Threshold effects in the U.S. budget deficit.
Arestis, Philip ; Cipollini, Andrea ; Fattouh, Bassam 等
I. INTRODUCTION
There has been an ongoing debate on whether the U.S. fiscal policy
is sustainable in the long run. In addressing this issue, a number of
studies have examined whether the U.S. public finances are compatible
with the government's intertemporal solvency constraint (Hamilton
and Flavin 1986; Trehan and Walsh 1988; Hakkio and Rush 1991; among
others). The requirement of budget processes to be sustainable implies
effectively that Ponzi games are ruled out as a viable option of
government finance. In other words, further new borrowing cannot be used
indefinitely as a method of financing interest payments on existing
debt. Therefore, the solvency constraint requires that any changes in
taxes and government spending are followed by adjustment in future
taxation and/or spending that equals to the original change in present
value. This solvency constraint imposes testable restrictions on the
time-series properties of key fiscal aggregates.
In this article we present new evidence on this ongoing solvency
debate utilizing an empirical framework that allows us to test whether
there have been threshold effects in the U.S. deficit. Unlike existing
empirical studies that focus only on the identification of regime shifts
in U.S. fiscal policy, we also offer an explanation and provide evidence
as to why these regime shifts might occur. Specifically, we argue that
for fiscal authorities to be able to meet the solvency constraint, they
would intervene through deficit cuts only when the government budget
deficit becomes very large. Therefore, we expect a mean reverting
dynamic behavior for deficits only when they are above some threshold
value. We test for this hypothesis using the threshold unit root
empirical methodology recently developed by Caner and Hansen (2001).
The article is organized as follows. Section II reviews the
empirical evidence. Section III describes the empirical methodology, and
section IV presents the empirical results, which are analyzed and
interpreted. Section V summarizes and concludes.
II. INTERTEMPORAL SOLVENCY CONDITION: EMPIRICAL UNDERPINNINGS
One strand of the empirical literature focuses on the stationarity
of the stock of public debt. Uctum and Wickens (1997) deal with
stochastic interest rates and primary surpluses that are allowed to be
either exogenous or endogenous to the stock of public debt. They show
that a necessary and sufficient condition for the intertemporal solvency
condition to hold is a stationary discounted stock of public debt.
Another strand of the empirical literature has concentrated on the
dynamics of the undiscounted inclusive-of-interest deficit, or
alternatively on the long-run relationship between government spending
and tax revenues. Trehan and Walsh (1988) show that government spending,
inclusive of interest payments, and government revenues should be
cointegrated with a cointegrating vector equal to [-1, 1]'. They
present evidence that supports this restriction. Hakkio and Rush (1991)
point out that a necessary condition for intertemporal solvency is the
existence of cointegration between government expenditure, inclusive of
interest payments, and government revenues, with a cointegrating vector
equal to [1, -[beta]]', and 0<[beta]< 1.
Quintos (1995) expands on Hakkio and Rush (1991) and shows that
cointegration is not necessary for the intertemporal balance condition
to hold. Specifically, she distinguishes between a weak and a strong
sustainability condition. The former implies that the government
solvency holds, but the undiscounted debt process is exploding at a rate
that is less than the growth rate of the economy. Although this case is
consistent with deficit sustainability, it is inconsistent with the
ability of the government to market its debt in the long run, especially
if the focus is on the debt to gross national product (GNP), or on the
debt per capita (see also Hakkio and Rush 1991).
In contrast, strong sustainability implies that the undiscounted
public debt is finite in the long run. As Quintos (1995) shows, strong
sustainability occurs when government spending, inclusive of interest
payments, and government revenues are cointegrated, with a cointegrating
vector that is equal to [-1, [beta]]', with [beta] = 1.
Alternatively, strong sustainability occurs if the total government
deficit series (inclusive of interest payments) is stationary. Weak
solvency occurs when 0 < [beta] < 1, regardless of the order of
integration of the estimated cointegrating regression residuals.
Empirical research on U.S. public deficit sustainability has
emphasized the importance of taking into account the possibility of
regime shifts in U.S. fiscal policy. Most of the studies that tested for
the presence of these shifts consider models with structural breaks,
where the breakpoints are either chosen arbitrarily (e.g., they are
exogenous) or are endogenously determined. Specifically, in the
empirical works of Hakkio and Rush (1991) and Tanner and Liu (1994), the
breakpoint is exogenously determined. Hakkio and Rush (1991) use a
sample that spans from the first quarter of 1952 to the fourth quarter
of 1988 and find that the intertemporal budget constraint is satisfied
in subsamples up until 1976 but that for the subsample 1976:1 to 1988:4
the constraint is violated. Tanner and Liu (1994) find evidence of
strong solvency by imposing a dummy variable for a level shift in the
cointegration vector at predefined points, that is, 1982(1) and 1981(4).
