Price competition in pharmaceuticals: the case of anti-infectives.
Wiggins, Steven N. ; Maness, Robert
I. INTRODUCTION
A fundamental question in industrial organization regards the
relationship between price and the number of sellers (N). The interest
in this issue has been rekindled by substantial recent work. (1) This
article uses an extensive data set to provide an empirical analysis of
the price N relationship for antiinfective pharmaceutical products. (2)
The analysis shows that (1) prices fall rapidly moving from one seller
to a few and (2) subsequent increases in the number of sellers continue
to reduce prices, even when there are numerous sellers. (3) Prices fall
about 83% as the number of sellers increases from 1 to between 6 and 15,
and fall by another 52% as sellers increase from the 6 to 15 range to
more than 40. These results contrast with previous work on
pharmaceuticals using more limited data and showing little impact of
entry on branded prices. (4) The results here indicate instead that the
effect of an increase in number of sellers on prices in pharmaceuticals
is similar to that found in other settings.
Pharmaceutical pricing behavior has attracted scrutiny from both
policy makers and academic economists. As such, there have been a number
of studies of pharmaceutical pricing behavior in general and the impact
of generic entry on branded and generic drug prices in particular. Most
of the previous studies have concentrated on small sets of drugs that
have faced patent expiration across a number of therapeutic classes.
Early studies focused on reduced form or semireduced form regression
models that showed that branded prices and generic prices responded
differently to generic entry. In particular, these studies showed that
branded prices responded little to generic entry, and in some studies
even increased (see Caves et al., 1991; Grabowski and Vernon 1992;
1996). Frank and Salkever (1992) developed a theoretical model to
explain the anomaly of rising branded prices in the face of generic
competition. Their model posited a segmented market where there existed
two groups of consumers--a quality-conscious segment that continues to
buy the established branded product after generic entry and a
price-conscious segment. Frank and Salkever show that because of the
segmented nature of the market, entry likely makes the demand facing the
branded manufacturer less elastic and thus leads to price increases.
Frank and Salkever (1997) provide empirical tests and confirm that,
consistent with the segmented markets theory, branded prices rise and
generic prices fall in response to generic entry.
Finally, a number of studies have attempted to characterize the
behavior of generic firms. Scott Morton (1999; 2000) finds that revenue
in the years before patent expiration is the most important determinant of how many generic firms enter a given market. She also finds that
generic firms tend to specialize in certain categories of products.
Reiffen and Ward (2002) develop a structural model of the response of
generic prices to generic entry.
This article investigates how prices decline as the number of
sellers rises, evaluating the ability of formal theoretical models to
organize the data. The results show that although existing models
organize some of the data regarding price declines, there are important
discrepancies between the data and existing models. We then characterize
the differences between the data and the models, providing a basis for
continued theoretical and empirical work.
There are a number of important differences between the data we use
and those of previous researchers. First, unlike previous research on
pharmaceutical pricing, our data are focused on a single therapeutic
category--anti-infectives. This focus on a single therapeutic category
provides a number of benefits, particularly with regard to controlling
for cost differences and demand differences. Anti-infectives in
particular is a useful category because they are primarily used for
acute conditions, thus making demand conditions more uniform. (5) In
addition, because anti-infectives primarily treat acute conditions, and
a single prescription is usually enough to treat a condition,
prescriptions make a natural measure of quantity. However,
anti-infectives are somewhat different from other therapeutic categories
in that generic entry has historically been less costly than in other
categories. The Abbreviated New Drug Application formula established by
the Hatch-Waxman Act in 1984, which reduced the requirements for
approval of generic products, had essentially been in place for decades
for anti-infectives. As a result, although other categories did not see
substantial generic entry until after 1984, anti-infectives had faced
numerous generic entrants for some time. In addition, many
anti-infective products, especially older ones, tend to be prescribed by
generic name instead of the brand name, which hastens the acceptance of
generic products. (6)
These factors have led some researchers to predict that branded
anti-infective prices may respond differently from those in other
categories. Early empirical research seemed to confirm that result.
Later empirical research has provided more mixed results, with some
studies showing a pattern of rising branded anti-infective prices in the
face of generic entry. (8) Our results are more in line with the earlier
studies, showing significant impact on branded prices from generic
entry.
A second difference in our data is that they measure activity at
the retail level. The use of retail prices raises two issues for our
analysis. Previous research has pointed out that pharmacists may have a
financial incentive to favor generic dispensing, especially since the
advent of managed care (see Grabowski and Vernon 1996). However, our
data end in 1990, when managed care was a much smaller factor than it is
today. A second issue is to what extent retail prices can be used to
analyze price competition among manufacturers. Given the intense
competition among retail pharmacies, and the use of simple pricing rules
that apply across most (if not all) drugs, price competition among
manufacturers is likely to be reflected in retail level data. (9)
The article also provides one of the few econometric analyses of
product differentiation, including identifying separate effects on
prices from increases in both generic and brand name competition. This
analysis of competition between branded and generic products shows (1)
that it is important to distinguish between branded products sold by
other innovative firms besides the pioneer and unbranded entry by
traditional generic manufacturers; (2) branded entry by other innovative
firms has a different effect on pioneer prices than generic entry by
strictly off-brand firms; and (3) there appears to be significant
competition between generic and brand-name sellers, including the
pioneer. Hence the results indicate that there are three distinctive
product groups in pharmaceuticals: the pioneer, branded versions of the
same molecule sold by other innovative firms, and ordinary generics, and
there is significant price competition within and between these groups.
II. THE EMPIRICAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN PRICE AND NUMBER OF
COMPETITORS
Aggregated Data
The data consist of retail-level pharmacy transaction data for all
anti-infective products over the 1984-90 period, (10) The data provide
yearly observations on total expenditures and quantity of prescriptions
sold for the individual sellers of anti-infective products. These data
are used to construct an annual price per prescription for each seller
of each product (detailed data appendix available on request). Attention
is restricted to anti-infectives to control for units of measure, cost,
and regulatory conditions across products. Doctors normally write an
anti-infective prescription for a quantity of medication designed to
cure a given infection. This practice makes the individual prescription
the natural unit of measure for anti-infectives. For other
pharmaceuticals, in contrast, a pill or a daily dose might be more
relevant. (11) The active ingredients for these products are also
commonly manufactured using identical equipment, making costs more
similar for anti-infectives than across pharmaceuticals as a whole.
Still, the analysis that follows introduces several control variables to
allow for cost differences in a more sophisticated way than in previous
work. (12)
Food and Drug Administration testing and review standards are also
the same within this class of products, so that regulatory costs and
standards are also similar. Hence cost differences are likely small, and
we can control adequately for different manufacturing techniques for
different groups of products (see Caves et al., 1991; Grabowski and
Vernon 1992; 1996).
We briefly review some summary statistics, a complete review is
available in the data appendix (available on request). The average price
(1982-84 dollars) in the sample is $10.29 with a standard deviation of
$21.68. The smallest price is 0 and the largest price is $391.46. (13)
The average branded price (constant dollars) is $30.30 with a standard
deviation of $45.77, and the average generic price (constant dollars) is
$6.27 with a standard deviation of $6.91. The number of sellers for a
given product varies from 1 (monopoly) to 61. The mean is 26.9 sellers.
