Are consumption and government expenditures sustitutes or complements? Morishima elasticity estimates from the fourier flexible form.
Fleissig, Adrian R. ; Rossana, Robert J.
1. INTRODUCTION
Macroeconomists paid relatively little attention to the economic
effects of government expenditures and to alternative methods of
financing those expenditures until Barro (1974, 1979, 1981) challenged
conventional views on the economic impact of government activity. Much
of the literature stimulated by these studies addressed the effects of
alternative financing methods for a given path of government
expenditures. But Barro (1981) also stressed the fact that government
expenditures can provide direct welfare to economic agents and that
variations in the level of government expenditures may have an impact on
the consumption decisions of households. As a result, many studies
estimate the extent to which economic agents treat government
expenditures as substitutes to or complements with private consumption
expenditures (e.g., Kormendi, 1983; Aschauer, 1985; Graham and Himarios,
1991; Ni, 1995). The degree of substitution or complementarity between
private consumption and government expenditures is of crucial importance
in assessing the impact of fiscal policies on economic welfare. Thus it
is important to establish the extent to which federal expenditures and
private consumption are substitutes or complements as a guide to the
design of fiscal policies.
There is much disagreement about the extent to which consumption
and government expenditures are substitutes or complements in use for
economic agents. (1) Studies differ in their details, so it is difficult
to know what might account for such diverse results. But it seems fair
to say that the relationship between government expenditures and
consumption is largely an open question. The diversity of the results,
however, may be a consequence of a number of restrictive assumptions
that have been used in various studies. Many of these assumptions appear
hard to justify a priori.
Studies typically estimate the parameters of an equation containing
private consumption and government expenditures, often assuming that the
relevant choice variable for the representative household is an
aggregate consumption measure given by the sum of nondurables and
services consumption (e.g., Aschauer, 1985; Reid, 1985; Bean, 1986;
Campbell and Mankiw, 1990) or the sum of nondurables, services, and the
service flow from durable goods (e.g., Kormendi, 1983; Graham and
Himarios, 1991). This implies that each component of private consumption
expenditures is a perfect substitute for the household, an assumption
for which there is no compelling theoretical basis. Similarly,
government expenditures (defense, nondefense, and state and local) are
typically aggregated (e.g., Feldstein, 1982; Aschauer, 1985; Reid, 1985;
Graham, 1993), with various studies excluding either federal or state
and local expenditures. Just as for private consumption expenditures,
these aggregation assumptions should be tested, rather t han simply
imposed in applied work. In addition, although substitution elasticities
are generally not constant in an optimizing framework, they are often
assumed to be constant in applications by using a single aggregate of
consumption or a utility function that imposes a constant elasticity of
substitution (e.g., Aschauer, 1985; and Ni, 1995). Finally, none of the
above-mentioned studies computes elasticities of substitution in a
manner consistent with microeconomic utility maximization principles.
(2)
In this article we provide estimates of elasticities of
substitution between consumption and government expenditures based on
the demand-systems approach that has been widely used in testing the
neoclassical theory of household behavior (see, eg., Deaton and
Muellbauer, 1980, and the survey of Barnett et al. 1992). This approach
has a number of attractive features, making it a substantial improvement
over the applied studies available in the macroeconomics literature.
The estimates in this article are based on an optimizing framework
where both government and consumption expenditures are treated as choice
variables by the representative household. In contrast, the typical
treatment of government expenditures in the macroeconomics literature is
that government expenditures are exogenous to optimizing households. But
the public elects agents to represent its interests when fiscal policies
are set so that it seems inappropriate to regard government expenditures
to be completely beyond the control of the public. It is plausible to
suppose that at least as a first approximation consumption decisions are
jointly determined with decisions on the appropriate level of government
activity. Our framework permits us to incorporate the joint nature of
these decisions. In addition, we use a more complete array of decision
variables compared to many earlier studies in the literature because we
incorporate three types of government expenditures (federal defense and
nondefense and state a nd local spending) along with consumption of
nondurables, services, and the stock of durable goods. Consumption and
government expenditures series will not be aggregated in this study,
allowing us to compute elasticities of substitution that may differ
between each of these expenditure components. Also, we do not require
service flows to be linear functions of consumption and government
expenditures, unlike many previous studies, nor will we impose
separability in the utility function. (3)
Furthermore, we estimate Morishima elasticities of substitution
because Blackorby and Russell (1989) show that it is the appropriate
measure of curvature or "ease" of substitution between pairs
of commodity bundles when there are more than two commodities chosen by
the household. This Morishima elasticity measure can be asymmetric and
variable over time.
