Voter preferences and state regulation of smoking.
Hersch, Joni ; Del Rossi, Alison F. ; Viscusi, W. Kip 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Tobacco taxation and smoking restrictions are two areas of
regulation for which states have maintained a high level of control
relative to the federal government. (1) Given this flexibility, states
have established a wide range of restrictions on smoking in areas such
as government workplaces, restaurants, bars. shopping malls, indoor
arenas, and hospitals. (2)
Although most states restrict smoking in hospitals, there is
considerable variation among states in restrictions in other areas. In
the 1998-99 period of this study, about two-thirds of states restricted
smoking in restaurants, whereas only four states restricted smoking in
bars.
What has led to variation in smoking restrictions across states? In
a democratic society one would expect voter preferences to play an
instrumental role in determining which policies are enacted and which
are not. This article provides the first empirical exploration of
whether state-level smoking restrictions are consistent with preferences
of the citizenry, taking into account both voting behavior and the role
of smoking status in influencing whether an individual votes.
Specifically, we examine whether voters' preferences for smoking
restrictions in restaurants, bars, malls, indoor sporting events, and
hospitals are consistent with state-level restrictions on smoking in
each of these public areas. (3) Our research draws on public choice
models of policy making by state and local governments. Voters'
preferences typically play a central role, because voting affects
legislators incentives to support regulations. (4) Public choice
research also finds that nonvoter factors may influence state and local
policy making. (5) In the case of smoking regulations, public health
advocates or tobacco industry lobbyists might influence regulatory
policies.
The specific building block of our analysis of state restrictions
on smoking is information on individuals' voting behavior, which we
link to their smoking status and preferences over smoking restrictions.
Our analysis uses measures of political pressure that account for
individual preferences as well as their voting behavior. To examine the
possible role of interest group pressures, we also control for nonvoter
influences on smoking regulation, including the proportion of the state
population who smoke, measures of state ideology, and size of the
tobacco industry.
With the exception of smoking in bars, there is majority support
for smoking restrictions. Unsurprisingly, smokers are less supportive of
restrictions than are nonsmokers. Nonetheless, even smokers demonstrate
a high level of support for many restrictions. Smokers are also less
likely to vote than are nonsmokers, even after controlling for other
demographic factors. The lower voting rate diminishes voter opposition
to antismoking regulation but is usually not critical in view of the
substantial support that most smoking restrictions have among smokers.
The political pressure indices for restrictions on smoking in each
public area are generally significantly related to the probability that
a state restricts smoking in that public area. The nonvoter factors,
such as the smoking rate in the state and tobacco's role in the
state economy, are rarely influential.
Policy debates over the desirability of smoking restrictions
emphasize possible health risks due to exposure to environmental tobacco
smoke (ETS) and effects on business profitability. The primary argument
for expanding smoking restrictions is to protect workers and customers
from exposure to ETS. (6) As our results show, voters are generally
supportive of smoking restrictions in public areas, which would thereby
protect workers as well as themselves and other customers. However,
there is a substantial controversy over the extent of health risks
associated with exposure to ETS. The basis for the push by the U.S.
Occupational and Safety Health Administration (OSHA) for increased
smoking restrictions to protect workers is the highly controversial U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) (1992) study on environmental
tobacco smoke. (7) Survey evidence indicates that respondents perceive
risks of ETS far in excess of those reported in the scientific
literature. (8) To the extent that voters' preferences for smoking
restrictions are governed by exaggerated beliefs rather than the lower
risk estimates that have appeared in the scientific literature, the
political support for these policies presumably is greater than it would
be if decisions were more informed.
The principal costs of smoking regulations are the possible loss of
profits to owners of bars, restaurants, and other businesses. Smokers
themselves are generally supportive of most smoking bans, so presumably
smokers do not find smoking restrictions overly burdensome. The evidence
on whether smoking bans lower restaurant and bar profitability is mixed
and may be transitory. (9) For example, in a survey of business owners
following the passage of a comprehensive smoking ban in a California
city, Boyes and Marlow (1996) found that 57% reported the ban had no
impact on their business, 17% experienced a positive effect, and 25% a
negative effect.
Evidence of voter support for these restrictions does not
necessarily imply that voters have considered these pertinent cost and
benefit components in forming their preferences. Moreover, the enactment
of restrictions that have broad public support does not necessarily
imply that there is a market failure. As Dunham and Marlow (2000a)
found, private operators of restaurants and bars often institute
nonsmoking sections voluntarily in response to the preferences of their
customers. Employers likewise took considerable initiative in
instituting smoking policies even before the wave of regulation. By
1991, 85% of all firms had implemented smoking policies, with 34% of
these being bans and an additional 34% prohibiting smoking in all open
work areas (see Viscusi 2002, 124). Some smoking restrictions have
emerged even without government regulation.
Our results indicate that the smoking restrictions that have been
adopted are in line with voter preferences and do not stem from power
wielded by narrowly defined special interest groups. Furthermore, the
broad support among individuals suggests that even in the absence of
government regulation, private market incentives may likewise result in
restrictions on smoking.
Our analysis of the determinants of state restrictions uses an
innovative measure of voter preferences. We introduce two different
measures of voter preferences, each of which is calculated using
individual data. The predicted voter pressure index weights the
preferences of voters by the expected probability that they will vote,
which is the information that political officials can observe ex ante.
The actual voter pressure index weights individual preferences by
whether they actually did vote and serves as an ex post measure of voter
preferences. The performance of these voter preference variables
differed somewhat, but each of these variables was strongly predictive
of most smoking restrictions.
II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
A model of the relation between voter preferences and regulation
serves as the framework for our analysis. Let [R.sub.j] be a 0-1
indicator of whether a particular smoking restriction has been chosen by
state j. We write the probability that state j has a particular smoking
restriction, [R.sub.j], using the following equation:
(1) Pr([R.sub.j] = 1) = [rho]([[alpha].sub.1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][r.sup.*.sub.j] + [X.sub.j][[alpha].sub.3] +
[Z.sub.j][[alpha].sub.4] + [[alpha].sub.5][S.sub.j]).
