Growth effects of shifting from a graduated-rate tax system to a flat tax.
Cassou, Steven P. ; Lansing, Kevin J.
I. INTRODUCTION
Recently, the debate concerning fundamental U.S. tax reform has led
to a number of proposals that involve a shift toward a consumption-based
system. (1) One such proposal is the so-called flat tax of Hall and
Rabushka (1995). The flat tax would apply a single tax rate to all labor
income above a given threshold and to all capital income after fully
expensing investment expenditures. Hall and Rabushka (1995) argue that
the adoption of their proposal would provide an enormous boost to the
U.S. economy by dramatically improving incentives to engage in
productive activities and would save taxpayers hundreds of billions of
dollars in compliance and administration costs. (2)
In this article, we develop a quantitative general equilibrium model to assess the growth effects of adopting a flat tax plan similar
to the one proposed by Hall and Rabushka (1995). The model captures many
of the features of the current U.S. tax code, such as graduated personal
tax rates, a standard personal deduction, separate tax rates applied to
personal and business income, double taxation of business income, and
differential tax treatment of physical and human capital. Under
appropriate parameter settings, the model can exhibit either endogenous or exogenous long-run growth. Our choice of functional forms facilitates
a closed-form solution to the model. This allows us to characterize
explicitly the economy's transition path following the reform.
A central issue in the debate over fundamental tax reform is the
effect that such a reform would have on economic growth. The present
analysis builds on the work of Stokey and Rebelo (1995), who use an
endogenous growth framework to identify the key model features and
parameters that are important for determining the quantitative impacts
of distortionary taxes on long-run growth. (3) Our study differs from
theirs and the bulk of the dynamic tax literature in one fundamental
respect. Here we evaluate the growth effects of shifting from a
graduatedrate tax system to a flat-rate system. Stokey and Rebelo (1995)
consider only flat-rate systems in which the marginal tax rate is equal
to the average tax rate.
We approximate the graduated-rate tax system in the U.S. economy by
an empirical tax rate function that allows the personal tax rate to
depend positively on household taxable income. In equilibrium, household
decisions are influenced by both the level and slope of the tax
schedule. To implement the flat tax reform, we shift the parameters of
the tax rate function to flatten the marginal tax schedule while
maintaining revenue neutrality. Our methodology treats the Hall-Rabushka
proposal as one that in effect moves a representative household from one
tax rate schedule to another. We view this setup as a reasonable
approximation to gauge the growth effects of tax reform at the macro
level. A more elaborate setup would of course allow for household
heterogeneity at a given point in time. In this regard, we note that
Caucutt et al. (2003) have recently examined the growth effects of
graduated-rate taxes in a two-period overlapping generations model that
includes both skilled and unskilled agents. In their model, a flatter
tax schedule increases the fraction of skilled agents in the economy.
The share of total output devoted to education rises accordingly and the
economy's long-run growth rate is observed to increase. The
quantitative implications of their model are difficult to compare to
ours, however, because their two-period framework implies a very long
time horizon between household decisions (about 30 years). Moreover,
their model abstracts from many of the features of the U.S. tax code
that we include here.
In addition to examining the consequences of flattening the
marginal tax schedule, we investigate the growth effects attributable to
other parts of the flat tax proposal, such as allowing full investment
expensing, eliminating the double taxation of business income, and
increasing the standard personal deduction. Although a flat tax may
result in a lower marginal tax rate for some categories of income, it
generally requires a higher average tax rate to pay for the more
generous expensing and deduction features. This mitigates the resulting
growth and level benefits. We also consider the tax treatment of human
capital investment, an element that is not specifically addressed by
Hall and Rabushka (1995). Judd (1998) argues that the Hall-Rabushka plan
does not treat physical and human capital symmetrically and therefore is
not equivalent to a pure consumption tax. We investigate whether this
feature is quantitatively important.
In the endogenous growth version of the model, we find that
adopting a flat tax can permanently increase per capita growth by 0.009
to 0.143 percentage points per year, depending on the elasticity of
household labor supply. The small growth effects that we obtain are due
to the form of the human capital technology where untaxed forgone
earnings represent the largest input to production. Through a series of
experiments, we decompose the long-run growth effect into the parts
attributable to the flattening of the marginal tax schedule, the full
expensing of physical capital investment, and the elimination of double
taxation of business income. We find that the most important
growth-enhancing element is the flattening of the marginal tax schedule.
The full expensing of physical capital investment contributes only a
small amount to the overall growth gain. Finally, we show that the
elimination of double taxation of business income can actually reduce
long-run growth when combined with full investment expensing. This is
because full expensing largely eliminates the distortion associated with
collecting revenue from double taxation. Doing away with double taxation
forces the government to replace this revenue using a higher postreform
tax rate. A higher postreform tax rate is harmful for growth because it
discourages labor effort and time devoted to human capital accumulation.
We find that the asymmetric treatment of physical and human capital
under the Hall-Rabushka type flat tax has only minor growth
consequences. This is because nondeductible investment accounts for only
a small fraction of the total costs of producing human capital. The
largest input to the production of human capital is forgone earnings,
which, as previously noted by Boskin (1977), is already implicitly
expensed.
In the exogenous growth version of the model, adopting a flat tax
yields a temporary growth gain but a permanent level shift. The
transition dynamics can be quite lengthy, however. Following the
adoption of a flat tax, the economy takes about 100 years to return to
its prereform growth rate. In the years immediately following the
reform, the economy's output trajectory is quite similar to that of
the endogenous growth model. In both versions of the model, shifting to
a flat tax initially produces a growth slowdown due to the immediate
reaction of hours worked and time in school to the higher postreform tax
rate that is needed to maintain revenue neutrality. The slowdown is only
temporary, however. After about six years, the additional capital
accumulation induced by changes in the tax code allows the postreform
output trajectory to overtake the prereform trend.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows. Section II
describes the model and the tax system. The incentive effects of the tax
system are examined in section III. Section IV describes our calibration procedure. Section V presents our quantitative results. Section VI
concludes. An appendix describes the solution of the model.
II. THE MODEL
The model economy consists of households, firms, and the
government. We allow for variable leisure, investment adjustment costs,
and a realistic version of the U.S. tax code. Our choice of functional
forms, inspired by the work of Hercowitz and Sampson (1991), permits a
closed-form solution of the model. The solution allows us to explicitly
characterize the economy's transition path following a tax reform.
Households and Firms
We model the representative household as choosing [{[c.sub.t],
[l.sub.t], [e.sub.t], [i.sub.ht], [i.sub.ht], [k.sub.t+1], [h.sub.t+1],
[[tau].sub.pt]}.sup.[infinity].sub.[t=0] to maximize
(1) [[infinity].summation over t=0] [[beta].sup.t] log[[c.sub.t] -
V([h.sub.t],[l.sub.t])], [beta] [member of] (0,1),
subject to
(2) [c.sub.t] + [i.sub.kt] + [i.sub.ht] = [r.sub.t][k.sub.t] +
[w.sub.t][h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]) - [T.sub.t],
(3) [T.sub.t] = [[tau].sub.pt][[w.sub.t][h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t]) - [D.sub.t] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])([r.sub.t][k.sub.t] -
[[phi].sub.k][i.sub.kt] - [[phi].sub.h][i.sub.ht])] +
[[tau].sub.b]([r.sub.t][k.sub.t] - [[phi].sub.k][i.sub.kt] -
[[phi].sub.h][i.sub.ht]), [eta] [member of] [0,1], [[phi].sub.i] [member
of] [0,1], i = k,h,
(4) [[tau].sub.pt] = F[[w.sub.t][h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]),
[r.sub.t][k.sub.t],[i.sub.kt], [i.sub.ht]],
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Equation (1) represents lifetime utility where [beta] is the
discount factor; [c.sub.t] is private consumption; [l.sub.t] is time
devoted to nonleisure activities, that is, work or education; and
[h.sub.t] is the household's stock of human capital or knowledge.
The disutility of nonleisure time is governed by the functional form
(7) V([h.sub.t],[l.sub.t]) = B[h.sub.t][l.sup.[gamma].sub.t], B
> 0, [gamma] > 0,
which implies that forgone leisure is adjusted for
"quality," as measured by [h.sub.t], reminiscent of the models
of Becker (1965) and Heckman (1976). Alternatively, we may interpret
V([h.sub.t],[l.sub.t]) as the reduced form of a more elaborate
specification that incorporates home production (see Greenwood et al.
1995, 161). Our specification for V([h.sub.t],[l.sub.t]) facilitates a
closed-form solution to the household's decision problem where tax
policy can affect the time allocation decision. As [gamma] [right arrow]
[infinity], the model reduces to one with fixed time allocations. The
intertemporal elasticity of substitution in labor supply is given by
1/([gamma]- 1).
Equation (2) is the within-period budget constraint where
[i.sub.kt] and [i.sub.ht] represent expenditures devoted to the
accumulation of physical capital [k.sub.t] and human capital [h.sub.t].
We interpret [i.sub.ht] as private-sector expenditures on education,
training, and research and development (R&D), which all contribute
to a broadly defined stock of knowledge [h.sub.t]. Given a total time
endowment normalized to one, households allocate their time across three
activities: they supply labor effort to firms in the amount [l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t], devote time to human capital formation (learning) in the
amount [e.sub.t], and spend the remainder of their time 1 - [l.sub.t] in
leisure.
Households receive a rental rate [r.sub.t] for each unit of
physical capital used in production and earn a wage [w.sub.t] for each
unit of effective labor employed by the firm. The goods-producing
technology is given by
(8) [y.sub.t] = [A.sub.0][k.sup.[phi].sub.t][[h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t])].sup.1-[phi], [A.sup.0] > 0, [phi] [member of] (0,1),
where [y.sub.t] is per capita output and [h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t]) represents the effective labor input. (4) Profit maximization implies
(9) [r.sub.t] = [phi][y.sub.t]/[k.sub.t],
(10) [w.sub.t] = (1 - [phi])[y.sub.t]/[[h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t])].