Substitution or complementarity relationships between goods
consumed by households must be determined empirically, not as matter of
theory. It is thus especially important to use a functional form that
does not bias estimates of such relationships. (4) To avoid imposing the
restrictive assumptions of earlier studies, we use the flexible Fourier
functional form of Gallant (1981) that can globally approximate the true
expenditure-share equations and allows elasticities of substitution to
vary across our sample data.
We provide short-run and long-run versions of our elasticity
estimates by using lagged data in our estimation procedure. Habit
formation and non-time-separable preferences (Eichenbaum, et al. 1988;
Eichenbaum and Hansen, 1990; Pollak and Wales, 1992) are just two
possibilities that motivate the inclusion of lagged data in utility
functions and other decision rules used by optimizing households.
Consumption is likely to adjust gradually over time in response to
shifts in relative prices, so it is reasonable to anticipate that
short-run and long-run results will differ to some degree. We can
observe those differences in our elasticity estimates.
Our short-run results consistently find that government and private
consumption expenditures are net Morishima substitutes. The results
display considerable heterogeneity: Estimated elasticities are
significantly different from unity, they are asymmetric, and they vary
considerably throughout our sample data. There are interesting temporal
patterns in our results. All elasticities involving federal defense
expenditures display a consistent pattern that is clearly related to the
declining level of defense expenditures. For example, defense goods and
private consumption goods have become weaker substitutes over time in
response to shifts in the relative prices of consumer goods. Our
short-run findings suggest that using Cobb-Douglas or Constant
Elasticity of Substitution (CBS) functional forms would be a
misspecification that can bias statistical inference.
The long-run results display less heterogeneity than our short-run
elasticities. Although the estimated long-run elasticities are much
closer to unity compared to their short-run counterparts, short-run
elasticities never equal unity. Many of our estimated long-run
elasticities are insignificantly different from unity. A unitary value
for the Morishima elasticity would arise from the solution of a static
optimization problem using a Cobb-Douglas utility function.
This article is organized in the following way. The next section
describes the optimization framework that forms the basis of our
empirical work. Section III discusses the data used and covers
estimation issues. Section IV reports the short-run and long-run
Morishima elasticity estimates, and the last section summarizes our
results. Because our elasticity estimates vary at every point in our
sample, it is not possible to report each elasticity estimate and its
associated standard error in a concise way within the body of the
article. As a result, we only report summary measures of our elasticity
estimates. An Appendix concludes. The Appendix reports the individual
parameter estimates obtained from estimation of the Fourier
expenditure-share equations and their associated standard errors.
II. THE FOURIER DEMAND-SYSTEMS FRAMEWORK
Household Behavior
The model underlying our analysis is an optimization framework
where it is assumed that a representative household wishes to maximize
the utility function
(1) u([c.sup.*.sub.t], [d.sup.*.sub.t], [g.sup.*.sub.t]),
where [c.sup.*] is a vector of service flows of nondurable goods
and services, [d.sup.*] refers to a vector of service flows from stocks
of durable goods, and [g.sup.*] denotes service flows from government
expenditures. The specification in (1) assumes that consumers get
utility from the services provided by government as well as from
nondurable goods, services, and durable goods.
Data on service flows are generally unavailable and must be
estimated in some manner. For example, service flows from nondurable
goods and services have often been assumed to be linear functions of
current and lagged expenditures on nondurable goods and services. (5)
However, these service flows need not be linear functions of consumption
expenditures so that, as an alternative specification, service flows are
treated in this study as the possibly nonlinear function
(2) [c.sub.t.sup.*] = [c.sub.t.sup.*]([c.sub.t]; [c.sub.t-1],
[c.sub.t-2],...),
where lagged consumption expenditures ([c.sub.t-j]) are present in
(2) to indicate that contemporaneous service flows are conditional on
past consumption expenditures.
Service flows from durable goods are often assumed to be
proportional to the stock of durable goods. (6) For example, Ni (1995,
596) assumes that [d.sub.t.sup.*] = [delta]([k.sub.t-1] - [d.sub.t]) and
[DELTA][k.sub.t] = [delta][d.sub.t], which together imply that
[d.sub.t.sup.*] = [delta][(1 - [delta]).sup.-1] [k.sub.t], where
[d.sub.t] denotes purchases of new durable goods, [k.sub.t] is the stock
of durable goods, and [delta] is the depreciation rate. More generally,
service flows from durable goods may be written as the possibly
nonlinear function
(3) [d.sub.t.sup.*] = [d.sub.t.sup.*]([k.sub.t]; [k.sub.t-1],
[k.sub.t-2],...),
indicating that service flows are conditional on lagged stocks of
durable goods. The lagged stocks in (3) have been interpreted as an
indication of habit persistence in house-hold behavior (Eichenbaum and
Hansen, 1988).
