Diagnosis murder: the death of state death taxes.
Conway, Karen Smith ; Rork, Jonathan C.
Since 1976, more than 30 states have eliminated their
"death" taxes and many others have reduced them. This
unexplored case of interstate tax competition presents a unique
opportunity to develop a new, more satisfying definition of competitor
based on historical elderly migration patterns. Using data from 1967
onward, we outline the recent history of state death tax competition and
present a spatial econometric analysis. Interstate tax competition is
evident and grows stronger when using migration-based definitions of
competitors. The article concludes with still more evidence of
interstate tax competition the recent movement by states to effectively
revive their death taxes. (JEL H7, D7)
I. INTRODUCTION
The federal estate tax has received wide attention especially
because its elimination has been a centerpiece of President George W.
Bush's tax proposals. (1) Largely overlooked, however, is the quiet
revolution that has been taking place at the state level. Since 1976, 31
of the 48 contiguous states have repealed their "death" or
estate, inheritance, and gift (EIG) taxes, instead relying only on the
pick-up tax whereby states capture a portion of the federal estate tax
liability but do not increase the overall liability of the estate. (2)
Of the remaining 12 states that still have EIG taxes, 2 have enacted
legislation that will eliminate them by 2005 and others are considering
doing so. Beyond the outright elimination of EIG taxes, many states have
also acted to reduce them in a variety of ways, such as exempting
certain beneficiaries, such as the spouse.
This trend is noteworthy for several reasons. Foremost, it appears
to us a prime example of intense interstate tax competition due to the
growing size and political influence of the elderly population. There is
additional political pressure because states may worry that high EIG
taxes will drive the high-income elderly to move to bordering states or
retirement havens. The stakes may be substantial. For example, Longino
and Crown (1989) estimate that Florida had a net gain of $5 billion in
income from the elderly migrants it received between 1985 and 1990, and
Sastry (1992, 73) estimates that one new job is created for every 2.5
elderly migrants it receives. State EIG tax competition also provides us
with a unique opportunity to explore alternative definitions of
competitor states beyond simple geography because the movements of the
tax base--the elderly--are fairly easy to track via historical migration
data. Yet no research to our knowledge has explored interstate EIG tax
competition.
Furthermore, these widespread changes in state EIG taxes provide
substantial cross-sectional and time-series variation that has been
mostly overlooked by researchers interested in the behavioral effects of
estate taxes. (3) State EIG tax policy is also still in flux. Current
and proposed changes in the federal estate tax have substantial revenue
consequences for states, effectively eliminating EIG tax revenues for
those that rely solely on the pick-up tax. How will the states react to
this change? At present, several states have enacted or are considering
legislation that would effectively decouple their EIG taxes from the
federal estate tax and so would preserve the revenue source. Indeed, as
the federal estate tax is slowly eliminated, EIG taxes in states that
continue to use them may be the only remaining taxes on bequests. Yet
little is known about them.
Our research seeks to fill this void. Using state-level data from
1967 to the present, we first describe the brief history and
geographical pattern of these widespread reductions in state EIG taxes.
To our knowledge, ours is the first research to document in a systematic
way this phenomenon. We begin with a chronology of the states that
eliminated completely their EIG taxes (thereby choosing to rely instead
only on the pick-up tax). However, there are many other ways that the
states may reduce their EIG taxes, such as increasing exemptions or
reducing tax rates. For example, in 1985 legislative sessions alone,
nine states increased personal exemptions or fully exempted spouses
(Eckl 1986). We therefore also describe this broader phenomena of tax
reductions with an eye for evidence of state competition.
Given the many ways that states may reduce their EIG taxes and the
subtleties of the timing of the wholesale elimination (many were phased
in over several years), focusing only on one policy action is incomplete
and likely to lead to erroneous conclusions. Rather, we explore the
extent of state EIG tax competition by estimating each state's EIG
tax reliance as a function of fiscal and political factors as well as
the EIG tax policy of its competitors. Our empirical approach follows
that of Case et al. (1993) and includes state and time fixed effects.
This research contributes to the tax competition literature both by
considering a tax that has been over-looked and by extending the
definition of what constitutes "neighbors/competitors" beyond
simple geography. Specifically, we use historical information on the
migration of elderly individuals between states to construct our
weights, which, we argue, should better capture the competitive climate
(or mobility of the tax base) among states. Past tax competition
research has relied solely on geography, and to our knowledge, no state
competition research has used migration as a measure of Tiebout-type
pressures. Using our migration-based definitions of competitor states
has a substantial impact on our results and suggests a stronger degree
of tax competition.
After investigating the presence and determinants of interstate tax
competition in this way, we then look at what is currently happening in
the state EIG tax policy arena. The current situation is rather
remarkable in the swiftness with which the states are reacting to
changes in federal estate tax policy that threatens to eliminate their
pick-up tax revenue source. It is also strongly suggestive that state
competition is again at work, this time however in the reinstitution (or
reincarnation) of state EIG taxes.
II. PAST RESEARCH
Our research borrows insights from and has possible implications
for at least three bodies of literature--state competition, elderly
migration, and federal estate taxation. Our primary contribution is to
the state competition literature, as our research first documents the
phenomena of widespread reductions of state EIG taxes and then explores
it empirically as a classic case of state tax competition. We also bring
new insights to this area by considering alternative definitions of
neighbor or competitor that go beyond simple geography. Because the tax
base that the states may be competing over consists primarily of the
elderly, our work intersects with research into Tiebout elderly
migration. Finally, both because of the temporal and cross-sectional
variability in state EIG taxes we uncover and because reducing EIG taxes
may have behavioral consequences other than migration which might
benefit the states (e.g., increased savings or labor supply), research
on the federal estate tax becomes relevant.
State Tax Competition and Elderly Migration
Although there are many arenas in which states interact with one
another, the prevailing literature can be broken down into three major
areas--expenditures, program adoptions, and taxation. There are insights
to be gained from all three, but the tax competition area is clearly the
most relevant for us. The mobility of capital plays an important role in
past models of tax competition. In these models, surveyed by Wilson
(1999), capital flows between jurisdictions as it searches for the
highest after-tax rate of return. A government will attempt to encourage
this inflow by lowering the tax it places on capital to a level below
that of its neighbors. In response, the first jurisdiction will often
lower its tax rate, and a battle of under-cutting will often result. In
a world of perfect capital mobility, the equilibrium outcome will be for
states to eliminate the tax in question. In reality, capital is not
perfectly mobile, because there is often a cost associated with
relocation. Hence, one does not witness such extreme results because at
some level, the savings received with lower taxation will not offset the
additional moving costs incurred by relocating capital.
The spatial econometric techniques used by Case et al. (1993) and
Baicker (2001) in their analyses of state expenditures have allowed for
a recent wave of empirical research focusing on the dimensions, if any,
in which tax competition is taking place. Not surprisingly, those taxes
that are considered to have a mobile tax base, such as property taxes
(Heyndels and Vuchelen 1998; Brueckner and Saavedra 2001; Revelli 2001),
business taxes (Buettner 2001), and excise taxes on motor fuel and
cigarettes (Rork 2003) are found to be subject to the forces of tax
competition by neighboring jurisdictions. In addition, Case (1993) and
Besley and Case (1995) argue for a political component to tax
competition, in that voters are likely to look to taxes of neighboring
states as a means of assessing economic conditions and hence the
performance of elected officials at home. (4)
The lesson from this research appears to be that states are engaged
in tax competition with their neighbors, especially when the tax base is
thought to be mobile. Just what tax base are the states competing over
in the case of EIG taxes? It appears likely that the tax base primarily
consists of the elderly, although as we will discuss, eliminating EIG
taxes may have other behavioral consequences. States may be competing
for wealthy elderly individuals who might choose their residence on the
basis of state tax policy. There is some support that elders are
considering EIG taxes when they make migration decisions. Using
migration flows of elderly individuals, Voss et al. (1988) and Conway
and Houtenville (2001, 2003) find evidence that high state EIG tax rates
discourage in-migration. However, the one study that examines individual
level data and simulates the effects of an actual change in state EIG
tax policy finds no significant effect (Dresher 1994). Interestingly,
research in this area has also largely overlooked the dramatic changes
in state EIG taxes over the past 30 years and instead has focused
chiefly on cross-sectional differences. One exception is Bakija and
Slemrod (2002), who look at the number and size of federal estate tax
returns over time in relation to state EIG and income tax policies;
their preliminary evidence suggests that the elderly do respond to state
EIG taxes in their location decisions.
Whether attracting or retaining the elderly is a wise policy is
also unclear. Though the presumption by many is that elderly migrants
positively affect the state (Longino and Crown 1989 call them "pure
gold" in estimating that Florida had a net gain of $5 billion in
income from the elderly migrants it received during 1985-90), their
total effect is likely more complex, especially on the public sector. A
comprehensive analysis that weighs all of their possible effects does
not exist, a void noted and discussed by Serow (1992).
Regardless of what research has found, it is clear that at least
some practitioners believe that EIG taxes are a powerful motivator to
move:
Yes, we're supposed to be called Michiganians,
but some of prefer the old Michigander. And wise
old Michiganders with estates had preferred to die
as Floridians, Texans, etc. Under Michigan's old
inheritance tax, the deceased's estate would have
to pay Michigan's inheritance tax even if the
estate's worth was under the federal estate tax
exemption for the first $600,000 in property
interest for most estates. This inheritance tax
could be quite costly (e.g. $77,400 if single person
left all $600,000 in assets to niece). Therefore, in
the past if [sic] made more sense for a Michigan
resident, who would have to pay a larger
inheritance tax, to become a Florida resident at
retirement in order to pay a lower Florida "pick-up"
tax. However, Michigan passed the Michigan
Estate Tax Act for persons dying after September
30, 1993. Now, for Michigan residents with
Michigan property, the tax is equal to the credit
allowed for state death taxes paid for federal
estate tax purposes (i.e. the state "picks-up" the
amount that would have gone.) Net effect: in a
typical estate, there will be no out-of-pocket cost
to Michigan residents because of this new tax
scheme. Therefore, there is no reason to become a
Floridian for death tax purposes (though
warm weather may also have something to do
with it) (The Gavel, February 1995,
www.forestlaw.com/gavel1-95.html).