Our measure for the number of related sellers has a mean of 31.6 and
ranges between 0 and 112. We also calculated the Herfindahl Hirschman
index (HHI) for each chemical entity in each year. The mean HHI in the
sample is 3,677, and the standard deviation is 2,669.
About 17% of the observations are for brand-name products, 13% are
pioneer products. The number of observations is fairly evenly spread
across the sample period and across IMS classifications. Erythromycins
(14%) and cephalosporins (9.6%) contain the largest number of
observations.
Almost half the observations (46%) are from drugs introduced before
1962. In other years, introductions vary from none in some years up to
8.4% of the sample in 1974. Thus the data set provides much detail and
ample variation for the empirical tests that follow.
Anti-infective products are broadly categorized according to the
general molecular structure of the central active chemical entity, such
as penicillins, tetracyclines, erythromycins, and cephalosporins. These
groups can be further disaggregated into specific molecular entities or
combinations, and the analysis here focuses on the number of sellers of
these individual products. Our data include 98 separately identified
compounds. The analysis also considers competition among sellers of
closely related molecules. Ellison et al. (1997) examine cross-product
price competition in cephalosporins, and find mixed evidence of price
competition across products for these closely related antibiotics. In
contrast, Stern (1994) finds that in two of his four categories there is
significant intermolecular substitution. Accordingly, in the
econometrics we allow for intermolecular effects, though our results are
more similar to Ellison et al. than to Stern.
Before turning to the theory and econometric specification,
however, it is valuable to examine the simple relationship between price
and number of sellers. Figure 1 presents these data. Although the
econometric analysis uses individual prices for each seller in a panel
data set, for clarity Figure 1 simply presents average prices, taking
the mean price of all drugs with a particular number of sellers. The
first point on the horizontal axis corresponds to drugs with one seller
and the price is averaged over all such products in the sample, the
second price is the average price for all two-seller drugs, and so
forth. (14) Figure 2 presents a similar view using HHI in place of
numbers of competitors.
[FIGURES 1-2 OMITTED]
The two panels of Figure 1 present two different looks at the data.
A shows average prices for all sellers, and B shows the average price
for just the pioneers--the firms that originally developed the
molecules. A shows a sharp drop in prices with the entry of the second
through fifth sellers. Prices fall from the single seller price of more
than $57 to $9.46 when there are five sellers. This rapid decline in
prices continues throughout most of the relevant range. B, focusing just
on the prices of the pioneer developer, shows essentially the same
pattern. Hence, these data show a decline in both overall average prices
and prices of the pioneer developer.
The continuing price decline is well illustrated through a series
of simple regressions of the price-N relationship, with progressive
truncation of the sample on N from the left-hand side. These regressions
permit one to assess the persistence of the inverse relationship between
price and N. The results show that there is a statistically significant
impact of the number of sellers on price, including when the sample is
restricted to more than 30 sellers. (15) Hence there is a significant,
continuing price decline in the reduced form that continues from only a
few sellers to more than 40. Focusing just on the pioneer products, the
results are highly similar. (16)
We tried other specifications, and all the results are broadly
similar. For instance, although our analysis concentrates on the price-N
relationship, we also calculated the HHI for each of our 98 chemicals.
The mean HHI was 3,677 with a standard deviation of 2,669. The range was
1,082 to 10,000. After constructing the HHI, we then replicated the
regressions using the HHI in place of the number of firms. We ran a
series of regressions, truncating the Herfindahl from above. The
coefficient remained positive and significant, even when the regression
was restricted to a HHI of less than 2,000. Thus, decreasing
concentration reduces price, even for chemicals with very low HHIs. (17)
It is unlikely that manufacturing cost differences explain the
observed differences in price. Anti-infectives appear to exhibit
constant marginal production costs, and manufacturing techniques are
highly similar. There are differences in presentation, such as tablets,
capsules, and suspensions, but these differences cut across products and
groups of products. The one place where presentation could make a large,
systematic difference is for intravenous drugs, which we investigate
later. Hence manufacturing cost differences are unlikely to explain
observed price differences. Still it is important to control carefully
for costs and various other factors that might affect the observed
price-N relationship, requiring a more detailed econometric
investigation.
An Econometric Analysis" of Oligopoly Models
To construct an econometric model of the relationship between price
and the number of sellers, it is useful to rely on formal models to
guide the analysis. The data summarized in Figure 1 show a continuous
decline in price, ruling out a simple Bertrand model of price
competition. Recognizing this, two simple alternative models of
competition are the standard Cournot quantity setting model and the
entry threshold model of Bresnahan and Reiss (1991). Standard Cournot
oligopoly theory predicts that prices should initially fall quickly and
then steadily approach marginal cost. A similar prediction is also
provided by Bresnahan and Reiss's entry threshold ratio method,
which predicts a steady fall in variable profit margins. We compare the
predictions of this simple Cournot model to the alternative of a simple
linear relationship between price and the number of sellers and to a
more general model that nests these alternatives.
To formalize the Cournot prediction, suppose a linear inverse demand of the form P(Q) = a - bQ with constant marginal cost, e < a,
and where Q represents total market output. With N identical sellers,
the market price generated by the Cournot model takes the following
familiar form:
(1) [P.sup.*] (N) = (a + cN)/(N+ 1).
Note that the Cournot model predicts a linear relationship between
price and roughly the inverse of the number of sellers.
The Cournot model only results in equation (1) when there is a
linear demand and constant marginal cost. Constant cost is highly
plausible for anti-infectives because the raw ingredients are
manufactured in batches that are small relative to total output and pill
making is constant cost. Linearity of demand, however, is a stronger
assumption suggesting that one can think of (1) as a Cournot-like
outcome rather than a structural test (see later discussion).
The Cournot model also assumes that firms are identical. For many
of the chemicals in our analysis, especially those that have been off
patent for a number of years, this assumption is plausible. The industry
uses batch production technology characterized by constant returns to
scale. For this reason, most of the previous literature in the field
also uses the number of competitors as the key variable determining the
competitiveness of prices (see Stern 1994; Ellison et al. 1997 for
instance). Though the results reported use the number of competitors as
the key variable, we also ran regressions using the HHI. The results are
broadly similar to those reported. Thus the assumption of identical
firms does not significantly affect the empirical results.
In our analysis N is the exogenous variable driving prices in
equilibrium. We treat N as exogenously predetermined by market size and
other factors in the previous period or periods, and price is then
determined by the predetermined number of sellers in a particular
period. Such an approach seems generally consistent with the data and
with previous research on the determinants of generic entry (see Scott
Morton 1999; 2000). For example, a regression of N on sales in the year
before patent expiration (where data are available) shows that such
sales explain more than 60% of variation of the number of sellers in the
postpatent period. Hence ex ante market size is the key variable driving
variation in N.
It is also important to control for other factors that might affect
prices. One key factor is possible competition from related products.
