首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月30日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Threshold effects in the U.S. budget deficit.
  • 作者:Arestis, Philip ; Cipollini, Andrea ; Fattouh, Bassam
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2004
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:There has been an ongoing debate on whether the U.S. fiscal policy is sustainable in the long run. In addressing this issue, a number of studies have examined whether the U.S. public finances are compatible with the government's intertemporal solvency constraint (Hamilton and Flavin 1986; Trehan and Walsh 1988; Hakkio and Rush 1991; among others). The requirement of budget processes to be sustainable implies effectively that Ponzi games are ruled out as a viable option of government finance. In other words, further new borrowing cannot be used indefinitely as a method of financing interest payments on existing debt. Therefore, the solvency constraint requires that any changes in taxes and government spending are followed by adjustment in future taxation and/or spending that equals to the original change in present value. This solvency constraint imposes testable restrictions on the time-series properties of key fiscal aggregates.
  • 关键词:Budget deficits;Fiscal policy

Threshold effects in the U.S. budget deficit.


Arestis, Philip ; Cipollini, Andrea ; Fattouh, Bassam 等


I. INTRODUCTION

There has been an ongoing debate on whether the U.S. fiscal policy is sustainable in the long run. In addressing this issue, a number of studies have examined whether the U.S. public finances are compatible with the government's intertemporal solvency constraint (Hamilton and Flavin 1986; Trehan and Walsh 1988; Hakkio and Rush 1991; among others). The requirement of budget processes to be sustainable implies effectively that Ponzi games are ruled out as a viable option of government finance. In other words, further new borrowing cannot be used indefinitely as a method of financing interest payments on existing debt. Therefore, the solvency constraint requires that any changes in taxes and government spending are followed by adjustment in future taxation and/or spending that equals to the original change in present value. This solvency constraint imposes testable restrictions on the time-series properties of key fiscal aggregates.

In this article we present new evidence on this ongoing solvency debate utilizing an empirical framework that allows us to test whether there have been threshold effects in the U.S. deficit. Unlike existing empirical studies that focus only on the identification of regime shifts in U.S. fiscal policy, we also offer an explanation and provide evidence as to why these regime shifts might occur. Specifically, we argue that for fiscal authorities to be able to meet the solvency constraint, they would intervene through deficit cuts only when the government budget deficit becomes very large. Therefore, we expect a mean reverting dynamic behavior for deficits only when they are above some threshold value. We test for this hypothesis using the threshold unit root empirical methodology recently developed by Caner and Hansen (2001).

The article is organized as follows. Section II reviews the empirical evidence. Section III describes the empirical methodology, and section IV presents the empirical results, which are analyzed and interpreted. Section V summarizes and concludes.

II. INTERTEMPORAL SOLVENCY CONDITION: EMPIRICAL UNDERPINNINGS

One strand of the empirical literature focuses on the stationarity of the stock of public debt. Uctum and Wickens (1997) deal with stochastic interest rates and primary surpluses that are allowed to be either exogenous or endogenous to the stock of public debt. They show that a necessary and sufficient condition for the intertemporal solvency condition to hold is a stationary discounted stock of public debt. Another strand of the empirical literature has concentrated on the dynamics of the undiscounted inclusive-of-interest deficit, or alternatively on the long-run relationship between government spending and tax revenues. Trehan and Walsh (1988) show that government spending, inclusive of interest payments, and government revenues should be cointegrated with a cointegrating vector equal to [-1, 1]'. They present evidence that supports this restriction. Hakkio and Rush (1991) point out that a necessary condition for intertemporal solvency is the existence of cointegration between government expenditure, inclusive of interest payments, and government revenues, with a cointegrating vector equal to [1, -[beta]]', and 0<[beta]< 1.

Quintos (1995) expands on Hakkio and Rush (1991) and shows that cointegration is not necessary for the intertemporal balance condition to hold. Specifically, she distinguishes between a weak and a strong sustainability condition. The former implies that the government solvency holds, but the undiscounted debt process is exploding at a rate that is less than the growth rate of the economy. Although this case is consistent with deficit sustainability, it is inconsistent with the ability of the government to market its debt in the long run, especially if the focus is on the debt to gross national product (GNP), or on the debt per capita (see also Hakkio and Rush 1991).

In contrast, strong sustainability implies that the undiscounted public debt is finite in the long run. As Quintos (1995) shows, strong sustainability occurs when government spending, inclusive of interest payments, and government revenues are cointegrated, with a cointegrating vector that is equal to [-1, [beta]]', with [beta] = 1. Alternatively, strong sustainability occurs if the total government deficit series (inclusive of interest payments) is stationary. Weak solvency occurs when 0 < [beta] < 1, regardless of the order of integration of the estimated cointegrating regression residuals.