This quote suggests that elderly migration may have been a factor
in Michigan's decision to eliminate its estate tax. Perhaps even
more important is that it reveals that a state's competitors are
not necessarily limited to its geographic neighbors, as is assumed in
all of the tax competition studies we know of (and cite). Exploring
whether this kind of thinking is typical is one of the purposes of this
article.
Federal Estate Taxation
As will be discussed in the next section, state EIG taxes are
tightly linked to the federal estate tax, which is currently being
reduced and may be eliminated in the near future. In other areas of
federal taxation, states have been shown to react to changes in federal
taxes. Besley and Rosen (1998) show that states match increases in
federal gasoline taxation with an increase in state tax rates. Goodspeed
(2000, 2002) discovered a similar responsiveness between national and
local income taxes among European states. In our descriptive analysis,
we also see a pattern of reducing state EIG taxes during times of major
federal tax reforms. In the last section of this article, we report on
the way that states are currently reacting to the recent changes in the
federal estate tax.
Most work involving federal estate taxation has focused on the
behavioral responses of individuals, responses such as the savings and
labor supply behaviors of both the individuals making the bequests and
the beneficiaries (see Gale and Slemrod 2000 for an excellent review of
the literature and the articles in Gale et al. 2001 for recent
advances). Past research has also considered the motives under-lying
bequests by exploring whether individuals take full advantage of lower
gift taxes via inter vivos transfers (e.g., Kuehlwein 1994; Joulfaian
2000a; McGarry 2001; Poterba 2001; Page 2003). Still others have
considered the impact on charitable contributions (Joulfaian 2000b;
Auten and Joulfaian 1996) and capital gains realization (Auten and
Joulfaian 2001).
This line of research demonstrates many other ways that states may
be affected by eliminating their EIG taxes beyond simply retaining or
building their tax base of elderly individuals. In a recent work,
Blumkin and Sadka (forthcoming) go one step further by demonstrating the
properties of an optimal estate tax in the presence of a complete set of
tax instruments. An interesting extension of our research, then, would
be to use their theoretical framework to examine whether states are
behaving optimally in their widespread reductions in EIG taxes.
Even more important, a look at past research on estate taxation
reveals how the various behavioral responses could be better identified
and ultimately understood if researchers took advantage of the
variability introduced by the revolution in state EIG taxes. The promise
of using state EIG taxes is evident in Page (2003), who uses the
variability of state EIG taxes to consider the impact of such taxes on
inter vivos giving. He points out that by looking at state EIG taxes,
one can investigate a much wider range of estates (because the federal
estate tax only taxes very large estates). Joulfaian (2000a, b) likewise
uses state variability to help identify the effects of estate taxation
on inter vivos giving and charitable contributions, respectively,
although his analyses are only limited to federal estate tax returns. To
our knowledge, only Bakija et al. (2003) have taken advantage of the
variability in state EIG tax policy over time, which as we discuss next,
is quite extensive.
III. A PRIMER ON STATE EIG TAXES
State EIG taxes are made up of three different types of taxes, (1)
estate taxes, (2) inheritance taxes, and (3) gift taxes. (5) Estate and
inheritance taxes are levied on the transfer of wealth that occurs at
death and as such are determined by the decedent's state of
residence. The primary difference between the two is that because
inheritance taxes are levied on the individual beneficiaries of
transfers made at death (and within two years of death), the tax rates
may differ depending on the type of beneficiary. Typically, those
beneficiaries with the closest relationship to the deceased have the
lowest rates (e.g., a spouse would pay less than a nephew). Conversely,
an estate tax is levied on the net estate of the deceased. The type of
beneficiaries of the estate has no effect on the tax imposed unless the
beneficiary is exempt (such as a surviving spouse). States impose an
estate or an inheritance tax, and in either case the tax rates and
exemptions vary widely across states. Gift taxes are not really death
taxes per se, but they act to prevent death tax avoidance that could
occur by transferring wealth prior to death. They also tend to have
similar rates and exemptions as the estate or inheritance tax in the
given state.
State EIG taxes have been in existence since 1826, but a permanent
federal estate tax was not imposed until 1916 (Eckl 1986). (6) In 1924,
Congress provided a credit against the federal tax for any EIG taxes
paid to the states. In other words, the state EIG taxes paid are
credited dollar for dollar against the federal estate tax liability
owed, up to a certain amount. This is known as the pick-up tax, whereby
the state picks up some of the federal tax liability without increasing
the total tax liability of the estate. All states, with the exception of
Nevada prior to the 1980s, take advantage of the pickup tax. We classify a state as eliminating their EIG tax, instead relying only on the
pick-up tax, when their tax laws are rewritten such that the state tax
liability is not to exceed this credit. We define the date as when those
laws become effective. (7) These dates were found from various sources,
including Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, Eckl (1986), and
direct correspondence with state officials.
A Quiet Revolution in State EIG Taxes
Prior to 1960, four states chose to levy only the pick-up
tax--Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, and Georgia. Not only are all of these
Southern states, but also the latter three are known as or are becoming
retirement havens for the younger elderly (Conway and Houtenville 2003).
The other states also took advantage of the pick-up tax, but they levied
additional EIG taxes. Nevada is an exception in that it never enacted an
EIG tax, but eventually took advantage of the pick-up tax in the late
1980s.
The year 1976 marks the beginning of a movement by the states to
eliminate EIG taxes in favor of only the pick-up tax. Table 1 presents a
chronology of the events, and Figure 1 provides information on the
geographical pattern in the form of a map. New Mexico was the first to
eliminate its EIG tax in January 1976, followed by Utah in January 1977.
Four states--Arizona, Colorado, Vermont, and Virginia---eliminated their
EIG taxes effective 1 January 1980. More generally, the trend to
eliminate EIG taxes has not been steady; rather it has clustered around
major changes in the federal tax law. (8) First of all, it is
interesting that the movement began in the same year as the Tax Reform
Act of 1976 (TRA76). TRA76 repealed the $60,000 exemption on estates and
replaced it with a unified credit of $47,000, which is equivalent to an
exemption of $175,625; this credit rose to an equivalent of $600,000 in
1981 (as a result of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981) where it
remained until increasing to $1 million in 1997 (as a result of the TRA
of 1997) (Joulfaian 2000c). Thus, 1976 also marks the beginning of the
federal estate tax law exempting a greater number of smaller estates,
which perhaps placed pressure on the states to do likewise.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The early 1980s witnessed many state actions to reduce EIG taxes,
with 11 states eliminating them between 1979 and 1983. Five more states
eliminated them between 1985 and 1988, with two doing so in the same
year as the Tax Reform Act of 1986. No states eliminated EIG taxes
(although many acted to reduce them) until 1991, when four states
eliminated them between 1991 and 1993. Once again, no actions were taken
until 1997; since then, nine states have eliminated their taxes and two
more have enacted legislation that will do so in the next few years.
This suggests that the movement may be picking up momentum again. It
also reveals that states may react to federal tax changes in setting
their own EIG tax policy, as found in other policy arenas by Besley and
Rosen (1998) and Goodspeed (2000, 2002). At the same time, however, the
phasing out of the federal estate tax (and thus the pick-up tax revenues
the states receive) has prompted several states to decouple their EIG
taxes from the federal tax, which effectively reinstitutes a state tax
on the estate. We discuss this development further in section VI.
Figure 1 reveals a limited geographic pattern to the movement. (9)
The four states that eliminated EIG taxes prior to 1976 are obviously
clustered in the Deep South. Yet Mississippi, which is in the same
cluster, just eliminated its EIG tax in 2000, and its neighbor,
Louisiana, is slated to do so in 2004. The Southwest, with the exception
of Oklahoma, had eliminated EIG taxes by 1983, as did the Mountain
states, with the exception of Montana, by 1988. With New
Hampshire's and Connecticut's elimination of EIG taxes by
2005, the entire New England region, along with New York, is devoid of
EIG taxes, although the actions occurred over a more than 20-year
period. The states that continue to have EIG taxes form geographic
blocks concentrated in the middle of the country and the Atlantic
seaboard.
Of course, part of the problem with this analysis is that we are
not controlling for other things. One of those things is the subtleties
in the timing of the policy actions. Many were phased in over several
years, and there is likely a significant lag between when the decision
was made and when the law became effective (witness Lousiana and
Connecticut). Another important factor is that the states have many ways
of reducing their EIG taxes beyond wholesale elimination. We discuss
some of those changes next.
Other Ways that States May Compete
An examination of state EIG tax policy changes reported in various
editions of Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism spanning the early
1980s to mid-1990s reveals that states made many different kinds of
changes to their EIG taxes during the period. (10) Probably the most
common action is to increase exemptions for taxable estates, at times
exempting entirely the spouse (e.g., New York as of 1/1/ 84, Connecticut
and New Jersey as of 7/1/88, and Iowa after 1987) or any homestead
created under the civil code (California, effective 1/1/ 1981) or
community property (Washington, effective 1984). A common pattern is for
states to begin increasing their exemptions a few years prior to the
elimination of their state EIG tax. For instance, Oregon steadily
increased the exemption for net tax taxable estates from 1980 to 1986
before eliminating the estate tax entirely for estates of decedents
dying on or after 1 January 1987. Texas, Washington, South Carolina, and
Massachusetts behaved similarly in increasing the exemption in the years
leading up to the elimination, whereas Rhode Island and Wisconsin had
policies that phased out the percentage owed in each year for their tax
such that it approached the pick-up tax. Michigan exempted family
businesses and farms from its inheritance tax in 1992, one year before
it eliminated the tax altogether.