Similarly, we write the service flows from government expenditures
as
(4) [g.sub.t.sup.*] = [g.sub.t.sup.*]([g.sub.t]; [g.sub.t-1],
[g.sub.t-2],...)
This expression reflects the fact that many government activities
involve the provision of durable goods, providing services to
house-holds that persist over time. In our empirical work reported
below, the vector [g.sub.t] will contain federal defense expenditures,
federal nondefense expenditures, and state and local government
expenditures.
Substituting (2)-(4) into (1) gives the utility function
(5) u([c.sub.t], [k.sub.t], [g.sub.t]; [c.sub.t-1], [c.sub.t-2],
... , [k.sub.t-1], [k.sub.t-2], ... , [g.sub.t-1],[g.sub.t-2], ...),
which is the objective function used by the representative
household in our analysis. See Fleissig (1997) for further details about
the properties of the utility function.
Let [x.sub.t] be a vector consisting of nondurable goods, services,
the stock of consumer durable goods, and government expenditures. Then
our optimizing framework is
(6) max u([x.sub.t]; [x.sub.t-1], [x.sub.t-2],...) subject to
[p.sub.t][x'.sub.t] = [m.sub.t],
where the budget constraint simply states that total expenditures,
[m.sub.t], equal the sum of expenditures on each good entering
contemporaneously into the utility function.
Elasticities of Substitution
The solution to (6) yields utility-constant commodity demand
functions that give optimal demands for goods as a function of relative
prices. Alternatively, if we use total expenditures as the normalizing
magnitude, then commodity demands are functions of
expenditure-normalized prices. In our empirical work reported later,
expenditures on each good as a share of total expenditures are a
function of these expenditure-normalized prices. Empirical estimates of
the relation between consumer goods and services and government
expenditure are analyzed using substitution elasticities. In models
containing only two commodities, the elasticity of substitution is quite
unambiguous: the two commodities must be net substitutes. But when there
are more than two commodities, Blackorby and Russell (1989) show that
substitution relationships depend on the direction in which the price
ratio changes and they show that the Morishima elasticity, not the
traditional Allen-Uzawa elasticity, is the correct measure of
substitution among commodities. The Morishima elasticity of
substitution, denoted by [M.sub.ij], is given by
(7) [M.sub.ij] = [p.sub.i][E.sub.ij](u, p)/[E.sub.j](u, p) -
[p.sub.i][E.sub.ii](u, p)/[E.sub.i](u, p) = [[epsilon].sub.ji] -
[[epsilon].sub.ii],
where [E.sub.i] and [E.sub.ij] are first and second derivatives of
the expenditure function E(u, p). As shown in (7), the Morishima
elasticity is the difference between two terms: The first term is the
response of the utility-constant demand for good j with the respect to a
shift in price [P.sub.i], and the second term is the response of the
utility-constant demand for good i with respect to a change in price
[p.sub.i]. If this expression is positive, goods i and j are defined to
be net substitutes and, if this magnitude is negative, they are net
complements. This elasticity measure need not be symmetric ([M.sub.ij]
[not equal to] [M.sub.ji]) because the log derivative of the commodity
ratio [x.sub.i]/[x.sub.j] with respect to [p.sub.i]/[p.sub.j] depends on
whether the change in the price ratio is attributed to a change in
[p.sub.i] or [p.sub.j]. The Morishima elasticity will be symmetric if
and only if the utility function is an implicit CES function.
It is important to note that our definition of substitution and
complementarity is not identical to that used in earlier studies. The
Morishima elasticity measures changes in government purchases and
private consumption in response to changes in relative prices. In
contrast, many previous studies define substitution between government
purchases and private consumption expenditures to mean that increases in
government purchases reduce the marginal utility of private consumption.
For example, the utility function U(c + [theta]g) used by Graham and
Himarios (1991) implies that the marginal utility of private consumption
(c) rises (falls) with an increase in government expenditures (g) if
[theta] is negative (positive). Consumption and government expenditures
thus are substitutes if [theta] > 0 and complements if [theta] <
0. In our analysis, consumption and government expenditures can be
substitutes even if the marginal utility of consumption does not fall
with an increase in government expenditures.