If state policy makers are responsive to voter preferences, then
[R.sub.j] will depend on [r.sup.*.sub.j], which is a measure of
preferences for smoking restrictions by voters in that state. This is
the key variable in our analysis and will be defined using equations (2)
and (3). The dependent variable focuses on regulations in place at a
particular point in time, as do the measures of preferences. States
established various regulations at different points of time, and an
alternative approach might be to examine the influence of factors
measured at the time the specific policy was adopted. However, most
existing regulations were already in place before any data on individual
preferences regarding smoking regulation were available. Therefore, our
formulation is a test of the consistency of preferences with regulatory
regimes rather than a test of which regulations will be adopted for the
first time during that period.
Smoking restrictions may also depend on a vector [X.sub.j] of
demographic variables that capture additional preference information not
reflected by [r.sup.*.sub.j]. Variables representing the influence of
interest groups and other political variables are given in a vector
[Z.sub.j]. The probability a state j has a smoking restriction might
also depend directly on the smoking rate of the state, given by
[S.sub.j]. The smoking rate has two opposing effects. As the fraction of
smokers rises, so does their political influence. However, a higher
smoking rate will increase the costs incurred by nonsmokers and
consequently may increase their support for smoking bans. We analyze the
consistency of regulatory policies with respect to two measures of voter
preferences [r.sup.*.sub.j]. Our first measure focuses on the political
pressure of expected voters. Politicians may not know the preferences of
those who actually vote, but instead assess the distribution of
preferences across the population and assign a corresponding probability
of voting for each individual. The first component used in constructing
this political pressure index is the voting probability for each
individual i in state j based on the following form:
(2) Pr([V.sub.ij] = 1) = [PHI]([[beta].sub.1] +
[Y.sub.ij][[beta].sub.2] + [[beta].sub.3][S.sub.ij]),
where V is the 0-1 indicator of voting, and Y is a vector of
characteristics, such as income and education that influence individual
voting behavior. Smoking status of the individual is also included as a
separate determinant of voting status.
We use the estimates from equation (2) to weight each
individual's reported preference for a ban on smoking in that area.
We then calculate the mean of this weighted preference variable within
each state and use this variable as an index of voter pressure in
support of regulation. Specifically, the predicted voter pressure index
for state j is of the form:
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [N.sub.j] is the number of observations in state j,
[[??].sub.ij] is the predicted probability of voting of individual i in
state j, and [p.sub.ij] = 1 if individual i in state j supports banning
smoking in the specified area and 0 otherwise.
Our second measure is based on the smoking regulation preferences
of the people within a state who actually did vote. The state-level
preference index of voters is the mean of the preference variable,
[p.sub.ij], taken over all voters in the state. We refer to this measure
as the actual voter pressure index. (10)
The two different voter pressure indices capture different
mechanisms by which voter influence may be exerted. With the predicted
voter pressure index, legislators assess the probabilities that
different constituents will vote as well as the associated preferences
of these individuals to calculate an expected political preference
measure of constituents. The second measure is based on the assumption
that legislators can identify the preferences of voters, or
alternatively, people are voting directly on smoking policies. In the
usual situation, voters are not considering narrowly defined smoking
referenda, so that the legislator must form a probabilistic assessment
of voters' expected preferences with respect to any type of policy.
III. INDIVIDUAL PREFERENCES FOR SMOKING REGULATIONS AND VOTING
RATES
In this section we provide estimates of [p.sub.ij] and
[[??].sub.ij], which are used to construct the measures of voter
pressure for regulation. We combine data from three waves of the Current
Population Survey (CPS). The CPS is a nationally representative monthly
survey of about 48,000 households. The basic monthly CPS survey provides
detailed information on labor force activity and demographics.
Supplements to the basic survey provide information on special topics.
Voting information is available on the CPS November 1998: Voting and
Registration Supplement. Information on smoking status and preferences
over smoking restrictions is provided in the Tobacco Use Supplement,
which was conducted in conjunction with the CPS in September 1998,
January 1999, and May 1999. (11)
The CPS sampling procedure makes it possible to link
individuals' information reported in different months of the
survey. Household members are interviewed for four consecutive months
and then reinterviewed again for four consecutive months in the same
period one year later. We can associate the smoking information from the
September and January surveys to the voting information on the November
survey for approximately half of the total number of respondents to the
September and January surveys. Specifically, those whose month in sample
(MIS) in September is 1, 2, 5, or 6 can be linked to their voting
information in the November survey, when their MIS is 3, 4, 7, or 8; and
likewise those with MIS 1, 2, 5, or 6 in November can be linked to their
smoking responses in January when their MIS will be 3, 4, 7, or 8. (12)
The variables used in the analysis are defined as follows. Voting
status is determined directly from the response to the November
supplement question, "Did [respondent] vote in the election held on
Tuesday, November 3?" Individual smoking status is determined by
the response to the question of whether the individual currently smoked
and was asked of all respondents (or their proxy) who reported smoking
at least 100 cigarettes in their lives.
Attitudes toward smoking in public areas were elicited from a
series of questions asking whether the respondent thought smoking in
that public area should be allowed. Specifically, respondents were
asked, "In [public area], do you think that smoking should be
allowed in all areas, in some areas, or not allowed at all?" for
each of the public areas of restaurants, hospitals, indoor work areas,
bars and cocktail lounges, indoor sporting events, and indoor shopping
malls. (13) There are consequently two possible break points that can be
used to construct a 0-1 indicator variable for a respondent's
support of smoking restrictions. Few respondents indicated that smoking
should be allowed everywhere in each of the public areas. Three percent
or less would impose no restrictions in each of the public areas other
than bars, for which 29% of the sample favored no restrictions. Basing
the voter preference variable on whether they believed smoking should
not be allowed at all showed considerably more variability.
Our sample is comprised of respondents with smoking status
reported. Only those age 18 and older are eligible to vote, so the
sample is also restricted to those 18 or older as of the November
survey. The resulting sample size is 63,576 observations with both
smoking and voting status reported. However, missing values on other
variables further reduce the sample size.
The primary source of missing information is preferences over
regulations. The basic CPS requests information on all household members
15 years of age and older and allows proxy respondents to report
information for unavailable household members. Proxy respondents were
also asked to report the smoking status of unavailable household
members, but only self-respondents were asked to report their
preferences over regulations. Twenty-one percent of the observations
were reported by proxy. Furthermore, some self-respondents failed to
answer some preference questions. We restrict the sample to
self-respondents who do not have missing values on any of the six
preferences regarding smoking limitations. This results in a sample of
47,798 individual observations.