During the same period, however, states made other changes to their
laws, some of which effectively increased their EIG taxes. For example,
Connecticut placed a 10% surcharge on inheritance taxes in 1983 and
shortened the due date for inheritance tax payments from nine to six
months after date of death in 1990 (while increasing the exemptions
during the same period). Likewise, in 1990 New York both expanded the
estate and gift tax base to include out-of-state property and, similar
to its neighbor Connecticut, accelerated both taxes by shifting their
administration to the Department of Taxation and Finance. (11) In the
year before they eliminated their EIG taxes, both Rhode Island and
Michigan like-wise accelerated the collection of these taxes. Other
changes include an increase in inheritance tax credits (North Carolina from 1987 to 1989), a reduction in inheritance tax rates (Tennessee,
which by reducing its rates on all other beneficiaries to match those of
the lowest category effectively switched to an estate tax after 1989),
and a change in rates and brackets for the estate tax (Mississippi after
10/1/89). States therefore have a multitude of ways to adjust their
state EIG tax policy, some subtle, such as collection and administration
policies, and others more obvious, such as eliminating their tax to rely
only on the pick-up tax.
Are there obvious patterns in these smaller changes? Our limited
inquiry leads us to believe so. The vast majority of the changes during
this period effectively reduced taxes, either by exempting entire
classes of beneficiaries or estates or by raising exemptions or lowering
tax rates. As mentioned earlier, many of these reductions were
precursors to the wholesale phase-out of the tax. Those actions that
increased taxes tended to be more subtle (e.g., accelerated collection)
or temporary (e.g., Ohio's delay of making spouses exempt).
Likewise, the same states tend to appear in these report summaries, such
as Connecticut and New York. Geography also appears to play a role as
revealed by the flurry of changes taking place in Connecticut, New York,
Rhode Island, and New Jersey in the late 1980s and early 1990s, and in
North Carolina, South Carolina, and Tennessee during the same period.
(12)
These reports also make clear that focusing on one policy
change--the date on which the elimination of state EIG taxes in favor of
the pick-up tax became effective-is missing other important avenues for
state competition and also the subtleties of how it took place. For
instance, Wisconsin eliminated its tax effective on 1 January 1992.
However, it began phasing out its tax in 1987--the year after its
neighbor Minnesota eliminated its tax and three years after another
neighbor, Illinois, eliminated its tax. Likewise, although
Wisconsin's neighbor Iowa continues to have an EIG tax, it
completely exempted spouses from inheritance taxation after 1987, the
year in which Wisconsin began phasing out its tax. Similar interactions
occurred between other neighboring states.
Ideally, one would study the individual policy changes, big and
small, and the interactions between states; however, quantifying and
distilling those changes into a variable to analyze is very difficult.
We therefore focus on the EIG tax revenues generated by each state as
the best summary measure of their policies. What has happened to state
EIG tax revenues during this period? Figure 2 reports the average
proportion of state tax revenue that came from state EIG taxes in every
year from 1968 until 1999. Interestingly, we see that the prominence of
state EIG taxes began to fall well before New Mexico kicked off the
pick-up revolution in 1976. In fact, it fell most steeply between 1968
and 1976, and continued its steep descent into the mid-1980s where it
has held fairly steady except for an uptick in the late 1990s (which is
likely due to large increases in estate sizes due to the economic boom).
This figure highlights that the competition on state EIG taxes is not
just limited to wholesale elimination; it also emphasizes the need to
control for the level of wealth in estimating state EIG tax revenues,
which we are able to do using state and time fixed effects.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
IV. DEFINING COMPETITORS AND OTHER MODEL SPECIFICATION ISSUES
The data used in our analyses encompasses 32 years of history from
1967 to 1999, because 1999 is the last year for which information on
some of our variables is available. We follow the practice of Case et
al. (1993) and others of limiting our analysis to the 48 contiguous
states. Alaska and Hawaii are typically eliminated both because they
have no geographic neighbors (and thus in typical tax competition
research are assumed to have no competitors) and because their economies
and fiscal policies are so different from the other 48 states. Annual
state financial data, including tax revenues, expenditures, and debt
issues, is compiled from various issues of State Government Finances.
Political variables along with state unemployment rates and the amount
of money transferred from federal to state government were compiled from
the Statistical Abstract of the United States. Series P-25 of Current
Population Reports, in conjunction with the Statistical Abstract of the
United States, was used to gather breakdowns of state population by age
including those aged 65 and older as well as 85 and older. (13) We also
use data on elderly migration. The elderly migration flows during
1965-70 that is, how many elderly moved between each pair of state--is
obtained from the 1970 Public Use Microdata Samples (PUMS) using
Micro-Analyst software.
The Econometric Model
We follow Case et al. (1993) by assuming that our EIG tax reliance
measure is a function of state characteristics ([X.sub.it]), state and
time fixed effects, and the tax measure of its 'competitors'.
Denoting Tit to be the tax measure in state i at time t yields a linear
relationship of
(1) [T.sub.it] = [X.sub.it][beta] + [theta][T.sub.jt] +
[[delta].sub.t] + [[zeta].sub.i] + [u.sub.it]
where [T.sub.it] represents the competitor's tax measure;
[[delta].sub.t] and [[zeta].sub.i] are year and state fixed effects,
respectively; and [u.sub.it] is a mean zero, normally distributed random
error. Because states have more than one competitor, Tit is replaced by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] where [W.sub.ij]
represents the weight assigned to state j. We discuss in the next
section the four different sets of weights we use.
Each state, therefore, has a set of weights (which can be thought
of as a 48 x 1 vector) signifying how important another state's tax
measure is in its own determination. Equation
(1) can be written as
(2) [T.sub.it] = [theta][W.sub.i][T.sub.t] + [X.sub.it][beta] +
[[delta].sub.t] + [[zeta].sub.i] + [u.sub.t],
where [W.sub.i] is the ith row of a weighting matrix, W. W is 48 x
48 matrix that assigns competitors to every state. This is known as a
spatial lag model.
The inclusion of [T.sub.t] on the right-hand side of equation (2)
means that estimation by ordinary least squares (OLS) will be
inconsistent, due to correlation with the error or simultaneity bias.
Intuitively, if tax competition is taking place, then the EIG policies
of one's competitors are going to be simultaneously determined with
one's own--for example, Alabama's policies are affected by
what Georgia is doing, and Georgia in turn will react to what Alabama
does. To deal with this endogeneity, we estimate equation (2) using the
instrumental variables approach outlined in Kelejian and Prucha (1998)
in which weighted values of the exogenous variables (WX) are used as
instruments. (14) This approach estimates a first-stage equation in
which competitor EIG tax reliance (WT) is regressed on the spatially
weighted values of the other characteristics (WX), which identifies the
structural equation. Intuitively, the model is identified with the
assumption that the other characteristics (e.g., state debt per capita)
of one's competitors do not directly affect EIG reliance once the
competitors' EIG reliance has been controlled for. This assumption
seems reasonable to us, that economic and demographic variables of
competitor states will not have an effect on EIG reliance over and above
their effect on the competitor's EIG reliance. As a check of this
approach, we perform three separate tests of these overidentifying
restrictions (i.e., that WX is uncorrelated with u in equation [2])
required for our instruments, the Hausman, Sargan N*[R.sub.2] and
Basmann tests, and our model passes all three. We also verify that WX is
jointly statistically significant in the first-stage regression (such
that it is correlated with WT).
A final consideration is the likelihood that the error term, u, in
equation (2) is both heteroscedastic and serially correlated. The
heteroscedasticity may arise because of the sampling variability of our
dependent variable--one would expect a small state to have a larger
variance than a large state, because the former is going to be more
strongly affected by the number and type of people who die each year.
The correlation may arise because we are following the same states
across time and there may be serial correlation within a state over time
that is not captured entirely by the state fixed effects. In addition,
other types of correlation may exist (e.g., across states at a point in
time) that are not captured by our model. For all of these reasons, we
calculate our standard errors via the bootstrap method in which 500
random samples of our original sample size are drawn with replacement
and then used to estimate 500 tax reliance equations. These 500 sets of
estimated coefficients are used to construct the bootstrap estimates of
the coefficient covariance matrix (standard errors and covariances).
Covariance estimates calculated via bootstrap are robust to correlation
among the errors and heteroscedasticity.
Constructing the Spatial Weights
Because the purpose of our analyses is to discover the factors that
push a state toward reducing its EIG taxes, defining which states are
competing with one another (i.e., defining W in equation [2]) is
critical. Accordingly, we use four different weighting matrices in
exploring which states are competitors, or neighbors, with one another.
For comparison with past studies of state competition, we begin
with two typical geography-based weights before moving on to two other
weights that use real economic information in the form of elderly
migration patterns. The first set of geographic weights used is known as
contiguity weights. States are considered competitors if they share a
common geographic border. In the case of New Hampshire, for instance,
Massachusetts, Maine, and Vermont would be considered competitors,
whereas Alabama would not. Each neighboring state would be given equal
weight, as they are assumed to exert equal influence. It is common for
weights to be row-standardized, meaning that the weights sum up to one.
Continuing with the New Hampshire example, Massachusetts, Vermont, and
Maine would each be given a weight of 1/3, whereas Alabama would be
assigned a weight of zero.
In this example, it may be the case that Massachusetts wields more
influence on New Hampshire than Maine, as it has a larger population.