Taxes paid to the government [T.sub.t] are given by equation (3)
where [[tau].sub.pt] is the personal tax rate and [[tau].sub.b] is the
business (or corporate) tax rate. Variables without time subscripts
represent constants for all t. The personal tax rate can change over
time as households make decisions that move them into a different tax
bracket. This possibility is captured by the tax rate function F[*] in
equation (4) which says that [[tau].sub.pt] depends on personal taxable
income.
Personal taxable income is equal to labor income, less the standard
deduction Dr, plus after-tax business income, which we assume is paid
out each period in the form of dividends. We use the symbol [eta]
[member of] [0, 1] to index the degree to which business income is taxed
twice by the tax code. (5) Earnings forgone while in school
[w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t] are implicitly expensed under the current
tax code (see Boskin 1977) and would receive the same treatment under
all proposed reforms.
The symbols and [[phi].sub.k] and [[phi].sub.h] denote the
fractions of investment in physical and human capital that can be
expensed, or immediately deducted from business taxable income. For
comparison with the U.S. tax system, [phi].sub.k] and [[phi].sub.h] can
be interpreted as index numbers that summarize the various elements of
the tax code that encourage saving or investment. Features that
influence [[phi].sub.k] include the depreciation allowance for physical
capital; the tax-deferred status of saving done through pensions, 401
(k)s, Keoughs, and retirement accounts; the favorable tax treatment of
long-term capital gains; and the relatively tax-free status of service
flows from owner-occupied housing. (6) Regarding [[phi].sub.h], firms
may expense the costs of formal worker training, the wages of workers
engaged in on-the-job training, job-related employee tuition, and
expenditures for R&D. There is also a 20% tax credit for qualifying
increases in R&D expenditures. (7)
Equations (5) and (6) describe the laws of motion for physical and
human capital. When [[delta].sub.k] = [[delta].sub.k] = 1, the capital
stocks depreciate completely each period, whereas 0 < [[delta].sub.i]
< 1, for i = k, h implies that capital stocks are long-lasting. This
nonlinear specification facilitates closed-form decision rules and can
be viewed as reflecting adjustment costs as in Lucas and Prescott
(1971). (8) Equation (5) implies that households can add to their stock
of physical capital in only one way: through goods investment
[i.sub.kt]. Equation (6) implies that human capital can be increased
through goods investment [i.sub.ht] or by the allocation of household
time [e.sub.t]. Introducing [i.sub.ht] as an input has an effect that is
similar to introducing physical capital [k.sub.t] as an input because
goods must be produced using physical capital. When [[delta].sub.h] = v
= 0, the model collapses to one with exogenous labor-augmenting
technological progress. In this case, the economy's long-run growth
rate is given by log([h.sub.t+1]/[h.sub.t]) = log [A.sub.2].
The Tax System
The personal tax function, equation (4), allows for graduated rates
and is assumed to take the following form
(11) [[[tau].sub.pt] = [[tau].sub.p][[w.sub.t][h.sub.t]([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t]) - [D.sub.t] + [eta](1 - [tau].sub.b] x ([r.sub.t][k.sub.t] -
[[phi].sub.k][i.sub.kt] - [[phi].sub.h][i.sub.ht)].sup.n] x
[[w.sub.t][H.sub.t]([L.sub.t] - [E.sub.t]) - [D.sub.t] + [eta](1 -
[[tau].sub.b]) x ([r.sub.t][K.sub.t] - [[phi].sub.k][I.sub.kt] -
[[phi].sub.h][I.sub.ht].sup.-n],
where capital letters denote economy-wide averages and
[[tau].sub.p] [member of] [0, 1] and n [greater than or equal to] 0 are
parameters that govern the level and slope of the tax schedule. (9)
Households view the economy-wide averages as outside their control. We
impose the aggregate consistency conditions [H.sub.t]=[h.sub.t],
[L.sub.t]=[l.sub.t], [E.sub.t]=[e.sub.t], [K.sub.t]=[k.sub.t],
[I.sub.kt]=[i.sub.kt], and [I.sub.ht]=[i.sub.ht] after decisions are
made. When n > 0, households with above-average taxable income face a
higher personal tax rate than those with below-average taxable income.
In contrast, when n = 0, all households face the same personal tax rate
[[tau].sub.p] regardless of their taxable income. In our model,
therefore, n > 0 represents a graduated-rate tax schedule and n=0
represents a horizontal or flat schedule.
The government sets the standard deduction [D.sub.t], which we
model as a constant fraction of average pretax income:
(12) [D.sub.t] = [alpha][Y.sub.t], [alpha] [greater than or equal
to] 0.
Because [D.sub.t] is a function of [Y.sub.t](as opposed to
[y.sub.t]), households take the deduction as given.
For our analysis, it is useful to distinguish between the average
and marginal tax rates on different categories of income. The average
personal tax rate is defined as personal taxes paid divided by personal
taxable income. The marginal personal tax rate is defined as the change
in personal taxes paid divided by the change in personal taxable income,
where we interpret "change" as an infinitesimally small
amount. Intuitively, the marginal tax rate represents the rate applied
to the last dollar earned. To derive the marginal personal tax rate, we
multiply equation (11) by personal taxable income and then differentiate
the resulting expression with respect to personal taxable income. After
imposing the aggregate consistency conditions, we obtain [[tau].sub.p](n
+ 1) as the marginal personal tax rate. A similar procedure can be used
to derive the marginal business tax rate. The expressions that govern
the various equilibrium tax rates are
(13) Average personal tax rate = [[tau].sub.p],
(14) Marginal personal tax rate = [[tau].sub.p] (n + 1),
(15) Average business tax rate = [[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 -
[[tau].sub.p])[[tau].sub.p],
(16) Marginal business tax rate = [[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 -
[[tau].sub.p])[[tau].sub.p](n + 1]
When n >0, marginal tax rates on both categories of income are
greater than the corresponding average tax rates. Notice that the
business tax schedule exhibits progressivity only indirectly via the
double taxation of business income.
Public Expenditures
The government sets the tax code parameters [[tau].sub.p],
[[tau].sub.b], n, [eta], [[phi].sub.k], [[phi].sub.h] and [alpha] to
finance a required level of per capita public expenditure [G.sub.t]. We
assume that [G.sub.t] does not contribute to either production or
household utility. The government budget constraint is given by
(17) [G.sub.t] = [[tau].sub.pt][[w.sub.t][H.sub.t]([L.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t]) - [D.sub.t] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b]) x ([r.sub.t][K.sub.t]
- [[phi].sub.k][I.sub.kt] - [[phi].sub.h][I.sub.ht])] +
[[tau].sub.b]([r.sub.t][K.sub.t] - [[phi].sub.k][I.sub.kt] -
[[phi].sub.h][I.sub.ht]).
For simplicity, our specification imposes a period-by-period
balanced budget. Per capita public expenditures are assumed to increase
in fixed proportion to the average level of income in the economy, such
that [G.sub.t] = [psi][Y.sub.t] where [psi][greater than or equal to]0.
This formulation ensures that public expenditures remain a significant
fraction of output as the economy grows. (10)
Consumption and Flat Taxes
The tax base under the current U.S. system is best described as a
hybrid between income and consumption such that
[[phi].sub.k],[[phi].sub.h] [member of] (0,1). If we impose
[[phi].sub.k] = [[phi].sub.h] = 1 together with [[tau].sub.p] =
[[tau].sub.b] = [tau] and n = [eta] = 0, then the tax system is
equivalent to one that taxes consumption at the rate [[tau.sub.c] =
[tau]/(1 - [tau]). (11) The Hall-Rabushka (1995) flat tax is sometimes
referred to as a consumption tax. However, as noted by Judd (1998), the
Hall-Rabushka plan calls for full expensing of new investment in
physical capital ([[phi].sub.k] = 1) but contains no provisions to
ensure equivalent treatment of human capital. Expenditures by
individuals on education would not be deductible from taxable income
under the Hall-Rabushka plan. In contrast, the Nunn-Dominici unlimited
saving allowance tax proposal (for details see Weidenbaum 1996) includes
a limited deduction for family expenditures on college tuition,
vocational training, or remedial education. We model a HallRabushka-type
flat tax by imposing [[phi].sub.k] = 1, [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] =
[tau], and n = [eta] = 0, while holding [[phi].sub.h] unchanged at its
prereform value.
It is important to recognize that a flat tax (or a pure consumption
tax) can still exhibit features that are considered progressive. The
crucial element that governs the progressivity of a flat tax is the
level of the standard deduction [D.sub.t]. To see this, consider an
alternative tax rate defined as total taxes paid [T.sub.t] divided by
gross pretax income [y.sub.t]. Using equations (3) and (11) with the
flat tax parameter settings [[phi].sub.k] = 1, [[tau].sub.p] =
[[tau].sub.b] = [tau], and n = [eta] = 0 yields
(18) [T.sub.t]/[y.sub.t] = [tau](1 - [i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t] -
[[phi].sub.h] [i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.i] - [D.sub.t]/[y.sub.t]).
If we assume that the standard deduction is held fixed at a
specific dollar amount D (as is the case under the U.S. tax code), then
the ratio D/[y.sub.t] declines as real income y, rises. If we further
assume that the ratios [i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t] and [i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.t]
remain constant (as they do under balanced growth), then equation (18)
says that the tax rate [T.sub.t]/[y.sub.t] will rise with income. In
other words, households with higher incomes will face higher tax
rates--a feature that is progressive.
In our model, the standard deduction is not held fixed but instead
rises with the average level of income, as given by equation (12). This
formulation ensures that the standard deduction continues to represent a
significant fraction of income as the economy grows over time.
Substituting equation (12) into equation (18) yields
(19) [T.sub.t]/[y.sub.t] = [tau](1 - [i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t] -
[[phi].sub.h] [i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.t] - [alpha][Y.sub.t]/[y.sub.t]),
which shows that households with aboveaverage incomes ([y.sub.t]
> [Y.sub.t]) continue to face higher tax rates than those with
below-average incomes ([y.sub.t] < [Y.sub.t]), even under a flat tax
(again assuming that the ratios [i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t] and
[i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.t] remain constant).
III. INCENTIVE EFFECTS OF THE TAX SYSTEM
In this section, we show how the tax system affects various aspects
of the equilibrium.