Table 1 examines how preferences over restrictions vary by voting
and smoking status. Overall, respondents are generally supportive of
banning smoking in public areas. The largest support for a smoking ban
is for hospitals, with 82% of the sample favoring no smoking in
hospitals, and the weakest support is for smoking bans in bars, with
only 29% in favor of prohibiting smoking entirely. The remaining
preferences all exceed 50% in favor of no smoking: 51% for restaurants,
68% in indoor work areas, 69% for malls, and 73% for indoor sporting
events.
As Table 1 demonstrates, preferences vary by both smoking and
voting status. Voters are more supportive of smoking restrictions than
are nonvoters, but the differences are not great. For instance, 55% of
voters favor banning smoking in restaurants, and 48% of nonvoters do.
Smokers who do not vote exhibit preferences that are similar to those of
smokers who do vote. The largest differences among individuals are by
smoking status. In every instance, voting smokers are considerably less
supportive of regulations than are voting nonsmokers. For example, 61%
of voting nonsmokers favor smoking bans in restaurants, in contrast to
only 21% of voting smokers.
Based on the statistics in Table 1, smokers comprise just under 16%
of the voting population. What percentage of the voting population must
smokers make up to have a majority of voters oppose the ban? For
restaurant bans, that critical level is 27%, whereas for malls it is
95%. Irrespective of the mix of smokers and nonsmokers among the voting
population, restrictions for bars lack majority support, and
restrictions for indoor sporting events, hospitals, and indoor work
areas have majority support.
To derive the predicted voter pressure index, we begin by
estimating the voting equation specified in equation (2). In addition to
smoking status and attitudes, our voting probability equation also
controls for family income, years of education, region, metropolitan
residence, age, marital status, sex, race, and ethnicity. Family income
is reported in 14 categories ranging from less than $5000 per year to
more than $75,000 per year. Family income is missing for 9% of the
sample; we include these observations in the analysis with an indicator
for missing values. For convenience, we assign the midpoint of the
category to create a continuous variable, imputing $80,000 to the top
open-ended category. The results are similar whether our estimates are
based on the categorical family income measure or the imputed continuous
measure. Marital status is grouped into three categories of married,
never married, or previously married (divorced, separated, widowed). We
include an indicator variable equal to 1 if race is white and another
variable equal to 1 if the respondent is Hispanic.
The sample means of the variables used in the analysis are reported
in the first column of Table 2. The sample voting rate is 50%, and 22%
of the respondents are smokers. The sample has fewer men than in the
population overall in part because the restriction to self-respondents
reduced the share of men who directly answer the survey. (14)
The last two columns of Table 2 present the estimated effect of
these variables on the probability of voting. The dependent variable is
equal to 1 if the individual voted in the November 1998 election and is
0 otherwise. Because the decision to vote is dichotomous, we use probit regression. Attitudes regarding smoking in public areas are included in
equation (1), whereas equation (2) omits these measures. We report the
original probit coefficients and the associated asymptotic standard
error (in parentheses), as well as estimates (in brackets) of the
marginal effect of a change in each of the explanatory variables.
The regression results in Table 2 indicate that individuals with
higher income, with higher education, who are older or married, are more
likely to vote, and men, those previously married, or those residing in
the Northeast or South (relative to the West) are less likely to vote.
Attitudes regarding smoking in public areas add little explanatory power
to the voter equation, although two of the attitudes measures have
statistically significant coefficients. Support for banning smoking in
hospitals increases the voting rates, but support for restrictions in
bars decreases the voting rate. The other four preferences do not have a
significant effect on voting. Attitudes toward smoking restrictions
consequently do not generate systematic efforts to vote in an effort to
support or oppose smoking restrictions.
The principal result in Table 2 is that smokers are considerably
less likely to vote than nonsmokers, even controlling for other
important determinants of voting status, such as income and education,
which are correlated with smoking. Smokers have a 0.09 percentage points
lower probability of voting, all else equal. Policy makers consequently
may be less responsive to smoker preferences because smokers tend to
vote with lower frequency than do nonsmokers, controlling for other key
variables. The means in Table 1 show that smokers, not surprisingly, are
less favorable toward banning smoking in public areas, and the means
indicate that voter preferences are more heavily weighted toward
nonsmoker preferences. The latter is caused in part by the lower voting
rates of smokers. Whether these different voting rates of smokers and
nonsmokers matter in terms of smoking policy choice depends on whether
voter preferences influence states' chosen smoking restrictions,
which we now address.
IV. STATE SMOKING RESTRICTIONS
Data on state (including the District of Columbia) smoking
restrictions are reported in the State Tobacco Activities Tracking and
Evaluation (STATE) System, which is an online source of current and
historical information on state tobacco control laws and other economic
and behavioral information on smoking and other tobacco use in states.
(15) For each state, the site provides the enactment and effective dates
of the most recent legislation, if any, restricting smoking in various
indoor areas as well as details about the type of restriction. (16)
Restrictions are broken down into four categories in order of
stringency: no restrictions, designated smoking areas, separate
ventilation requirements, and smoking bans. Given the dates of the CPS
Tobacco Use Supplement preference data for 1998 99. we analyze
restrictions as of 31 January 1999. (17)
Table 3 reports the number of states that have smoking restrictions
in restaurants, bars, malls, enclosed arenas, and hospitals. The most
common policy is restricting smoking in hospitals, with 43 states having
some smoking restriction. Hospitals also have the most variation in the
stringency of smoking restrictions, with six states banning smoking in
hospitals entirely, and eight states having no restrictions in
hospitals. Designated smoking areas are the most common requirement for
restaurants and enclosed arenas, required in restaurants in 28 states
and in enclosed arenas in 21 states. At the other extreme, only four
states restrict smoking in bars and eight states restrict smoking in
malls.
Tables 4 and 5 provide descriptive statistics for other state-level
data used in the regressions. The smoking rate, S, in each state was
found from the CPS Tobacco Use Supplement. (18) On average across all
states, about one in five adults are smokers, but there is considerable
variation in smoking rates for states, with a range of 13.2% to 32.2%.
