.0
(0.0003) (a) --
[0.0012] (a)
Female sample 0.0034 8.5 4716
(0.0005) (a)
[0.0021]
0.0041 10.2
(0.0005) (a) --
[0.0022] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0037 9.6 6273
male sample (0.0003) (a)
[0.0008] (a)
0.0048 12.4
(0.0004) (a) --
[0.0009] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0042 7.6 27,526
female sample (0.0014) (a)
[0.0023] (c)
0.0075 13.5
(0.0014) (a) --
[0.0024] (a)
B: Wage equation
results
1992-97 death risk
Full sample 0.0413 8.3 -1374
(0.0036) (a)
[0.0138] (a)
0.0687 13.7
(0.0044) (a) --
[0.0206] (a)
Male sample 0.0371 7.4 3383
(0.0042) (a)
[0.0128] (a)
0.0647 12.9
(0.0052) (a) --
[0.0189] (a)
Female sample 0.0495 9.9 -214
(0.0072) (a)
[0.0247] (a)
0.0553 11.1
(0.0080) (a) --
[0.0279] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0430 8.6 2679
male sample (0.0046) (a)
[0.0110] (a)
0.0632 12.6
(0.0056) (a) --
[0.0124] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0573 11.5 28,688
female sample (0.0175) (a)
[0.0284] (b)
0.0941 18.8
(0.0180) (a) --
[0.0284] (a)
1997 death risk
Full sample 0.0399 8.0 -1526
(0.0036) (a)
[0.0140] (a)
0.0650 13.0
(0.0042) (a) --
[0.0215] (a)
Male sample 0.0366 7.3 3088
(0.0042) (a)
[0.0129] (a)
0.0614 12.3
(0.0050) (a) --
[0.0199] (a)
Female sample 0.0471 9.4 -137
(0.0069) (a)
[0.0242] (c)
0.0532 10.6
(0.0076) (a) --
[0.0275] (c)
Blue-collar 0.0434 8.7 2187
male sample (0.0046) (a)
[1.0106] (a)
0.0607 12.1
(0.0054) (a) --
[0.0134] (a)
Blue-collar 0.0604 12.1 28,042
female sample (0.0166) (a)
[0.0273] (b)
0.0958 19.2
(0.0169) (a) --
[0.0274] (a)
(a) Indicates statistical significance at the 99% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(b) Indicates statistical significance at the 95% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(c) Indicates statistical significance at the 90% confidence level,
two-tailed test.
(1.) The variable for the worker's perceived exposure to
dangerous conditions was used in Viscusi (1979) and elsewhere, where
this measure is also interacted with objective measures of job risks.
Other studies have elicited workers' subjective assessments of the
probability of job injury, as in Viscusi and O'Connor (1984),
leading to estimates of the implicit value of injury that paralleled
those generated using objective risk data.
(2.) For a recent survey of U.S. value-of life studies, see Viscusi
and Aldy (2003). See also the industry-based estimates of risk in
Kniesner and Leeth (1991) for Australia and Japan and the analysis of
occupational mortality data for the United Kingdom by Marin and
Psacharopoulos (1982).
(3.) Measurement error remains a continuing issue in the
value-of-life literature. Black and Kniesner (2003) provide an in-depth
analysis of measurement error for the job risk variable.
(4.) The levels of the risk values also differed, however,
complicating the theoretical predictions.
(5.) See U.S. BLS Current Population Survey (CPS) unpublished
table, Table 6, Employed persons by detailed industry and major
occupation, annual average 1997 (based on the CPS).
(6.) Indeed, the only year in which the number of workplace
fatalities differed by more than 100 from that for 1997 was 1994, in
which there were 6632 fatalities, or 394 more than 1997, which is a 6%
difference.
(7.) For example, Moore and Viscusi (1990), 73, report BLS risk
levels of 0.00005 and NTOF death risks of 0.00008.
(8.) For additional discussion, see Thaler and Rosen (1976),
Viscusi (1979; 1993), Smith (1979), and Rosen (1986), among others.
(9.) The injury risk variable is the BLS incidence rate for
nonfatal occupational injuries and illnesses, lost workday cases, by
industry in 1997.
(10.) wages and benefits in equation (2) are measured on a weekly
basis rather than an hourly basis. Taxes were assigned as follows.