With the level dummy incorporated, they find evidence of cointegration
and acceptance of the null that [beta] is equal to unity. Haug (1995)
and Quintos (1995) allow for the breakpoint to be endogenously
determined. Using a recursive test for the stability of the
cointegrating vector [1, -[beta]]', Haug (1995) does not detect any
structural change in the conduct of U.S. fiscal policy over the past
four decades. Quintos (1995) uses a statistical procedure that is very
similar to that used by Haug (1995) with only the null hypothesis being
different.
Quintos (1995) suggests that the U.S. deficit process has undergone
a shift in recent times, with deficit being sustainable only in a weak
sense in the post-1980 period. Most recently, Martin (2000) examined
sustainability on the basis of a cointegration model with multiple
endogenous breaks in both the intercept and slope parameters. For this
purpose, Martin (2000) applies a Bayesian methodology incorporating
Markov chain Monte Carlo simulators and finds evidence of multiple
breaks and strong sustainability over the whole sample period. This
sample period is 1947-92 and is the same as that used by Quintos (1995).
In this article we extend the period to 2002:1.
Moreover, we attempt to take the literature on U.S. deficit with
structural breaks one step further by offering an explanation and
providing evidence for the occurrence of regime shifts in the budget
deficit. For this purpose, we follow Bertola and Drazen (1993), who show
that the government solvency requirement implies that any increase in
current government spending (which has the effect of increasing the
current fiscal deficit) has a nonlinear effect on the expected present
discounted value of the future government spending. Under these
circumstances linear techniques may not be accurate in characterizing
the deficit process. Specifically, the authors develop a framework in
which there exist trigger points in the process of budget cuts, such
that significant reduction in budget deficits may take place only when
the ratio of deficit to output reaches a certain threshold. This may
reflect the existence of political constraints blocking deficit cuts,
which are relaxed only when the budget deficit reaches a sufficiently
high level, deemed to be unsustainable (Bertola and Drazen 1993; Alesina
and Drazen 1991). Consequently, in our empirical model we expect the
fiscal process to follow different dynamics depending on whether the
change in the deficit is below or above that threshold. Mean reverting
dynamic behavior for deficits is present only when the change in the
deficit is above a certain threshold. For this reason, we use a
threshold autoregressive (TAR) model, in which the deviations of a
threshold variable (observable) from a trigger point (to be estimated)
are used to explain the occurrence of (possible) regime shifts in the
U.S. deficit. It is customary to test the null of linearity against the
alternative of a specific nonlinear process (a TAR model, in this
article) only after finding evidence of a stationary time series on the
basis of standard linear unit root tests. This sequential testing
procedure may affect the inference results (1) In this article we follow
Caner and Hansen (2001), the first to allow for a joint test for
linearity and stationarity in the time series under investigation.
Our empirical results reveal the following important findings. The
U.S. budget deficit is sustainable in the long run, but it has undergone
regime shifts. These two results are consistent with those of many
existing empirical studies. We also find evidence that these regime
shifts can be explained by the extent of the change in the deficit. More
specifically, only when the increase in deficit per capita reaches a
certain threshold will fiscal authorities intervene to reduce the
deficit. Hence, we are able to identify two regimes, with the budget
deficit following different dynamics in each one of them. These results
provide support for the existence of trigger points in the U.S. fiscal
policy adjustment.
III. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY
Standard unit root and cointegration estimation procedures assume
that there is a tendency for a variable to move toward a long-run
equilibrium in every time period. However, as Balke and Fomby (1997)
observe, movements toward the long-run equilibrium need not occur in
every period. The presence of fixed costs of adjustment, for instance,
may imply that only when the deviation from the equilibrium exceeds a
critical threshold do the benefits exceed the costs of adjustment, and,
therefore, economic agents act to move back to equilibrium. This type of
discrete adjustment process has been used to describe many economic
phenomena, such as the behavior of inventories or investment. In this
work we attempt to characterize the discrete adjustment in the policy
makers' attitude toward public finance solvency in terms of a
threshold stationary process for the government deficit.