Thus, we create a second set of geographic weights known as
population-contiguity weights. States must still share a common
geographic border to be considered a competitor, but now the weight
varies on the basis of population. To create the weight for
Massachusetts, the population of Massachusetts would be divided by the
entire bordering population (i.e., the population of Massachusetts,
Vermont, and Maine). Note that in this case the weights are row
standardized. A non-row-standardized weight for Massachusetts in this
case would be just its population.
Our other two measures are in line with the aforementioned quote
from The Gavel, which alluded to how states may consider the policies of
other states to which they are losing or gaining large numbers of
elderly individuals. Thus, we construct two other sets of weights,
referred to as flow and corridor, which are based on historical elderly
migration flows using 1965 70 migration flow data from the 1970 PUMS.
State j will be considered a flow competitor of state i should it be the
case that there are elderly migrants moving from state j to state i,
that is, state i is receiving elderly migrants from state j. Given that
most interstate elderly movement is across borders, this measure will
still be heavily based on geography, but this measure allows us to also
account for Michigan-Florida or Michigan-New York competition as well.
Similar to the way the population-contiguity weights are created, the
flow weight for state i (with state j) is simply the total elderly
immigrants into state i that originated from state j divided by all the
elderly in-migrants into state i, regardless of state of origin. Thus,
if 30% of New York's elderly in-migrants came from Connecticut,
Connecticut would be assigned a weight of 0.3 in being defined as one of
New York's competitors.
States may also be concerned about losing their elderly residents,
however, as evidenced by The Gavel quote. Our preferred and final
measure is therefore one that captures the entire corridor of migrants
between the two states--that is, the number of elderly individuals who
are moving between the two states. State j is a corridor competitor of
state i should it be the case that state j is either sending or
receiving elderly migrants to/from state i. This measure assumes that a
state views itself as competing with another state if it is either
losing elderly individuals to it or luring them from it. Note that any
states that were flow competitors are automatically corridor
competitors, although the weight will differ. The weights are calculated
similar to the flow weights, with the exception that the weight is based
on the percentage of the total corridor a state accounts for, rather
than the percentage of the total flow. This will place a greater weight
on those states for which there is a relatively large amount of movement
of the elderly, regardless of direct. (15)
In constructing the flow and corridor weights, we use historical
migration flow data from 1965-70 to avoid endogeneity. State actions to
eliminate EIG taxes may affect elderly migration patterns; indeed, one
hypothesis maintains that it is the goal of these actions. We therefore
use the same weights for the entire period the data cover. One
alternative is to update the measure every 10 years as it becomes
available through the census. However, this would lead to discrete
changes at 10-year intervals, some of which may be due to sampling error
as the flow estimates are based on a sample of the total population. We
can also take comfort in the fact that primary elderly migration
patterns, especially corridors, have changed fairly slowly over time.
(16) Finally, it is important to note that because of the prevalence of
border moves, all four measures place some weight on geographic
neighbors. The latter two measures augment geography by taking account
of movements beyond the bordering states and are based on what we
hypothesize the states are competing over.
Choice of Variables
The means of our dependent and explanatory variables are listed in
Appendix Table A. 1. Although imperfect, we believe that state EIG tax
revenues are the best summary measure of a state's approach to EIG
taxation. It should capture all of the deliberate changes that a state
makes to its EIG tax laws and distill them into a measure that the state
itself should care about: the revenues produced. It is also a measure
that is easy for taxpayers to understand. In addition, although state
EIG tax revenues are going to be affected by the levels and types of
individual wealth, the richness of the data allows us to control for
these confounding effects with state and time fixed effects, as well as
our explanatory variables.
Our primary measure of state EIG tax policy, T in equations (1) and
(2), is the tax share measure, calculated by dividing state EIG tax
revenues by overall state tax revenues. Taxpayers and policy makers
should be considering the entire tax structure of the state when making
their decisions, and this measure allows for that. Furthermore, it is
not confounded by the size of the public sector. In our sensitivity
analyses, we consider several alternative measures, including per capita
state EIG taxes and state EIG taxes per death. One might argue that
taxpayers would use these measures as a best guess of their approximate
burden from the tax; however, we argue that they suffer from being an
absolute rather than relative measure. (17) Other possible measures
include marginal or average tax rates for a certain size estate;
however, as the discussion in section III reveals, a state's EIG
tax system has many components beyond the tax rate for a given estate,
and so such a measure also suffers from being incomplete. Rather, as one
of our sensitivity checks we construct a pseudo-average tax rate using
information about total federal gross estates in each state, which is
available for a small number of years.
To isolate evidence of tax competition, we must include any other
economic or political factors that we believe might affect a
state's EIG policy over time, written as X in equations (1) and
(2); however, we must also include any variables that help capture
variation in our EIG tax reliance measure (T) that is not due to
deliberate state EIG policy, such as a change in the number and size of
the estates in the state. One variable that belongs for both reasons is
the per capita income in the state. A wealthier state may choose a
different EIG policy both for economic and political reasons, but it is
also more likely to have a greater number of large estates, which will
generate larger EIG revenues, regardless of the state's actual EIG
policy. Per capita income also helps control for the tendency of states
that have experienced the most in-migration (from all age groups) to
also have high growth in income. Another variable with dual roles is the
percentage of the population that is over age 65 and over age 85. We
include both over 85 and over 65 because we hypothesize that the two age
groups exert different sorts of pressures. The younger elderly may be a
more politically active group than the older elderly, and there is
evidence that their migration decisions are more sensitive to state
fiscal policies (Conway and Houtenville 2003). The size of the older
elderly population is more likely to approximate for the potential tax
base; however, both variables may have confounding effects on state EIG
revenues because they may capture both political pressures and the tax
base.
To capture the state's fiscal situation (and thus the ability
to reduce EIG taxes), we include the per capita federal transfers
received by the state, the state debt per capita, and the unemployment
rate. (18) The political environment is reflected by whether it is an
election year, and dummy variables for whether both houses and the
governor are Democratic or Republican.
We also include the percent of state tax revenue that is raised
through personal income taxes and, separately, sales taxes. These
variables capture the availability of other sources of revenue, and so a
strong presence of these taxes may make it easier to eliminate EIG
taxes. In addition, potential elderly migrants likely consider the
entire tax climate of the state in the decisions to move, and there is
some evidence that they are discouraged by an income tax (Cebula 1990).
Thus, a state with a heavy income or sales tax burden may feel more
pressure to reduce their EIG taxes to compete for wealthy elderly
migrants. However, one might argue that states make decisions about all
of their tax policies simultaneously, so that including these two
alternative tax sources could lead to bias. We first address this by
including the previous year's values for these taxes in all
specifications. In addition, as a robustness check, we explore the
impact of excluding these variables from the model.
Finally, we include state and year fixed effects in all
specifications. The state effects should capture any unobserved state
characteristics that are stable over time and would subsume any regional
effects. The year effects control for changes in the federal tax code
that may influence a state's decision; they also help capture
business cycle effects, although not perfectly because states may be
affected differently. However, including the state unemployment rate
should help capture these differences.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Our main model therefore includes the aforementioned explanatory
variables plus state and time fixed effects, uses four different
weighting schemes and our tax share measure of state EIG tax policy, and
uses annual data from 1967 to 1999. However, as will be discussed
further, we subject this baseline model to several model specification
checks. These checks include excluding the income and sales tax
variables, using alternative measures of state EIG reliance, taking
account of the fact that the states' ability to tinker with their
EIG taxes has decreased over time because many now have only the pick-up
tax, and using a random weighting scheme to explore whether our model is
picking up only spurious correlation rather than state competition.
Main Model Results
Table 2 shows the results for the revenue share using the four
different weighting schemes and annual data from 1968-99. Recall that
all models include state and time fixed effects to help control for
unobservables. For our key variable, the competitors' EIG tax
reliance, the results are unequivocal; there is a substantial,
statistically significant effect of the EIG tax reliance of competitor
states, no matter how we choose to define competitors. Furthermore, the
strength of this competition grows as our definition of competitor
expands to include elderly migration patterns. The size of the effect is
striking as well. Our estimates suggest that a 10% decrease in the EIG
tax share of a competitor leads to between a 2.2% to 4.3% decrease in
the state's own EIG tax share. These estimates are consistent with
what has been found in the literature for other taxes with mobile tax
bases. (19) Our empirical results therefore strongly suggest that states
are paying attention to what their competitors are doing when they
devise their EIG tax policy.
The other variables are also fairly stable across the different
definitions of competitor. We find that personal income taxes are very
important, suggesting that a heavy reliance on income taxes either
enables or puts pressure on the state to rely less on EIG taxes. It
appears as if states are avoiding having their constituents undergo
double jeopardy in terms of wealth taxation. Sales taxes, on the other
hand, do not appear important to a state's reliance on EIG
taxation. The impact of having an older population leads to an increase
in our EIG reliance measure. This is not surprising given that the
elderly are the most likely group to be leaving an estate; as discussed
earlier, these variables play dual roles making interpretation
difficult. We return to this issue when we discuss our alternative
specifications. The only other variable that has a significant influence
is the unemployment rate, which has a positive effect on a state's
reliance on EIG taxes.
Robustness Checks
Next we subject our baseline model to several robustness checks,
the key results of which are summarized in Table 3. (20) First, we
explore the impact of excluding the states' (lagged) reliance on
personal income and sales taxes. The resulting estimated
competitors' E1G tax reliance coefficients are reported in the
second row of Table 3. Excluding these two variables has little impact
on the results except to slightly decrease the magnitude of the effect.
The other variables' coefficients (not reported) are likewise
unaffected. For this reason and because personal income taxes are
statistically significant, we continue to include these two variables in
the rest of the analysis.