Other variables were chosen to match the vectors X and Z from equation
(1) of the model. We proxy X by real median household income. A positive
income elasticity for increased regulation is consistent with higher
valuation of health with higher income. The vector Z consists of two
variables reflecting the influence of interest groups and political
ideology. These variables are the percent of a state's gross state
product (GSP) from tobacco agriculture and tobacco manufacturing, and an
indicator of whether the majority of both houses of the state
legislature and the governor of the state belong to the Republican
party. (19)
The key independent variable in the state analysis is a measure of
[r.sup.*.sub.j] representing the political pressure for restricting
smoking in particular areas. As noted earlier, we use two measures of
political pressure, the predicted voter pressure index based on
individual preferences weighted by the probability of voting, and the
second based on the preferences of actual voters. The means for each of
these political pressure indices for the 5 public areas are reported in
Table 5. (20) Because the voting rate calculated at the individual level
is 50 percent, the mean of the predicted voter pressure index is about
half of the mean of the actual voter pressure index.
Tables 6 and 7 report probit estimates for restrictions on smoking
in restaurants, bars, malls, enclosed arenas, and hospitals. The smoking
restriction variable, [R.sub.j], is equal to 1 if the state has a
smoking restriction of any kind in the indicated area, and equal to 0 if
not. Table 6 reports the estimates using the predicted voter pressure
index, and Table 7 is based on the actual voter pressure index. Based on
the predicted voter pressure index, we find that voter preferences are
positively related to the probability of restriction, with effects that
are statistically significant at the 95% level for restaurants, bars,
and enclosed arenas and at the 90% level for malls. Using the actual
voter pressure index, the probability of restriction in bars, malls, and
enclosed arenas is positively related to the voter index at the 90%
level or higher. These findings indicate that state policies restricting
smoking in bars, malls, and enclosed arenas are consistent with voter
preferences.
Although voter preferences are consistently associated with the
probability that a state has a smoking restriction, the nonvoter factors
are less influential. Smoking rates do not affect regulatory policies,
which may reflect the conflicting influences captured by this variable.
Median household income is positively related to smoking restrictions in
hospitals (at the 95% level in Table 7, and marginally significant with
p-value = 0.11 in Table 6), but the state's median income is not
associated with the probability that the state has other smoking
restrictions. The percentage of GSP attributable to tobacco is only
significantly related to the probability of having a restriction in
hospitals, with states with a larger tobacco economy less likely to
restrict smoking in hospitals. (21) For the estimates using the
predicted voter pressure index in Table 6, the indicator for Republican
governor/state legislature is negative and significantly related to
whether a state has a restaurant or mall restriction at the 90% level.
This variable is not included in the probit regression for bars because
all states that have a Republican governor and state legislature have no
bar restriction, and therefore the variable fully explains the
"failure" category of restriction. (22) In alternative
specifications (not reported in the tables) we also explored possible
relationships of neighboring states' policies on a state's
chosen restriction using regional indicator variables. Although some
regional indicator variables were occasionally statistically
significant, there was no consistent pattern, and the group of variables
as a whole did not add to the explanatory power of the regressions.
Smoking policies do not appear to spread around regions.
As Table 3 shows, most states do not restrict smoking at all or
require designated smoking areas only. Consequently there are too few
observations with more restrictive policies to analyze the influence of
voter preferences on stringency of restrictions. The exception is
hospital restrictions, in which states show considerable variability in
stringency of smoking across states. We estimate ordered probit
regressions, with the results reported in Table 8. The dependent
variable takes on four possible discrete values: 0 if no restriction; 1
if separate smoking areas are allowed; 2 if separate ventilation or no
smoking is required; and 3 if smoking is banned in hospitals. There is
some evidence that voter preferences for smoking bans have an impact on
the degree of chosen restrictions. The predicted voter pressure index is
positively and significantly related to the degree of restrictions, but
the actual voter pressure is not significantly related to the degree of
restrictions at conventional levels. (23) Higher median household income
leads to greater severity of smoking restrictions. The influence of the
tobacco industry in the state is also evident as the stringency of
smoking restrictions declines with the percent GSP from tobacco. The
indicator for Republican governor/state legislator has no effect on the
chosen level of hospital restrictions.
V. SIMULATIONS AND PREDICTIONS
The regression equations in Tables 6 and 7 can serve a predictive
purpose as well. Consider the values for the state of New York, which
engaged in a highly visible debate over smoking restrictions. The
coefficient estimates predict the probability that New York will adopt a
smoking ban for restaurants is 0.51 using Table 6 coefficients and 0.60
using Table 7 coefficients. The probability of New York adopting a
smoking ban in bars is virtually zero using the coefficient estimates
from these tables. (24) Nevertheless, in response to Mayor
Bloomberg's efforts, New York City imposed a smoking ban for bars
and restaurants that took effect in 2003. Also in that year, the state
of New York enacted the Clean Indoor Air Act, which prohibited smoking
in indoor work sites, including bars and restaurants. Many political
observers credit this result to intense lobbying by public health
professionals and interest groups like the American Cancer Society.
Consistent with our empirical results, much controversy has arisen about
the New York smoking ban for bars since its enactment, to the point that
a lawsuit to stop the ban has been filed by bar and tavern owners and an
industry association. (25)
Notwithstanding the prominence given to the New York smoking ban,
nationwide, bans on smoking in bars are much less likely to be adopted
than are other forms of smoking restrictions. As of June 2003, only five
states had imposed such bans on smoking in bars. (26) The limited
support for smoking bans in bars is consistent with the results of this
article.
How would policy outcomes throughout the country differ if only the
preferences of smokers were permitted to influence policy? To examine
this counterfactual, we looked at the number of states for which 50% of
smokers favor banning smoking in each area. In no state do the majority
of smokers favor banning smoking in restaurants or bars. Presumably, if
smokers controlled such policies, there would be fewer restrictions on
smoking in these places. In about half the states a majority of smokers
support a ban of smoking in malls, and in about 60% of states a majority
of smokers favor banning smoking in enclosed arenas. For smoking in
hospitals, in all but one state the majority of smokers are in favor of
a ban. It appears that smoking restrictions would be little different
for malls, enclosed arenas, and hospitals if smokers ruled on these
issues.