The TAR model was introduced by Tong (1978), who considered the
possibility of a mean reverting time series only after hitting a certain
threshold. Chan (1993) demonstrated that the least squares estimates of
the threshold is superconsistent and found its asymptotic distribution,
and Hansen (1997) developed an alternative approximation to the
asymptotic distribution of the threshold. Chan (1991) and Hansen (1996)
studied the asymptotic distribution of the likelihood ratio test for a
threshold. Balke and Fomby (1997) extended the idea of threshold effects
to a long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship among different
series. All these studies rely on the assumption of stationary data and
therefore do not discriminate between nonstationary and/or nonlinear
time series. The work of Caner and Hansen (2001) is the first to provide
statistical tests for the null of a stationary TAR process, which
simultaneously allow for both effects.
The Econometric Framework
The TAR model can be described by
(1) [DELTA][y.sub.t] = [[theta]'.sub.1][X.sub.t-1]([Z.sub.T-1]
< [lambda]) + [[DELTA]'.sub.2][x.sub.t-1]I([Z.sub.t-1] [greater
than or equal to] [lambda]) + [u.sub.t]
where t = 1, ... T;[x.sub.t-1] = (int, [y.sub.t-1],
[DELTA][y.sub.t-1] ... [[DELTA].sub.t-k])';I(x) is the indicator
function, and [u.sub.t] is an i.i.d error. The threshold variable
[Z.sub.t-1] = [y.sub.t-1] - [y.sub.t-m-1], is predetermined and strictly
stationary, and m is the delay order. (2) The deterministic component
int stands for an intercept; [DELTA][y.sub.t-j] = [y.sub.t-j]-
[y.sub.t-j-1] is the first-order difference at lag j. The threshold
[lambda] is unknown, and it takes values in the interval [lambda]
[member of] [LAMBDA] = [[[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2]], where
[[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2] are chosen so that Prob([Z.sub.t]
[less than or equal to] [[lambda].sub.1]) = [[pi].sub.1] > 0 and
Prob([Z.sub.t] [less than or equal to] [[lambda].sub.2])= [[pi].sub.2]
< 1. (3) In so far as the description of the empirical methodology is
concerned, it is convenient to consider the vectors [[theta].sub.1] =
([[rho].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [[alpha].sub.1])' and [[theta].sub.2]
= ([[rho].sub.2] [[beta].sub.2] [[alpha].sub.2])', where
[[rho].sub.1] and [[rho].sub.2] are the slopes on the lagged levels,
[[beta].sub.2] and [[beta].sub.2] are the slopes on the deterministic
component, and [[alpha].sub.1] and [[alpha].sub.2] are the slopes on the
lagged differences in the two regimes.
When estimating the TAR model, for each [lambda] [member of]
[LAMBDA], we estimate [[theta].sub.1] and [[theta].sub.2] by least
squares (LS). The LS point estimate of the threshold [lambda], and of
the corresponding vectors [[theta].sub.1] and [[theta].sub.2] are those
that minimize the residual sum of squares. To test the null hypothesis
of linearity, that is, [H.sub.0]: [[theta].sub.1] = [[theta].sub.2],
against the alternative of threshold effects, we use a Wald test statistic, [W.sub.T]. The latter is not identified under the null; its
asymptotic distribution, under the assumption of stationary data, was
investigated by Davies (1987), Chan (1991), Andrews and Ploberger
(1994), and Hansen (1996). Caner and Hansen (2001) find that under the
restriction of a unit root process, the asymptotic distribution of
[W.sub.T] depends on the data structure, which implies that critical
values cannot be tabulated, and therefore the authors suggest two
bootstrap methods to approximate the asymptotic distribution of
[W.sub.T]. One method is appropriate for the stationary case, and the
other is appropriate for the unit root case. If the true order of
integration is unknown, then Caner and Hansen (2001) suggest calculating
the bootstrap critical values and p-values both ways and base inference
on the more conservative (larger) p-value. Furthermore, the authors
suggest that setting the bounds of the trimming region to [[pi].sub.1] =
0.15 and [[pi].sub.2] = 0.85 provides a reasonable trade-off between the
power and size properties of the test for threshold effects (see Caner
and Hansen 2001 for details). (4)
Unit Root Tests
As for the unit root tests, the following statistics are employed:
1. Two-sided Wald test statistic, [R.sub.2T], for the null of unit
root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.1] = 0, against the
alternative [H.sub.1]: [[rho].sub.1] [not equal to] 0 or [[rho].sub.2]
[not equal to] 0;
2. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [R.sub.1T], for the null of
unit root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.2] = 0, against the
alternative [H.sub.1]: [[rho].sub.1] < 0 or [[rho].sub.2] < 0;
3. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [t.sub.1], for the null of unit
root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.2] = 0, against the
alternative ofstationarity only in regime 1, that is, [H.sub.1]:
[[rho].sub.1] <0 and [[rho].sub.2] = 0;
4. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [t.sub.2], for the null of unit
root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.1] = 0, against the
alternative of stationarity only in regime 2 that is, [H.sub.1] :
[[rho].sub.1] = 0 and [[rho].sub.1] < 0.