Equilibrium Decision Rules
In the appendix, we show that standard techniques yield the
following closed-form expressions for the equilibrium decision rules:
(20) [i.sub.kt] = [a.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.k])[y.sub.t],
[[tau].sub.k] [equivalent to] (1 - [phi].sub.k]) x [[tau].sub.b] +
[eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p](n + 1)] /{1 -
[[phi].sub.k][[[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b]) [[tau].sub.p](n +
1)]},
(21) [i.sub.ht] = [b.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.h])[y.sub.t],
[[tau].sub.h] [equivalent to] {(n + 1)[[tau].sub.p] -
[[phi].sub.h][[[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p] (n +
1)]}/{1 - [[phi].sub.h][[[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])
[[tau].sub.p](n + 1)]},
(22) [c.sub.t] = {1 - [[tau].sub.p](1 - [phi] - [alpha]) -
[phi][[[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.b]] - [a.sub.0]
(1 - [[tau].sub.k]) x [1 - [[phi].sub.k]([[tau].sub.b] + [eta] (1 -
[[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p])] - [b.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.h]) x [1 -
[[phi].sub.h]([[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])
[[tau].sub.p])]}[y.sub.t],
(23) ([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]) = [A.sub.3][{[1 - [[tau].sub.p](n +
1)] x [([h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]).sup.[phi]}.sup.1/([phi]+[gamma]-1)],
(24) [e.sub.t] = [A.sub.3][A.sub.4][{[1 - [[tau].sub.p](n + 1)] x
[([h.sub.t]]/[k.sub.t]).sup.[phi]}.sup.1/([phi]+[gamma]-1),
where [a.sub.0], [b.sub.0], [A.sub.3], and [A.sub.4] represent
combinations of deep parameters, and [y.sub.t] is equilibrium per capita
output (or income). By substituting equation (23) into equation (8), we
obtain the following expression for equilibrium per capita output:
(25) [y.sub.t] = [A.sub.0][A.sup.1-[phi].sub.3][k.sup.[phi][gamma]
/([phi]+[gamma]-1).sub.t][h.sup.(1-[phi])([gamma]-1)/([phi]+
[gamma]-1).sub.t] x [[1 - [[tau].sub.p](n + 1)].sup.(1-[phi])
/([phi]+[gamma]-1)].
Private-sector investment depends on the effective marginal tax
rates [[tau].sub.k] and [[tau].sub.h], which combine the statutory tax
code parameters [[tau].sub.p], [[tau].sub.b], n, and [eta] with the
expensing parameters [[phi].sub.k] and [[phi].sub.h]. A pure consumption
tax implies [[tau].sub.k] = [[tau].sub.h] = 0. A labor supply distortion
will continue to exist, however, as long as [gamma] < [infinity]. As
[gamma][right arrow][infinity] this distortion will also be eliminated
making a consumption tax equivalent to a lump-sum tax. All else equal,
equation (25) implies that per capita output (or income) is a decreasing
function of the ratio [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t], a result that stems from the
labor decision rule (23). The labor decision rule says that time devoted
to market work declines as the household acquires more human capital
relative to physical capital. The education decision rule (24) exhibits
the same property. Intuitively, this occurs because higher levels of
human capital raise the opportunity cost of time that is not devoted to
leisure.
Transition Dynamics and Balanced Growth
The model's tractable nature allows us to characterize
explicitly the economy's dynamic transition path for any set of
initial conditions [k.sub.0] and [h.sub.0]. By substituting the decision
rules and the expression for equilibrium output (25) into the laws of
motion (5) and (6) we obtain
(26) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(27) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Our specification of a goods-producing technology (8) that exhibits
constant returns to scale in the two reproducible factors [k.sub.t] and
[h.sub.t], together with the functional forms (1), (5), and (6), imply
that the model possesses a unique balance growth path in which
[k.sub.t], [h.sub.t], [y.sub.t], [c.sub.t], [i.sub.kt], and [i.sub.kt]
all grow at the same constant rate. To derive an expression for the
balanced growth ratio R = [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t], we divide equation (27)
by equation (26) and impose R = [h.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1] =
[h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]. This procedure yields
(28) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The Per Capita Growth Rate
By taking log of equations (26) and (27), we obtain two equivalent
expressions for the per capita balanced growth rate [mu]:
(29) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(30) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where R is given by equation (28).
Equation (30) helps provide some insight into the robustness of
results reported in the literature regarding the effects of
distortionary taxes on long-run growth. Models that omit direct
investment of goods in human capital or assume fixed time allocations
will shutdown some channels through which tax policy can affect growth.
For example, Lucas (1990) finds that distortionary taxes have very small
growth effects in a model where the only inputs to the production of
human capital are [h.sub.t] and household time. This case corresponds to
our model with [[delta].sub.h] = 0. In the models of King and Rebelo
(1990) and Kim (1998), the humancapital inputs are [h.sub.t] and
[i.sub.ht]. This case corresponds to our model with v = 0. Our setup
adheres to a commonly used specification where the human capital inputs
are h.sub.t], [i.sub.ht] (or [k.sub.t]), and household time.
Revenue Neutrality
The flat-tax proposal of Hall and Rabushka is designed to be
revenue neutral. The intent of the plan is to improve economic
efficiency while leaving aside arguments about the appropriate size of
government. (12) Given that a tax reform can affect the trend growth
rate of all variables in our model, the concept of revenue neutrality
used here is a relative one. Specifically, we hold tax revenues fixed
relative to output. (13) Given that tax revenues must finance public
expenditures, according to [G.sub.t] = [psi][Y.sub.t], revenue
neutrality requires that [psi] remain unchanged as tax code parameters
are varied. By substituting equations (9), (10), (12), (20), and (21)
into equation (17) and then imposing the aggregate consistency
conditions, we obtain the following relationship among the tax code
parameters:
(31) [psi] = [[tau].sub.p](1 - [phi] - [alpha]) + [[[tau].sub.b] +
[eta](1 -[[tau].sub.b]) [[tau].sub.p]][[phi] - [a.sub.0][[phi].sub.k](1
- [[tau].sub.k]) - [b.sub.0][[phi].sub.h](1 - [[tau].sub.h])],
where the effective marginal tax rates [[tau].sub.k] and
[[tau].sub.h] are defined in equations (20) and (21). In our
experiments, a particular reform may cause any number of tax code
parameters to change simultaneously. Revenue neutrality is maintained by
adjusting [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] = [tau] under the new system
such that equation (31) is satisfied at the prereform value of [psi]. In
general, adopting a flat tax requires a higher average tax rate to pay
for the more generous expensing and deduction features and to compensate
for the loss of revenue from doing away with double taxation.
IV. CALIBRATION
Parameter values are chosen so that the model's balanced
growth path matches various characteristics identified from U.S. data.
For parameters that are important for the results, a range of values is
examined. A time period in the model is taken to be one year. We
calibrate the prereform tax system to resemble the hybrid
income-consumption tax system in the U.S. economy. As many authors have
noted, the current system already allows a significant portion of U.S.
saving to escape distortionary taxation.
It is well known that the behavior of dynamic tax models is
sensitive to assumptions about the labor supply elasticity. We therefore
consider the values [gamma] = 6, 3, and 2.25, which imply intertemporal
elasticities of substitution in labor supply of 0.2, 0.5, and 0.8,
respectively. These elasticities are in the range of values obtained
from empirical studies if one considers both males and females and
adjustments along both intensive and extensive margins (see Eissa 1996;
Mulligan 1999).
We choose [phi] = 0.36 to match the average share of capital income
in U.S. gross domestic product (GDP), as estimated by Poterba (1997).
The constants [A.sub.0], [A.sub.1], and [A.sub.2] are chosen to achieve
the calibration targets of [mu] = 1.80%, [k.sub.t]/[y.sub.t] = 2.61, and
[h.sub.t/[k.sub.t] = 13. Our measure of the U.S. physical capital stock
includes structures, equipment, consumer durables, and residential
components. Our target for [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t] is based on the Jorgenson
and Fraumeni (1989, table 5.33) capital stock estimates, which take into
account the imputed value of human capital in nonmarket activities, such
as school, leisure, or home production. (14)
The elasticity parameters [[delta].sub.k] and [[dalta].sub.h] are
chosen so that the model matches the U.S. average ratios of
[i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t] = 0.22 and [i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.t] = 0.025. Consistent
with our measure of physical capital, [i.sub.kt] includes structures,
equipment, consumer durables, and residential components. Our measure of
im includes private-sector expenditures on education, training, and
R&D. (15)
We choose the discount factor [beta] to achieve an after-tax
interest rate of 4% based on the estimates of Poterba (1997, table 1).
(16) The elasticity parameter v in the human capital technology and the
household preference parameter B are chosen to achieve the
balanced-growth time allocations of [e.sub.t] = 0.12 and
[l.sub.t]-[e.sub.t] = 0.17. These are the values estimated by Jones et
al. (1993) for the U.S. economy.
The tax code parameters [[tau].sub.p] and n are estimated from the
1994 U.S. tax schedule for married taxpayers with no children who file
IRS form 1040jointly. The tax schedule, taken from Mulligan (1997, table
5-2), displays 12 different tax brackets that derive from the combined
effects of the federal individual income tax, the earned income tax
credit, and employee and employer contributions to Social Security and
Medicare. The Hall-Rabushka proposal does not call for any changes to
Social Security or Medicare; the tax schedules for these programs are
already flat for the average taxpayer. Nevertheless, these programs
influence the slope of the prereform tax schedule. The marginal tax
brackets from Mulligan (1997) are used to construct an average personal
tax schedule, which is shown in Figure 1.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In Figure 2, we plot the U.S. average personal tax rate versus the
income ratio, which we define as personal taxable income divided by its
mean level. This ratio represents the empirical counterpart of the
expression inside the square brackets in equation (11). In constructing
Figure 2, we use a mean taxable income of $42,600, which is based on tax
return data from 1994. (17) Using 350 data points (one for each $1,000
of taxable income), we perform a nonlinear least squares regression of
the average personal tax rate on the corresponding income ratio. The
regression yields
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
(32) Average Personal Tax Rate = 0.2528[(Income Ratio).sup.0.2144].