The Fourier Flexible Form
An indirect utility function can be approximated by parametric
functions such as the Cobb-Douglas, quadratic, CES, or constant relative
risk aversion. The difficulty with parametric forms is that they can
often restrict the substitution relationship between commodities and
often fail to give a good approximation to the utility function, as
suggested by the frequent rejection of the corresponding overidentifying
restrictions implied by economic models. A more precise approximation to
the utility function can be obtained using a flexible functional form.
Moreover, flexible functional forms have the convenient property of
leaving elasticities of substitution unrestricted (Diewert, 1974).
Diewert (1974) defines a flexible functional form as a second-order
local approximation to an arbitrary, twice-continuously differentiable function at a given point. Diewert-flexible functions have some
limitations--they can only provide a local approximation in a delta
neighborhood of unknown and often small size, and they may fail to
measure how accurately partial derivatives of the true utility function
are estimated. Estimating partial derivatives is important because the
Morishima elasticities are functions of the partial derivatives of the
data generating function. Semi-nonparametric functions, such as the
Fourier flexible form and the asymptotically ideal model, give global
approximations of the unknown data generating function and its partial
derivatives and thus are free of the shortcomings of Diewert-flexible
functions. (7)
Gallant (1981) augments Diewert's definition of a flexible
functional form by requiring the function to globally approximate both
the true utility function and its partial derivatives. The
semi-nonparametric Fourier flexible form developed by Gallant (1981) and
extended by Fisher and Fleissig (1997) will be used in this study to
approximate the indirect utility function from the solution of (6), used
in deriving the expenditure-share equations that we estimate (see later
discussion). This indirect utility function can be written as
(8) f(.) = [u.sub.0] + b' v + (1/2)v' Cv
+ [summation over (A/[alpha]=1)] ([u.sub.0[alpha]] + 2 [summation
over (J/j=1)][[u.sub.j[alpha]] COS(j[k'.sub.[alpha]]v)
--[w.sub.j[alpha]] sin(j[k'.sub.[alpha]]v)]),
where
C = -- [summation over (A/[alpha]=1)]
[u.sub.0[alpha]][k.sub.[alpha]][k'.sub.[alpha]].
In the expressions, parameters to be estimated are contained in the
vectors {b}, {[u.sub.j[alpha]]}, and {[w.sub.j[alpha]]}. The vector of
current and lagged expenditure-normalized prices ([p.sub.i]/m) for
commodities is denoted by v. The term [k'.sub.[alpha]] is referred
to as a multi-index and is an n-vector of integers denoting partial
differentiation of the utility function. The parameters A and J
determine the degree of the Fourier polynomials and are determined by
empirical testing (see the Appendix).
The utility function in (8) has two parts: a quadratic part, given
by [u.sub.0] + b'v + (1/2)v' Cv, and a Fourier series component, given by the remainder of the expression. Special cases of
(8) generate functional forms that have been popular in applied work.
For example, if the vector v consists solely of expenditure-normalized
prices for the sum of contemporaneous nondurables and services and if
the parameters {[u.sub.j[alpha]]} and {[w.sub.j[alpha]]} are set to
zero, the quadratic form in Hall (1978) emerges. If v consists of
durable and nondurable goods and if the parameters {[u.sub.j[alpha]]}
and {[w.sub.j[alpha]]} are zero, the utility function is that of
Bernanke (1985) without adjustment costs. Substitutability between goods
in the utility function is determined by the parameters
{[u.sub.0[alpha]]}, {[u.sub.j[alpha]]}, and {[w.sub.j[alpha]]}. The
elasticity of substitution is free to change over time and does not
depend on the precision of a single parameter estimate, as in Bernanke
(1985).
Our estimates are based on Fourier expenditure share equations
arising from the solution of the optimization problem given in (6).
Using Roy's identity, these expenditure-share relationships, y(.),
are given by
(9) [y.sub.i](.) = [[v.sub.i][b.sub.i] - [summation over
(A/[alpha]=1)] ([u.sub.0[alpha]] v'[k.sub.[alpha]] + 2 [summation
over (J/j=1)] [[u.sub.j[alpha]] sin (j[k'.sub.[alpha]] v) +
[w.sub.j[alpha]] cos (j[k'.sub.[alpha]]v)]) [k.sub.i[alpha]]
[v.sub.i]] / [b'v - [summation over (A/[alpha]=1)]
([u.sub.0[alpha]] v' [k.sub.[alpha]] + 2 [summation over (J/j=1)] j
[[u.sub.j[alpha]] sin (j[k'.sub.[alpha]] v) + [w.sub.j[alpha]]
cos(j[k'.sub.[alpha]]v)]) [k'.sub.[alpha]]v]
for i = 1,..., n goods. The time notation has been suppressed in
(9). This expression, along with the restrictions implied by ordinary
consumer theory (budget shares for all six goods must sum to one, and
cross-price derivatives of the Hicksian demand functions must be
symmetric) is the basis for our empirical work.