Workers with a married spouse present are assigned married filing
status, workers with married spouses absent are assigned married filing
separately, and all others were assigned single filing. Each person
received the standard deduction and exemptions, that is, married filers
received three exemptions and married filing separately received two
exemptions, as did single filers. Federal tax data were from the
Commerce Clearing House, 1998 U.S. Master Tax Guide, 1997; state taxes
were from the U.S. Census Bureau (1999), No. 522 State
Governments--Revenue by State: 1997 and No. 732 Personal Income, by
State: 1990 to 1998. Data for District of Columbia were from the U.S.
Census Bureau Web site, www.census.gov/govs/estimate/97s109dc.html.
(11.) The notable exception is the analysis in Viscusi and Moore
(1987) and Moore and Viscusi (1990).
(12.) Moreover, the average tax rate depends on the wage rate as
well.
(13.) The instruments used for the full sample runs and the
blue-collar female runs included the state's average tax rate and
the total workers' compensation benefits in the state divided by
the size of the labor force. The instruments used for the blue-collar
male sample runs included the total workers' compensation benefits
in the state divided by the size of the labor force, the state's
unemployment percentage, and a Republican governor dummy variable. These
variables were all significant predictors of the workers'
compensation replacement rate and were not significant predictors of the
wage rate either individually or jointly. The instrument set varied for
the blue-collar male workers and the blue-collar female runs as well as
the full-sample runs because some variables were not valid instruments
in different samples, that is, they were significant predictors of the
wage rate. The instrumental variables regression estimates generated
were very similar to the OLS estimates in magnitude. The Hausman test for endogeneity, however, implied that one could not reject the
hypothesis that the expected workers' compensation replacement rate
was not endogenous, for example, [chi square](1) = 0.51, Prob > [chi
square] = 0.48 for the full-sample equation with the occupation-industry
death risk variable, [chi square](1) = 2.42, Prob > [chi square] =
0.12 for the blue-collar male equation, and [chi square] = 0.74, Prob
> [chi square] = 0.39 for the blue-collar female equation.
(14.) For discussion of this procedure, see Huber (1967) and Rogers
(1993).
(15.) Top coded observations were excluded from the sample. Workers
with wages of $1923 per week (or $100,000 per year) and usual weekly
hours of 99 were excluded. The highest percent of the omissions was for
the male subsample, for which under 4% were eliminated. For the full
sample, about 2% of the observations were affected. For the key samples
of male and female blue-collar workers, less than 1% of the observations
were affected.
(16.) Respondents who reported less than a ninth-grade education
were also excluded from the sample.
(17.) The critical F values for the test are for tests such as
[F.sub.0.05] (31, 98,969), for which the critical test value is 1.46.
The estimated F values for pooling the male and female subsamples as
opposed to a simple female dummy variable ranged from 30.7 to 30.9 for
the four different fatality risk measures (1992-97 average
industry-occupation risk, 1997 industry-occupation risk, 1992-97
industry risk, and 1997 industry risk) for the wage equation, and
similarly a range of F vales of 41.3 to 42.0 for the semi-logarithmic
equation results. Similarly the estimated F values for pooling the
blue-collar male and blue-collar female subsample, as opposed to a
simple female dummy variable, ranged from 38.3 to 38.6 for the four
different fatality risk measures for the wage equation results and
ranged from 24.5 to 24.8 for the semi-log equation results.
(18.) The studies that have included a workers' compensation
variable in the hedonic wage equation for fatality risks are Arnould and
Nichols (1983), Butler (1983), Kniesner and Leeth (1991), and a series
of works summarized in Moore and Viscusi (1990).
(19.) More specifically, abstracting from the influence of loading,
the worker structures his or her compensation to maximize expected
utility subject to the constraint that the marginal product equals (1 -
p)w +pb.
(20.) See Moore and Viscusi (1990), 39. This value of h is what
they label "1 + a" in their model.
(21.) The equation estimated here also differed in other ways, such
as inclusion of a fatality risk variable.
(22.) See p. 82 of Insurance Information Institute (2001).
(23.) This equation was multiplied by 200,000,000 to annualize the
wages (assuming 2000 hours worked per year) and to take into account the
fact that the death risk measure is per 100,000 workers.