VI. CONCLUSION
There have been remarkable changes in the public's support for
smoking restrictions. Gallup poll results in 1977 found that only 16% of
the population favored a ban on smoking in public places (trains, buses,
airplanes, restaurants, offices), and in 1978 only 43% favored banning
smoking completely on commercial airplanes. By the 1998-99 period
analyzed here, a majority of voters favored smoking bans in all public
areas except for bars, for which support remains under 50%.
Analysis of individual data indicated that smokers are less likely
to vote, controlling for other economic and demographic characteristics
of the individual, and that smokers are less supportive of smoking
restrictions. However, smokers themselves demonstrate relatively high
percentages in favor of banning smoking in many public places, so higher
voting rates among smokers would have a small impact on state smoking
policies.
Smoking restrictions are responsive to voter preferences in the
state and, perhaps surprisingly, in many instances are consistent with
the preferences of smokers themselves. There is an ordinal match-up of
voter preferences and smoking restrictions. Hospital bans command the
greatest support and smoking restrictions in hospitals are most
widespread, whereas smoking restrictions for bars are the least common
and the least favored by the public. State regulations continue to vary
in part because of differences in voters' views of smoking
restrictions.
Despite the relation between preferences and restrictions and the
generally high level of support in favor of bans, the prevalence of
smoking restrictions appears to be relatively low. One frequent
explanation for the lack of universal smoking restrictions is the
importance of the tobacco industry in the states' economies, but we
find that this factor has a negative effect only for hospital smoking
restrictions. The gap between voter support for smoking restrictions and
the presence of such policies within a state suggests that state
restrictions are likely to become more widespread in the future.
ABBREVIATIONS
CPS: Current Population Survey
EPA: Environmental Protection Agency
ETS: Environmental Tobacco Smoke
GSP: Gross State Product
MIS: Month In Sample
OSHA: Occupational Safety and Health Administration
TABLE 1
Mean Preferences for Smoking Bans, by Voting and Smoking Status
All Voters-- Voters--
Place of Smoking Ban Respondents Voters Smokers Nonsmokers
Restaurants 0.514 0.545 0.207 0.608
Bars 0.292 0.312 0.080 0.356
Malls 0.690 0.706 0.487 0.747
Indoor sporting events 0.726 0.752 0.554 0.789
Hospitals 0.822 0.834 0.655 0.868
Indoor work areas 0.675 0.702 0.439 0.751
Number of observations 47,798 23,796 3,744 20,052
Nonvoters-- Nonvoters--
Place of Smoking Ban Nonvoters Smokers Nonsmokers
Restaurants 0.483 0.203 0.589
Bars 0.271 0.072 0.347
Malls 0.674 0.503 0.740
Indoor sporting events 0.700 0.538 0.762
Hospitals 0.809 0.669 0.863
Indoor work areas 0.649 0.416 0.738
Number of observations 24,002 6,605 17,397
TABLE 2
Individual Determinants of Voting (Dependent Variable: Voted in
November 1998 Election)
Variable Mean (SD) (1) (2)
Voter (dependent 0.50
variable) (0.50)
Smoker 0.217 -0.217 ** -0.222 **
(0.412) (0.016) (0.015)
[-0.086] [-0.088]
Family income (x 1000) 41.62 0.006 ** 0.006 **
(24.57) (0.0003) (0.0003)
[0.002] [0.002]
Family income missing 0.08 0.113 ** 0.112 **
(0.27) (0.026) (0.026)
[0.045] [0.045]
Education 13.12 0.092 ** 0.093 **
(2.91) (0.002) (0.002)
[0.037] [0.037]
Male 0.43 -0.032 ** -0.034 **
(0.49) (0.013) (0.013)
[-0.013] [-0.014]
Age 46.71 0.027 ** 0.027 **
(17.18) (0.0004) (0.0004)
[0.011] [0.011]
Married 0.61 0.111 ** 0.111 **
(0.49) (0.018) (0.018)
[0.044] [0.044]
Previously married 0.21 -0.173 ** -0.173 **
(0.41) (0.022) (0.022)
[-0.069] [-0.069]
Northeast 0.21 -0.177 ** -0.179 **
(0.41) (0.018) (0.019)
[-0.070] [-0.071]
Midwest 0.25 0.021 0.020
(0.43) (0.018) (0.018)
[0.009] [0.008]
South 0.31 -0.194 ** -0.200 **
(0.46) (0.017) (0.017)
[-0.077] [-0.079]
White 0.87 0.013 0.014
(0.33) (0.019) (0.019)
[0.005] [0.006]
Hispanic 0.07 -0.359 ** -0.360 **
(0.25) (0.027) (0.027)
[-0.140] [-0.141]
Restaurant ban 0.51 0.021
(0.50) (0.017)
[0.008]
Bar ban 0.29 -0.056 **
(0.45) (0.016)
[-0.023]
Mall ban 0.69 -0.023
(0.46) (0.019)
[-0.009]
Indoor sporting events 0.73 0.032
ban (0.45) (0.019)
[0.013]
Hospital ban 0.82 0.039 *
(0.38) (0.020)
[0.016]
Indoor work area ban 0.68 0.005
(0.47) (0.017)
[0.002]
Constant -2.626 ** -2.584 **
(0.047) (0.045)
Pseudo R-squared 0.14 0.14
Log likelihood -28,594.64 -28,605.16
Number of observations 47,798 47,798 47,798
Notes: Table reports probit coefficients with standard errors in
parentheses and marginal effects in brackets. The dependent variable
equals 1 if the individual voted in the November 1998 election, and
0 otherwise. ** (*) indicates coefficient is significantly different
from zero at 1% (5%) level, two-sided tests.
TABLE 3
Prevalence of State Smoking Restrictions January 1999
Number of States with Type of Restriction
Place of Separate Smoking Separate
Regulation No Restriction Areas (a) Ventilation (b)
Restaurants 20 28 0
Bars 47 3 1
Malls 43 6 1
Enclosed arenas 28 21 1
Hospitals 8 35 2
Number of States with
Type of Restriction
Place of No Any Smoking
Regulation Smoking Restriction
Restaurants 3 31
Bars 0 4
Malls 1 8
Enclosed arenas 1 23
Hospitals 6 43
(a) Designated smoking areas required or allowed.
(b) Designated smoking areas allowed if separately ventilated or no
smoking without separate ventilation.
TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics for State Data
(State Characteristics)
Mean
Variable (SD)
Smoking rate 0.218
(0.030)
Median income/10,000 3.853
(0.572)
Percent GSP from tobacco 0.263
(0.899)
Republican governor/state legislature 0.255
(0.440)
TABLE 5
Descriptive Statistics: State Voter Pressure Indices
Predicted Voter Actual Voter
Pressure Index, Pressure Index,
Area of Mean Mean
Smoking Ban (SD) (SD)
Restaurants 0.268 0.537
(0.043) (0.074)
Bars 0.155 0.305
(0.021) (0.045)
Malls 0.353 0.708
(0.052) (0.075)
Indoor sporting events 0.377 0.759
(0.054) (0.071)
Hospitals 0.414 0.834
(0.047) (0.047)
TABLE 6
Smoking Restriction Probit Regressions
Restaurants Bars Malls
Predicted voter pressure index 25.47 ** 43.84 ** 17.74 *
(10.10) (20.11) (9.75)
Smoking rate 5.84 11.31 -9.40
(10.21) (18.43) (11.24)
Median income 0.13 -0.06 -0.33
(x$10,000) (0.44) (0.64) (0.67)
Percent GSP from tobacco 0.04 -24.07 -27.51
(0.31) (27.59) (35.10)
Republican governor/ -0.80 * -- -1.67 *
state legislature (0.49) (0.92)
Pseudo R-squared 0.26 0.32 0.34
Log likelihood -25.33 -9.47 -14.58
Enclosed Arenas Hospitals
Predicted voter pressure index 11.30 ** 13.33
(4.66) (10.87)
Smoking rate -2.02 17.18
(7.66) (14.50)
Median income -0.01 1.83
(x$10,000) (0.39) (1.14)
Percent GSP from tobacco 0.09 -0.93 *
(0.25) (0.55)
Republican governor/ -0.07 -0.36
state legislature (0.46) (0.92)
Pseudo R-squared 0.14 0.46
Log likelihood -30.33 -11.90
Notes: Table reports probit coefficients with standard errors in
parentheses. The dependent variable equals 1 if the state has any
smoking restriction in that public area, and 0 otherwise. Each
equation also includes a constant term (not reported).
** (*) indicates coefficient is significantly different from zero at
5% (10%) level, two-sided tests.
TABLE 7
Smoking Restriction Probit Regressions
Restaurant Bars Malls
Actual voter pressure index 6.11 10.36 * 9.04 **
(4.72) (5.69) (4.39)
Smoking rate 0.37 -1.96 -7.84
(10.51) (12.55) (11.09)
Median income 0.59 0.10 0.13
(x$10,000) (0.37) (0.58) (0.54)
Percent GSP from tobacco -0.23 -19.66 -24.19
(0.30) (30.60) (31.10)
Republican governor/ -0.47 -- -1.36
state legislature (0.45) (0.87)
Pseudo R-squared 0.17 0.22 0.35
Log likelihood -28.21 -10.99 -14.40
Enclosed Arenas Hospital
Actual voter pressure index 6.93 ** 4.17
(3.31) (8.03)
Smoking rate -0.82 15.70
(7.79) (14.60)
Median income 0.32 2.21 **
(x$10,000) (0.36) (1.00)
Percent GSP from tobacco 0.06 -1.03 **
(0.26) (0.50)
Republican governor/ 0.16 0.33
state legislature (0.44) (0.67)
Pseudo R-squared 0.11 0.43
Log likelihood -31.09 -12.60
Notes. Table reports probit coefficients with standard errors in
parentheses. The dependent variable equals 1 if the state has any
smoking restriction in that public area, and 0 otherwise. Each
equation also includes a constant term (not reported).
** (*) indicates coefficient is significantly different from zero at
5% (10%) level, two-sided tests.
TABLE 8
Ordered Probit Regressions of Degree of Smoking
Restrictions in Hospitals
Coefficients (SE)
(1) (2)
Predicted voter 13.01 *
pressure index (7.53)
Actual voter 9.08
pressure index (6.42)
Smoking rate 11.73 14.47
(8.34) (9.21)
Median income 1.74 *** 1.96 ***
(x$10,000) (0.61) (0.56)
Percent GSP from -0.94 ** -1.03 **
tobacco (0.43) (0.41)
Republican govern or/ -0.89 -0.49
state legislature (0.60) (0.51)
Pseudo R-squared 0.39 0.38
Log likelihood -28.84 -29.45
Notes: The dependent variable taking on four possible discrete values
from 0 (no restriction) to 3 (smoking ban). Each equation also includes
a constant term (not reported).
*** [**] (*) indicates coefficient is significantly different from
zero at 1% [5%] (10%) level, two-sided tests.
(1.) Federal involvement in tobacco regulation has been isolated to
a few areas. It has had a primary role in investigating and reporting
the health consequences of tobacco use and in establishing restrictions
on advertising and labeling requirements. Congress has also passed laws
specifying restrictions on smoking on domestic flights and in facilities
that serve children and receive federal funding. If states do not
institute certain laws and enforce those laws to decrease smoking and
tobacco use among minors, they face significant reductions in the
Substance Abuse Prevention and Treatment block grant. See
www.samhsa.gnv/csap/SYNAR/sydex.htm for details.
(2.) There are numerous local laws imposing smoking restrictions.
Local laws that are perceived as successful can lead to widespread
adoption, and economic interests may also be influential. Once local
laws are enacted, affected enterprises may press for state regulation to
avoid losing patrons to nearby cities. See "Smoke-Free,
Statewide," Boston Globe, 11 May 2003, p. 10. On the other hand, 17
states have some level of preemption of local indoor smoking laws, which
forbids lower-level jurisdictions from passing laws more stringent than
those set at the state level or simply forbids any different local laws.
We address only state-level restrictions in this article, leaving for
future research the important question of interactions between state and
local restrictions.
(3.) Studies that have examined the political economy of other
types of smoking policies include Hunter and Nelson (1992), Besley and
Rosen (1998), and Nelson (2002), who empirically investigate the
determinants of cigarette tax rates. Jacobson et al. (1993) examine the
evolution of antismoking legislation using six states as case studies.
(4.) See Inman (1987) for an overview of political economy models
of policy making.