Empirical research on U.S. public deficit sustainability has emphasized the importance of taking into account the possibility of regime shifts in U.S. fiscal policy. Most of the studies that tested for the presence of these shifts consider models with structural breaks, where the breakpoints are either chosen arbitrarily (e.g., they are exogenous) or are endogenously determined. Specifically, in the empirical works of Hakkio and Rush (1991) and Tanner and Liu (1994), the breakpoint is exogenously determined. Hakkio and Rush (1991) use a sample that spans from the first quarter of 1952 to the fourth quarter of 1988 and find that the intertemporal budget constraint is satisfied in subsamples up until 1976 but that for the subsample 1976:1 to 1988:4 the constraint is violated. Tanner and Liu (1994) find evidence of strong solvency by imposing a dummy variable for a level shift in the cointegration vector at predefined points, that is, 1982(1) and 1981(4). With the level dummy incorporated, they find evidence of cointegration and acceptance of the null that [beta] is equal to unity. Haug (1995) and Quintos (1995) allow for the breakpoint to be endogenously determined. Using a recursive test for the stability of the cointegrating vector [1, -[beta]]', Haug (1995) does not detect any structural change in the conduct of U.S. fiscal policy over the past four decades. Quintos (1995) uses a statistical procedure that is very similar to that used by Haug (1995) with only the null hypothesis being different.

Quintos (1995) suggests that the U.S. deficit process has undergone a shift in recent times, with deficit being sustainable only in a weak sense in the post-1980 period. Most recently, Martin (2000) examined sustainability on the basis of a cointegration model with multiple endogenous breaks in both the intercept and slope parameters. For this purpose, Martin (2000) applies a Bayesian methodology incorporating Markov chain Monte Carlo simulators and finds evidence of multiple breaks and strong sustainability over the whole sample period. This sample period is 1947-92 and is the same as that used by Quintos (1995). In this article we extend the period to 2002:1.

Moreover, we attempt to take the literature on U.S. deficit with structural breaks one step further by offering an explanation and providing evidence for the occurrence of regime shifts in the budget deficit. For this purpose, we follow Bertola and Drazen (1993), who show that the government solvency requirement implies that any increase in current government spending (which has the effect of increasing the current fiscal deficit) has a nonlinear effect on the expected present discounted value of the future government spending. Under these circumstances linear techniques may not be accurate in characterizing the deficit process. Specifically, the authors develop a framework in which there exist trigger points in the process of budget cuts, such that significant reduction in budget deficits may take place only when the ratio of deficit to output reaches a certain threshold. This may reflect the existence of political constraints blocking deficit cuts, which are relaxed only when the budget deficit reaches a sufficiently high level, deemed to be unsustainable (Bertola and Drazen 1993; Alesina and Drazen 1991). Consequently, in our empirical model we expect the fiscal process to follow different dynamics depending on whether the change in the deficit is below or above that threshold. Mean reverting dynamic behavior for deficits is present only when the change in the deficit is above a certain threshold. For this reason, we use a threshold autoregressive (TAR) model, in which the deviations of a threshold variable (observable) from a trigger point (to be estimated) are used to explain the occurrence of (possible) regime shifts in the U.S. deficit. It is customary to test the null of linearity against the alternative of a specific nonlinear process (a TAR model, in this article) only after finding evidence of a stationary time series on the basis of standard linear unit root tests. This sequential testing procedure may affect the inference results (1) In this article we follow Caner and Hansen (2001), the first to allow for a joint test for linearity and stationarity in the time series under investigation.

Our empirical results reveal the following important findings. The U.S. budget deficit is sustainable in the long run, but it has undergone regime shifts. These two results are consistent with those of many existing empirical studies. We also find evidence that these regime shifts can be explained by the extent of the change in the deficit. More specifically, only when the increase in deficit per capita reaches a certain threshold will fiscal authorities intervene to reduce the deficit. Hence, we are able to identify two regimes, with the budget deficit following different dynamics in each one of them. These results provide support for the existence of trigger points in the U.S. fiscal policy adjustment.

III. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY

Standard unit root and cointegration estimation procedures assume that there is a tendency for a variable to move toward a long-run equilibrium in every time period. However, as Balke and Fomby (1997) observe, movements toward the long-run equilibrium need not occur in every period. The presence of fixed costs of adjustment, for instance, may imply that only when the deviation from the equilibrium exceeds a critical threshold do the benefits exceed the costs of adjustment, and, therefore, economic agents act to move back to equilibrium. This type of discrete adjustment process has been used to describe many economic phenomena, such as the behavior of inventories or investment. In this work we attempt to characterize the discrete adjustment in the policy makers' attitude toward public finance solvency in terms of a threshold stationary process for the government deficit.

The TAR model was introduced by Tong (1978), who considered the possibility of a mean reverting time series only after hitting a certain threshold. Chan (1993) demonstrated that the least squares estimates of the threshold is superconsistent and found its asymptotic distribution, and Hansen (1997) developed an alternative approximation to the asymptotic distribution of the threshold. Chan (1991) and Hansen (1996) studied the asymptotic distribution of the likelihood ratio test for a threshold. Balke and Fomby (1997) extended the idea of threshold effects to a long-run equilibrium (cointegrating) relationship among different series. All these studies rely on the assumption of stationary data and therefore do not discriminate between nonstationary and/or nonlinear time series. The work of Caner and Hansen (2001) is the first to provide statistical tests for the null of a stationary TAR process, which simultaneously allow for both effects.

The Econometric Framework

The TAR model can be described by

(1) [DELTA][y.sub.t] = [[theta]'.sub.1][X.sub.t-1]([Z.sub.T-1] < [lambda]) + [[DELTA]'.sub.2][x.sub.t-1]I([Z.sub.t-1] [greater than or equal to] [lambda]) + [u.sub.t]

where t = 1, ... T;[x.sub.t-1] = (int, [y.sub.t-1], [DELTA][y.sub.t-1] ... [[DELTA].sub.t-k])';I(x) is the indicator function, and [u.sub.t] is an i.i.d error. The threshold variable [Z.sub.t-1] = [y.sub.t-1] - [y.sub.t-m-1], is predetermined and strictly stationary, and m is the delay order. (2) The deterministic component int stands for an intercept; [DELTA][y.sub.t-j] = [y.sub.t-j]- [y.sub.t-j-1] is the first-order difference at lag j. The threshold [lambda] is unknown, and it takes values in the interval [lambda] [member of] [LAMBDA] = [[[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2]], where [[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2] are chosen so that Prob([Z.sub.t] [less than or equal to] [[lambda].sub.1]) = [[pi].sub.1] > 0 and Prob([Z.sub.t] [less than or equal to] [[lambda].sub.2])= [[pi].sub.2] < 1. (3) In so far as the description of the empirical methodology is concerned, it is convenient to consider the vectors [[theta].sub.1] = ([[rho].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [[alpha].sub.1])' and [[theta].sub.2] = ([[rho].sub.2] [[beta].sub.2] [[alpha].sub.2])', where [[rho].sub.1] and [[rho].sub.2] are the slopes on the lagged levels, [[beta].sub.2] and [[beta].sub.2] are the slopes on the deterministic component, and [[alpha].sub.1] and [[alpha].sub.2] are the slopes on the lagged differences in the two regimes.

When estimating the TAR model, for each [lambda] [member of] [LAMBDA], we estimate [[theta].sub.1] and [[theta].sub.2] by least squares (LS). The LS point estimate of the threshold [lambda], and of the corresponding vectors [[theta].sub.1] and [[theta].sub.2] are those that minimize the residual sum of squares. To test the null hypothesis of linearity, that is, [H.sub.0]: [[theta].sub.1] = [[theta].sub.2], against the alternative of threshold effects, we use a Wald test statistic, [W.sub.T]. The latter is not identified under the null; its asymptotic distribution, under the assumption of stationary data, was investigated by Davies (1987), Chan (1991), Andrews and Ploberger (1994), and Hansen (1996). Caner and Hansen (2001) find that under the restriction of a unit root process, the asymptotic distribution of [W.sub.T] depends on the data structure, which implies that critical values cannot be tabulated, and therefore the authors suggest two bootstrap methods to approximate the asymptotic distribution of [W.sub.T]. One method is appropriate for the stationary case, and the other is appropriate for the unit root case. If the true order of integration is unknown, then Caner and Hansen (2001) suggest calculating the bootstrap critical values and p-values both ways and base inference on the more conservative (larger) p-value. Furthermore, the authors suggest that setting the bounds of the trimming region to [[pi].sub.1] = 0.15 and [[pi].sub.2] = 0.85 provides a reasonable trade-off between the power and size properties of the test for threshold effects (see Caner and Hansen 2001 for details). (4)

Unit Root Tests

As for the unit root tests, the following statistics are employed:

1. Two-sided Wald test statistic, [R.sub.2T], for the null of unit root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.1] = 0, against the alternative [H.sub.1]: [[rho].sub.1] [not equal to] 0 or [[rho].sub.2] [not equal to] 0;

2. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [R.sub.1T], for the null of unit root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.2] = 0, against the alternative [H.sub.1]: [[rho].sub.1] < 0 or [[rho].sub.2] < 0;

3. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [t.sub.1], for the null of unit root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.2] = 0, against the alternative ofstationarity only in regime 1, that is, [H.sub.1]: [[rho].sub.1] <0 and [[rho].sub.2] = 0;

4. A one-sided Wald test statistic, [t.sub.2], for the null of unit root, [H.sub.0]: [[rho].sub.1] = [[rho].sub.1] = 0, against the alternative of stationarity only in regime 2 that is, [H.sub.1] : [[rho].sub.1] = 0 and [[rho].sub.1] < 0.

The first two test statistics allow us to test whether the series under study is stationary. In the context of this study, these test statistics can be used to examine whether the U.S. budget deficit is sustainable in the long run. The third and fourth test statistics allow us to identify which of the regimes is stationary. This identification is important because it allows us to examine whether budget deficits follow different dynamics after they reach a certain threshold. As mentioned, it could be the case that fiscal authorities will intervene to cut the budget deficit only when the increase in the per capita deficit has reached a certain threshold.

If there are no threshold effects (unidentified case), the asymptotic distribution of each of the four statistics is found to be dependent on the data structure. However, asymptotic bounds, free of nuisance parameters other than the trimming range, are found. Consequently, critical values can be tabulated, and p-values can be computed (see Table 3 in Caner and Hansen 2001). As for the asymptotic distribution of each of the four statistics in the presence of threshold effects (identified case), the authors find that the Dickey-Fuller tabulated critical values provide a conservative bound for the [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2] tests. Furthermore, they find that the expression derived for the asymptotic distributions of the one-sided [R.sub.1] test and of the two-sided [R.sub.2] test are only useful for computing the critical values for the latter. (5) Finally, improved finite sample inference may be conducted using a bootstrap distribution for both the unidentified and identified threshold cases.

IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

The data set used in this study comprises quarterly observations over the period 1947:2 to 2002:1. Our focus is on the dynamics of the total (inclusive of interest payments) real per capita U.S. government surplus (see Figure 1). (6) Hence, we concentrate only on the strong sustainability condition (see Quintos 1995 for details). Following Franses and Van Dijk (2000), we use the minimization of the Akaike (1973) information criteria (AIC) and Hannan and Quinn (1979) (HQ) statistics to detect the appropriate lag order k and delay parameter m for the threshold variable. (7) It is clear from Tables 1 and 2 that both criteria suggest a lag order of four and a delay parameter of order two for the TAR process in (3). Hence, the semiannual change in the surplus per capita ([y.sub.t-1] - [y.sub.t-3]) is the chosen threshold variable.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

In Table 3, we report the threshold test and the unit root tests for the TAR model with a delay parameter of order two. The bootstrap p-values (both unrestricted and under the unit root assumption) corresponding to the Wald tests [W.sub.T] indicate that we can reject the null hypothesis of linearity in favor of the alternative that there is a threshold effect in the U.S. budget surplus per capita. This indicates that the U.S. fiscal policy has undergone structural shifts, a conclusion reached by most empirical studies (Martin 2000; Quintos 1995; among others).

The unit root tests show some interesting results regarding the time-series properties of the U.S. real per capita budget surplus. Both the one-sided and the two-sided [R.sub.2] Wald tests give evidence of stationary process. However, the individual t-ratios tests, [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.1], identify the presence of a unit root only in the second regime. (8) In fact, these results are confirmed by the LS estimates of the TAR model reported in Table 4, where there is evidence of a statistically significant mean reverting dynamics only in the lower regime, that is, when the (semiannual) change in the surplus per capita reaches the estimated threshold point estimate of-0.313. (9) These results suggest that the dynamics of the budget surplus per capita are different depending on whether the (semiannual) change in surplus per capita is above or below the estimated threshold value.