Because budget shares must add to unity, estimation of a system of
n budget-share equations will result in a residual covariance matrix that is singular. We follow the traditional approach and estimate a
system of n-1 share equations and recover parameter estimates for the
omitted equation from the estimated n-1 equations. Barten (1969) shows
that the parameter estimates are invariant to the choice of share
equation omitted from estimation.
III. DATA AND ESTIMATION ISSUES
The government and consumption expenditures data that we use are
from the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) and are
available in Citibase. We use data on government expenditures for three
types of activities: defense, nondefense, and state and local
expenditures, all measured in billions of 1992 U.S. dollars. Prices for
these magnitudes are measured by their implicit deflators. For private
consumption expenditures, we use data on constant-dollar nondurable
goods, services, and the stock durable goods. Expenditures and price
indexes for nondurable goods and services are from NIPA, also available
in Citibase. We constructed the stock of consumer durable goods using a
benchmark stock for 1946:4 from Musgrave (1979), combined with data on
purchases of durable goods and an assumed depreciation rate of 6% per
quarter, as in Ni (1995). The user cost of durable goods is calculated
using a depreciation rate of 6% per quarter, the NIPA price index for
durable goods, and an interest rate. The one-month T-bill rate,
converted into a quarterly series, is the interest rate used in
calculating Diewert's (1974) formula for the user cost for durable
goods. (8) Resident population was used to convert magnitudes to per
capita levels. The data span 1947 to 1996 at quarterly frequency and are
adjusted for seasonality.
Parameter estimates for the Fourier flexible form were obtained
using maximum likelihood. We searched over a wide range of starting
values to estimate the expenditure-share equations in the system (see
the Appendix). (9) A series of Wald tests were carried out to determine
the number of lags for each series. Four lags were used for each
variable in our system based on the results from these tests. The
economic content of the Fourier parameter estimates is obtained by
estimating the Morishima elasticities of substitution. Because there are
no costs of adjustment to equilibrium, lagged variables capture
adjustment to the ultimate long-run steady state and are used to
estimate short-run elasticities of substitution. In the long run, agents
have time to fully adjust their consumption decisions, and thus we also
analyze the long-run Morishima elasticity. To estimate long-run
Morishima elasticities, set [x.sub.t] = [x.sub.t-j] for j = 1,..., 4,
then take the parameter estimates and recalculate (7).
The standard errors in nonlinear models are usually calculated
using the delta method with analytical derivatives. We calculate the
covariance matrix for the estimated Fourier flexible form and the
Morishima elasticities. The covariance matrix for k nonlinear
constraints for a function of the parameter vector [theta], h([theta]),
is calculated as V(h([theta])) =
([partial]h/[partial]([theta]))'V([theta])([partial]h/[partial]([thet a]))', evaluated at the estimated [theta] vector. Using
h([theta]) and its variance, the Wald statistic W =
h([theta])V(h([theta])).sup.-1] h([theta])' is distributed
asymptotically as a chi-square statistic with k degrees of freedom under
the null hypothesis.
There was evidence of first-order serial correlation in the
estimated demand-share system of equations when the equation system was
first estimated. Autocorrelation is commonly found in demand systems and
was first analyzed in detail by Berndt and Savin (1975) for the type of
system that we estimate. If the disturbance vector, [e.sub.t], has the
AR(1) form [e.sub.t] = R[e.sub.t-1] + [u.sub.t] where R is an
autoregressive parameter matrix, adding up requires the matrix R to be
diagonal with identical diagonal elements. Our estimates correct for
this evident serial correlation.
It is useful to be aware of the time-series behavior of our data as
an aid to interpreting the elasticity estimates reported later. Although
these patterns are known, a brief discussion is given here to facilitate
the discussion of our elasticity estimates.
In per capita terms, the salient feature of our data is the
systematic decline in defense expenditures that began in the early
1950s. Federal defense expenditures have fluctuated about a negative
trend over most of our sample and, measured as shares of government
expenditures, there has been a shift in the mix of government spending:
defense spending has fallen and nondefense spending has increased
modestly, and state and local spending has substantially increased. As
for consumption, all series follow positively sloped time paths, but,
using shares of total consumption, services have increased while
nondurable and durable consumption decline over our sample data.