(5.) Stigler (1971), Peltzman (1976), and Becker (1983) have
modeled the role of political pressures from interest groups. In many
empirical studies, nonvoter variables add explanatory power to the
determination of public spending. Ahmed and Greene (2000) find interest
group models perform about as well as median voter models in explaining
local spending in New York State counties. Congleton and Bennett (1995)
find support for both median voter and special interest models in the
determination of state highway expenditures. Stanton and Whitehead
(1994) find intergovernmental relations, state wealth, special
interests, and other political variables are important determinants of
states' air and water pollution control expenditures. Case et al.
(1993) find a significant positive impact of neighboring states'
spending on a state's chosen funding.
(6.) Regulations may also reduce smoking prevalence. The U.S.
Department of Health and Human Services (2000) provides a comprehensive
review of the large body of literature on the effect of smoking
restrictions on individual smoking behavior. In a recent study, Evans et
al. (1999) find that workplace smoking bans reduce smoking prevalence
among workers subject to bans by more than 5 percentage points and
reduce average cigarette consumption among those workers by about 10%.
(7.) The EPA's meta-analysis found a 19% increase in lung
cancer risk to nonsmokers from exposure to ETS, significant at the 90%
level, which translates into 3000 deaths per year. The methodology of
the EPA study has been widely criticized and was the subject of a
federal lawsuit (Flue-Cured Tobacco Cooperative Stabilization Corporation v. United States Environmental Protection Agency, 4
F.Supp.2d 435 [1998]). Recent research finds no effect of ETS on
long-term mortality from tobacco-related disease (Enstrom and Kabat
2003). For a discussion of the role of the EPA report in OSHA's
decision to classify ETS as a workplace hazard, see for example Karr and
Gutfeld (1992).
(8.) Survey evidence for Spain, which has cigarette warnings and
smoking risk beliefs comparable to those in the United States, is
instructive. Spanish respondents believe that 25% of people exposed to
ETS will get lung cancer and 25% will get heart disease, and that the
average person will lose six years of life expectancy due to exposure to
ETS. See Viscusi (2002, 120-21).
(9.) Dunham and Marlow (2000b) critique the methodology of several
studies that conclude that business profitability is not harmed by
smoking restrictions. Their own study finds that owners expect a drop in
revenue if laws banning smoking in these establishments were instituted,
with owners of bars expecting larger losses than restaurant owners.
(10.) There was negligible variation in median voter preferences
across states; consequently our analyses are based on state mean values.
The median voters in all states preferred allowing smoking in some areas
for bars, and they all preferred no smoking at all for hospitals, indoor
sporting events, and malls. Only for smoking in restaurants was there
any variation in median preferences across states. As we will describe
in section III, the survey specified only three possible responses for
reporting preferences over smoking restrictions. To test the median
voter model, ideally we would measure individual support for smoking
restrictions using a continuous scale. With a greater number of
gradations we would also expect more variability in the median response
by state, making a test of the median voter model feasible.
(11.) This supplement was sponsored by the National Cancer
Institute and is similar to the Tobacco Use Supplement surveys conducted
in 1992-93 and 1995-96. Ideally one would analyze the evolution of
regulation between survey waves, but too few states changed their
regulations between 1993 and 1999 to permit analysis of changes in
regulatory status. We are not able to use data from the May 1999 wave
because it is not possible to link information from this survey to
voting status reported in the November 1998 wave.
(12.) It is not possible to link all such respondents because
household members are not followed to their new residence if they move.
Instead, the new occupants of the residence are surveyed. To match the
same individual across surveys, we use information on household
identifier, individual-specific identifier, and household number (CPS
variables HHID, LINENO, and HHNUM). The latter number is assigned 1 for
the original household and will increment by 1 when a household is
replaced. Thus, individuals are matched if all of these variables are
the same in both surveys. In theory, matching on these three variables
should be sufficient to avoid mismatches, but in practice various
recording errors occur (see, e.g., Madrian and Lefgren 2000). We use
four additional criteria. First, we require that MIS differs by 2 in
matching the smoking information to the voting information, so that
individuals who are surveyed for the first time in September are being
surveyed for their third time in November, and so forth. We also require
that individuals match on sex and on race and that age changes in the
later survey by no more than one year.
(13.) For convenience, we refer throughout the paper to indoor
shopping malls as "malls" and bars and cocktail lounges as
"bars."
(14.) Without the restriction to sell-respondents, the male share
is 46.3%.
(15.) The STATE system can be found online at
www2.cdc.gov/nccdphp/osh/state/. The system was developed by the Centers
for Disease Control and Prevention, Office on Smoking and Health,
National Center for Chronic Disease Prevention Health Promotion, and it
is updated quarterly using legislative databases.
(16.) There is also information about exceptions, enforcement, and
penalties.
(17.) Extending the cut-off date to 30 June 1999 to allow for a lag
in responding to voter preferences yielded no changes in the
restrictions variables for the categories of indoor smoking restrictions
analyzed here.
(18.) We use the smoking rate including smoking information
reported by proxies in the state-level analysis.
(19.) Belief in the ability of markets to address smoking
restrictions without government intervention is likely to be correlated
with Republican party affiliation. Boyes and Marlow (1996) found less
support for restaurant smoking bans among those who felt that
market-based allocation of voluntary smoking/nonsmoking sections
effectively dealt with the smoking issue.
(20.) Although the CPS survey reports preferences for indoor work
areas, this appeared to be only loosely linked to corresponding
restrictions. Because we found no statistically significant link between
chosen restrictions on government or private work sites and preferences
for restrictions in indoor work areas, these results are not presented
in the article. We use preferences for restrictions at indoor sporting
events in the equations for state restrictions on smoking in enclosed
arenas.
(21.) In a univariate regression estimated using observations from
1300 owners of restaurants, bar, and taverns, Dunham and Marlow (2000a)
find a negative relation between tobacco manufacturing in the state and
whether a state has a smoking law affecting restaurants. It is difficult
to compare our multiple regression results, which use states as the unit
of analysis, to their results based on individual observations.