In Figure 2 we construct a confidence interval for the threshold parameter following the method of Hansen (2000). The bounds of this confidence interval are given by the intersection of the likelihood ratio sequence plot and a flat line at the appropriate asymptotic critical value. (10) For the 90% confidence interval, the critical value is 5.94 (see Hansen 2000; Table 1), and the lower and upper bounds are - 1.78 and -0.01, respectively. This confidence region would suggest that politicians would become sensitive to budget deficits only when the semiannual decrease in the real surplus per capita (or increase in the real deficit per capita) is either bad enough or shows up in the books (given that the upper bound is close to zero). A 95% confidence interval would confirm these conclusions. (11)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

There is also evidence of delays in the fiscal stabilization plans, because the lag order of the TAR process is equal to four (quarters) and policy makers react only after half a year to an undesirable decrease in the surplus per capita. This delay can be explained by taking into account political and institutional frictions. More concretely, in the U.S. case, all rules and regulations according to which budgets are drafted, approved, and implemented can imply long delays in modifying budget deficits. Alesina and Perotti (1996a; 1996b) review the effect of voting procedures in the preparation and implementation of the budget on delays in fiscal stabilization plans and conclude in a similar vein.

Further Discussion

In Figure 3, we plot the deviations of the semiannual change in the surplus per capita (threshold variable) from the estimated threshold point estimate over the sample period. Note that in this figure positive values identify the upper regime, and negative values identify the lower regime (which includes 40% of the total sample observations). We impose horizontal lines in the figure to identify the dates of the most significant switches during the period under study. (12) During the 1950s and early 1960s, regime shifts were mainly related to recessions and/or wartime. Figure 3 shows a major shift in U.S. budgetary policy during the Korean War, when there is an abrupt shift in 1951:2 from a large real surplus per capita to a large real deficit per capita, reaching a peak in 1951:3. During Eisenhower's presidency, there were two minor shifts in 1957:3 and 1960:4 caused mainly by two short-lived recessions (Evans 1990). During the 1960s, the figure shows three main switches from surplus to deficit (1964:2, 1967:1, and 1969:3), occurring during Johnson's presidency. These switches correspond in part to the tax cut proposals initiated by Kennedy and promoted and signed as law during Johnson's presidency. They also correspond to the budgetary requirements of the Vietnam War, which increased significantly especially in 1967, and the sharp increases in domestic spending associated with the Great Society Programs (Ippolito 1990). (13) A major shift from per capita surplus to per capita deficit occurs in 1974:3, peaks in 1975:2, and corresponds to the 1973 oil crisis, which plunged the U.S. economy into a deep recession.14 This switch into per capita deficit is bigger than the one associated with the second oil crisis period of 1979:4, and peaking in 1980:2.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Figure 3 clearly shows another major shift in 1981:3. This date is quite significant because it is the largest switch experienced in period of peace, tranquility, and without external shocks. This shift, which occurred at the beginning of the Reagan presidency, corresponded to the legislation passed by Congress aimed at cutting personal income taxes over the next three years (the 1981 Economic Recovery Tax Act). Because the tax cuts were not met by equal cuts in government spending, the federal budget went into deficit and remained so for a considerable period of time. It is interesting to note that many regime shifts (1985:3, 1986:3, and 1989:3) occurred during Reagan's presidency, mainly in his second term. Those regime switches reflect in part the intensive political and economic debate in Congress and in the media and the efforts to reduce the large and growing budget deficit. Those efforts were manifested in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Balanced Budget and Emergency Deficit Control Act, which called for progressive reduction in the deficit and the achievement of a balanced budget by the early 1990s (Ippolito 1990). Despite efforts to balance the budget, other major shifts from per capita surplus to per capita deficit occurred in 1989:3 and in 1991:3. Those switches occurred during the Bush (Senior) presidency and correspond closely to a recession that plunged the economy at the beginning of Bush's term and later to the budgetary requirements of the Gulf War. Those deficits did not last long, and in 1993:1 the budget went into surplus and remained so for the rest of the 1990s. This coincided with President Clinton's move to the White House and the importance he attached to balancing the budget in his economic policy.

Finally, the graph shows another switch from a per capita surplus to a per capita deficit in 2001:1. This switch can be explained by resorting to the slowing of the economy after a period of exceptional growth. The peak of the deficit in 2001:3 can be justified by referring, in addition to the continuing slowdown, to the preparations for the war in Afghanistan. It is of note that out of the 14 switches identified in the graph, 5 of them took place during Democrat presidency and 9 during Republican presidency.

V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

In this article, we have been concerned with investigating empirically the long-run sustainability of fiscal policy in the United States during the period spanning from 1947 to 2002. The theoretical framework has been provided by the government intertemporal budget constraint. The latter states that the discounted value of the public debt stock tends to zero over time, and it has testable implications on the process driving the total government deficit. By contrast to previous studies, which focused on the possibility of structural breaks in the deficit dynamics, we provide an explanation and gauge evidence for the occurrence of regime shifts in U.S. fiscal policy. Using a threshold unit root estimation procedure recently proposed by Caner and Hansen (2001), we provide evidence that the U.S. fiscal policy has undergone structural shifts in the past four decades. Our findings suggest that these switches are driven by asymmetries in the adjustment process, an issue not addressed previously in the literature. More specifically government authorities would intervene b) cutting deficits only when they have reached a certain threshold.