Ellison et al. (1997) found little evidence to support such competition,
and Stern (1994) finds such effects in some categories. To control for
these effects we included the number of other sellers in the appropriate
broader category of anti-infectives, such as penicillins, tetracyclines,
and so forth. Brand recognition is also important, and we included a
dummy variable for versions of the same molecule sold by other
innovative companies that had achieved brand recognition. (18) Below we
undertake a more extensive analysis of branded, pioneer, and generic
products. In contrast, different presentations of drugs do not differ
sharply, except injectable products are systematically more expensive to
manufacture and distribute. We introduced an IV dummy to control for
these possible cost differences.
There are also potential cost and demand differences that require
fixed effects to control for product age, product group, and year. Year
of introduction fixed effects were included to control for differences
in product age that could lead to differences in either demand or cost.
For example, physicians sometimes use older products first in a course
of therapy, potentially affecting demand and price. Alternatively there
may be a trend where manufacturing costs of more recently developed
products are higher due to the more advanced nature of the products.
Individual year of introduction fixed effects provide a flexible
procedure for accounting for such differences, and we will compare the
results of using such fixed effects with a simple time trend.
In addition, products in different therapeutic subcategories may
differ in manufacturing cost. Even though anti-infectives are generally
manufactured using similar techniques, there could exist some
differences across categories, such as tetracyclines or penicillins.
Accordingly, we include fixed effects for these groups. Finally, fixed
effects were included for individual sample years to control for changes
in demand over time. (19) The extensive use of fixed effects provides a
much richer set of controls for cost and demand differences than the
existing literature. For example, Caves et al. (1991) consider products
across therapeutic categories (such as cardiovasculars versus
anti-infectives) and simply use a single fixed effect for
anti-infectives, which is equivalent to imposing a restriction that all
of the fixed effects considered here are zero because the entire data
set consists of anti-infectives. Hence the present study provides a
large advance in the control of cost and demand factors in studying
pharmaceutical pricing relationships.
We used weighted least squares because the cells for different
numbers of sellers had sharply different variances. We used as weights
the inverses of the estimated standard deviation of the residual for
each value of the number of competitors. (20) The results from the
estimation are reported in Table 1. The results show general goodness of
fit with a large F-statistic, [R.sup.2], and all of the key variables
are highly significant.
The model derived from equation (I) does a good job of explaining
the empirical relationship between price and the number of sellers of a
given product. The results show that price is closely related to the
inverse of the number of sellers of individual products, as predicted by
the Cournot model. The parameter estimate for 1/(N + 1) is 28.70 with a
t-statistic of 7.07. The parameter estimates indicate rapid price
declines when a firm loses its (patent-protected) monopoly and faces
competitors. A second seller drops prices by nearly $5, the third by
$2.39, the fourth by about $1.43, and the fifth by about $0.97. These
price effects, moreover, are large relative to the mean price in the
sample of $10.29. Hence, when there are more sellers in a market the
price falls sharply, but these price effects moderate quickly. Still, a
significant though small effect continues far into the sample; going
from 25 to 35 competitors is predicted to reduce prices in the
structural model by $0.31, or about 7.5%.
It is worth noting several other results. First, the brand name
variable shows an economically and statistically significant markup of
$3.35 for brand-name products compared to generics. Because the mean
price of generic products in the sample is slightly more than $6, this
variable indicates roughly a 50% mark-up of brand-name
products--products of other innovative firms--over generics. (21) The
variable representing intravenous products also shows a substantial
price premium; the coefficient indicates that such products are priced
at $13.11 more than other products, ceteris paribus.
Though the number of sellers of the compound in question (N) has a
large effect on price, the number of sellers of related compounds
([N.sub.R]) has little effect. As noted, parameters predict a price
decline of nearly $5 moving from monopoly to duopoly, and a rise in
number of sellers from two to three cuts prices by another $2.50, and so
forth. In contrast, the coefficient for sellers of related products is
small, only 1.333, not quite significant at the 95% confidence level.
Hence, these data suggest that price effects are driven primarily by
changes in the number of sellers of the compound in question, where we
concentrate the remainder of our analysis. (22)
Although we concentrate on sellers of individual chemicals, we do
not interpret these chemicals as being separate markets. Instead, we
take the weaker position that taking the number of sellers of related
products into account makes little empirical difference. Hence it is
appropriate to focus primary attention on sellers of individual
products.
Before turning to the other specifications it is important to
consider the fixed effects. (23) The results show that only 9 of the 24
individual year of introduction fixed effects are statistically
significantly different from the omitted median (1973) at the 5%
confidence level. However, an F-test reveals that these effects are
jointly significant at the 1% level (F = 14.38). Inspection of the
coefficients shows that prior to 1973 all 11 are negative and after 1973
8 of 14 are positive. Nevertheless, there does not exist a simple trend
in that there is considerable variation in the individual year fixed
effects over time, showing that this method provides a highly flexible
method for accounting for possible vintage effects.
The year of introduction dummies are included to control for
vintage effects, such as increased quality for newer drugs, which
Lichtenberg (2001) demonstrates is an important attribute of newer drugs
relative to older ones. To quantify these effects in a simple way, we
also ran the regression using an age variable in place of year of
introduction dummies. This procedure also permits us to test whether our
more general treatment of vintage effects materially affected the
results. Age is defined as years since introduction of the chemical. We
also include age squared to account for potential nonlinear vintage
effects. This parametric treatment of age is more restrictive than the
year dummies defined and used because it constrains age effects to a
quadratic form. The results, however, are essentially unchanged for all
the key variables. These results also ensure that the specification of
age effects does not account for any differences between the results
here and those of other investigators. The estimate of the key
coefficient on 1/(N + 1) in this specification is 37.18 with a
t-statistic of 8.97. The coefficient for age is -0.461 with a
t-statistic of -7.14. The squared term is small, 0.007, with a
t-statistic of 5.70. For drugs that first entered the market during our
sample period, the average first-year price is $54.41. The quadratic age
effects thus predict a fall in price of little more than 13% over 40
years ($7.14). This parametric approach suggests that systematic age
effects for these products are small.
Turning to the therapeutic subcategory fixed effects, we omitted
the median fixed effect for trimethoprim (IMS class 15500). Of the 20
fixed effects for individual product groups, only 10 are statistically
significantly different from this median. Even though the number of
significant coefficients is small, the data do indicate significant
differences across subcategories because a joint test restricting these
coefficients to zero is highly significant with an F-value of 58.16.
Finally, only three of the year fixed effects (1984-89) are
significant at the 5% level. Furthermore, there is no distinct trend in
the year coefficients, which indicates that the data do not suggest a
simple trend in price over the sample period.
The fixed effects show that it is important to control for cost and
demand conditions. The rich set of fixed effects shows substantial
nonlinear variation by year of introduction, and there are generally
small but significant differences in prices across subcategories. These
fixed effects provide a significant improvement over existing work and
control well for possible cost and demand differences. Hence the
measured effect of competitors on price should not be the result of cost
or demand differences.