(22.) Inclusion of the Republican governor/state legislature
variable results in 13 observations being dropped from the probit
analyses for bars. The results estimated using a linear probability
model (which allows the inclusion of this variable without dropping
observations) leads to results consistent with those reported in Tables
6 and 7. We also note that multicollinearity does not seem to be a
problem in this sample because the simple correlations are relatively
low. The correlations among smoking rate, median income, and percent
tobacco are as follows: smoking rate and median income, -0.34; smoking
rate and percent tobacco, 0.28, and median income and percent tobacco,
-0.04.
(23.) The p-value for the actual voter pressure index is equal to
0.16.
(24.) These predicted probabilities are calculated using the
following values of the independent variables for New York State:
predicted voter pressure index for restaurants, 0.25, and for bars,
0.16; actual voter pressure index for restaurants, 0.52, and for bars,
0.33; smoking rate, 19.8%; real median income, $37,394; percent GSP in
tobacco, 0.22%; and Republican state, 0.
(25.) See Haberman (2003, A21). For information on the lawsuit see
Precious (2003, A9).
(26.) The five states are California, Connecticut, Delaware, Maine,
and New York. See Zezima (2003).
REFERENCES
Ahmed, Sultan, and Kenneth V. Greene. "Is the Median Voter a
Clear-Cut Winner? Comparing the Median Voter Theory and Competing
Theories in Explaining Local Government Spending." Public Choice,
105(3-4), 2000, 207-30.
Becker, Gary S. "A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups
for Political Influence." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3),
1983, 371-400.
Besley, Timothy J., and Harvey S. Rosen. "Vertical
Externalities in Tax Setting: Evidence from Gasoline and
Cigarettes." Journal of Public Economics, 70(3), 1998, 383-98.
Boyes, William J., and Michael L. Marlow. "The Public Demand
for Smoking Bans." Public Choice, 88(1-2), 1996, 57-67.
Case, Anne C., Harvey S. Rosen, and James R. Hines Jr. "Budget
Spillovers and Fiscal Policy Interdependence: Evidence from the
States." Journal of Public Economics, 52(3), 1993, 285-307.
Congleton, Roger D., and Randall W. Bennett. "On the Political
Economy of State Highway Expenditures: Some Evidence of the Relative
Performance of Alternative Public Choice Models." Public Choice,
84(1-2), 1995, 1-24.
Dunham, John, and Michael L. Marlow. "The Effects of Smoking
Laws on Seating Allocations of Restaurants, Bars, and Taverns."
Economic Inquiry, 38(1), 2000a, 151-57.
--. "Smoking Laws and Their Differential Effects on
Restaurants, Bars, and Taverns." Contemporary Economic Policy,
18(3), 2000b, 326-33.
Enstrom, James E., and Geoffrey C. Kabat. "Environmental
Tobacco Smoke and Tobacco Related Mortality in a Prospective Study of
Californians, 1960-98." British Medical Journal, 326, 2003,
1057-61.
Evans, Williams N., Matthew C. Farrelly, and Edward Montgomery.
"Do Workplace Smoking Bans Reduce Smoking?" American Economic
Review, 89(4), 1999, 729-47.
Haberman, Clyde. "If Virtue Has Prevailed in Smoking Ban, Why
Are So Many People Upset?" New York Times, 25 July 2003, p. A21.
Hunter, William J., and Michael A. Nelson. "The Political
Economy of State Tobacco Taxation." Public Finance/Finances
Publiques, 47(2), 1992, 214-28.
Inman, Robert P. "Markets, Government, and the 'New'
Political Economy," in Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 2,
edited by Alan J. Auerbach and Martin Feldstein. New York: Elsevier,
1987, 647-777.
Jacobson, Peter D., Jeffrey Wasserman, and Kristiana Raube.
"The Politics of Antismoking Legislation." Journal of Health
Politics, Policy & Law, 18(4), 1993, 787-819.
Karr, Albert, and Rose Gutfeld. "Workplace: OSHA Inches Toward
Limiting Smoking." Wall Street Journal, 16 January 1992, B1.
Madrian, Brigitte C., and Lars John Lefgren. "An Approach to
Longitudinally Matching Current Population Survey (CPS)
Respondents." Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 26(1),
2000, 31-62.
Nelson, Michael A. "Using Excise Taxes to Finance State
Government: Do Neighboring State Taxation Policy and Cross-Border
Markets Matter?" Journal of Regional Science, 42(4), 2002, 731-52.
Peltzman, Sam. "Toward a More General Theory of
Regulation." Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 1976, 211-48.
Precious, Tom. "Bar Industry Sues State to Block Smoking
Ban." Buffalo News, 23 July 2003, p. A9.
Stanton, Timothy J., and John C. Whitehead. "Special Interests
and Comparative State Policy: An Analysis of Environmental Quality
Expenditures." Eastern Economic Journal, 20(4), 1994, 441-52.
Stigler, George J. "The Theory of Economic Regulation."
Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 1971, 3-21.
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Reducing Tobacco Use:
A Report of the Surgeon General. U.S. Department of Health and Human
Services, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, National Center
for Chronic Disease Prevention, Office of Smoking and Health, Atlanta,
GA, 2000.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Respiratory Health Effects of
Passive Smoking: Lung Cancer and Other Disorders. EPA/600/6-90/006F,
Office of Health and Environmental Assessment. Washington, DC: U.S.
Environmental Agency, 1992.
Viscusi, W. Kip. Smoke-Filled Rooms: A Postmortem on the Tobacco
Deal. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2002.
Zezima, Katie. "National Briefing New England: Maine:
Expansion of Smoking Ban." New York Times, 25 June 2003, p. A18.
JONI HERSCH, ALISON F. DEL ROSSI, and W. KIP VISCUSI *
* Viscusi's research is supported by the Harvard Olin Center
for Law, Economics, and Business.
Hersch: Adjunct Professor of Law, Harvard Law School, 1557
Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138. Phone 1-617-495-2832, Fax
1-617-495-3010, E-mail jhersch@law.harvard.edu
Del Rossi: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, St.
Lawrence University, Canton, NY 13617. Phone 1-315-229-5449, Fax
1-315-229-5819, E-mail adelrossi@stlawu.edu
Viscusi: Cogan Professor of Law and Economics, Harvard Law School,
Hauser 302, 1575 Massachusetts Ave., Cambridge, MA 02138. Phone
1-617-496-0019, Fax 1-617-495-3010, E-mail kip@law.harvard.edu