The first two test statistics allow us to test whether the series
under study is stationary. In the context of this study, these test
statistics can be used to examine whether the U.S. budget deficit is
sustainable in the long run. The third and fourth test statistics allow
us to identify which of the regimes is stationary. This identification
is important because it allows us to examine whether budget deficits
follow different dynamics after they reach a certain threshold. As
mentioned, it could be the case that fiscal authorities will intervene
to cut the budget deficit only when the increase in the per capita
deficit has reached a certain threshold.
If there are no threshold effects (unidentified case), the
asymptotic distribution of each of the four statistics is found to be
dependent on the data structure. However, asymptotic bounds, free of
nuisance parameters other than the trimming range, are found.
Consequently, critical values can be tabulated, and p-values can be
computed (see Table 3 in Caner and Hansen 2001). As for the asymptotic
distribution of each of the four statistics in the presence of threshold
effects (identified case), the authors find that the Dickey-Fuller
tabulated critical values provide a conservative bound for the [t.sub.1]
and [t.sub.2] tests. Furthermore, they find that the expression derived
for the asymptotic distributions of the one-sided [R.sub.1] test and of
the two-sided [R.sub.2] test are only useful for computing the critical
values for the latter. (5) Finally, improved finite sample inference may
be conducted using a bootstrap distribution for both the unidentified
and identified threshold cases.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The data set used in this study comprises quarterly observations
over the period 1947:2 to 2002:1. Our focus is on the dynamics of the
total (inclusive of interest payments) real per capita U.S. government
surplus (see Figure 1). (6) Hence, we concentrate only on the strong
sustainability condition (see Quintos 1995 for details). Following
Franses and Van Dijk (2000), we use the minimization of the Akaike
(1973) information criteria (AIC) and Hannan and Quinn (1979) (HQ)
statistics to detect the appropriate lag order k and delay parameter m
for the threshold variable. (7) It is clear from Tables 1 and 2 that
both criteria suggest a lag order of four and a delay parameter of order
two for the TAR process in (3). Hence, the semiannual change in the
surplus per capita ([y.sub.t-1] - [y.sub.t-3]) is the chosen threshold
variable.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In Table 3, we report the threshold test and the unit root tests
for the TAR model with a delay parameter of order two. The bootstrap
p-values (both unrestricted and under the unit root assumption)
corresponding to the Wald tests [W.sub.T] indicate that we can reject
the null hypothesis of linearity in favor of the alternative that there
is a threshold effect in the U.S. budget surplus per capita. This
indicates that the U.S. fiscal policy has undergone structural shifts, a
conclusion reached by most empirical studies (Martin 2000; Quintos 1995;
among others).
The unit root tests show some interesting results regarding the
time-series properties of the U.S. real per capita budget surplus. Both
the one-sided and the two-sided [R.sub.2] Wald tests give evidence of
stationary process. However, the individual t-ratios tests, [t.sub.1]
and [t.sub.1], identify the presence of a unit root only in the second
regime. (8) In fact, these results are confirmed by the LS estimates of
the TAR model reported in Table 4, where there is evidence of a
statistically significant mean reverting dynamics only in the lower
regime, that is, when the (semiannual) change in the surplus per capita
reaches the estimated threshold point estimate of-0.313. (9) These
results suggest that the dynamics of the budget surplus per capita are
different depending on whether the (semiannual) change in surplus per
capita is above or below the estimated threshold value.
In Figure 2 we construct a confidence interval for the threshold
parameter following the method of Hansen (2000). The bounds of this
confidence interval are given by the intersection of the likelihood
ratio sequence plot and a flat line at the appropriate asymptotic
critical value. (10) For the 90% confidence interval, the critical value
is 5.94 (see Hansen 2000; Table 1), and the lower and upper bounds are -
1.78 and -0.01, respectively. This confidence region would suggest that
politicians would become sensitive to budget deficits only when the
semiannual decrease in the real surplus per capita (or increase in the
real deficit per capita) is either bad enough or shows up in the books
(given that the upper bound is close to zero). A 95% confidence interval
would confirm these conclusions. (11)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
There is also evidence of delays in the fiscal stabilization plans,
because the lag order of the TAR process is equal to four (quarters) and
policy makers react only after half a year to an undesirable decrease in
the surplus per capita. This delay can be explained by taking into
account political and institutional frictions. More concretely, in the
U.S. case, all rules and regulations according to which budgets are
drafted, approved, and implemented can imply long delays in modifying
budget deficits. Alesina and Perotti (1996a; 1996b) review the effect of
voting procedures in the preparation and implementation of the budget on
delays in fiscal stabilization plans and conclude in a similar vein.