Comparing the expression to equation (11) Implies [[tau].sub.p] =
0.2528 and n 0.2144. (18) Figure 2 shows that the fitted relationship is
close to the U.S. tax schedule for income ratios around 1.0 but flatter
than the U.S. tax schedule for income ratios below 0.8 and above 1.2.
This suggests that our calibration procedure yields a conservative
estimate of the growth benefits of adopting a flat tax. Our experiments
will examine the sensitivity of the computed growth effects to different
values of the prereform slope parameter n.
The tax code parameter a is calibrated by dividing the total dollar
amount of standard deductions taken in 1994 by U.S. GDP. This procedure
yields [alpha] = 0.056. (19) Following Hall and Rabushka (1995), we set
[[tau].sub.b] = 0.35 to match the statutory corporate tax rate. We set
[eta] = 1 to reflect double taxation of business income. We adopt
Auerbach's (1996, 51) estimate of [[tau].sub.k] = 0.16 to calibrate
the baseline value of [[phi].sub.k] because his estimate takes into
account the effective marginal tax rates for both residential and
nonresidential capital. (20) A difficult parameter to pin down is
[[phi].sub.h], which represents the fraction of private goods investment
in human capital that is tax deductible. Recall that our measure of
[i.sub.ht] includes private-sector expenditures on education, training,
and R&D. Privately funded R&D investment (which is tax
deductible) has averaged slightly more than 1% of GDP since 1954.
Private expenditures for education and training (which are mostly not
tax deductible) are roughly the same magnitude. We combine these
observations to come up with an estimate of [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5. Later,
we demonstrate that our quantitative results are not very sensitive to
changes in [[phi].sub.h].
Table 1 summarizes the results of the calibration exercise.
Substituting the tax code parameters into the expression for
[[tau].sub.h] in equation (21) yields [[tau].sub.h] = 0.044. With
[[tau].sub.k] = 0.160 and [[tau].sub.h] = 0.044, the baseline tax
structure is more favorable to human capital when it comes to private
goods investment. Substituting the tax code parameters into equation
(31) yields [psi] = 0.231, which says that public expenditures represent
about 23% of output in the model. The figure is close to the U.S.
average. The calibrated value of the marginal business tax rate in the
model is [[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p](n + 1) =
0.550. For comparison, McGrattan et al. (1997) report estimates of the
average marginal tax rate on capital income for the period 1947 to 1992
Their end-of-sample estimate is 0.482.
>From equation (5), Tobin's q in the model is given by
(33) q = ([differential][k.sub.t+1]/[differential]
[k.sub.t])/([differential][k.sub.t+1]/[differential][i.sub.kt] = (1 -
[[delta].sub.k])[i.sub.kt]/([delta].sub.k][k.sub.t]) = 1.39.
Eberly (1997, table 1) estimates Tobin's q using U.S.
firm-level data over the period 1981 to 1994. She obtains a mean
estimate of 1.56 and a median estimate of 1.18. Comparing these figures
to (33) suggests that our model provides a reasonable portrayal of U.S.
investment fundamentals.
The baseline parameters imply that untaxed forgone earnings
represent 95% of the total costs of producing human capital. (21) Only
about 3% of the total costs of producing human capital are not tax
deductible. (22) As a comparison, Clotfelter (1991, 72) estimates that
forgone earnings represent 49%-79% of college education costs (tuition,
room, board, and forgone earnings) for males and 41%-71% for females
over various two-year periods from 1969 to 1988. Dupor et al. (1996)
estimate an upper bound of 8% for the share of privately borne human
capital costs which are not tax deductible.
V. QUANTITATIVE RESULTS
Figures 3 through 8 summarize the results of our tax reform
experiments using the endogenous growth version of the model. To
construct these figures, we use equation (29) to compute the balanced
growth rate under the pre- and postreform tax systems. On the vertical
axis of each figure, we plot the change in long-run growth [DELTA][mu]
(in percentage points) that results from a sudden unannounced switch
from the existing graduated-rate tax system to a revenue-neutral flat
tax. We plot [DELTA][mu] for a range of values of the prereform slope
parameter n. The estimated U.S. value of n = 0.2144 is highlighted in
each figure. In addition, we plot [DELTA][mu] for three different values
of [gamma], which correspond to the labor supply elasticities,
[([gamma]-1).sub.-1] = {0.2, 0.5, 0.8}. For each value of n and [gamma]
in the figures, we recalibrate the other parameters of the model so that
the prereform economy continues to match the empirical facts described
in section IV.
[FIGURES 3-8 OMITTED]
Table 2 summarizes the identifying characteristics of the tax
systems that we consider.
Figure 3 depicts the results of our baseline reform experiment.
This reform captures many of the features of the Hall-Rabushka proposal,
such as equal tax rates applied to personal and business income
([[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] = [tau]), a flat tax schedule (n = 0), no
double taxation of business income ([eta] = 0), and full expensing of
physical capital investment ([[phi].sub.k] = 1). The standard deduction
parameter for this experiment is held fixed at its prereform value of
[alpha] = 0.056.
Figure 3 shows that as the prereform tax schedule becomes steeper
(n increases), the growth gains from adopting a flat tax become larger.
When n = 0.2144, the prereform tax structure matches the estimated
steepness of the U.S. tax schedule. At this point, the relevant
prerefonn tax rates are:
Average personal tax rate = [[tau].sub.p] = 0.253,
Marginal personal tax rate = [[tau].sub.p](n+1)=0.307,
Average business tax rate = [[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 -
[[tau].sub.b]) x [[tau].sub.p] = 0.514,
Marginal business tax rate = [[tau].sub.b] + q(1 - [[tau].sub.b]) x
[[tau].sub.p] (n + 1) = 0.550.
The postreform average and marginal tax rate is given by
[[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3437. Thus the baseline reform
lowers the marginal business tax rate but raises the marginal personal
tax rate. (23) When n=0.2144, the reform yields a growth gain of between
0.009 and 0.143 percentage points, depending on the elasticity of
household labor supply. A less elastic labor supply implies a smaller
growth gain because hours worked ([l.sub.t]-[e.sub.t]) and time in
school ([e.sub.t]) are both less sensitive to changes in the after-tax
wage. In shifting to a flat tax, hours worked increase by only 0.6%
(from 0.170 to 0.171) when the elasticity is 0.2, but increase by 2.3%
(from 0.170 to 0.174) when the elasticity is 0.8. In each case, time in
school increases by the same percentage as hours worked. These results
are consistent with the findings of other studies that show that the
growth effects of distortionary taxation are sensitive to assumptions
about the elasticity of household time allocations.
All of the reforms we consider exhibit relatively small growth
effects due to the form of the human capital technology where untaxed
forgone earnings represent the largest input to production. The computed
growth effects would have been even smaller if we had adopted a utility
function with more curvature than logarithmic, implying higher risk
aversion. Small growth effects from tax reform are consistent with the
findings of many authors, including Lucas (1990), Devereux and Love
(1994), and Stokey and Rebelo (1995). Nevertheless, it is important to
recognize that quantitative theoretical models cannot decide the
question of whether distortionary taxes have large or small growth
effects. The answers will always depend on the chosen form of the human
capital technology, the degree of risk aversion, and the values of other
key parameters, such as the labor supply elasticity. (24)
The far left in Figure 3 corresponds to n = 0 in the prereform tax
system. This point isolates the growth gains attributable to the other
(nonslope) features of the flat tax reform. The vertical intercept shows
that the combined effects of the other elements produces a negative
growth gain. We will elaborate further on this point in our discussion
of Figures 5 and 6.
Figures 4 through 6 illustrate variants of the baseline reform in
which a key element is not included. Figure 4 corresponds to a reform
that does not include full expensing of physical-capital investment.
Figure 5 corresponds to a reform that does not eliminate double taxation
of business income. Figure 6 corresponds to a reform that does not
flatten the personal tax schedule.
Comparing Figure 4 to Figure 3 shows that leaving out full
expensing of physical capital investment reduces the growth gain by only
a small amount. This is because the prereform value of [[phi].sub.k] =
0.844 (which derives from our calibration target of [[tau].sub.k] -
0.16) captures the fact that a large fraction of U.S. saving is done
through vehicles like pensions, retirement accounts, and 401(k) plans,
which already receive consumption tax treatment. The growth effect of
increasing 0k from 0.844 to 1.0 is small.
Figure 5 shows that a reform that does not eliminate double
taxation is actually beneficial for growth--provided the reform
continues to include full expensing of physical capital investment. The
intuition for this result is straightforward. From equation (20), we see
that setting [[phi].sub.k] = 1 yields [[tau].sub.k] = 0. This sharply
reduces the tax distortion to physical-capital investment although a tax
distortion still exists via the expression for [y.sub.t] in equation
(25). When [[phi].sub.k] = 1, double taxation of business income is a
low-distortion source of revenue that allows the government to implement
the reform with a lower postreform tax rate. (25) From Table 2, we see
that [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3169 for this tax reform,
which is the lowest postreform tax rate of all the experiments we
consider. The lower postreform tax rate leads to faster growth by
encouraging labor effort and time devoted to human capital accumulation.
Figure 6 shows that a reform that does not flatten the slope of the
personal tax schedule is harmful for growth. This is consistent with the
findings discussed earlier; the other elements of the reform shrink the
tax base and force the government to impose a higher postreform tax rate
to maintain revenue neutrality.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Figure 7 illustrates the growth effects of switching to a pure
consumption tax. The reform is accomplished by allowing full expensing
for both physical and human capital investment such that [[phi].sub.k] =
[[phi].sub.h] = 1. This experiment is aimed at investigating the
quantitative implications of the point made by Judd (1998) that the
Hall-Rabushka proposal is actually biased in favor of physical capital.