ABBREVIATIONS

AIC: Akaike Information Criteria

GNP: Gross National Product

HQ: Hannan and Quinn

LS: Least Squares

NIPA: National Income and Product Accounts

TAR: Threshold Autoregressive

APPENDIX: DATA

The data for nominal government spending (net of interest payments) and government revenues are the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) figures in billions of U.S. dollars. Real government spending and real government revenues are obtained by dividing the nominal values of government spending and government revenues by the GNP price deflator (1996 is the base year). Both nominal GNP and real GNP (in 1996 dollars) were obtained from NIPA. To calculate the interest payments we first deflated the previous period's market value of the privately held gross federal debt by the GNP deflator. The market value of the debt was obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. We then multiplied this by the appropriately deflated nominal interest rates, following Hakkio and Rush (1991). Because we focus on real surplus per capita, we use the ex post realinterest rate minus the rate of population growth. For the nominal interest rate, we use the Treasury long-term bond yields obtained from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release. Population figures are the midperiod estimation obtained from NIPA.
TABLE 1

AIC Lag and Delay Orders Choice

k 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
m

1 0.892 0.951 0.917 0.852 0.853 0.942 0.980
2 -- 0.933 0.902 0.835 0.854 0.938 0.949
3 -- -- 0.904 0.870 0.879 0.963 0.974
4 -- -- -- 0.906 0.887 0.955 0.980
5 -- -- -- -- 0.914 0.947 0.970
6 -- -- -- -- -- 0.988 0.986
7 -- -- -- -- -- -- 0.982
8 -- -- -- -- -- -- --

k 8
m

1 0.992
2 0.989
3 0.999
4 1.01
5 0.989
6 1.01
7 1.02
8 1.10

Note: m is the delay order in the long difference [y.sub.t-1] -
[y.sub.t-m-1], and k denotes the lag length.

TABLE 2

HQ Lag and Delay Orders Choice

k 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
m

1 1.02 1.08 1.05 0.980 0.982 1.07 1.11
2 -- 1.05 1.02 0.951 0.970 1.05 1.06
3 -- -- 1.01 0.972 0.981 1.06 1.08
4 -- -- -- 0.995 0.976 1.04 1.07
5 -- -- -- -- 0.990 1.02 1.05
6 -- -- -- -- -- 1.05 1.05
7 -- -- -- -- -- -- 1.03
8 -- -- -- -- -- -- --

k 8
m

1 1.12
2 1.10
3 1.10
4 1.10
5 1.06
6 1.08
7 1.07
8 1.14

Note: m is the delay order in the long difference [y.sub.t-1] -
[y.sub.t-m-1], and k denotes the lag length.

TABLE 3

Threshold and Unit Root Tests for the TAR Model

Bootstrap threshold test (a)
Wald statistic = 25.8 Boot. p-value = 0.015 Asym. p-value = 0.015
Two-sided Wald test for unit root (b)
Wald statistic = 16.6 Boot. p-value = 0.019 Asym. p-value = 0.016
One-sided Wald test for unit root (b)
Wald statistic = 16.2 Boot. p-value = 0.019 Asym. p-value = 0.014
[t.sub.1]-test for stationarity (c)
t-stat = 4.03 Boot. p-value = 0.004 Asym. p-value = 0.006
[t.sub.2]-test for stationarity (d)
t-stat = -0.587 Boot. p-value = 0.899 Asym. p-value = 0.861

Notes: The p-values for the threshold and unit root tests were obtained
by 5000 bootstrap replications. The results reported in the table
correspond to a trimming region (which defines the bounds [[pi].sub.1],
and [[pi].sub.2] within which the threshold falls) given by the values
[0.15, 0.85]. The results (available on request from the authors) are
robust to different trimming regions. We have used Gauss for all
estimations reported in Table 3.

(a) The Wald statistic tests the null of linearity against the
alternative of threshold effect (the bootstrap p-values reported are
for the unrestricted and unit root restriction cases).

(b) The two-sided [R.sub.2] and one-sided [R.sub.1] Wald statistics
test the null of unit root against the alternative that either the
first or the second regime is threshold stationary (both the
asymptotic and the bootstrap p-values are reported).