Further Discussion
In Figure 3, we plot the deviations of the semiannual change in the
surplus per capita (threshold variable) from the estimated threshold
point estimate over the sample period. Note that in this figure positive
values identify the upper regime, and negative values identify the lower
regime (which includes 40% of the total sample observations). We impose
horizontal lines in the figure to identify the dates of the most
significant switches during the period under study. (12) During the
1950s and early 1960s, regime shifts were mainly related to recessions
and/or wartime. Figure 3 shows a major shift in U.S. budgetary policy
during the Korean War, when there is an abrupt shift in 1951:2 from a
large real surplus per capita to a large real deficit per capita,
reaching a peak in 1951:3. During Eisenhower's presidency, there
were two minor shifts in 1957:3 and 1960:4 caused mainly by two
short-lived recessions (Evans 1990). During the 1960s, the figure shows
three main switches from surplus to deficit (1964:2, 1967:1, and
1969:3), occurring during Johnson's presidency. These switches
correspond in part to the tax cut proposals initiated by Kennedy and
promoted and signed as law during Johnson's presidency. They also
correspond to the budgetary requirements of the Vietnam War, which
increased significantly especially in 1967, and the sharp increases in
domestic spending associated with the Great Society Programs (Ippolito
1990). (13) A major shift from per capita surplus to per capita deficit
occurs in 1974:3, peaks in 1975:2, and corresponds to the 1973 oil
crisis, which plunged the U.S. economy into a deep recession.14 This
switch into per capita deficit is bigger than the one associated with
the second oil crisis period of 1979:4, and peaking in 1980:2.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 3 clearly shows another major shift in 1981:3. This date is
quite significant because it is the largest switch experienced in period
of peace, tranquility, and without external shocks. This shift, which
occurred at the beginning of the Reagan presidency, corresponded to the
legislation passed by Congress aimed at cutting personal income taxes
over the next three years (the 1981 Economic Recovery Tax Act). Because
the tax cuts were not met by equal cuts in government spending, the
federal budget went into deficit and remained so for a considerable
period of time. It is interesting to note that many regime shifts
(1985:3, 1986:3, and 1989:3) occurred during Reagan's presidency,
mainly in his second term. Those regime switches reflect in part the
intensive political and economic debate in Congress and in the media and
the efforts to reduce the large and growing budget deficit. Those
efforts were manifested in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Balanced
Budget and Emergency Deficit Control Act, which called for progressive
reduction in the deficit and the achievement of a balanced budget by the
early 1990s (Ippolito 1990). Despite efforts to balance the budget,
other major shifts from per capita surplus to per capita deficit
occurred in 1989:3 and in 1991:3. Those switches occurred during the
Bush (Senior) presidency and correspond closely to a recession that
plunged the economy at the beginning of Bush's term and later to
the budgetary requirements of the Gulf War. Those deficits did not last
long, and in 1993:1 the budget went into surplus and remained so for the
rest of the 1990s. This coincided with President Clinton's move to
the White House and the importance he attached to balancing the budget
in his economic policy.
Finally, the graph shows another switch from a per capita surplus
to a per capita deficit in 2001:1. This switch can be explained by
resorting to the slowing of the economy after a period of exceptional
growth. The peak of the deficit in 2001:3 can be justified by referring,
in addition to the continuing slowdown, to the preparations for the war
in Afghanistan. It is of note that out of the 14 switches identified in
the graph, 5 of them took place during Democrat presidency and 9 during
Republican presidency.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
In this article, we have been concerned with investigating
empirically the long-run sustainability of fiscal policy in the United
States during the period spanning from 1947 to 2002. The theoretical
framework has been provided by the government intertemporal budget
constraint. The latter states that the discounted value of the public
debt stock tends to zero over time, and it has testable implications on
the process driving the total government deficit. By contrast to
previous studies, which focused on the possibility of structural breaks
in the deficit dynamics, we provide an explanation and gauge evidence
for the occurrence of regime shifts in U.S. fiscal policy. Using a
threshold unit root estimation procedure recently proposed by Caner and
Hansen (2001), we provide evidence that the U.S. fiscal policy has
undergone structural shifts in the past four decades. Our findings
suggest that these switches are driven by asymmetries in the adjustment
process, an issue not addressed previously in the literature. More
specifically government authorities would intervene b) cutting deficits
only when they have reached a certain threshold.