Turning to the other specifications, an alternative to the highly
nonlinear, inverse specification of column (1) of Table 1 is a linear
relationship. To test between these specifications, one can nest the two
models including both the linear and nonlinear terms, as is done in
column (2) of Table 1. The results for the nested model indicate that
both terms are significant, suggesting that prices fall faster than the
simple Cournot-like model would predict. Furthermore, although the
linear terms are significant, they are economically small. For example,
as the second firm enters, the primary model predicts a price decline of
about $5, whereas the nested model predicts a somewhat slower price
decline of just over $3; these differences are fairly small so that both
models organize the data fairly well and in an economically similar way.
The most important difference between the nested model and the
Cournot-like model regards their prediction of price declines when there
are large numbers of firms. The nested model predicts a larger price
decline when there are large numbers of firms and seems to capture
better the empirical phenomenon of continuing price declines far into
the sample. In fact, the linear term is roughly the same size as the
coefficient in the simple regressions of price on N when the sample is
restricted to more than 30 sellers; hence, the linear term in the nested
model enables it to capture the continuing price declines far into the
sample.
Another difference occurs in the effect of the number of sellers of
related compounds. In the inverse specification, these sellers have a
marginally significant effect, whereas in the nested specification,
these products have a statistically insignificant effect. The small size
of these effects and their sensitivity to the specification may help
explain the disparate findings of Stern (1994) and Ellison et al.
(1997).
The third column of Table 1 shows the simple linear model without
the nonlinear term, and the results are similar. The model exhibits
large F-statistics and [R.sup.2] as in the other two specifications, and
the coefficients of all explanatory variables are of the right sign and
statistically significant. The key difference is that the linear model
does not capture the sharp initial price decline that characterizes the
Cournot and nested models.
Hence the results show a large impact of initial entry on prices of
these various therapeutic compounds. This relationship is present,
moreover, both in a simple reduced-form analysis and in an in-depth
econometric analysis, where control is introduced for product age,
potential manufacturing cost differences, the number of sellers of
closely related products, and method of administration. (24)
We also ran these regressions with HHIs in place of the number of
competitors. This regression is reported in the final column of Table 1.
The results show a good fit, with an [R.sup.2] of 0.808, slightly less
than for the regressions using number of sellers. The coefficient on the
HHI for individual chemicals is positive and significant, indicating
that decreasing concentration does reduce price. The coefficient on the
HHI for the other chemicals in the IMS class is negative and
significant, with a coefficient equal in size to that of its own
chemical entity, indicating that decreased concentration in the broader
class results in higher prices.
Because of this anomaly, we also ran the HHI regression (column
[4]) with other HHI removed. The results were almost identical to those
reported in Table 1, column (4) (the coefficient in this regression was
also 0.0004, with t = 4.816). Thus, removing other HHI from the primary
regression does not alter the results in any way. We also repeated the
regressions in column (1) and (4) using the log of price as the
dependent variable. The results are qualitatively unchanged. (25)
The price N regressions and the price--H HI regression represent
two competing linear models. Though we report results on both models, we
conducted routine econometric tests to determine which model best
explains the data. The results were inconclusive. One method to test
these nonnested alternatives is to create an artificial nested model
that includes both (HHI and other HHI) and (1/[1 + N] and 1/[1 +
[N.sub.R]]) as independent variables along with all the control
variables and then conduct an F-test on the HHI coefficients and the N
coefficients (see Greene 1993, 222-23). The results indicate that
neither specification can be rejected. The F-test that the coefficients
on HHI and other HHI are both zero is 4.21. However, in this
specification, the coefficient on HHI is not statistically significant
(0.00009, with a t-statistic of 1.19), and the joint significance may be
driven by the significance of the other HHI coefficient, which is
negative (-0.0003, t-statistic = -2.21). The test that 1/(1 + N) and
1/(1 + [N.sub.R]) are simultaneously zero is also easily rejected
(F(2,3110)=21.69). We also conducted a J-test of the two competing
models to ensure that the results were not affected by the control
variables (see Greene 1993, 223). Using the J-test, the hypothesis that
the HHI model does not add any explanatory power cannot be rejected, and
the symmetric hypothesis for the Cournot model is easily rejected. Thus,
the J-test seems to favor using the inverse of the number of competitors
as an independent variable over using HHI.
It is interesting to note the similarities and differences between
these results and those in prior work. Perhaps the most closely related
work in the literature on the price-N relationship is Bresnahan and
Reiss (1991). They examine prices for dentists, auto repair shops, and
the like in geographically isolated county seats. Their key finding was
that the largest competitive impact occurs moving from two to three
firms, another large impact moving from three to four, and smaller
subsequent price impacts. They also argue that their inferred prices in
relatively concentrated county seats remained considerably above those
in "competitive urban markets."
The analysis here shows a sharp price drop as the number of sellers
increases from one to four or five and much smaller price effects
thereafter, similar to their finding. Bresnahan and Reiss also find a
significant difference between price estimates in concentrated (county
seats) and unconcentrated (urban) markets. Their finding is consistent
with our results, which show a continuing price decline as N gets
relatively large.
In contrast, the analysis here shows different results from those
found in previous research on pharmaceuticals. Studies by Caves et al.
(1991) and Grabowski and Vernon (1992) showed small branded price
effects from entry. The results here show that pharmaceutical prices
respond to an increase in the number of sellers similar to price
responses found in other markets. There are several possible
explanations for these differences in results.
Perhaps the most important is that the sample here is much larger
than that used in these prior studies and contains much more variation
in the number of sellers. In addition, we do not restrict attention to a
short period following patent expiration but instead consider a variety
of products with sharply different numbers of sellers. We also control
more tightly for cost and demand differences. A different type of
possibility is that the analysis here focuses on anti-infectives. Such a
focus contributes to better control for cost and demand differences, but
comes at the cost of a more narrow focus. For example, by concentrating
on anti-infectives, the analysis focuses on products for which a single
prescription is designed to cure, usage patterns are similar, and
underlying cost conditions are likely more similar. These factors
improve the econometrics but of course mean that extrapolation to other
therapeutic categories must await further analysis.
The analysis corresponds to standard analyses of the price-N
relationship and prior studies of pharmaceutical pricing. The omission is that it does not take into account the differentiated nature of
branded and unbranded products. We now turn to an explicit analysis of
the differentiated nature of pharmaceutical products and the effect of
such differentiation on pricing.
III. PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND PRICE COMPETITION
Considerably more can be learned about pricing by recognizing the
differentiated nature of generic and brand-name products. Brand-name
products generally attract quality-conscious-customers, and generic
firms compete over price. Competition within and between these segments
can provide insight into pricing patterns and permits testing of
specific models of competition between these groups.
One issue is to define a brand name, and there are two reasonable
alternatives. One way is to categorize the original patent-protected
product, defined hereafter as the pioneer, as the only brand name. A
second way is to include products marketed by other innovative companies
that are separately promoted and have achieved significant brand
recognition even though they are not the pioneer. We evaluate both
alternatives. To separate products with significant brand recognition,
we categorized products specifically listed by brand name in the
Scientific American Textbook of Medicine. These products are generally
detailed to doctors in varying degrees and may or may not differ from
more traditional generic entry.