(c) The [t.sub.1] statistic tests the null of unit root against the
alternative that the first regime is stationary (both the asymptotic
and the bootstrap p-values are reported).

(d) The [t.sub.2] statistic to test the null of unit root against the
alternative that the second regime is stationary (both the asymptotic
and the bootstrap p-values are reported).

TABLE 4

Estimation of TAR

Variable Regime 1 Regime 2

Intercept -0.831 0.382
 (0.262) (0.220)
Y(t-1) -0.137 0.018
 (0.034) (0.032)
DY(t-1) -0.082 -0.238
 (0.107) (0.123)
DY(t-2) 0.010 0.221
 (0.106) (0.120)
DY(t-3) 0.155 -0.109
 (0.094) (0.101)
DY(t-4) -0.237 -0.172
 (0.097) (0.095)


(1.) In Cipollini (2001) (see also Sarno 2001, where the analysis is in line with Cipollini), a smooth transition regression model is employed to describe the nonlinear dynamics of the UK budget deficit. This is undertaken to explain and provide evidence as to why regime shifts in the budget deficit occur. However, the linearity test used is conditional on the stationary properties of the data.

(2.) It is important to observe that the threshold variable not only can be the long difference, but also can be the lagged first-order difference or the lagged level. However, in the empirical analysis we found evidence of nonlinearity only when the long difference is used as the threshold variable. In other words, policy makers intervene when the change over the year in the deficit per capita reaches a certain threshold.

(3.) Caner and Hansen (2001) observe that it is typical to treat [[pi].sub.1] and [[pi].sub.2] symmetrically so that [[pi].sub.2] = 1 - [[pi].sub.1], which imposes the restriction that no regime has less than [[pi].sub.1]% observations of the total sample.

(4.) However, as the authors observe, because this particular choice is somewhat arbitrary, it would be sensible in practical applications to explore the robustness of the results to this choice. As we suggest in Table 3, our results are robust in this sense.

(5.) The bounds, free of nuisance parameters, of the 10%, 5%, and 1% critical values for the two-sided [R.sub.2] test are 11.17, 13.12, and 17.29, respectively.

(6.) For a detailed description of the variables and data sources, see the data appendix.

(7.) Given the number of observations T, the number of regressors n, and the estimated residual sum of squares RSS, the AIC statistic is equal to log (RSS) +2n/T. The HQ statistic is log (RSS) + 2n log(log(T))/T.

(8.) The asymptotic p-values and the calculated bootstrapped p-values are those corresponding to the unidentified threshold case (see section II for discussion, and Caner and Hansen 2001 for details).

(9.) The shift in the error correcting dynamics of the surplus per capita is statistically significant, because 0.015 is the bootstrap p-value for the Wald test of the null that the slopes on the lagged value across the two regimes are equal.

(10.) The likelihood ratio sequence for the threshold guesses is defined as L[R.sub.n]([lambda]) = [[S.sub.n]([lambda]) - [S.sub.n] ([lambda])]/[[sigma].sup.n], where [S.sub.n]([lambda]) and [S.sub.n]([lambda]) are the residual sums of squared error sequence and the corresponding minimum, respectively, and [[sigma].sup.2] is the residual variance from LS estimation.

(11.) The bounds for the 95% confidence interval are [-1.74, 0.34], where the upper bound is still close to zero. It is also the case that this confidence interval is still skewed toward negative values.

(12.) To not overcrowd the figure, we only identify the most significant shifts from per capita surplus to per capita deficit.

(13.) From 1967 onward, Johnson finally realized that there was an urgent need to control the deficit and called for an increase in tax revenues through a tax surcharge (Ippolito 1990). Those efforts are reflected partly in Figure 3, where those is evidence of many switches from per capita deficit to per capita surplus. Those efforts, however, were interrupted more than once by the financing requirements of the Vietnam War.

(14.) Earlier minor switches in the late 1960s and early 1970s, which occurred in Nixon's presidency, were mainly related to the financing of the Vietnam War.

REFERENCES

Akaike, A. "Information Theory and an Extension of the Maximum Likelihood Principle," in Second International Symposium of Information Theory, edited b) B. N. Petrov and F. L. Saki, Budapest, 1973.

Alesina, A., and R. Drazen. "Why Are Stabilisation Delayed?" American Economic Review, 82, 1991, 1170-88.

Alesina, A., and R. Peroni. "Budget Deficits and Budge Institutions," NBER Working Paper No. 5556 1996a. Cambridge, MA.

--. "Fiscal Discipline and the Budget Process. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceeding 86, 1996b, 40l-7.