When n = 0.2144, Figure 7 shows that switching to a pure consumption tax
yields a long-run growth gain of between 0.031 and 0.156 percentage
points. Figure 3 shows that switching to a Hall-Rabushka type flat tax
yields a long-run growth gain of between 0.009 and 0.143 percentage
points. The long-run growth gains implied by the two reforms differ by
only about 0.02 percentage points. These similar outcomes are not
surprising given that nondeductible goods investment in human capital (1
- [[phi].sub.h])[i.sub.ht] accounts for only a small fraction of the
total costs of producing human capital in our model.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
In Figure 8, we allow the standard deduction parameter to change
from its prereform value of [alpha] = 0.056. The figure plots
[DELTA][mu] versus the ratio [[alpha].sub.new]/[[alpha].sub.old] where
[[alpha].sub.new] and [[alpha].sub.old] represent the standard deduction
parameters under the flat tax and the existing U.S. tax system,
respectively. We hold [[alpha].sub.old] fixed at 0.056 and allow
[[alpha].sub.new] to vary from 0 to 0.168. As the ratio
[[alpha].sub.new]/[[alpha].sub.old] increases, the growth gains become
smaller as revenue neutrality necessitates a higher postreform tax rate.
At the far right when [[alpha].sub.new]/[[alpha].sub.old] = 3, the
postreform tax rate is [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].sub.b] = [tau] = 0.4119.
At this point, adopting a flat tax reduces long-run growth. In general,
the desired features of progressivity that are achieved through a
more-generous standard deduction come at the cost of sacrificed growth
gains.
As a supplement to the information provided in the figures, Table 3
summarizes the balanced growth properties of the various tax systems for
the case of the intermediate labor supply elasticity, [([gamma] -
1).sub. -1] = 0.5.
Finally, Figure 9-12 compare the transition dynamics of the
endogenous and exogenous growth versions of the model. To compute the
transition paths for the exogenous growth model, we set [[delta].sub.h]
= v = 0 and [A.sub.2] = exp(0.018) = 1.018. All other parameters are
unchanged from before. Each simulation starts from the economy's
balanced growth path with [h.sub.0]/[k.sub.0] = 13. We choose h0 such
that per capita output [y.sub.t] is equal to 1.0 in the period preceding
the reform. Figures 9 and 10 depict the output and growth rate
trajectories for the baseline flat tax reform (shown earlier in Figure
3) with the intermediate labor supply elasticity, [([gamma] - 1).sub.
-1] = 0.5. Figures 11 and 12 depict the corresponding trajectories for
the reform with no change in the double taxation parameter [eta] (shown
earlier in Figure 5).
In Figures 9 and 10, we see that shifting to a flat tax initially
produces a growth slowdown in both the endogenous and exogenous growth
versions of the model. This is due to the immediate reaction of hours
worked and time in school to the higher postreform tax rate that is
needed to maintain revenue neutrality. The slowdown is only temporary,
however, because the reform's investment incentives eventually
cause the output trajectory to overtake the prereform trend after about
six years. Nevertheless, in the real-world, such an outcome could pose a
challenge to the political feasibility of the reform. If elected policy
makers are myopic relative to the average household, they may be
unwilling to endure a near-term growth slowdown to achieve the permanent
benefits of a flat tax. (26)
[FIGURE 9-10 OMITTED]
The simulations show that it takes a long time (about 100 years)
for the output trajectory of the endogenous growth model to overtake the
output trajectory of the exogenous growth model. The exogenous growth
model exhibits a temporary output advantage because households do not
need to divert resources to accumulate human capital. This allows
physical capital to be accumulated more quickly. Figure 10 shows that
adopting a flat tax produces a permanent growth gain in the endogenous
growth model but only a temporary growth gain (with a permanent level
shift) in the exogenous growth model. The transition dynamics of the
exogenous growth model turn out to be quite lengthy, however. Following
the adoption of a flat tax, it takes about 100 years for the economy to
return to its prereform growth rate. In the years immediately following
the reform, the economy's output trajectory is quite similar to
that of the endogenous growth model.
In Figures 11 and 12, we see that a reform that does not eliminate
double taxation of business income produces a milder slowdown in the
periods immediately following the adoption of the reform. This result is
consistent with our earlier discussion; double taxation is beneficial
for growth when combined with full investment expensing. The simulations
show that it now takes less time (about 20 years) for the output
trajectory of the endogenous growth model to overtake the output
trajectory of the exogenous growth model.
[FIGURE 11-12 OMITTED]
A quantitative summary of the transition paths is presented in
Table 4.
VI. CONCLUSION
This article developed a simple theoretical framework to assess the
growth effects of shifting from a graduated-rate tax system to a flat
tax. The model captures the incentive effects of rising marginal tax
rates on household decisions to consume, work, learn, and invest. These
decisions, in turn, influence the rate of economic growth. Our baseline
reform experiment predicts that a revenue-neutral flat tax can
permanently increase per capita growth by 0.009 to 0.143 percentage
points per year relative to a graduated-rate tax system calibrated to
match features of the U.S. tax code. The flattening of the marginal tax
schedule is the most important element of the reform for enhancing
growth. Allowing full expensing of physical capital investment
contributes only a small amount to the overall growth gain. The
elimination of double taxation of business income is actually harmful
for growth when combined with the full expensing provision.
Although our model is admittedly an abstract and simplified
representation of the vastly complex U.S. tax code, we believe it
provides some useful insight into the potential growth benefits of
currently proposed tax reforms. By imposing the discipline of general
equilibrium, we have attempted to take into account the macroeconomic repercussions that may be induced by a major overhaul of the U.S. tax
system. Some important caveats regarding the interpretation of our
results are in order, however. First, although our model provides a
theoretical framework for evaluating claims regarding the growth
benefits of adopting a flat tax, the empirical evidence regarding the
links between tax policy and long-run growth is somewhat inconclusive.
(27) Second, our results, like those of Stokey and Rebelo (1995), show
that the growth effects of distortionary taxes are sensitive to the
choice of parameter values. In particular, the labor supply elasticity
has a substantial impact on the growth implications of the reform.
Third, because our model abstracts from stochastic shocks, we allow no
role for the tax code in providing implicit insurance against income
uncertainty. (28) Fourth, our model assumes that all households are
identical and therefore cannot be used to address distributional issues.
(29) That said, the model and tax reform characteristics that we have
identified as important for determining the magnitude of the growth
effects will also be present in more complicated frameworks.
ABBREVIATIONS
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
R&D: Research and Development
APPENDIX
This appendix outlines the derivation of the equilibrium household
decision rules. The Lagrangian for the household's problem can be
written as
(A1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.],
where [[lambda].sub.t] is the Lagrange multiplier associated with
the household budget constraint (2). To conserve space, we have not
substituted out [i.sub.kt] and [i.sub.ih] using equations (5) and (6).
We make use of these substitutions to derive the following first-order
conditions with respect to the indicated variables:
(A2a) [k.sub.t+1]: [[lambda].sub.t] [1 - [[phi].sub.k]
[[tau].sub.h] - [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[phi].sub.k][[tau].sub.pt] (n +
1)][i.sub.kt]/([[delta].sub.k][k.sub.t+1] = [beta][[lambda].sub.t+1] {[1
- [[tau].sub.b] - [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b][[tau].sub.pt] x 9n + 1)
[r.sub.t+1] + [1 - [[phi].sub.k][[tau].sub.b] - [eta](1 + [[tau].sub.b])
[[phi].sub.k] x [[tau].sub.pt+1](n + 1)](1 + [[delta].sub.k])
[i.sub.kt+1]/([delta].sub.k][k.sub.t+1])},
(A2b) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.],
(A2c) (c.sub.t) : [[lambda].sub.t] = 1/([c.sub.t] - B[h.sub.t]
[l.sup.[gamma].sub.t]),
(A2d) [l.sub.t] : [[lambda].sub.t][1 - [[tau].sub.pt](n +
1)][w.sub.t] [h.sub.t] =
B[gamma][h.sub.t][l.sup.[gamma]-1.sub.t]/[c.sub.t] - B[h.sub.t]
[l.sup.[gamma].sub.t],
(A2e) [e.sub.t] : [1 - [[tau].sub.pt](n + 1)][w.sub.t][h.sub.t] =
[1 - [[phi].sub.h][[tau].sub.b] -[eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[phi].sub.h]
[[tau].sub.pt](n + 1)]v[i.sub.ht]/([[delta].sub.h][e.sub.t]),
where [[tau].sub.pt], is given by equation (11). The transversality conditions are [lim.sub.t[right arrow][infinity]]
[[beta].sup.t][[lambda].sub.t] [k.sub.t+1] = 0 and [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]. The first term on the right side
of equation (A2b) shows that households take into account the influence
of human capital on the amount of quality-adjusted leisure. In
particular, higher levels of human capital will raise the opportunity
cost of time that is not devoted to leisure.
The equilibrium decision rules are obtained using the method of
undetermined coefficients. To solve for the decision rules, we first
impose the aggregate consistency conditions [H.sub.t] = [h.sub.t],
[L.sub.t] = [l.sub.t], [E.sub.t] = [e.sub.t], [K.sub.t] = [k.sub.t],
[I.sub.kt] = [i.sub.kt], and [I.sub.ht] = [i.sub.ht]. These conditions
imply [[tau].sub.pt] = [[tau].sub.p] for all t. We make the conjecture that the decision rules take the form:
(A3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.],
(A4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.],
(A5) [[lambda].sup.-1.sub.t] = [d.sub.0][y.sub.t],
(A6) ([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t) = [f.sub.0][l.sub.t],
where [a.sub.0], [b.sub.0], [d.sub.0], and [f.sub.0] are constants
to be determined, and [y.sub.t] is equilibrium per capita output. By
substituting the conjectured decision rules and the profit maximization
conditions (9) and (10) into the first-order conditions for [k.sub.t+1]
and [h.sub.t+1] and also making use of equations (A2c) and (A2d), we
obtain
(A7) [a.sub.0] = [theta][[delta].sub.k]/([rho] + [[delta].sub.k]),
(A8) [b.sub.0] = (1 - [theta)[[delta].sub.h][1 +
([gamma][f.sub.0]).sup.-1]]/([rho] + [[delta].sub.,
where [rho] [equivalent to] 1/[beta] the household's rate of
time preference.
Substituting the expression for [w.sub.t]= from equation (10) into
the first-order condition (A2e) and then making use of equations (A4),
(A6), and (A8) yields
(A9) [f.sub.o] = ([rho] + [[delta].sub.h] + v/[gamma])/([rho] +
[[delta].sub.h] + v).