(24.) These findings for injuries are surveyed by Viscusi (1992;
1993) and Viscusi and Aldy (2003).
(25.) If instead, the injury variable had been retained but not the
workers' compensation variable, the value of life would be $ 8.4
million. REFERENCES
Arnould, Richard J., and Len M. Nichols. "Wage-Risk Premiums
and Workers' Compensation: A Refinement of Estimates of
Compensating Wage Differentials." Journal of Political Economy, 91
(2), 1983, 33240.
Black, Dan A., and Thomas Kniesner. "On the Measurement of Job
Risk in Hedonic Wage Models." Paper presented at 2003 AEA meetings,
Syracuse University, 2003.
Brown, Charles. "Equalizing Differences in the Labor
Market." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(1), 1980, 113-34.
Butler, Richard J. "Wage and Injury Rate Responses to Shifting
Levels of Workers' Compensation," in Safety and the Work
Farce, edited by John D. Worrall. Ithaca: ILR Press, 1983, 61-86.
Hersch, Joni. "Compensating Differentials for Gender-Specific
Job Injury Risks." American Economic Review, 88(3), 1998, 598 607.
Huber, Peter J. "The Behavior of Maximum Likelihood Estimates
under Non-Standard Conditions," in Proceedings of the Fifth
Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, edited by
Lucien M. LeCam and Jerzy Neyman. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Press, 1967, 221-33.
Insurance Information Institute. Fact Book 2001. New York:
Insurance Information Institute, 2001.
Kniesner, Thomas J., and John D. Leeth. "Compensating Wage
Differentials for Fatal Injury Risk in Australia, Japan, and the United
States." Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 4(1), 1991, 75-90.
Marin, Alan, and George Psacharopoulos. "The Reward for Risk
in the Labor Market: Evidence from the United Kingdom and a
Reconciliation with Other Studies." Journal of Political Economy,
90(4), 1982, 827-53.
Mellow, Wesley, and Hal Sider. "Accuracy of Response in Labor
Market Surveys: Evidence and Implications." Journal of Labor
Economics, 1(4), 1983, 331-44.
Moore, Michael J., and W. Kip Viscusi. Compensation Mechanisms for
Job Risks. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990.
Rogers, William H. "Regression Standard Errors in Clustered
Samples." Stata Technical Bulletin, 13, 1993, 19-23.
Rosen, Sherwin. "The Theory of Equalizing Differences,"
in Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and Richard
Layard. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1986, 641-42.
Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library,
[1776] 1937.
Smith, Robert S. The Occupational Safety and Health Act.
Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 1976. --,
"Compensating Wage Differentials and Public Policy: A Review."
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 32(3), 1979, 339-52.
Thaler, Richard, and Sherwin Rosen. "The Value of Saving a
Life: Evidence from the Market," in Household Production and
Consumption, edited by Nestor E. Terleckyj. Cambridge, MA: NBER, 1976,
265-98.
Viscusi, W. Kip. Employment Hazards: An Investigation of Market
Performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1979.
--, Fatal Tradeoffs: Public and Private Responsibilities for Risk.
New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.
--, "The Value of Risks to Life and Health." Journal of
Economic Literature, 30(4), 1993, 1912-46.
Viscusi, W. Kip, and Joseph Aldy. "The Value of Statistical
Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates throughout the World."
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27(1), 2003, 5-76.
Viscusi, W. Kip, and Joni Hersch. "Cigarette Smokers as Job
Risk Takers." Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(2), 2001,
269-80.
Viscusi, W. Kip, and Charles O'Connor. "Adaptive
Responses to Chemical Labeling: Are Workers Bayesian Decision
Makers?" American Economic Review, 74(5), 1984, 942-56.
W. KIP VISCUSI, This research is supported in part by the Sheldon Seevak Research Fund; the Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business;
and the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. DeYett Law provided superb
research assistance. I express gratitude to the BLS for permission to
use the CFOI data, and an anonymous referee provided helpful comments.
Neither that agency nor EPA bear any responsibility for the accuracy of
any risk measures I calculated for this article or the research results.
Viscusi: Cogan Professor of Law and Economics, Harvard Law School,
1575 Mass. Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138. Phone 1-617-496-0019, Fax
1-617-495-3010, E-mail Kip@law.harvard.edu