Distinguishing between pioneers, brand names, and generics leads to
several reduced form relationships between price and N. We are
particularly interested in: (1) average brand-name prices and the total
number of sellers, (2) average brand name prices and the number of brand
name sellers, (3) average prices of pioneer products and the total
number of sellers, and (4) average generic prices and the total number
of sellers. These relationships are illustrated in the four panels of
Figure 3. Panel A shows the relationship between average brand-name
prices and the total number of sellers of a chemical. A shows that the
price of brand-name drugs falls steadily with the number of competitors
until there are roughly 25 to 30 competitors; afterward the point
estimate indicates continued price declines, but the decline is no
longer statistically significant.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Panel B of Figure 3 provides a different look at brand-name prices
by showing how the average price of brand-name products is related to
the number of brand name sellers of the chemical. (26) The data show a
considerable but irregular decline in price as the number of brand name
sellers rises. Panel C shows that prices of pioneers steadily decline as
the number of sellers of the chemical rises. This panel is a repeat of
Figure 1B. Note that the price decline exhibited here is much like that
of Figure 1A. Finally, D presents data on average generic prices as
related to the total number of competitors. The results show that for
generic products prices fall steadily until there are more than 30
competitors. (27)
These data show that increases in the number of sellers of
individual chemicals leads to price decreases over a large range, but
the pattern of decrease and average price levels differ significantly
for branded and generic products. For generics significant price effects
continue far into the sample, whereas prices stabilize for brand names
when there are large numbers of sellers.
We now turn to a more detailed econometric analysis of the
competition between brand name and generic sellers of these products.
It is common in the industry to view brand-name products as being
differentiated from their generic competitors. Pricing patterns after
patent expiration and generic entry show that the price of the pioneer
product remains much higher than the level of generic competitors for
substantial periods of time. In fact, previous empirical studies have
found that prices of pioneer products tend to rise after generic entry
(see Grabowski and Vernon 1992; Masson and Steiner 1985). A useful way
to approach competition between branded and generic products is to view
them as differentiated products. In this setting, additional generic
entry should have a larger impact on generic prices than on brand-name
prices because entry is taking place closer to existing generic
competitors in product space.
Table 2 presents several specifications of the relationship between
price declines for branded and generic drugs. Because generic drugs are
likely to compete more closely with each other than with branded
products, one might expect branded prices to fall more slowly than
generic prices when additional generics enter. Such a possibility is
also consistent with some of the empirical works described. To address
this issue in detail, we postulate several specifications where one
variable captures the overall price decline and a separate variable
captures the differential decline in the price of branded products.
The first column in Table 2 is derived from a formal model of
spatial competition (see Wiggins and Maness 1998). The specification is
very similar to the Cournot analysis. The other specifications relax the
highly specific functional form to test the qualitative result that
brand-name prices should fall more slowly than generic prices. Column
(1) of Table 2 reports the results of the first specification. The
control variable coefficients are qualitatively similar to those in
section II. The F-statistics and [R.sup.2] are large. The primary
coefficients of interest in column (1) are the coefficient for the
inverse of the number of sellers, and the variable interacting this
variable with brand name. The inverse of the number of sellers has the
incorrect sign but is not statistically significant. In contrast, the
results show that generic entry lowers brand-name prices.
The second column in Table 2 reports a logarithmic specification,
and the third reports a linear specification. The final column in Table
2 uses HHI in place of a functional form based on the number of
competitors. All four specifications show a significant effect of
generic entry on brand-name prices but little effect of generic entry on
generic prices. The result is that the analysis is that the data
indicate faster price declines for brand names than generics, contrary
to the conclusions of previous empirical research.
In addition, we examine several nonstructural alternatives. These
models also permit empirical examination of how multiple branded sellers
affect prices, in addition to the impact of generics on branded prices,
and vice versa.
Frank and Salkever (1992) developed a model for a "segmented
market" in pharmaceuticals with two groups, a loyal group of
price-inelastic brand-name consumers and a relatively price sensitive
group of consumers. (28) They argue there is little competition between
these segments. In such a case, the prices of brand-name products will
be unaffected by the number of generic competitors and, symmetrically,
the number of brand-name sellers ought not affect generic prices. An
alternative view is that all products besides the original pioneer are
generic. This view is implicit in much of the empirical literature,
which generally examines only the pioneer's prices, implicitly
treating all entry as generic. (29) This approach implies that pioneer
products represent one category and all other products represent
another.
Our approach, in contrast, separates products sold by other
innovative companies, because these companies are the ones who sell the
incremental "branded" products (so-called branded generics) in
the sample. To the extent that branded entry causes larger price
effects, the results indicate that branding leads to more effective
price competition by incrementally reducing prices in the branded and/or
generic segments.
Table 3 presents weighted least squares regressions investigating
these hypotheses. A pooling test was conducted to see if the three
product categories could be pooled with respect to the effect of the
number of sellers, and the results reject pooling. Subsequent pooling
tests were conducted for pooling pioneers and other brand names and for
generics and brand names, and in each case pooling was rejected.
Accordingly the econometric results will analyze the separate effects of
branded and generic entry. (30)
The regression results permit an in-depth analysis of the nature of
competition between brand-name and generic sellers and the effect on
prices. In the brand-name price regression, both brand name and generic
entry affects prices, but the coefficient on brand-name products is
about ten times as large as the coefficient on generic products and is
the incorrect sign. Nevertheless, the results show significant
competition between these product groups, which is inconsistent with the
segmented market hypothesis and with the notion that all sellers other
than the pioneer should be treated similarly.
Turning to the generic price equation, the results clearly indicate
that generic firms do respond to brand-name entry. Note, however, there
are important differences in how generic prices respond to other generic
as opposed to brand-name entry. The linear term for generic entry is
large and significant, whereas the inverse term is small and not
significant. For brand-name entry the response is similar, but the
effect of brand-name entry on generic prices is substantially larger
(-0.88 per brand-name entrant versus -0.16 for an additional generic
entrant). The results once again show significant competition between
branded products sold by innovators and generics.
The results for pioneer products--products sold by the original
developer--also contrast with the segmented market hypothesis. Generic
entry has a large and statistically significant effect on pioneer
prices, both for the linear and nonlinear terms. Hence pioneer products
do indeed lower prices quite significantly in the face of additional
generic competition. (31) Furthermore, there is suggestive support for
the hypothesis that branded entry also effects pioneer prices in that
the linear term is quite large and statistically significant, although
the inverse of the number of brand-name sellers has the wrong sign.
Hence the results support the argument that there is significant
competitive interaction between pioneer, brand name, and generic firms.
These results indicate considerable competition and show that increases
in the number of sellers in any segment generally reduce prices in the
remaining segments. This competition suggests that markets are less
segmented than previous discussions suggest.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
This article has provided an empirical investigation of the
relationship between price and the number of sellers in pharmaceuticals.
The analysis used a data set covering all anti-infective products and
showed that initial entry led to sharp price reductions, with prices
falling from the range of more than $60 per prescription for single
sellers, $30 when there are two or three sellers, and less than $20 when
there are four or more sellers. The results also show that prices
continued to decline with additional entry, eventually approaching $4
for products with more than 40 sellers.