ABBREVIATIONS
AIC: Akaike Information Criteria
GNP: Gross National Product
HQ: Hannan and Quinn
LS: Least Squares
NIPA: National Income and Product Accounts
TAR: Threshold Autoregressive
APPENDIX: DATA
The data for nominal government spending (net of interest payments)
and government revenues are the National Income and Product Accounts
(NIPA) figures in billions of U.S. dollars. Real government spending and
real government revenues are obtained by dividing the nominal values of
government spending and government revenues by the GNP price deflator (1996 is the base year). Both nominal GNP and real GNP (in 1996 dollars)
were obtained from NIPA. To calculate the interest payments we first
deflated the previous period's market value of the privately held
gross federal debt by the GNP deflator. The market value of the debt was
obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. We then multiplied
this by the appropriately deflated nominal interest rates, following
Hakkio and Rush (1991). Because we focus on real surplus per capita, we
use the ex post realinterest rate minus the rate of population growth.
For the nominal interest rate, we use the Treasury long-term bond yields
obtained from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release. Population
figures are the midperiod estimation obtained from NIPA.
TABLE 1
AIC Lag and Delay Orders Choice
k 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
m
1 0.892 0.951 0.917 0.852 0.853 0.942 0.980
2 -- 0.933 0.902 0.835 0.854 0.938 0.949
3 -- -- 0.904 0.870 0.879 0.963 0.974
4 -- -- -- 0.906 0.887 0.955 0.980
5 -- -- -- -- 0.914 0.947 0.970
6 -- -- -- -- -- 0.988 0.986
7 -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.982
8 -- -- -- -- -- -- --
k 8
m
1 0.992
2 0.989
3 0.999
4 1.01
5 0.989
6 1.01
7 1.02
8 1.10
Note: m is the delay order in the long difference [y.sub.t-1] -
[y.sub.t-m-1], and k denotes the lag length.
TABLE 2
HQ Lag and Delay Orders Choice
k 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
m
1 1.02 1.08 1.05 0.980 0.982 1.07 1.11
2 -- 1.05 1.02 0.951 0.970 1.05 1.06
3 -- -- 1.01 0.972 0.981 1.06 1.08
4 -- -- -- 0.995 0.976 1.04 1.07
5 -- -- -- -- 0.990 1.02 1.05
6 -- -- -- -- -- 1.05 1.05
7 -- -- -- -- -- -- 1.03
8 -- -- -- -- -- -- --
k 8
m
1 1.12
2 1.10
3 1.10
4 1.10
5 1.06
6 1.08
7 1.07
8 1.14
Note: m is the delay order in the long difference [y.sub.t-1] -
[y.sub.t-m-1], and k denotes the lag length.
TABLE 3
Threshold and Unit Root Tests for the TAR Model
Bootstrap threshold test (a)
Wald statistic = 25.8 Boot. p-value = 0.015 Asym. p-value = 0.015
Two-sided Wald test for unit root (b)
Wald statistic = 16.6 Boot. p-value = 0.019 Asym. p-value = 0.016
One-sided Wald test for unit root (b)
Wald statistic = 16.2 Boot. p-value = 0.019 Asym. p-value = 0.014
[t.sub.1]-test for stationarity (c)
t-stat = 4.03 Boot. p-value = 0.004 Asym. p-value = 0.006
[t.sub.2]-test for stationarity (d)
t-stat = -0.587 Boot. p-value = 0.899 Asym. p-value = 0.861
Notes: The p-values for the threshold and unit root tests were obtained
by 5000 bootstrap replications. The results reported in the table
correspond to a trimming region (which defines the bounds [[pi].sub.1],
and [[pi].sub.2] within which the threshold falls) given by the values
[0.15, 0.85]. The results (available on request from the authors) are
robust to different trimming regions. We have used Gauss for all
estimations reported in Table 3.
(a) The Wald statistic tests the null of linearity against the
alternative of threshold effect (the bootstrap p-values reported are
for the unrestricted and unit root restriction cases).
(b) The two-sided [R.sub.2] and one-sided [R.sub.1] Wald statistics
test the null of unit root against the alternative that either the
first or the second regime is threshold stationary (both the
asymptotic and the bootstrap p-values are reported).
(c) The [t.sub.1] statistic tests the null of unit root against the
alternative that the first regime is stationary (both the asymptotic
and the bootstrap p-values are reported).
(d) The [t.sub.2] statistic to test the null of unit root against the
alternative that the second regime is stationary (both the asymptotic
and the bootstrap p-values are reported).