Andrews, D. W. K., and W. Ploberger. "Optimal Tests When a Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only under the Alternative." Econometrica, 62, 1994, 1383-414.

Balke, N. S., and T. B. Fomby. "Threshold Cointegration." International Economic Review, 38, 1997, 627-45.

Bertola, G., and A. Drazen. "Trigger Points and Budget Cuts: Explaining the Effects of Fiscal Austerity. American Economic Review, 83(1), 1993, 11-26.

Caner, M., and B. E. Hansen. "Threshold Autoregression with a Unit Root." Econometrica, 69, 2001, 1555-96.

Chan, K. S. "Percentage Points of Likelihood Ratio Tests for Threshold Autoregression." Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B, 53, 1991, 691-96.

--. "Consistency and Limiting Distribution of the Least Squares Estimator of a Threshold Autoregressive Model." Annals of Statistics, 21, 1993, 520-33.

Cipollini, A. "Testing for Government Intertemporal Solvency: A Smooth Transition Error Correction Model Approach." Manchester School, 69(6), 2001, 643-55.

Davies, R. B. "Hypothesis Testing When a Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only under the Alternative." Biometrika, 74, 1987, 33-43.

Evans, G. R. Red Ink. The Budget, Deficit, and Debt of the US Government. San Diego: Academic Press, 1990.

Franses, P. H., and Van Dijk, D. Non-Linear Time Series Models in Empirical Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.

Hakkio, C. S., and M. Rush. "Is the Budget Deficit 'Too Large'?" Economic Inquiry, 29, 1991, 429-45.

Hamilton, J. D., and M. A. Flavin. "On the Limitation of Government Borrowing: A Framework for Empirical Testing." American Economic Review, 76. 1986,808-19.

Hannan, E. J., and B. G. Qainn. "The Determination of the Order of an Autoregression." Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 41, 1979, 190-95.

Hansen, B. E. "Inference When a Nuisance Parameter Is Not Identified under the Null Hypothesis." Econometrica, 64, 1996, 413-30.

--. "Inference in TAR Models." Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 1, 1997, 119-31.

Hansen, B. "Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation." Econometrica, 68, 2000, 575-603.

Haug, A. "Has Federal Budget Deficit Policy Changed in Recent Years?" Economic Inquiry, 33, 1995, 104-18.

Ippolito, D. S. Uncertain Legacies: Federal Budget Policy from Roosevelt through Reagan. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia, 1990.

Martin, G. M. "US Deficit Sustainability: A New Approach Based on Multiple Endogenous Breaks." Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15, 2000, 83-105.

Quintos, C. E. "Sustainability of the Deficit Process with Structural Shifts." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 13, 1995, 409-17.

Sarno, L. "The Behavior of US Public Debt: A NonLinear Perspective." Economics Letters, 74, 2001, 119-25.

Tanner, E., and P. Liu. "Is the Budget Deficit 'Too Large': Some Further Evidence." Economic Inquiry, 32, 1994, 511-18.

Tong, H. "On a Threshold Model," in Pattern Recognition and Signal Processing, edited by C. H. Chen. Amsterdam: Sijoff and Noordhoff, 1978.

Trehan, B., and C. E. Walsh. "Common Trends, The Government Budget Constraint and Revenue Smoothing." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 1988, 425-44.

Uctum, M., and M. Wickens. "Debt and Deficit Ceilings, and Sustainability of Fiscal Policies: An Intertemporal Analysis." CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1612, 1997.

PHILIP ARESTIS, ANDREA CIPOLLINI, and BASSAM FATTOUH *

* We are grateful to an anonymous referee for helpfulcomments. We are also grateful to Bruce Hansen for helpful suggestions and for making available his Gauss Programme to estimate and make inferences on the TAR model. The usual disclaimer applies.

Arestis: Professor, Department of Land Economy, University of Cambridge, 19 Silver Street, Cambridge CB3 9EP, U.K. Phone 44-0-1223-766-971, Fax 44-01223-337-160, E-mail pa267@cam.ac.uk

Cipollini: Lecturer in Economics, Queen Mary and Westfield College, University of London, Mile End Road, London, E1 4NS, U.K. Phone 44-020-7893-5905, Fax 44-020-7893-3580, E-mail a.cipollini@qmul.ac.uk

Fattouh: Lecturer in Financial Economics, CeFiMS, SoAS, University of London, Thornhaugh Street, Russell Square, London WC1H 0HG, U.K. Phone 44-020-7898-4053, Fax 44-020-7898-4089, E-mail bfll@soas.ac.uk
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有