The results show that increases in the number of competitors
significantly reduce prices, even when there are numerous sellers. These
results tie in nicely with those of Bresnahan and Reiss (1991). Using
small, isolated county seats, they find that the competitive effects of
entry diminish after the third or fourth entrant but that prices
stabilize above those in unconcentrated urban markets. The results here
show a similar, rapid initial price decline, and then go on to show a
continuing steady decline as the number of sellers rises from a few to
many.
The analysis also showed, however, that existing models do not
explain well the observed pricing pattern. The analysis showed prices
broadly consistent with Cournot quantity setting, though prices declined
more with large N than that model would predict.
The analysis also ties into the emerging work on pharmaceutical
prices. The analysis here has extended that work in several directions.
One direction is to provide a much more comprehensive analysis of
pricing in a specific, important therapeutic category. Our results show
substantial price sensitivity and stand in contrast to results found by
Caves et al. and Grabowski and Vernon. There are several possible
reasons for these differences. One is that the analysis here relied on
all anti-infectives, not restricting attention to the period closely
following patent expiration. The greater variation in the number of
sellers also provides a richer data set particularly because the
analysis used data exclusively since 1984, when there were large numbers
of generic sellers. This date is important because it follows the
Waxman-Hatch Act, which eased the burdens of generic entry. A second
possible reason is that anti-infectives may be more price-sensitive than
other segments of the pharmaceutical industry. This possibility, of
course, means that one must be careful in drawing inferences from this
analysis to pharmaceuticals more generally. (32)
The analysis also provided an econometric investigation of
differentiated product models by treating brand-name and generic
products as differentiated. The problem is to explain the persistent
price difference between brand-name products and their generic
competitors. The results indicate that a general spatial model of
product differentiation does not adequately explain pricing behavior in
the pharmaceutical industry because brand-name products respond
aggressively to generic entry. The results, however, also reject the
segmented market hypothesis, showing instead that there is important
competition between the pioneer, brand name, and generic segments.
Multiple products achieve brand recognition, and there are important
differences in the competitive effects of additional branded entry
compared to the effects of incremental generic entry. For both generic
and brand-name firms, there is a significant inverse relationship
between price and the number of competitors, whether those competitors
are brand name or generic producers.
The broad implication of the analysis is that entry of additional
sellers reduces prices much more substantially than previous work would
suggest. The extent to which these results carry over to other
therapeutic classes remains an important, unresolved issue.
TABLE 1
Regression Results Based on the Cournot Model
Courant Nested
Variable Model (1) Model (2)
Constant 2.969 6.920
(12.350) (7.142)
N -- -0.080
(-4.379)
1/([N.sub.R] + 1) 28.698 18.534
(7.067) (3.783)
HHI -- --
[N.sub.R] -- -0.007
(-0.676)
1/([N.sub.R] + 1) 1.333 1.234
(1.938) (1.746)
Other HHI -- --
Intravenous products dummy 13.106 13.239
(18.916) (19.207)
Brand-name products dummy 3.354 3.340
(16.282) (16.190)
Mean dependent variable (weighted) 10.29 10.29
(1.48) (1.48)
Observations 3168 3168
F-statistic 249.16 242.26
[R.sup.2] 0.818 0.819
Root MSE 0.864 0.866
Variable Linear Model (3) HHI Model (4)
Constant 9.199 4.385
(11.422) (8.600)
N -0.118 --
(-7.596)
1/([N.sub.R] + 1) -- --
HHI -- 0.0003
(4.141)
[N.sub.R] -0.011 --
(-1.080)
1/([N.sub.R] + 1) -- --
Other HHI -- -0.0003
(-2.171)
Intravenous products dummy 13.139 13.023
(19.025) (18.203)
Brand-name products dummy 3.407 3.592
(16.525) (17.072)
Mean dependent variable (weighted) 10.29 10.29
(1.42) (1.40)
Observations 3168 3168
F-statistic 249.30 243.16
[R.sup.2] 818 0.808
Root MSE 0.868 0.837
Note: Dependent variable: real price per prescription. N = number of
sellers. [N.sub.R] = number of sellers of related products.
HHI = Herfindahl index. t-statistics are in parentheses. Real price is
in 1982-84 dollars. Regressions are weighted OLS. Weights are
calculated by number of competitors and in each regression are equal
to the standard deviation of the residual for each number of
competitors. An appendix, available from the authors, contains the
fixed effects results.
TABLE 2
Test of a Spatial Model
f([N.sub.G]) f([N.sub. f([N.sub.
=1/(2[N. G])=log G])= HHI
sub.G] + 1) ([N.sub.G]) [N.sub.G]
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)
Constant -77.778 26.731 -39.739 -55.495
(-9.092) (2.557) (-3.985) (-5.954)
f([N.sub.G]) -18.464 -2.855 -0.433 --
(-0.785) (-1.644) (-4.313)
HHI -- -- -- 0.001
(5.880)
Brand-name dummy 2.962 10.269 8.256 4.720
variable (BRAND) (3.870) (3.643) (5.999) (3.451)
BRAND * f 40.379 -2.103 -0.202 --
([N.sub.G]) (2.317) (-2.207) (-3.391)
BRAND * HHI -- -- -- -0.0002
(-0.708)
Intravenous 3.999 5.207 5.922 4.102
products dummy (1.472) (1.862) (2.021) (1.466)
F-statistic 112.32 109.30 110.03 102.34
[R.sup.2] 0.849 0.846 0.847 0.837
Root MSE 0.963 0.956 0.957 0.892
Notes: [N.sub.G]=number of generic competitors. HHI-Herfindahl index.
t-statistics are in parentheses. Dependent variable is real price is in
1982-84 dollars. Regressions are weighted OLS. Weights are calculated
by number of competitors and in each regression are equal to the
standard deviation of the residual for each number of competitors.
Fixed effects dummy coefficients are not reported. Regressions only
include cases where market has a single brand-name seller and one or
more generic sellers. Regressions are based on 565 observations meeting
these conditions.
TABLE 3
Nested Nonspatial Models of Product Differentiation
Pioneer Brand-Name
Products (Other than
Variable Only Pioneer) Generic Only
Constant 21.601 42.207 13.516
(7.599) (4.965) (6.736)
1/([N.sub.G]+1) 14.183 5.106 0.411
(4.270) (1.431) (0.071)
1/([N.sub.B]+1) -8.417 -57.222 0.279
(-3.173) (-2.904) (0.206)
[N.sub.G] -0.085 -0.094 -0.155
(-2.409) (-3.087) (-7.551)
[N.sub.B] -2.628 -5.091 -0.882
(-4.077) (-4.395) (-2.364)
Intravenous products dummy 10.531 13.892 3.535
(10.378) (19.502) (2.544)
Mean of price (weighted) 36.72 12.58 5.93
(1.97) (2.51) (1.41)
Number of observations 394 171 2491
F-statistic 214.11
[R.sup.2] 0.830
Notes: Dependent variable = price. [N.sub.G] = number of generic
competitors. [N.sub.B] = number of brand-name competitors.
t-statistics are in parentheses. Dependent variable is real price is in
1982-84 dollars.