Substituting equation (A9) back into equation (A8) and solving for
[b.sub.0] yields
(A10) [b.sub.0] = (1 - [theta])[[delta].sub.h](1 - [[gamma].sup.-1]
/(p + [[delta].sub.h]+v/[gamma]).
A convenient property of the utility function (1) is that It can be
solved for independently of the marginal utility of income [lambda].
Substituting the expression for [w.sub.t] from equation (10) into the
first-order condition for [l.sub.t] and then making use of equations
(A2c), (A6), and (A9) yields
(A11) [l.sub.t] = [{[A.sub.0](1 - [theta])(B[gamma]).sup.-1][1 +
v(1 - [[gamma].sup.-1])/([rho] + [[delta].sub.h] + v/[gamma])][theta] [1
- [[tau].sub.p](n + t)] x [([h.sub.i]/[k.sub.t]).sup.-[theta]]
s}.sup.1/([theta]+[gamma]-1]
Equation (A11) can now be used to solve for ([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]
and [e.sub.r using the conjectured relationships ([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t])
= [f.sub.o][l.sub.t] and [e.sub.t] = ([f.sup.-1.sub.0] - 1)([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t]). The results are
(A12) ([l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]) = [A.sub.3][{[1 - [[tau].sub.p](n +
1)] ([h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]).sup.-[theta]}.sup.1/([theta]+[gamma]-1),
A3 [equivalent to] {[A.sub.0](1 - [theta][(B[gamma]).sup.-1] [[1 +
v(1 - [[gamma].sup.-1])/([rho] + [[delta].sub.h] +
v/[gamma])].sup.1-[gamma]]}.sup.1/([theta]+[gamma]-1)],
(A13) [e.sub.t] = [A.sub.3][A.sub.4][{[1 - [[tau].sub.p](n + 1)]
[([h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]).sup.-[theta]]}.sup.1/([theta]+[gamma]-1)],
[A.sub.4] [equivalent to] v(1 - [[gamma].sup.-1])/([rho] +
[[delta].sub.h] + v/[gamma]).
To obtain equilibrium consumption, we substitute the investment
decision rules (A3) and (A4) and the profit maximization conditions (9)
and (10) into the household budget constraint (2). After collecting
terms, this procedure yields
(A14) ct = {1 - [[tau].sub.p](1 - [theta] - [alpha]) - [theta]
[[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p] - [a.sub.0] (1 -
[[tau].sub.k][1 - [[phi].sub.k]([[tau].sub.b] + [eta] (1 -
[[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p])] - [b.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.h] [1 -
[[phi].sub.h]([[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])
[[tau].sub.p])]}[y.sub.t].
The next step is to verify that the conjectured forms of equations
(A3)-(A6) are correct by showing that [d.sub.0] is in fact constant. We
use the first-order condition for [c.sub.t] to obtain
(A15) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.],
where the second equality replaces B[h.sub.t][l.sup.[gamma].sub.t]
by an equivalent expression that is obtained by combining equations
(A2c) and (A2d). Substituting the consumption decision rule (A14) into
the expression and solving for [d.sub.0] yields
(A16) [d.sub.0] = 1 - [[tau].sub.p](1 + [theta] - [alpha]) -
[theta][[tau].sub.n] + [eta](1 + [[tau].sub.b][[tau].sub.p]} -
[a.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.k]{1 - [[phi].sub.k][[tau].sub.b] + [eta] (1 -
[[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p]]} - [b.sub.0](1 - [[tau].sub.h] {1 -
[[phi].sub.k][[tau].sub.b] + [eta](1 - [[tau].sub.b])[[tau].sub.p]]} -
[(0 - [theta])/([gamma][f.sub.0])][1 - [[tau].sub.p](n + 1)],
which is a constant and thus verifies our conjecture.
TABLE 1
Calibrated Parameter Values
Labor Supply
Elasticity
Parameter 0.2 0.5 0.8 Empirical Fact to Match
[gamma] 6.000 3.000 2.250 Labor supply elasticity
[theta] 0.360 0.360 0.360 Average share of physical
capital in output = 0.36
[A.sub.0] 0.231 0.231 0.231 Average per capita output
growth [mu] = 1.80%
[A.sub.1] 1.173 1.173 1.173 Average [k.sub.t]/[y.sub.t]
= 2.61
[A.sub.2] 1.078 1.123 1.233 Average [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.k]
= 13
[[delta].sub.k] 0.057 0.057 0.057 Average [i.sub.kt]/[y.sub.t]
= 0.22
[[delta].sub.h] 0.001 0.002 0.004 Average [i.sub.ht]/[y.sub.t]
= 0.025
v 0.022 0.039 0.075 Fraction of time in school
or training [e.sub.t]
= 0.12
B 6.248 0.305 0.161 Fraction of time in market
work ([l.sub.t] -
[e.sub.t]) = 0.17
[beta] 0.979 0.979 0.979 After-tax interest rate = 4%
[[tau].sub.p] 0.253 0.253 0.253 Fitted value from 1994 U.S.
tax schedule
n 0.214 0.214 0.214 Fitted value from 1994 U.S.
tax schedule
[alpha] 0.056 0.056 0.056 Ratio of 1994 U.S. standard
deductions to GDP
[eta] 1.000 1.000 1.000 Double taxation of business
income
[[tau].sub.b] 0.350 0.350 0.350 Statutory corporate tax rate
[[phi].sub.k] 0.844 0.844 0.844 Effective marginal capital
tax rate [[tau].sub.k] = 0.16
[[phi].sub.h] 0.500 0.500 0.500 Fraction of tax-deductible
goods investment in human
capital
TABLE 2
Characteristics of the Tax Systems
Tax Code
Parameter
Tax System Values
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) [[tau].sub.p] 0.253,
[[tau].sub.p] = 0.350 n=0.214
Baseline fat tax reform [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3427 n=0
Reform with no change in [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
[[phi].sub.k] sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3174 n=0
Reform with no change in [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
[eta] sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3169 n=0
Reform with no change in n [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3431 n=0.214
Pure consumption tax reform [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
sub.b] = [tau] = 0.3520 n=0
Reform with change in [[tau].sub.p] = [[tau].
[alpha] sub.b] = [tau] [??]
0.3437 n=0
Tax System Tax Code Parameter Values
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) [eta] = 1 [[phi].sub.k] = 0.844
Baseline fat tax reform [eta] = 0 [[phi].sub.k] = 1
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] [eta] = 0 [[phi].sub.k] = 0.844
Reform with no change in
[eta] [eta] = 1 [[phi].sub.k] = 1
Reform with no change in n [eta] = 0 [[phi].sub.k] = 1
Pure consumption tax reform [eta] = 0 [[phi].sub.k] = 1
Reform with change in
[alpha] [eta] = 0 [[phi].sub.k] = 1
Tax System Tax Code Parameter Values
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] = 0.056
Baseline fat tax reform [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] = 0.056
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] = 0.056
Reform with no change in
[eta] [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] = 0.056
Reform with no change in n [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] = 0.056
Pure consumption tax reform [[phi].sub.h] = 1 [alpha] = 0.056
Reform with change in
[alpha] [[phi].sub.h] = 0.5 [alpha] [??] 0.056
TABLE 3
Balanced-Growth Properties of Tax Systems with Intermediate Labor
Supply Elasticity
Tax System Tax Rate [mu] %
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) [[tau].sub.t]=0.253 1.800
[[tau].sub.b]=0.35
Baseline flat tax reform [tau] = 0.3437 1.857
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] [tau] = 0.3174 1.854
Reform with no change in
[eta] [tau] = 0.3169 1.953
Reform with no change in n [tau] = 0.3431 1.638
Pure consumption tax reform [tau] = 0.3520 1.878
Reform with [[alpha].sub.new]
/[[alpha].sub.old]=3 [tau] = 0.4119 1.660
[c.sub.t]/ [i.sub.kt]/ [i.sub.ht]/
Tax System [y.sub.t] [y.sub.t] [y.sub.t]
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) 0.524 0.220 0.025
Baseline flat tax reform 0.487 0.262 0.021
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] 0.504 0.244 0.021
Reform with no change in
[eta] 0.483 0.262 0.024
Reform with no change in n 0.489 0.262 0.018
Pure consumption tax reform 0.481 0.262 0.026
Reform with [[alpha].sub.new]
/[[alpha].sub.old]=3 0.488 0.262 0.019
[k.sub.t]/ [h.sub.t]/ [l.sub.t]/
Tax System [y.sub.t] [k.sub.t] [e.sub.t]
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) 2.61 13.0 0.170
Baseline flat tax reform 3.08 9.86 0.173
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] 2.87 11.0 0.173
Reform with no change in
[eta] 3.02 9.98 0.176
Reform with no change in n 3.20 9.75 0.165
Pure consumption tax reform 3.06 10.0 0.172
Reform with [[alpha].sub.new]
/[[alpha].sub.old]=3 3.18 9.78 0.166
Tax System [e.sub.t]
Graduated-rate system (U.S.) 0.120
Baseline flat tax reform 0.122
Reform with no change in
[[phi].sub.k] 0.122
Reform with no change in
[eta] 0.124
Reform with no change in n 0.117
Pure consumption tax reform 0.121
Reform with [[alpha].sub.new]
/[[alpha].sub.old]=3 0.117
Notes: The computations assume [gamma]=3 such that
[([gamma]-1).sup.-1]=0.5. The remaining nontax parameters are shown in
the middle column of Table 1. [mu]=per capita output growth rate,
[[tau].sub.k]=effective tax rate for physical capital investment,
[[tau].sub.h]=effective tax rate for human capital investment,
[c.sub.t]/[y.sub.t]=ratio of consumption to output, [i.sub.kt]/
[[y.sub.t]=ratio of physical capital investment to output, [i.sub.kt]/
[y.sub.t]=ratio of human capital investment to output, [k.sub.t]/
[y.sub.t]=ratio of physical capital stock to output, [h.sub.t]/
[k.sub.t]=ratio of human to physical capital stocks, [l.sub.t]-
[e.sub.t]=fraction of time spent in working, [e.sub.t]=fraction of
time spent in school/training.