Second, we explore several alternative measures of EIG tax reliance
to make sure that our results are robust to our choice of measure. The
first two measures use an absolute rather than relative measure of the
EIG tax burden. One could argue that the EIG share of state tax revenue,
our main measure, could fluctuate because of changes to other sources of
revenue--which could have little to do with tax competition. We
therefore use, alternately, EIG taxes per capita and EIG taxes per
death. The competitors' tax reliance coefficients are reported in
the third and fourth lines of Table 3. In general, using either of these
measures instead of the state EIG tax share yields similar results and
even stronger evidence of interstate EIG tax competition. The estimated
competitors' tax reliance coefficients increase in magnitude and
range from 0.38 to 0.64. Most of the other coefficients also behave
similarly across the two measures with a couple of exceptions. Personal
income taxation appears less important and now has a positive effect,
although it is not statistically significant. This is likely due to our
now using an absolute measure. More important is that using EIG taxes
per death diminishes the effect of having a very old population (percent
over 85 years old). This lends additional support to our argument that
including the age variables is capturing the fact that a larger elderly
population is going to generate more EIG tax revenue. When one redefines
to be EIG per death, this relationship is understandably weakened, as
expected.
However, even these measures could fluctuate for reasons other than
tax competition. Although including the percent of the population over
age 65 and over age 85 helps control for the fact that states with big
elderly populations will generate more EIG tax revenues, they do not
capture the differences within the elderly. The rich elderly generate
most of the EIG tax revenues, and the percentage of the elderly that are
rich may vary a great deal from state to state. They may also react to
state EIG tax policy so that reverse causality may exist. (Low
competitors' EIG tax reliance may lure the rich elderly and erode the tax base, making the state's reliance also appear lower.)
Likewise, asset values and wealth accumulation behaviors may vary across
states and over time--and perhaps be influenced by state EIG tax policy.
Our third measure seeks to address all of these issues by using
information about the aggregate value of gross estates reported on
federal estate tax returns. (21) This variable should capture the
geographic and temporal differences in the wealth of the elderly
residing in the state, as well as any random variation in the types of
people who die in a given year (e.g., a billionaire dies in a small
state). Unfortunately, however, this variable is only available for a
limited number of years--1970, 1977, 1983, 1986, 1987, 1990, 1993, and
1998. As noted in section III, the bulk of reductions in state EIG taxes
came in the early years of our sample, which makes the missing early
years of this data especially troubling. Given the volatile nature of
the data and the large number of holes in the data, we believe we must
drop the missing years from this particular analysis, which reduces our
sample size by approximately 75%. For this reason, we use this
information as a sensitivity check rather than include it in our main
specification.
Using this information we construct our third alternative measure,
which redefines state EIG tax reliance to be total state EIG tax
revenues divided by the aggregate value of gross estates reported on
federal estate tax returns. This measure can be viewed as roughly
approximating an average tax rate on estates. As the federal estate tax
exempts small estates, this measure will be larger in a state if it (1)
taxes small estates not subject to federal taxation, and/or (2) levies
high taxes on those estates subject to federal taxation. The results of
this exercise are reported in the fifth line of Table 3. Again, the
results are quite similar to our main specification and our other
exercises. The estimated magnitude of tax competition is quite similar
and tends to be even larger than in our baseline model, especially when
migration-based weights are used. The statistical significance of these
coefficients is diminished somewhat, which is not surprising given the
much smaller number of observations and the loss of so many of the early
years of apparent EIG tax competition. The other coefficients are
affected in a manner similar to when we use per capita or per death
measures in that personal income taxes are no longer important. This
specification, however, completely eliminates the effects of having an
elderly population on EIG revenues, further suggesting that the positive
effects found in our baseline model are due to a larger EIG tax base.
(22)
A related issue is that EIG taxes have the potential to be
extremely volatile--for example, the death of one billionaire in a small
state can greatly skew the numbers for that year. To make sure that such
volatility is not driving our results and to smooth out the volatility,
we reestimate the model using three-year moving averages of all of the
variables to see if there is a difference. (23) The key results for this
exercise are reported in the sixth row of Table 3. Here we see that the
estimated degree of interstate tax competition grows, if anything, when
moving averages are used. The other variable coefficients are similar
with the two interesting exceptions that per capita federal transfers
and election year, which were both negative before, are now also
statistically significant. Therefore, our evidence of interstate EIG tax
competition is not due to random volatility in EIG tax revenues and
appears to be quite robust to alternative measures of EIG tax reliance.
Our next set of exercises recognizes that once a state abolishes
its EIG tax and relies solely on the pick-up tax, it has also greatly
reduced its ability to further tinker with its EIG tax policy. Rather,
its revenues are completely determined by the federal estate tax code
and the estates of its taxpayers. Because the number of pick-up states
grew steadily during the period our sample covers, one would expect to
see a weakening of interstate tax competition--evidenced by a shrinking
competitors' EIG tax reliance coefficient--over time. This presents
an interesting opportunity to test the validity of our results and
perhaps dispel the concern that we are simply picking up spurious correlations in state EIG tax revenues. To accomplish this, we split our
sample into the 1970s, the 1980s and the 1990s and then reestimate the
model for each time period. (24)
The next three rows of Table 3 report the estimated
competitors' EIG tax coefficients for each of the four weights
across the three time periods. Immediately evident is how our estimates
of the degree of interstate tax competition steadily decline over time.
In the 1970s, the response is always statistically significant and
ranges from 0.42 to 0.93, the latter of which is about double the
response found for other taxes (see note 19). In the 1980s, the response
is smaller (ranging from 0.22 to 0.371) but still significant. In the
1990s, however, the response is either zero or even negative. We are
somewhat puzzled by the negative response that appears with our
migration-based weights for the 1990s. Given that there is a fairly
small number of states who can still compete during this period (25 at
the beginning and 17 by the end of the 1990s), it is not clear what this
measure is capturing, especially for the majority of states in the
sample who had little control over their state tax revenues. If it is a
measure of the underlying spurious correlation between state tax
revenues, then it makes the strong, positive responses we find in the
rest of the analysis all the more remarkable. More generally, the
explanatory power of the model (as measured by the [R.sup.2] and the
joint significance of the explanatory variables other than the year and
state effects) steadily declines as one moves from the early years to
the later years. This combined with the dramatic fall in the estimated
responses over time is further support for our interpretation of these
effects as interstate tax competition.
Another way to explore the issue is to allow the competitors'
tax reliance coefficient to vary between pick-up and non-pick-up states.
Because pick-up states no longer have any way to compete, we would
expect their competitors' reliance coefficients to be zero. We
accomplish this by adding an interaction term--whether a state is a
pick-up state in the prior year multiplied by the competitors' tax
reliance variable--which we also treat as endogenous. If our hypothesis
is correct, then the coefficient on the interaction term should be of
approximately equal magnitude and opposite sign, so that the sum is
zero. We perform a t-test of this restriction--that is, whether the
competitors' reliance coefficient for pick-up states (which is the
sum of the main coefficient and the interaction term) is zero. Given
that the majority of the tests are supportive, we also reestimate the
model imposing this restriction by interacting a nonpick-up dummy
variable with the competitors' tax reliance variable.
The results of these exercises are reported in the tenth through
twelfth lines of Table 3. In the first exercise, strong evidence of our
hypothesis exists as the coefficients on the interaction term are always
negative, statistically significant, and of near equal magnitude as the
primary coefficient. Furthermore, in three out of four cases we fail to
reject the hypothesis that they sum to zero, suggesting that the effect
of competitors' EIG reliance is zero for pick-up states. (In the
fourth case, it is negative rather than positive suggesting that any
spurious correlation is negative, if anything, and is working against
evidence of tax competition.) Imposing this restriction typically leads
to the estimated magnitude of tax competition to increase over our
baseline model. Dealing with pick-up states in this way therefore
strengthens our evidence of state EIG tax competition.
Our last robustness check attempts to verify that we are indeed
capturing state tax competition and not spurious correlation or simply
the random spread of a good idea (although the latter should be captured
with our time dummies). Following Case et al. (1993), we reestimate our
model using weights based on the alphabetical order of the states, which
clearly should have nothing to do with competitive forces. Specifically,
two states are defined as neighbors or competitors if they are adjacent
to each other alphabetically (e.g., Arizona has Alabama and Arkansas for
competitors; Alabama has Wyoming and Arizona for competitors). The
estimated competitors' EIG tax coefficient from this exercise is
reported at the bottom of Table 3. Using these nonsensical weights
completely eliminates any evidence of competition, both in terms of
magnitude and statistical significance, and confirms that our other
analyses are not simply picking up spurious correlation among the
states.
Our spatial analysis of state EIG tax reliance, then, provides
strong evidence that interstate EIG tax competition has been quite
intense over the past 30 years, especially in the earlier part of the
period when most states had not yet finished their race to the bottom.
The strength of this competitive response grows when we use a definition
of competitor that goes beyond simple geography. It is also robust to
using alternative measures of state EIG tax policy and to different
treatments of the pick-up tax phenomena. Perhaps the most compelling
evidence that states are competing in the EIG tax arena, however, is
revealed with a quick look at what the states are doing now.
VI. THE RENCARNATION OF STATE DEATH TAXES?
Are state EIG taxes really dead? Apparently not. The federal tax
cut package adopted in June 2001 is phasing out and will eventually
eliminate the federal estate tax. This change will effectively eliminate
the pick-up tax revenues for the states. It also reduces revenues for
those states that have not eliminated their EIG taxes because they still
take advantage of the pick-up tax. Specifically, the pick-up tax credit
for state estate taxes paid will be reduced by 25% each year beginning
in 2002 and is eliminated completely by 2005. The revenue consequences
for the states is substantial; McNichol et al. (2003) report that states
would have received approximately $6 billion from the tax credit in
fiscal year 2003 alone had the law not changed. How are the states
reacting to the change? As it turns out, many states are now effectively
bringing their death taxes back to life.