TABLE 4
Estimation of TAR
Variable Regime 1 Regime 2
Intercept -0.831 0.382
(0.262) (0.220)
Y(t-1) -0.137 0.018
(0.034) (0.032)
DY(t-1) -0.082 -0.238
(0.107) (0.123)
DY(t-2) 0.010 0.221
(0.106) (0.120)
DY(t-3) 0.155 -0.109
(0.094) (0.101)
DY(t-4) -0.237 -0.172
(0.097) (0.095)
(1.) In Cipollini (2001) (see also Sarno 2001, where the analysis
is in line with Cipollini), a smooth transition regression model is
employed to describe the nonlinear dynamics of the UK budget deficit.
This is undertaken to explain and provide evidence as to why regime
shifts in the budget deficit occur. However, the linearity test used is
conditional on the stationary properties of the data.
(2.) It is important to observe that the threshold variable not
only can be the long difference, but also can be the lagged first-order
difference or the lagged level. However, in the empirical analysis we
found evidence of nonlinearity only when the long difference is used as
the threshold variable. In other words, policy makers intervene when the
change over the year in the deficit per capita reaches a certain
threshold.
(3.) Caner and Hansen (2001) observe that it is typical to treat
[[pi].sub.1] and [[pi].sub.2] symmetrically so that [[pi].sub.2] = 1 -
[[pi].sub.1], which imposes the restriction that no regime has less than
[[pi].sub.1]% observations of the total sample.
(4.) However, as the authors observe, because this particular
choice is somewhat arbitrary, it would be sensible in practical
applications to explore the robustness of the results to this choice. As
we suggest in Table 3, our results are robust in this sense.
(5.) The bounds, free of nuisance parameters, of the 10%, 5%, and
1% critical values for the two-sided [R.sub.2] test are 11.17, 13.12,
and 17.29, respectively.
(6.) For a detailed description of the variables and data sources,
see the data appendix.
(7.) Given the number of observations T, the number of regressors
n, and the estimated residual sum of squares RSS, the AIC statistic is
equal to log (RSS) +2n/T. The HQ statistic is log (RSS) + 2n
log(log(T))/T.
(8.) The asymptotic p-values and the calculated bootstrapped
p-values are those corresponding to the unidentified threshold case (see
section II for discussion, and Caner and Hansen 2001 for details).
(9.) The shift in the error correcting dynamics of the surplus per
capita is statistically significant, because 0.015 is the bootstrap
p-value for the Wald test of the null that the slopes on the lagged
value across the two regimes are equal.
(10.) The likelihood ratio sequence for the threshold guesses is
defined as L[R.sub.n]([lambda]) = [[S.sub.n]([lambda]) - [S.sub.n]
([lambda])]/[[sigma].sup.n], where [S.sub.n]([lambda]) and
[S.sub.n]([lambda]) are the residual sums of squared error sequence and
the corresponding minimum, respectively, and [[sigma].sup.2] is the
residual variance from LS estimation.
(11.) The bounds for the 95% confidence interval are [-1.74, 0.34],
where the upper bound is still close to zero. It is also the case that
this confidence interval is still skewed toward negative values.
(12.) To not overcrowd the figure, we only identify the most
significant shifts from per capita surplus to per capita deficit.
(13.) From 1967 onward, Johnson finally realized that there was an
urgent need to control the deficit and called for an increase in tax
revenues through a tax surcharge (Ippolito 1990). Those efforts are
reflected partly in Figure 3, where those is evidence of many switches
from per capita deficit to per capita surplus. Those efforts, however,
were interrupted more than once by the financing requirements of the
Vietnam War.
(14.) Earlier minor switches in the late 1960s and early 1970s,
which occurred in Nixon's presidency, were mainly related to the
financing of the Vietnam War.
REFERENCES
Akaike, A. "Information Theory and an Extension of the Maximum
Likelihood Principle," in Second International Symposium of
Information Theory, edited b) B. N. Petrov and F. L. Saki, Budapest,
1973.
Alesina, A., and R. Drazen. "Why Are Stabilisation
Delayed?" American Economic Review, 82, 1991, 1170-88.
Alesina, A., and R. Peroni. "Budget Deficits and Budge
Institutions," NBER Working Paper No. 5556 1996a. Cambridge, MA.
--. "Fiscal Discipline and the Budget Process. American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceeding 86, 1996b, 40l-7.
Andrews, D. W. K., and W. Ploberger. "Optimal Tests When a
Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only under the Alternative."
Econometrica, 62, 1994, 1383-414.
Balke, N. S., and T. B. Fomby. "Threshold Cointegration."