TABLE 4
Transition Paths for Selected Reforms with Intermediate Labor Supply
Elasticity
Year log [k.sub.t]/ [h.sub.t]/
([y.sub.t]/ [y.sub.t] [k.sub.t]
[y.sub.t-1])
(%)
Graduated-
rate system
(U.S.) 0 1.800 2.61 13.0
Baseline flat
tax reform
(endogenous
growth
model) 1 0.324 2.65 13.0
5 2.114 2.71 12.5
10 2.068 2.77 12.0
50 1.902 3.01 10.3
[infinity] 1.857 3.08 9.86
Baseline flat
tax reform
(exogenous
growth
model) 1 0.324 2.65 13.0
5 2.180 2.70 12.6
10 2.125 2.76 12.1
50 1.892 3.00 10.3
[infinity] 1.800 3.11 9.69
Reform with
no change
in [eta]
(endogenous
growth
model) 1 1.410 2.62 13.0
5 2.200 2.67 12.5
10 2.157 2.73 12.0
50 1.997 2.96 10.4
[infinity] 1.954 3.02 9.98
Reform with
no change
in [eta]
(exogenous
growth
model) 1 1.410 2.62 13.0
5 2.206 2.67 12.5
10 2.147 2.73 12.0
50 1.898 3.00 10.2
[infinity] 1.800 3.11 9.49
[l.sub.t]/ [e.sub.t]
[e.sub.t]
Graduated-
rate system
(U.S.) 0.170 0.120
Baseline flat
tax reform
(endogenous
growth
model) 0.166 0.117
0.167 0.118
0.168 0.119
0.172 0.122
0.173 0.122
Baseline flat
tax reform
(exogenous
growth
model) 0.166 0.117
0.167 0.118
0.168 0.119
0.172 0.121
0.174 0.123
Reform with
no change
in [eta]
(endogenous
growth
model) 0.169 0.119
0.170 0.120
0.171 0.121
0.175 0.123
0.176 0.124
Reform with
no change
in [eta]
(exogenous
growth
model) 0.169 0.119
0.170 0.120
0.171 0.121
0.175 0.124
0.177 0.125
Notes: The computations assume [gamma]=3 such that
[([gamma] - 1).sup.-1]=0.5. The remaining nontax parameters are shown
in the middle column of Table 1. log([y.sub.t]/[y.sub.t-1])=per capita
output growth rate in year t, [k.sub.t]/[y.sub.t]=ratio of physical
capital stock to output, [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]=ratio of human to physical
capital stocks, [l.sub.t] - [e.sub.t]=fraction of time spent working,
[e.sub.t]=fraction of time spent in school/training.
(1.) For detailed descriptions and analyses of the various
proposals, see the two conference volumes Frontiers of Tax Reform
(Boskin 1996) and Economic Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform (Aaron and
Gale 1996), and two U.S. government publications: Joint Committee on
Taxation (1997) and U.S. Congressional Budget Office (1997).
(2.) A similar reform proposal was originally put forth by Friedman
(1962, 175).
(3.) Other research that examines the quantitative effects of tax
reform on long-run growth includes King and Rebelo (1990), Lucas (1990),
Rebelo (1991), Jones et al. (1993) Pecorino (1993; 1994), Devereux and
Love (1994), Laitner (1995), Milesi-Ferreni and Roubini (1998), Glomm
and Ravikumar (1998), Ortigueira (1998), Kim (1998), Cassou and Lansing
(2003), and Caucutt et al. (2003), among others.
(4.) Alternatively, we could model households as competitive
entrepreneurs that operate their own production technology. Under this
setup, we would replace [r.sub.t][k.sub.t] in equations (2)-(4) with the
term [y.sub.t] - [w.sub.t][h.sub.t] ([l.sub.t]-[e.sub.t]). The resulting
equilibrium decision rules would be identical to those derived here.
(5.) If business income was not paid out as dividends but instead
reinvested by the firm, then the household would accrue capital gains
from the resulting increase in the firm's stock price. Any realized
capital gains would also be subject to a second round of taxation at the
personal level.
(6.) The investment tax credit for equipment was abolished by the
Tax Reform Act of 1986.
(7.) For further details on the tax treatment of human capital, see
Quigley and Smolensky (1990) and Steurle (1996).
(8.) Kim (2003) shows that equation (5) can be viewed as a special
case of a more general specification where [k.sub.t+1] = [A.sub.1][[(1 -
[delta].sub.k])[k.sup.1-[sigma].sub.t] +
[[delta].sub.k][([i.sub.kt]/[[delta].sub.k]).sup.1-[sigma]]].sup.1
/(1-[sigma]). Our setup implies [sigma] = 1, whereas a linear law of
motion with no adjustment costs would imply [sigma] = 0. Aside from
reflecting adjustment costs, our setup can be viewed as capturing the
behavior of an aggregate stock that is measured by adding up different
types of capital (structures, equipment, consumer durables, residential)
that each display different depreciation characteristics.
(9.) Guo and Lansing (1998) employ a simplified version of equation
(11) to study government stabilization policy.
(10.) Cassou and Lansing (2003) show that the common practice of
modeling public expenditures as entirely wasteful (as opposed to
providing utility) can lead to a substantial downward bias in the
computed welfare gain from a growth-enhancing tax reform if these
wasteful expenditures are held fixed relative to the size of the economy
(as we do here). Our formulation for [G.sub.t] does not pose any
problems for the present analysis because we are only interested in
computing the growth and level effects of the tax reform, not welfare
effects.
(11.) In this case, the equilibrium version of the household budget
constraint (2) can be written as: [c.sub.t] + [[tau].sub.c]([c.sub.t] -
[D.sub.t]) + [i.sub.kt] + [i.sub.ht] = [Y.sub.t], where ([c.sub.t] -
[D.sub.t]) represents taxable consumption expenditures.
(12.) Cassou and Lansing (2003) show that the appropriate size of
government can be an important factor in determining the welfare gains
from fundamental tax reform.
(13.) Altig et al. (2001) employ a similar definition of revenue
neutrality by holding tax revenues fixed when measured in effective
units of labor. In our model, effective labor is given by hi ([l.sub.t]
- [e.sub.t]), which grows at the same rate as output along the
economy's balanced growth path.
(14.) Studies that restrict their attention to market activities
obtain estimates of [h.sub.t]/[k.sub.t] [approximately equal to] 3. See
Davies and Whalley (1991, appendix) for a review of various studies that
estimate the aggregate value of human capital.
(15.) Private expenditures on education are from the Citibase
series GAESE. R&D expenditure data are from National Patterns of
R&D Resources: 1994, National Science Foundation (1995), table B-15
and p. 10. Physical capital and investment data are from Fixed
Reproducible Tangible Wealth in the United States, U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis (1998).
(16.) The after-tax interest rate r is defined by introducing
privately issued real bonds (which exist in zero net supply) into the
household budget constaint. The balanced-growth version of the
first-order condition for bonds implies r = exp([mu] - log[beta]) - 1.
(17.) There were 42,228,108 joint returns filed in 1994, which
accounted for a total taxable income of $1,800,054,965,000. Dividing the
second number by the first yields a mean taxable income across all joint
returns of $42,627. See U.S. Internal Revenue Service (1997, table 1,
25).
(18.) Gouveia and Strauss (1994) estimate U.S. average personal tax
rates from 1979 to 1989 using a functional form that employs three
parameters: Average Personal Tax Rate = b{1 - [[s[(Economic
Income).sup.p] + 1].sup.-1/p}, where Economic Income is expressed in
thousands of dollars. In our model, this specification would cause the
asymptotic average and marginal tax rates to both equal b, because
household income grows over time.
(19.) In 1994, total standard deductions were $397.1 billion. See
U.S. Internal Revenue (1997, table 7, 197).
(20.) An alternative calibration strategy would be to choose
[[phi].sub.k] such that the magnitude of expensed investment
[[phi].sub.k][i.sub.kt] coincides with a measure of capital depreciation
[delta][k.sub.t] where a standard linear law of motion for physical
capital would imply [delta] = 1 - exp([mu]) + [i.sub.k]/k. Given the
U.S. value of [i.sub.k]/k = 0.084, the alternative calibration strategy
would yield [[phi].sub.k] = 0.785 and [[tau].sub.k] = 0.208. Use of
these values would increase the growth gain of adopting a flat tax by
about 0.01 to 0.04 percentage points.
(21.) Forgone earnings are given by [w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t].
The total costs of producing human capital are given by
[w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t] + [i.sub.ht]. For our calibration,
[w.sub.t][h.sub.t] [e.sub.t]/([w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t] + [i.sub.ht])
= 0.948.
(22.) The total costs of producing human capital are given by
([w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t] + [i.sub.ht]). The nontax-deductible
portion of these costs are given by (1 - [[phi].sub.h])[i.sub.ht]. For
our calibration (1 -
[[phi].sub.h])[i.sub.ht]/([w.sub.t][h.sub.t][e.sub.t] + [i.sub.ht]) =
0.026.
(23.) In 1994 about two-thirds of U.S. taxpayers faced a federal
income tax rate of 15%. If there was no change in the standard deduction
(as we assume in the baseline reform experiment) then these taxpayers
would have experienced an increase in their marginal tax rate under the
Hall-Rabushka proposal, which specifies a flat tax rate of 19 percent.
See Hall and Rabushka (1996, 44).
(24.) In an earlier version of this article (Cassou and Lansing
1996), we showed that it is possible to obtain much larger long-run
growth effects using a model with log utility and an Arrow-Romer-type
spillover mechanism for human capital accumulation. This type of human
capital technology involves no forgone earnings.
(25.) A related result is obtained by Guo and Lansing (1997). They
show that an accelerated depreciation allowance combined with a positive
tax rate applied to all capital-type income is a low-distortion source
of revenue because it can partially confiscate economic profits.
(26.) Arrow and Kurz (1970) consider the possibility of futurity
divergence between the policy maker and private agents and discuss the
implications for fiscal policy.