(1.) See, for example, Applebaum (1982), Bresnahan (1981),
Bresnahan and Reiss (1991), Caves et al. (1991), Porter (1993), Reiss
and Spiller (1989), and Suslow (1986); portions of this literature are
summarized in Bresnahan (1989).
(2.) Although our analysis concentrates on the relationship between
price and the number of firms, there has also been substantial work on
the relationship between price and concentration.
(3.) It should be noted that there is little if any price effect
when the second generic enters, but price effects become significant as
the third and fourth generics enter.
(4.) The analysis here builds on Caves et al. (1991) and Grabowski
and Vernon (1992) but covers a much larger set of products, including
all 98 in the anti-infective category. In contrast, Caves and colleagues
used 30 products and Grabowski and Vernon used only 18. Later studies
also use limited numbers of products. Frank and Salkever (1997) have a
sample of 45 drugs; Reiffen and Ward (2002) uses 32 drugs. By using a
larger number of products concentrated in a single therapeutic category,
we hope to determine bow prices are affected by the number of sellers
for an entire group of products and avoid thorny problems associated
with the heterogeneities in product use. The analysis here also provides
a much more in-depth evaluation of the competition between branded and
generics not found in these earlier investigations.
(5.) Several studies note that the demand and supply conditions may
be different for acute versus chronic drugs. See Lu and Comanor (1998),
Scott Morton (1999, 2000).
(6.) Such acceptance may also occur because the U.S. Food certifies
the manufacture of each batch of active ingredient for anti-infectives,
but not necessarily for other drags.
(7.) See in particular, Schwartzman (1976, chapter 12). See also
Congressional Budget Office (1998, chapter 3).
(8.) Both Ellison (1998), and Griliches and Cockburn (1994) find
that average branded anti-infective prices rise with generic entry,
whereas Ellison et al. (1997) find significant responsiveness between
branded and generic products.
(9.) The IMS data we use for our empirical analysis do not include
rebates that are commonly paid by branded manufacturers to managed care.
Congressional Budget Office (1998) notes that these rebates can continue
and increase after generic entry, and thus not measuring them can
obscure an important source of price competition for branded
manufacturers. Note, however, that wholesale level data from IMS possess
the same weakness, and to the extent that such rebates are important,
our results underestimate the degree to which branded manufacturers
respond to generic entry.
(10.) The data were obtained from the National Prescription Audit
of IMS America. Total expenditures and quantity data are collected from
a stratified random sample of pharmacies and then used to construct
nationwide retail sales estimates. In the present analysis, these
monthly data have been aggregated into annual series, forming a panel
data set where the unit of observations are annual data for an
individual product sold by an individual company.
(11.) It should be noted that there may be different dosing and
different presentations, e.g. liquid versus tablet, but that regardless
of the dosing or presentation the standard practice is to write a
prescription to cure the infection--which is why physicians tenaciously encourage patients to take all of the prescription.
(12.) The analysis introduces dummy variables for each class of
products--for example, tetracyclines and penicillins--and also uses
separate dummy variables for year of introduction that allows a
flexible, nonparametric estimation of possible trends or other changes
in cost over time, reflecting increased complexity due to more
sophisticated molecules or changes in manufacturing techniques. These
controls represent a significant improvement over previous work (see,
e.g., Caves et al. 1991, who use a dummy variable by therapeutic class,
which would be the same as imposing constant costs for all products in
our sample).
(13.) The reader should note that there are seven observations
where total revenue is reported as zero and several observations where
revenue is also extraordinarily high, both yielding outliers in pricing
calculations. Reestimation without these observations does not
qualitatively change the results.
(14.) With 98 product categories and 7 years of data, there are 686
possible industry concentration outcomes. For example, there are 178
monopolies and 45 duopolies (90 price observations) making up the first
two points in Figure 1.
(15.) The coefficient on the number of sellers in the simple
price-N truncated regressions are as follows (t-statistics m
parentheses): for regressions including all chemicals (N > 0), [beta]
= -0.47 (-21.42); for the regressions including only chemicals with five
or more competitors (N [greater than or equal to] 5), [[beta] = -0.15
(-14.213); for N [greater than or equal to] 10, [beta] = -0.13 (-14.46);
for N [greater than or equal to] 20, [beta] = -0.15 (-13.38); N [greater
than or equal to] 30, [beta] = -0.06 (-3.81); N [greater than or equal
to] 40, [beta] = -0.01 (-0.43).
(16.) It should be noted that there is a single outlier for the
pioneer products, which makes some difference in the results. There
appear to be data problems with the prices for this drug, Vibramycin
(PFizer: the pioneer doxycycline). If Vibramycin is included, the effect
of N is insignificant for N [greater than or equal to] 20, and
significant and positive for N [greater than or equal to] 30. With
Vibramycin removed, the result is a significant negative coefficient for
N [greater than or equal to] 20 and negative but insignificant for N
[greater than or equal to] 30. We have not found other instances where
Vibramycin swings results in this way or other similar outliers.
(17.) The coefficients on the HHI in the truncated regressions are
as follows (t-statistics in parentheses): for the whole sample, 0.003
(24.54); restricting the sample to HHI < 5,000, 0.001 (11.48); for
HHI < 3,000, 0.002 (5.214); for HHI < 2,000, 0.005 (6.97); for HHI
< 1,000, no observations.
(18.) This information on brand names was obtained from Scientific
American Medicine. See section 3 for a more complete investigation of
our definition of brand name and how brand name affects pricing and
price competition.
(19.) The data appendix provides summary statistics for the various
fixed effects.
(20.) This method implies that separate weights are calculated for
each regression reported in the article. The results were not
qualitatively affected by using a common set of weights, except as
reported in the HHI regressions.
(21.) The analysis in section III contains a more complete
treatment of these issues.
(22.) Results with other specifications, such as using different
functional forms for N and using the HHI in place of the number of
firms, yield broadly similar results.
(23.) A complete tabulation of regression results, including the
fixed effects, is available on request.
(24.) One limitation of the approach is that it imposes the Cournot
model. A second alternative is to construct a general conjectural variations model which nests the Cournot conjecture and let the data
determine if the Cournot conjecture can be rejected. We constructed such
a model and found (using nonlinear least squares) that the Cournot
conjecture could not be rejected.
(25.) An appendix containing the results of this regression is
available on request.
(26.) Note that care must be used in interpreting these figures.
For instance, the first point in B does not represent an average
monopoly price because there may still be competition from generic
sellers even if there are no other brand name sellers of a given
chemical.