International Economic Review, 38, 1997, 627-45.
Bertola, G., and A. Drazen. "Trigger Points and Budget Cuts:
Explaining the Effects of Fiscal Austerity. American Economic Review,
83(1), 1993, 11-26.
Caner, M., and B. E. Hansen. "Threshold Autoregression with a
Unit Root." Econometrica, 69, 2001, 1555-96.
Chan, K. S. "Percentage Points of Likelihood Ratio Tests for
Threshold Autoregression." Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B, 53, 1991, 691-96.
--. "Consistency and Limiting Distribution of the Least
Squares Estimator of a Threshold Autoregressive Model." Annals of
Statistics, 21, 1993, 520-33.
Cipollini, A. "Testing for Government Intertemporal Solvency:
A Smooth Transition Error Correction Model Approach." Manchester
School, 69(6), 2001, 643-55.
Davies, R. B. "Hypothesis Testing When a Nuisance Parameter Is
Present Only under the Alternative." Biometrika, 74, 1987, 33-43.
Evans, G. R. Red Ink. The Budget, Deficit, and Debt of the US
Government. San Diego: Academic Press, 1990.
Franses, P. H., and Van Dijk, D. Non-Linear Time Series Models in
Empirical Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.
Hakkio, C. S., and M. Rush. "Is the Budget Deficit 'Too
Large'?" Economic Inquiry, 29, 1991, 429-45.
Hamilton, J. D., and M. A. Flavin. "On the Limitation of
Government Borrowing: A Framework for Empirical Testing." American
Economic Review, 76. 1986,808-19.
Hannan, E. J., and B. G. Qainn. "The Determination of the
Order of an Autoregression." Journal of the Royal Statistical
Society B, 41, 1979, 190-95.
Hansen, B. E. "Inference When a Nuisance Parameter Is Not
Identified under the Null Hypothesis." Econometrica, 64, 1996,
413-30.
--. "Inference in TAR Models." Studies in Nonlinear
Dynamics and Econometrics, 1, 1997, 119-31.
Hansen, B. "Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation."
Econometrica, 68, 2000, 575-603.
Haug, A. "Has Federal Budget Deficit Policy Changed in Recent
Years?" Economic Inquiry, 33, 1995, 104-18.
Ippolito, D. S. Uncertain Legacies: Federal Budget Policy from
Roosevelt through Reagan. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia,
1990.
Martin, G. M. "US Deficit Sustainability: A New Approach Based
on Multiple Endogenous Breaks." Journal of Applied Econometrics,
15, 2000, 83-105.
Quintos, C. E. "Sustainability of the Deficit Process with
Structural Shifts." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,
13, 1995, 409-17.
Sarno, L. "The Behavior of US Public Debt: A NonLinear
Perspective." Economics Letters, 74, 2001, 119-25.
Tanner, E., and P. Liu. "Is the Budget Deficit 'Too
Large': Some Further Evidence." Economic Inquiry, 32, 1994,
511-18.
Tong, H. "On a Threshold Model," in Pattern Recognition
and Signal Processing, edited by C. H. Chen. Amsterdam: Sijoff and
Noordhoff, 1978.
Trehan, B., and C. E. Walsh. "Common Trends, The Government
Budget Constraint and Revenue Smoothing." Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 1988, 425-44.
Uctum, M., and M. Wickens. "Debt and Deficit Ceilings, and
Sustainability of Fiscal Policies: An Intertemporal Analysis." CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1612, 1997.
PHILIP ARESTIS, ANDREA CIPOLLINI, and BASSAM FATTOUH *
* We are grateful to an anonymous referee for helpfulcomments. We
are also grateful to Bruce Hansen for helpful suggestions and for making
available his Gauss Programme to estimate and make inferences on the TAR
model. The usual disclaimer applies.
Arestis: Professor, Department of Land Economy, University of
Cambridge, 19 Silver Street, Cambridge CB3 9EP, U.K. Phone
44-0-1223-766-971, Fax 44-01223-337-160, E-mail pa267@cam.ac.uk
Cipollini: Lecturer in Economics, Queen Mary and Westfield College,
University of London, Mile End Road, London, E1 4NS, U.K. Phone
44-020-7893-5905, Fax 44-020-7893-3580, E-mail a.cipollini@qmul.ac.uk
Fattouh: Lecturer in Financial Economics, CeFiMS, SoAS, University
of London, Thornhaugh Street, Russell Square, London WC1H 0HG, U.K.
Phone 44-020-7898-4053, Fax 44-020-7898-4089, E-mail bfll@soas.ac.uk