(27.) Padovano and Galli (2001) find that measures of effective
marginal tax rates are negatively correlated with growth in a panel of
23 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
countries from 1950 to 1990. They argue that most previous studies
employ measures of effective average tax rates. This poses problems of
collinearity with government expenditures that may either enhance or
retard growth. A similar point is made by Kneller et al. (1999), who
find that distortionary taxation reduces growth in a study of 22 OECD
countries from 1970 to 1995.
(28.) See Eaton and Rosen (1980) and Hamilton (1987) for models
that address this issue.
(29.) Altig et al. (2001) and Ventura (1999) consider the
distributional consequences of tax reform in life-cycle models.
REFERENCES
Aaron, H. J., and W. G. Gale (eds.). Economic Effects of
Fundamental Tax Reform. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press,
1996.
Altig, D., A. J. Auerbach, L. J. Kotlikoff, K. A. Smetters, and J.
Walliser. "Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the United
States." American Economic Review, 91, 2002, 574-95.
Arrow, K. J., and M. Kurz. Public Investment, The Rate of Return,
and Optimal Fiscal Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1970.
Auerbach, A. J. "Tax Reform, Capital Accumulation, Efficiency,
and Growth," in Economic Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform, edited
by H. J. Aaron and W. G. Gale. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
Press, 1996, 29-73.
Becker, G. S. "A Theory of the Allocation of Time."
Economic Journal, 75, 1965, 493-517.
Boskin, M. J. "Notes on the Tax Treatment of Human
Capital," in Conference on Tax Research 1975. Washington, DC:
Office of Tax Analysis, Department of the Treasury, 1977.
Boskin, M. J. (ed.). Frontiers of Tax Reform. Stanford, CA: Hoover
Institution Press, 1996.
Cassou, S. P., and K. J. Lansing. "Growth Effects of a Flat
Tax." Working Paper 9615. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 1996.
--. "Tax Reform with Useful Public Expenditures." Working
Paper 98-09. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 2003.
Caucutt, E. M., S. Imrohoroglu, and K. B. Kumar. "Growth and
Welfare Analysis of Tax Progressivity in a Heterogeneous-Agent
Model." Review of Economic Dynamics, 6, 2003, 546-77.
Clotfelter, C. T. "Demand for Undergraduate Education,"
in Economic Challenges in Higher Education, edited by C. T. Clotfelter,
R. G. Ehrenberg, M. Getz, and J. J. Siegfried. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1991, 17-139.
Davies, J., and J. Whalley. "Taxes and Capital Formation: How
Important Is Human Capital?" in National Saving and Economic
Performance, edited by B. D. Bernheim and J. B. Shaven. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1991, 163-97.
Devereux, M. B., and D. R. F. Love. "The Effects of Factor
Taxation in Two-Sector Model of Endogenous Growth." Canadian
Journal of Economies, 27, 1994, 509-36.
Dupor, B., L. Lochner, C. Taber, and M. B. Wittekind. "Some
Effects of Taxes on Schooling and Training." American Economics
Association Papers and Proceedings, 86, 1996, 340-46.
Eaton, J., and H. S. Rosen. "Taxation, Human Capital, and
Uncertainty." American Economic Review, 70, 1980, 705-15.
Eberly, J. C. International Evidence on Investment
Fundamentals," European Economic Review, 41, 1997, 1055 1078.
Eissa, N. "Tax Reforms and Labor Supply," in Tax Policy
and the Economy 10, edited by J. M. Poterba. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1996, 119-51.
Friedman, M. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1962.
Glomm, G., and B. Ravikumar. "Flat-Rate Taxes, Government
Spending on Education, and Growth." Review of Economic Dynamics, 1,
1998, 306-25.
Gouveia, M., and R. P. Strauss. "Effective Federal Individual
Income Tax Functions: An Exploratory Analysis." National Tax
Journal, 47, 1994, 317-39.
Greenwood, J., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright. "Household
Production in Real Business Cycle Theory," in Frontiers of Business
Cycle Research, edited by T. F. Cooley. Princeton, N J: Princeton
University Press, 1995. 157-74.
Guo, J., and K. J. Lansing. "Tax Structure and Welfare in a
Model of Optimal Fiscal Policy." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Economic Review, 33(1), 1997, 11-23.
--. "Indeterminacy and Stabilization Policy." Journal of
Economic Theory, 82, 1998. 481-90.
Hall, R. E., and A. Rabushka. The Flat Tax, 2nd ed. Stanford, CA:
Hoover Institution Press, 1995.
--. "The Flat Tax: A Simple, Progresssive Consumption
Tax," in Frontiers of Tax Reform, edited by M. Boskin. Stanford,
CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1996, 27-53.
Hamilton, J. H. "Optimal Wage and Income Taxation with Wage
Uncertainty." International Economic Review, 28, 1987, 373-88.
Heckman, J. J. "A Life-Cycle Model of Earnings, Learning, and
Consumption." Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1976, S11-S44.
Hercowitz, Z., and M. Sampson. "Output Growth, the Real Wage,
and Employment Fluctuations." American Economic Review, 81, 1991,
1215-37.
Joint Committee on Taxation. Joint Committee on Taxation Tax
Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, Series JCS-21-97.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1997.
Jones, L. E., R. Manuelli, and P. E. Rossi. "Optimal Taxation
in Models of Endogenous Growth." Journal of Political Economy, 101,
1993, 485-517.
Jorgenson, D. W., and B. M. Fraumeni. "The Accumulation of
Human and Nonhuman Capital, 1948 84," in The Measurement of Saving,
Investment, and Wealth, edited by R. E. Lipsey and H. S. Tice. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1989, 227-82.
Judd, K. L. "Taxes, Uncertainty, and Human Capital."
American Economies Association Papers and Proceedings', 88, 1998,
289-92.
Kim, J. "Functional Equivalence between Intertemporal and
Multisectoral Adjustment Costs." Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 27, 2003, 533-49.
Kim, S. "Growth Effect of Taxes in an Endogenous Growth Model:
To What Extent Do Taxes Affect Economic Growth?" Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 23, 1998, 125-58.
King, R. G., and S. Rebelo. "Public Policy and Economic
Growth: Developing Neoclassical Implications." Journal of Political
Economy, 98, 1990, S127-50.
Kneller, R., M. F. Bleany, and N. Gemmell. "Fiscal Policy and
Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries." Journal of Public Economics,
74, 1999, 171-90.
Laitner, J. "Quantitative Evaluations of Efficient Tax
Policies for Lucas' Supply Side Models." Oxford Economic
Papers, 47, 1995, 471-92.
Lucas, R. E. Jr. "Supply-Side Economics: An Analytical
Review."Oxford Economic Papers, 42, 1990, 293-316.
Lucas, R. E. Jr., and E. C. Prescott. "Investment under
Uncertainty." Econometrica, 39, 1971, 659-81.
McGrattan, E. R., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright. "An Equilibrium
Model of the Business Cycle with Household Production and Fiscal
Policy." International Economic Review, 38, 1997, 267-90.
Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., and N. Roubini. "Growth Effects of
Income and Consumption Taxes." Journal of Money Credit and Banking,
30, 1998, 721-44.
Mulligan, C. B. Parental Priorities Economic Inequality. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1997.
--."Substitution over Time: Another Look at Labor Supply over
the Life Cycle," in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998, edited by B.
S. Bernanke and J. Rotemberg. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 1999, 75-134.
National Science Foundation. National Patterns of R&D
Resources: 1994. National Science Foundation, 1995.
Ortigueira, S. "Fiscal Policy in an Endogenous Growth Model
with Human Capital Accumulation." Journal of Monetary Economics,
42, 1998, 323-55.
Padovano, F., and E. Galli. "Tax Rates and Economic Growth in
the OECD Countries 1950-1990." Economic Inquiry, 39, 2001, 44-57.
Pecorino, P. "Tax Structure and Growth in a Model with Human
Capital." Journal of Public Economics, 52, 1993, 251-71.
--. "The Growth Rate Effects of Tax Reform." Oxford
Economic Papers, 46, 1994, 492-501.
Poterba, J. M. "The Rate of Return to Corporate Capital and
Factor Shares: New Estimates Using Revised National Income Accounts and
Capital Stock Data." Working Paper 6263. National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1997.
Quigley, J. M., and E. Smolensky. "Improving Efficiency in the
Tax Treatment of Training and Educational Expenditures." Research
in Labor Economics, 11, 1990, 77-95.
Rebelo, S. "Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run
Growth." Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1991, 500-521.
Steuerle, C. E. "How Should Government Allocate Subsidies for
Human Capital?" American Economics Association Papers and
Proceedings, 86, 1996, 353-57.
Stokey, N. L., and S. Rebelo. "Growth Effects of Flat-Rate
Taxes." Journal of Political Economy, 103, 1995, 519-50.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. "Fixed Reproducible Tangible
Wealth in the United States; Revised Estimates for 1925-1997,"
Survey of Current Business, 78, September 1998, 36 -46.
U.S. Congressional Budget Office. The Economic Effects of
Comprehensive Tax Reform. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1997.
U.S. Internal Revenue Service. Statistics of Income Bulletin, 16,
Spring 1997.
Ventura, G. "Flat Tax Reform: A Quantitative
Exploration." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23, 1999,
1425-58.
Weidenbaum, M. "The Nunn-Domenici USA Tax: Analysis and
Comparisons," in Frontiers of Tax Reform, edited by M. Boskin.
Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1996, 54-69.
KEVIN P. CASSOU and KEVIN J. LANSING *
* For helpful comments and suggestions, we thank William Gale, Greg
Huffman, Kenneth Judd, Rodi Manuelli, Alvin Rabushka, B. Ravikumar, Ben
Russo, and participants in the CEPR/Tilburg University Conference on
Dynamic Aspects of Taxation, Tilburg, 8-10 September 2000. Part of this
research was conducted while Lansing was a national fellow at the Hoover
Institution, whose hospitality is gratefully acknowledged.
Cassou: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Kansas State
University, 327 Waters Hall, Manhattan, KS 66506. Phone 1-785-532-6342.
Fax 1-785-532-6919, E-mail scassou@ksu.edu
Lansing: Senior Economist, Research Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA 94120-7702.
Phone 1-415-974-2393, Fax 1-415-977-4031, E-mail
kevin.j.lansing@sf.frb.org