As documented thoroughly in McNichol et al. (2003), states have the
option of decoupling from the federal estate tax to preserve these tax
revenues. Decoupling requires either changing (or, interestingly enough,
failing to change) state law so that the automatic connection between
the state estate tax credit in the federal code and the amount of state
estate taxes owed is broken. In some states, state law references the
federal estate tax law as of a specific date. For these states, all that
is required to decouple is failing to update that date. For others,
state law makes no reference to a specific date and so a state must
initiate changes to its law to preserve their EIG tax revenues. For
example, Rhode Island decoupled in this way during its 2001 legislative
session by setting the state's estate tax equal to the amount of
the federal credit as determined by IRS code as of 1 January 2001.
Wisconsin acted similarly. Of course, states could also decouple by
enacting a new, separate estate or inheritance tax. In all cases,
however, the state EIG tax liability net of the federal tax credit will
increase as a result.
According to an August 7 report by McNichol (2003), 12 states have
taken action to decouple, and another 6 plus the District of Columbia will remain decoupled unless they take action. Figure 3 displays on a
map these 18 states and also shows which states have or have not
eliminated their EIG taxes in favor of the pick-up tax. (25) A strong
geographic pattern is immediately obvious, especially along the Eastern
seaboard, where the line of decoupling is virtually unbroken (except for
New Hampshire, Connecticut, and Delaware) from Maine to North Carolina.
Likewise, there are geographic clusters in other parts of the country
(e.g., Washington-Oregon and Minnesota-Wisconsin-Illinois). When states
that still have EIG taxes are included, one sees an even stronger
geographic pattern to state EIG taxation. The Eastern seaboard,
Mid-Atlantic, and Midwest are much more likely to impose a state EIG
tax--either by continuing to retain their tax, decoupling from the
federal law, or both. In contrast, the Deep South, Southwest, and
Mountain states are so far completely devoid of decoupling, and all have
eliminated their EIG taxes. It therefore appears that a state is more
likely to have decoupled if its geographic neighbors also have decoupled
or still have a EIG tax, which is compelling evidence of interstate
competition. Three states with a long history of no EIG taxes--Alabama,
Florida, and Nevada, two of which are heavy net importers of the
elderly--would likely need to alter constitutional provisions on the
amount of estate taxes levied (McNichol 2003). California would require
a vote of the people.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
What this illustrates is that state EIG tax policy is still very
much in flux. States appear to be paying attention to one another, or at
the very least are behaving in geographic clusters. It has taken 25
years for 30 states to completely eliminate state EIG taxes in favor of
the pick-up tax (and many other states have likewise reduced their taxes
during the period). In contrast, within the past two years, 18 states,
13 of which had eliminated their EIG taxes, have effectively increased
their EIG taxes in response to the threat of losing their pick-up tax
revenues. Why this sudden reversal in state EIG tax policy? A possible
political explanation is that decoupling is a very subtle and largely
invisible way of increasing a tax. However, a recent article in the
Boston Globe suggests the contrary with its quote from estate planning attorney, Stephen Ziobrowski, "You don't see much advice
suggesting people leave Massachusetts any more, but maybe attorneys will
just re-draft those old letters and suggest that their clients move to
Florida.... That's where people used to go to avoid
Massachusetts's estate tax, and it may be what they start doing
again." (26) Perhaps it is the current economic downturn that is
forcing states to take any actions possible to retain and build up their
tax revenues. It might even be a combination of factors--the reductions
in EIG taxes have not produced the results (in either migration or other
behavioral responses) that states had hoped for, and this presents a
perfect opportunity to bring the tax back at a small political cost and
a large fiscal benefit. In any case, it appears that the state EIG tax
revolution is far from over.
VII. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This research takes a close look at what has happened to state
death or EIG taxes over the past 30 years. We note that more than 30
states have eliminated their EIG taxes (instead relying only on the
pick-up tax) since 1976 and that there have been many other state policy
changes that likewise reduce their burden. Yet this unique arena of
potential interstate tax competition with a potentially mobile group of
affluent elderly as the prize has gone largely unexplored. We
investigate this phenomena by first exploring in a descriptive way the
historical patterns of EIG tax elimination and reduction. This analysis
reveals the complexity of the EIG itself and the difficulty of measuring
efforts to eliminate or reduce it in a specific way. We then perform a
spatial empirical analysis of the state's overall reliance on EIG
taxes, and in so doing extend the usual definition of competitors beyond
geography by using historical information on elderly migration patterns,
as presumably states should be watching the policies of states to which
they are losing (or from which they are gaining) their tax base--the
elderly. Our results provide very strong evidence of interstate tax
competition, and the intensity of the competition grows as our
migration-based definitions of competitors are used and the time period
is limited to an era in which states had maximum ability to change their
policies.
Now the movement to reduce or eliminate EIG taxes has reached the
federal government as well. Interestingly, the movement at the federal
level appears to be inspiring the states to effectively bring back their
EIG taxes through decoupling, and those actions have been swift and
geographically clustered. The decoupling movement is too recent and
ongoing for us to thoroughly examine its causes, but the emerging
pattern provides additional, compelling evidence that interstate tax
competition is once again playing a role.
What happens in the state EIG tax arena in the coming months and
years is quite relevant for researchers interested in either state tax
competition or the effects of estate taxation. The current movement to
decouple is remarkable as one would expect a movement to increase taxes
to be much slower than the usual race to the bottom, yet the opposite is
true here. Simply tracing out this movement to its logical conclusion
will likely yield important insights into the nature of state policy
competition and the politics of increasing taxes. As the federal estate
tax is gradually eliminated, state EIG taxes will be the only remaining
taxes on bequests. Looking backward, one can see that there has been a
great many changes to these taxes. These changes provide a multitude of
natural experiments with which researchers can study the consequences of
EIG taxation on individual behaviors and state budgets and thereby draw
inferences about optimal EIG tax policy. Looking forward, one sees a
state tax policy that is still very much in flux and still apparently
subject to the forces of state policy competition.
TABLE 1
Chronology of State Actions to Eliminate Their EIG Taxes
Year State Date (If Tied)
1976 New Mexico
1977 Utah
1978
1979 North Dakota
1980 Arizona, Colorado, Vermont, Virginia 1 January
1981 Missouri
1982 Washington 1 January
California 1 July
1983 Illinois, Wyoming 1 January
Texas 1 September
1984
1985 West Virginia
1986 Minnesota 1 January
Maine 1 July
1987 Oregon
1988 Idaho
1989
1990
1991 Rhode Island
1992 South Carolina, Wisconsin 1 January
1993 Michigan
1994
1995
1996
1997 Massachusetts
1998 Kansas
1999 Delaware, North Carolina 1 January
2000 Mississippi 1 January
New York 31 January
2001 Montana 1 January
South Dakota 1 July
2002
2003 New Hampshire
States with Elimination Upcoming: Lousiana (2004),
Connecticut (2005)
States that Still Have EIG Taxes: Indiana, Iowa, Kentucky,
Maryland, Nebraska, New
Jersey, Ohio, Oklahoma,
Pennsylvania, Tennessee
States that Eliminated Prior to 1976: Alabama, Arkansas,
Florida, Georgia, Nevada
Notes: Effective June 2002, Kansas reenacted a succession tax, which is
an inheritance tax exempting spouses, siblings, lineal ancestors, and
lineal descendants.
TABLE 2
Spatial 2SLS Results for State EIG Tax Reliance
(1) (2) (3)
Weight Measure Contiguity Population Flow
Independent variable
Competitors' EIG tax 0.28936 *** 0.22137 *** 0.42688 ***
reliance (0.01615) (0.04837) (0.07032)
Last year's measure of 0.00037 0.00075 0.00217
sales taxation (0.00400) (0.00420) (0.00392)
Last year's measure of -0.01535 *** -0.01661 *** -0.01743 ***
personal income taxation (0.00429) (0.00431) (0.00400)
Percent of population 85 0.40586 ** 0.40288 ** 0.39632 **
years or older (0.18207) (0.19311) (0.18894)
Percent of population 65 0.07495 ** 0.07535 ** 0.06799 *
years or older (0.03457) (0.03376) (0.03603)
State per capita income -0.00002 -0.00002 -0.00003
(in 1000s) (0.00017) (0.00024) (0.00021)
State per capita federal -0.00320 -0.00330 -0.00304
transfers (0.00258) (0.00277) (0.00272)
State per capita debt -0.00016 -0.00028 -0.00033
(0.00056) (0.00063) (0.00065)
State unemployment rate 0.00049 *** 0.00050 *** 0.00052 ***
(0.00011) (0.00011) (0.00011)
Same party-Democrat -0.00008 -0.00010 -0.00007
(0.00037) (0.00037) (0.00038)
Same party-Republican 0.00006 0.00005 0.00018
(0.00048) (0.00053) (0.00052)
Election year dummy -0.00055 -0.00052 -0.00052
(Yes = 1) (0.00033) (0.00033) (0.00033)
Constant -0.00473 -0.00283 -0.00610
(0.01088) (0.01229) (0.01214)
(4)
Weight Measure Corridor
Independent variable
Competitors' EIG tax 0.38913 ***
reliance (0.08743)
Last year's measure of 0.00109
sales taxation (0.00410)
Last year's measure of -0.01897 ***
personal income taxation (0.00446)
Percent of population 85 0.39058 **
years or older (0.18583)
Percent of population 65 0.06623 *
years or older (0.03662)
State per capita income -0.00003
(in 1000s) (0.00027)
State per capita federal -0.00345
transfers (0.00284)
State per capita debt -0.00035
(0.00069)
State unemployment rate 0.00055 ***
(0.00012)
Same party-Democrat -0.00014
(0.00041)
Same party-Republican 0.00326
(0.00048)
Election year dummy -0.00053
(Yes = 1) (0.00034)
Constant -0.00504
(0.01225)
Notes: All regressions included state and year fixed effects.
Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. *** significant at the
99% level, ** significant at the 95% level, and * significant at the
90% level.
TABLE 3
Sensitivity Checks on the Coefficient for Competitors' EIG Tax Reliance
(1) (2) (3)
Weight Measure Contiguity Population Flow
Baseline model--tax 0.28936 *** 0.22137 *** 0.42688 ***
share (Table 2) (0.01615) (0.04837) (0.07032)
Without alternative 0.28357 *** 0.19331 *** 0.35814 ***
tax measures (0.06095) (0.04978) (0.07563)
Changes in measuring
dependent variable
Per capita EIG tax 0.40168 *** 0.40697 *** 0.53736 ***
revenue (0.13266) (0.09947) (0.13424)
Per death EIG tax 0.38120 *** 0.40427 *** 0.53872 ***
revenue (0.14056) (0.11029) (0.14881)
EIG revenues/total 0.28530 * 0.31532 ** 0.61368 **
estate value (0.17465) (0.13782) (0.26588)
3-year average of EIG 0.33053 *** 0.23850 *** 0.46353 ***
revenues (0.06246) (0.04440) (0.06255)
Changes in time period
Just 1970s 0.46708 *** 0.42693 *** 0.90656 ***
(0.09616) (0.09759) (0.16749)
Just 1980s 0.23942 * 0.22046 *** 0.31516 ***
(0.12770) (0.07506) (0.10975)
Just 1990S -0.09770 -0.27369 ** -0.65466 ***
(0.09991) (0.11323) (0.23625)
Treating pick-up states
differently
Competitors' effect 0.37698 ** 0.26909 *** 0.43395 ***
(0.05637) (0.04728) (0.07000)
Competitors' effect -0.35977 *** -0.40514 *** -0.37274 ***
interacted with pick-up (0.02894) (0.02989) (0.02898)
dummy
Impose zero restriction 0.36409 *** 0.35322 *** 0.38409 ***
on pick-up states (0.02858) (0.02856) (0.02847)
Using random 0.02199
(alphabetical) weights (0.03234)
(4)
Weight Measure Corridor
Baseline model--tax 0.38913 ***
share (Table 2) (0.08743)
Without alternative 0.26349 ***
tax measures (0.08158)
Changes in measuring
dependent variable
Per capita EIG tax 0.63528 ***
revenue (0.14618)
Per death EIG tax 0.63825 ***
revenue (0.17937)
EIG revenues/total 0.50566 *
estate value (0.27013)
3-year average of EIG 0.45245 ***
revenues (0.07727)
Changes in time period
Just 1970s 0.92801 ***
(0.20476)
Just 1980s 0.37085 ***
(0.12437)
Just 1990S -0.80789 ***
(0.28767)
Treating pick-up states
differently
Competitors' effect 0.39871 ***
(0.08614)
Competitors' effect -0.39857 ***
interacted with pick-up (0.03049)
dummy
Impose zero restriction 0.39859 ***
on pick-up states (0.02849)
Note: All regressions included state and year fixed effects.
Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. *** significant at the
99% level, ** significant at the 95% level, and * significant at the
90% level.
ABBREVIATIONS
EIG: Estate, Inheritance, and Gift OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
PUMS: Public Use Microdata Samples TRA: Tax Reform Act
* We thank Deniz Arslan, Stephen Fink, and Liping Zheng for their
able research assistance; the numerous state officials who helped
provide the necessary data; Meg Stewart for help creating our maps; and
Jan Brueckner, Jim Hines, Robert Mohr, Jon Skinner, and two anonymous
referees for helpful comments. This research has also benefited from the
comments received at the National Tax Association Meetings, the Winter
Meetings of the Econometric Society, Eastern Economic Association
Meetings, and the UNH Economics Seminar.
(1.) See the work of Gale and Slemrod (2000), Poterba (2001), and
the articles in Gale et al. (2001).
(2.) The pick-up tax, sometimes referred to as the soak-up tax or
gap tax, arises from federal tax law whereby state EIG taxes are
credited dollar for dollar against the federal estate tax liability
owed, up to a certain amount. The state therefore picks up some of the
federal estate tax revenue without increasing the total tax liability.
All states take advantage of this tax credit. We use the term EIG taxes
throughout to denote any estate, inheritance, or gift tax rather than
using the cumbersome label "estate, inheritance, and gift" or
politically charged "death". Five states eliminated their EIG
taxes prior to 1960 or never had them.
3. Rather, most emphasize only the federal estate tax. Four notable
exceptions are Page (2003), Bakija et al. (2003), and Joulfaian
(2000a,b), which we discuss shortly. Only Bakija et al. (2003) take
advantage of the temporal variation in state EIG tax policy.
(4.) Beyond taxation, neighboring jurisdictions have also been
found to influence the adoptions of lotteries (Alm et al. 1993), tax
abatements (Anderson and Wassmer 1995), growth controls (Brueckner
1998), and environmental regulations (Fredriksson and Millimet 2002).
(5.) For further discussion of the history and specifics of state
death taxes, see Eckl (1986).
(6.) It is interesting to note that federal estate/inheritance
taxes had been enacted and subsequently repealed several times prior to
1916, often to support a war. See Gale and Slemrod (2000) and Joulfaian
(2000c) for a brief history and thorough discussion of the workings of
the federal estate tax.
(7.) There are obvious limitations to this measure. A preferable
measure might be the date that the law was proposed or was voted on.
However, the fact that laws must pass various legislative bodies and the
governor makes this difficult. In addition, the fact that many states
have phased their laws in slowly suggests that the effective date may
have been an important part of the decision.
8. We thank Jim Hines for first pointing out how strong this
relationship is.
(9.) Note that we are limiting our discussion--and our analyses to
the continental48 states. It is a common practice to exclude Alaska and
Hawaii from studies of state policies because they have no geographic
neighbors and are different in many respects from the other 48 states.
(10.) Two types of tables are often reported in these documents.
One summarizes major state tax changes in 19--, and the other reports
the exemptions, credits, and rates for state estate and inheritance
taxes and includes notes that document changes (and the dates) to these
policies. This information is not reported in a consistent way every
year during the period, so our summary of it should not be viewed as a
complete accounting of events. In addition, the reports end in 1994
because of the elimination of the Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR).
(11.) This lead to accelerated collections of the estate tax, from
80% to 90% of estimated payments, and the gift tax from no estimated
payments to 90% of estimated payments, according to Significant Features
of Fiscal Federalism, volume 1, 1992, Table 17.
(12.) In chronological order, Connecticut placed a 10% surcharge on
inheritance taxes in 1983, followed by New York, who allowed unlimited
deductions for spouses. In 1985, Connecticut raised inheritance tax
exemptions, and New Jersey also reduced its inheritance tax. In 1986
Connecticut began phasing out its inheritance tax on spouses. In 1987,
Rhode Island began phasing out its estate tax altogether, and New Jersey
exempted spouses effective 1 July 1988. In 1990, Connecticut, New York,
and Rhode Island all accelerated the collection of tax payments, and New
York expanded the tax base to include out-of state property. For North
Carolina, South Carolina, and Tennessee, for example, in 1987 alone
South Carolina began phasing out the estate tax (completed by 7/1/91),
North Carolina increased its inheritance tax credits, and Tennessee
increased exemptions for two types of beneficiaries.
(13.) Population breakdowns by state for the 85+ category were
first reported in 1980. For years prior, the number was estimated based
on (1) the difference in overall population growth between the state and
the nation, (2) the difference in population growth for the 65+ group
between the state and the nation, and (3) the difference between the
growth rate of each state for 1980-99 in the 65+ and 85+ categories. The
exact algorithm is available on request.
(14.) Note that an alternative approach is to invert the system and
estimate via maximum likelihood. However, should spatial error
dependence also be present, maximum likelihood may provide false
evidence of strategic interaction. (see Brueckner 2003 for a
discussion). Although results remain unchanged using maximum likelihood,
in the article we present the instrumental variable technique because it
has been shown (Kelejian and Prucha 1998) to yield consistent estimates,
even in the presence of spatial error dependence.
(15.) In creating the flow and corridor weights, we also tried
limiting ourselves to high-income elderly migrants (those with annual
income of more than $25,000 in 1970) but found that it made little
difference in the results.
(16.) See Conway and Houtenville (2003) for a discussion of the
trends they uncover contrasted with earlier studies, and Rogers and
Raymer (1999) for a descriptive analysis of the internal migration
behavior of the elderly since 1950.
(17.) For example, two states could have the same per capita or per
death state EIG tax revenues, but EIG taxes could be a much smaller
portion of the overall budget in one than the other if the size of their
public sectors differed. We believe that a taxpayer would treat the two
states differently for this reason. The per capita measure is also
somewhat confounded by swings in other population groups (recall that we
are controlling for the older age groups) because it is state tax
revenues divided by total population.
(18.) We define federal transfers and state debt in per capita
terms as opposed to their revenue share because we believe that is a
more accurate measure of a state's fiscal climate or income. For
example, a state that receives $500 per capita is being subsidized much
more heavily by the federal government and therefore should face fewer
fiscal pressures than a state receiving $250 per capita. The same is not
necessarily true for a comparison of tax shares because the variables
are confounded by the size of the public sectors; two states could
receive the same level of transfers per capita, but the one with the
smaller public sector would appear better off if the share were used. A
similar logic applies to state debt.