(27.) The coefficients for the number of competitors is as follows
(t-statistics in parentheses): For brand-name prices: N > 0, [beta]=
-0.95 (-8.93), N [greater than or equal to] 10, [beta]= -0.13 (-3.84), N
[greater than or equal to] 20, [beta] = -0.12 (-2.62), N [greater than
or equal to] 30, [beta] = -0.03 (-0.38), N [greater than or equal to]
40, [beta] = -0.02 (0.13). For generic prices: N > 0, -0.14 (-16.71);
N [greater than or equal to] 5, -0.12 (-14.17); N [greater than or equal
to] 10, -0.12 (-13.78); N [greater than or equal to] 20, -0.15 (-13.84);
N [greater than or equal to] 30 -0.07 (-4.40); N [greater than or equal
to] 40, -0.01 (0.38). For the HHI regressions, the coefficients are as
follows. For brand names: overall, [beta] = 0.006 (11.34); HHI <
5,000, [beta] = 0.001 (2.88); HHI < 4,000, [beta] = 0.001 (1.873),
HHI < 3,000, [beta] 0.002 (1.584); HHI < 2,000, [beta] 0.004
(1.13). For generic prices: overall, [beta]=0.0006 (9.22), HHI <
5,000, [beta] = 0.001 (10.72), HHI < 4,000, [beta] = 0.002 (9.20),
HHI < 3,000, [beta] = 0.002 (5.34), HHI < 2,000, [beta] = 0.006
(7.23).
(28.) See also Grabowski and Vernon (1992). Frank and Salkever
(1997) provide empirical support for the segmented market hypothesis by
demonstrating that branded prices tend to rise with generic entry while
generic prices tend to fall.
(29.) See, for example, Grabowski and Vernon (1992), Caves et al.
(1991), and Frank and Salkever (1997).
(30.) Due to data limitations, the unreported fixed effects
discussed earlier are pooled across all three types, pioneer, other
brand name, and generic. To the extent that these fixed effects
represent cost and demand differences among chemicals, this
specification is correct.
(31.) There are several possible reasons for these differences from
Grabowski and Vernon. Perhaps the most important is that we have a much
larger sample--they considered only 18 products. It is also possible
that their results are confounded due to difficult to control for cost
differences, or that our results are special due to the differential
characteristics of anti-infectives.
(32.) Reasons for such caution include possible cost and regulatory
differences, the fact that a single prescription is often part of a
maintenance program of therapy in other pharmaceutical areas, and such
repeated use may lead to differences in brand loyalty and competition.
REFERENCES
Applebaum, E. "The Estimation of the Degree of Oligopoly
Power." Journal of Econometrics, 19, 1982, 287-99.
Bresnahan, T. F. "Departures from Marginal-Cost Pricing in the
American Automobile Industry: Estimates for 1977-1978." Journal of
Econometrics, 11, 1981, 201-27.
--. "Empirical Studies of Industries with Market Power,"
in The Handbook of Industrial Organization, edited by R. Schmalensee and
R. Willig. North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1989.
Bresnahan, T. F., and P. C. Reiss. "Entry and Competition in
Concentrated Markets." Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 1991,
977-1009.
Caves, Richard E., Michael D. Whinston, and Mark A. Hurwitz.
"Patent Expiration, Entry and Competition in the U.S.
Pharmaceutical Industry." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity:
Microeconomics, 1991, 1-66.
Congressional Budget Office. How Increased Competition from Generic
Drugs Has Affected Prices and Returns in the Pharmaceutical Industry.
July 1998.
Dunne, Timothy, and Mark J. Roberts. "Costs, Demand, and
Imperfect Competition as Determinants of Plant-Level Output
Prices." Manuscript, Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State
University, December 1991.
Ellison, Sara F. "What Prices Can Tell Us about the Market for
Antibiotics." Working Paper, MIT, July 1998.
Ellison, Sara F., Iain Cockburn, Zvi Griliches, and Jerry Hausman.
"Characteristics of the Demand for Pharmaceutical: An Examination
of Four Cephalosporins." Rand Journal of Economics, 28(3), 1997,
426-46.
Frank, Richard G., and David S. Salkever. "Pricing, Patent
Loss and the Market for Pharmaceuticals." Southern Economic
Journal, October 1992, 165-79.
--. "Generic Entry and the Pricing of Pharmaceuticals."
Journal of Economies & Management Strategy, 6(1), 1997, 75-90.
Grabowski, Henry G., and John M. Vernon. "Brand Loyalty, Entry
and Price Competition in Pharmaceuticals after the 1984 Drug Act."
Journal of Law & Economics, 35, October 1992, 331-50.
--. "Longer Patents for Increased Generic Competition: The
Waxman-Hatch Act after One Decade." PharmacoEconomics, 10(suppl 2),
1996, 110-23.
Greene, William H. Econometric Analysis, 2nd ed. New York:
Macmillan, 1993.
Griliches, Zvi, and Iain Cockburn. "Generics and New Goods in
Pharmaceutical Price Indexes." American Economic Review, 84(5),
1994, 1213-32.
Lichtenberg, Frank R. "Are the Benefits of Newer Drugs Worth
Their Cost? Evidence from the 1996 MEPS." Health Affairs,
September/October 2001, 241-51.
Lu, Z. John, and William Comanor. "Strategic Pricing of New
Pharmaceuticals." Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, February
1998, 108-18.
Masson, Alison, and Robert L. Steiner. Generic Substitution and
Prescription Drug Prices: Economic Effects of State Product Selection
Laws. Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission, 1985.
Porter, R. "A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint Executive
Committee, 1880-1886." Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 1983, 301-14.
Reiffen, David, and Michael R. Ward. "Generic Drug Industry
Dynamics." Working Paper, FTC, February 2002.
Reiss. Peter C., and Pablo T. Spiller. "Competition and Entry
in Small Airline Markets." Journal of Law & Economics, 32,
October 1989, S179-S202.
Schmalensee, Richard. "Entry Deterrence in the Ready-to-Eat
Breakfast Cereal Industry." Bell Journal of Economics, 1978,
305-27.
Schwartzman, David. Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1976.
Scientific American Medicine. Edited by Edward Rubinstein and
Daniel Federman. New York: Scientific American, 1994.
Scott Morton, Fiona M. "Entry Decisions in the Generic
Pharmaceutical Industry." Rand Journal of Economics, 30(3), Autumn
1999, 421-40.
Scott Morton, Fiona M. "Barriers to Entry, Brand Advertising,
and Generic Entry in the US Pharmaceutical Industry." International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 2000, 1085-104.
Stern, Scott. "Product Demand in Pharmaceutical Markets."
Mimeo, Sloan School of Management, MIT, 1994.
Suslow, V. "Estimating Monopoly Behavior with Competitive
Recycling: An Application to Alcoa." Rand Journal of Economics,
17(3), 1986, 389-403.
Wiggins, Steven N., and Robert Maness. "Price Competition in
Pharmaceutical Markets: The Case of Anti-infectives." Working
Paper, Texas A&M University, 1998.
STEVEN N. WIGGINS and ROBERT MANNESS *
* We thank Michael Baye, Dean Lueck, and seminar participants at
Chicago, LSU, Penn State, Texas A&M, UCLA, the University of Texas,
and the spring 1994 meetings of the Industrial Organization Group of the
NBER for helpful comments. Financial support from Merck & Co. is
gratefully acknowledged.
Wiggins: Professor, Department of Economics, Texas A&M
University, College Station, TX 77843-4228. Phone 1-979-845-7351, Fax
1-979-847-8757, E-mail swiggins@tamu.edu
Maness: Senior Managing Economist, LECG, LLC, 2700 Earl Rudder
Frwy., Suite 4800, College Station, TX 77845. Phone 1-979-694-5780, Fax
1-979-694-2442, E-mail rmaness@lecg.com