(19.) For example, Rork (2003) found a response rate of 4-6% for
cigarette taxation and Revelli (2001) found a response rate of 4-5% for
property taxation in the United Kingdom.
(20.) The full results from any of the estimated models discussed
in this section are available on request.
(21.) This information can be found in the Compendium of Federal
Estate Tax and Personal Wealth Studies, along with various issues of the
Statistics of Income Bulletin, published by the IRS Statistics of
Income.
(22.) An alternative way of using this information is to include it
as an explanatory variable. We reestimated our baseline model including
the aggregate value of gross estates and the per capita estate value,
alternatively. Neither variable is ever statistically significant and
the estimated competitors" tax reliance coefficients are quite
similar and grow in magnitude, if anything. The only substantial
difference was that the effect of having an elderly population was again
diminished.
(23.) We calculated these averages two ways. One takes the moving
average of the final variable--that is, tax share--whereas the other
takes the moving average of the numerator (state death taxes) and of the
denominator (total state tax revenues) separately and then calculates
the shares. The two methods yielded nearly identical results, so we
report the results from the first method, which we find more intuitive.
(24.) The results we report use annual data. However, using the
three-year moving averages did not substantively alter our results.
Likewise, we split the sample into four periods--1968-75, 1976-83,
1984-91, 1992-99--and then into two 15-year periods and find very
similar results.
(25.) The 12 states that took action to decouple (as classified by
McNichol 2003) are IL, ME, MD. MA, MN, NE, NJ, NC, PA, RI, VT, and WI.
The six states that will remain decoupled unless they take action are
KS, NY, OH, OR, VA, and WA, plus the District of Columbia. Oklahoma is
the only state that has no need to decouple because it has a separate
tax that is designed such that it does not suffer a loss from the
federal changes. Kansas is also an unusual case in that after
eliminating its inheritance taxes in 1998, it adopted a succession tax
effective 6 June 2002. A succession tax differs from an inheritance tax
in that it exempts spouses, siblings, lineal ancestors, and lineal
descendants from taxation.
(26.) "Residents Face Higher Estate Taxes," Boston Globe,
15 November 2002.
REFERENCES
Aim, J., M. McKee, and M. Skidmore. "Fiscal Pressure, Tax
Competition, and the Introduction of State Lotteries." National Tax
Journal, 46(4), 1993, 463-76.
Anderson, J., and R. Wassmer. "The Decision to 'Bid for
Business': Municipal Behavior in Granting Property Tax
Abatements." Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25(6), 1995,
727-38.
Auten, G., and D. Joulfaian. "Charitable Contributions and
Intergenerational Transfers." Journal of Public Economics, 59(1),
1996, 55-68.
--. "Bequest Taxes and Capital Gains Realizations."
Journal of Public Economics, 81(2), 2001, 213-29.
Baicker, K. "The Spillover Effects of State Spending."
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 8383, Cambridge,
MA, 2001.
Bakija, J., and J. Slemrod. "Evidence on the Impact of
Progressive State Taxes on the Locations and Estates of the Rich."
Mimeo, 2002.
Bakija, J., W. Gale, and J. Slemrod. "Charitable Bequests and
Taxes on Inheritances and Estates: Aggregate Evidence from across States
and Time." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 93(2),
2003, 366-70.
Besley, T., and A. Case. "Incumbent Behavior: Vote-Seeking,
Tax-Setting, and Yardstick Competition." American Economic Review,
85(1), 1995, 25-45.
Besley, T., and H. Rosen. "Vertical Externalities in Tax
Setting: Evidence from Gasoline and Cigarettes." Journal of Public
Economics, 70(3), 1998, 383-98.
Blumkin, T., and E. Sadka. "Estate Taxation with Intended and
Accidental Bequests." Journal of Public Economics, forthcoming.
Brueckner, J. "Testing for Strategic Interaction among Local
Governments: The Case of Growth Controls." Journal of Urban
Economics, 44(3), 1998, 438 67.
--. "Strategic Interaction among Governments: An Overview of
Empirical Studies." International Regional Science Review, 26(2),
2003, 175-88.
Brueckner, J., and L. Saavedra. "Do Local Governments Engage
in Strategic Property-Tax Competition?" National Tax Journal,
54(2), 2001, 203-29.
Buettner, T. "Local Business Taxation and Competition for
Capital: The Choice of the Tax Rate." Regional Science and Urban
Economics, 31 (2-3), 2001, 215-45.
Case, A. "Interstate Tax Competition after TRA86."
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 12(1), 1993, 136-48.
Case, A., J. Hines Jr., and H. Rosen. "Budget Spillovers and
Fiscal Policy Interdependence." Journal of Public Economics, 52(3),
1993, 285-307.
Cebula, R. "A Brief Empirical Note on the Tiebout Hypothesis
and State Income Tax Policies." Public Choice, 67(1), 1990, 87-89.
Conway, K. S., and A. Houtenville. "Elderly Migration and
State Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the 1990 Census Migration
Flows." National Tax Journal, 54(1), 2001, 103-23.
--. "Out with the Old, In with the Old: A Closer Look at
Younger versus Older Elderly Migration." Social Science Quarterly,
84(2), 2003, 309-28.
Dresher, K. "Local Public Finance and the Residential Location
Decisions of the Elderly." Ph.D. diss., University of Wisconsin,
1994.
Eckl, C. "Death Taxes," in Reforming State Tax Systems,
edited by S. Gold. Denver, CO: National Conference of State
Legislatures, 1986, 291-306.
Fredriksson, P., and D. Millimet. "Strategic Interaction and
the Determination of Environmental Policy across U.S. States."
Journal of Urban Economics, 51(1), 2002, 101-22.
Gale, W., and J. Slemrod. "Life and Death Questions about the
Estate and Gift Tax." National Tax Journal, 53(4,1), 2000, 889-912.
Gale, W., J. Hines Jr., and J. Slemrod. Rethinking Estate and Gift
Taxation. Washington: Brookings Institute, 2001.
Goodspeed, T. "Tax Structure in a Federation." Journal of
Public Economics, 75(3), 2000, 493-506.
--. "Tax Competition and Tax Structure in Open Federal
Economies: Evidence from OECD Countries with Implications for the
European Union." European Economic Review, 46(2), 2002, 357-74.
Heyndels, B., and J. Vuchelen. "Tax Mimicking among Belgian
Municipalities." National Tax Journal, 51(1), 1998, 89-101.
Joulfaian, D. "Choosing between Gifts and Bequests: How Taxes
Affect the Timing of Wealth Transfers." Office of Tax Analysis
Paper #86, 2000a.
--. "Estate Taxes and Charitable Bequests by the
Wealthy." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no.
7663, Cambridge, MA, 2000b.
--. "A Quarter Century of Estate Tax Reforms." National
Tax Journal, 53(3-1), 2000c, 343-60.
Kelejian, H., and 1. Prucha. "A Generalized Spatial Two-Stage
Least Squares Procedure for Estimating a Spatial Autoregressive Model
with Autoregressive Disturbances." Journal of Real Estate Finance
and Economies, 17(1), 1998, 99-121.
Kuehlwein, M. "The Non-Equalization of True Gift and Estate
Tax Rates." Journal of Public Economics, 53(2), 1994, 319-23.
Longino, C., and W. Crown. "The Migration of Old Money."
American Demographics, 11(10), 1989, 28-31.
McGarry, K. "The Cost of Equality: Unequal Bequests and Tax
Avoidance." Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), 2001, 179-204.
McNichol, E. "Many States Are Decoupling from the Federal
Estate Tax Cut." Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, revised 7
August 2003.
McNichol, E., I. Lav, and D. Tenny. "States Can Retain their
Estate Taxes even as the Federal Estate Tax Is Phased Out." Center
on Budget and Policy Priorities, revised 4 February 2003.
Page, B. "Bequest Taxes, Inter Vivos Gifts and the Bequest
Motive." Journal of Public Economies, 87(5-6), 2003, 1219-29.
Poterba, J. "Estate and Gift Taxes and Incentives for Inter
Vivos Giving in the US." Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), 2001,
237-64.
Revelli, F. "Spatial Patterns in Local Taxation: Tax Mimicking
or Error Mimicking?" Applied Economies, 33(9), 2001, 1101-7.
Rogers, A., and J. Raymer. "The Regional Demographics of the
Elderly Foreign-Born and Native-Born Populations in the United States Since 1950." Research on Aging, 21(1), 1999, 3-35.
Rork, J. "Coveting Thy Neighbors' Taxation."
National Tax Journal, 56(4), 2003, 775-88.
Sastry, M. L. "Estimating the Economic Impacts of Elderly
Migration: An Input-Output Analysis." Growth and Change, 23(1),
1992, 54-79.
Serow, W. "Unanswered Questions and New Directions in Research
on Elderly Migration: Economic and Demographic Perspectives."
Journal of Aging and Social Policy, 4(3-4), 1992, 73-89.
Voss, P. R., R. J. Gunderson, and R. Manchin, "Death Taxes and
Elderly Interstate Migration." Research on Aging, 10(3), 1988,
420-50.
Wilson, J. "Theories of Tax Competition." National Tax
Journal, 52(2), 1999, 269-304.
KAREN SMITH CONWAY and JONATHAN C. RORK*
Conway: Professor, Department of Economics, University of New
Hampshire, Durham, NH 03824. Phone 1-603-862-3386, Fax 1-603-862-3383,
E-mail ksconway@cisunix.unh.edu
Rork: Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Vassar College,
Poughkeepsie, NY 12604. Phone 1-845-437-7398, Fax: 1-845-437-7576,
E-mail: rork@vassar.edu