IV. ESTIMATED ELASTICITIES OF SUBSTITUTION
Estimation results are given in Tables 1 and 2. Our notation is as
follows: the Morishima elasticity of substitution between variables i
and j is denoted by [M.sub.ij]([M.sub.ji]) when relative prices change
due to a change in the price of variable i(j). Elasticities are indexed
for i = 1,...,6 where:
Government Expenditures
1 = Defense 2 = Nondefense 3 = State and Local
Consumer Expenditures
4 = Nondurables 5 = Services 6 = Stock of Durable Goods.
The tables contain summary statistics for the Morishima
elasticities that we estimate at each point in our sample. The tables
contain the mean, median, maximum, and minimum estimate for each
elasticity estimate. The same summary data, except for the mean, is
provided for the standard errors attached to these elasticity estimates.
Short-Run Estimates
Table 1 contains summary information about the estimated short-run
Morishima elasticities. Substitution elasticities are significantly
different from zero at the 5% level at every point in our sample (see
the Appendix for individual parameter estimates and standard errors). In
fact, the Morishima elasticities are estimated very precisely at all
sample points. The estimated elasticities are always positive for all
pairs of expenditure series. Thus all pairs of government and
consumption expenditure series are observed to be net Morishima
substitutes.
An important empirical issue is whether our estimated functional
form satisfies the regularity restrictions imposed by neoclassical
microeconomic theory. These regularity conditions are adding-up,
homogeneity, symmetry, nonnegativity, monotonicity, and the curvature
conditions (quasi-concavity) on the indirect utility function. Following
Christensen et al. (1975) and Fisher et al. (2001), adding-up,
homogeneity, and symmetry are imposed on the Fourier prior to
estimation. The results (available on request) show that there are no
violations of nonnegativity, monotonicity, and quasi-concavity. Thus the
Fourier flexible form, for this data set, satisfies neoclassical
regularity restrictions. (10)
Additional aspects of our results are illuminated by the estimated
Morishima elasticities for defense expenditures and the consumption of
services, denoted by [M.sub.15] and [M.sub.51]. The behavior of these
estimated elasticities is representative of the characteristics found in
many other estimated elasticities, Figures 1 and 2 contain time-series
plots of the estimated Morishima elasticities for these series. The
dotted lines in the diagrams are the standard error bands associated
with each elasticity estimate.
Inspection of the individual elasticity estimates for defense
spending and services shows that there is considerable variability in
our estimated elasticities. For example, Table 1 reveals that [M.sub.15]
ranges in value from a minimum of 1.019 to a maximum of 1.199, whereas
[M.sub.51] has a minimum value of 0.804 and a maximum of 0.984. Similar
differences may be found in other pairwise comparisons from Table 1. The
estimated elasticities over all pairs of goods range in value from a
minimum of 0.388 ([M.sub.42]) to a maximum of 1.376 ([M.sub.25]).
Figures 1 and 2 confirm this; the figures show substantial changes over
time in the elasticities that we estimate.
The summary data clearly suggest that the estimated elasticities
are asymmetric. The figures clearly show this asymmetry for [M.sub.15]
and [M.sub.51]. One elasticity, [M.sub.15], always exceeds unity, and
[M.sub.51] always lies below unity. Inspection of all the estimated
elasticities and their standard errors confirms that they are asymmetric
for all pairs of goods and statistically different from one. Theoretical
assumptions restricting substitution elasticities to be symmetric and
constant are not supported by the data.
The summary data in Table 1 may possibly mask interesting temporal
patterns in our results. It is apparent from Figures 1 and 2 that the
elasticities for defense and services vary systematically over our
sample, with [M.sub.15] displaying a positive trend most of the time and
[M.sub.51] displaying a negative trend. It is interesting to see how
these temporal patterns match up with the time-series behavior of
defense spending and consumption of services. Inspection of the data
reveals that the temporal pattern of the elasticities corresponds
closely with the time-series behavior of federal defense expenditures.
Whenever federal defense expenditures are falling, as they do over most
of our sample data, we observe [M.sub.15] ([M.sub.51]) to be rising
(falling). Similarly, any other elasticity that involves government
defense expenditures displays this same pattern. That is, [M.sub.1j]
([M.sub.j1]) rises (falls) for j = 4, 5, 6. (11) To interpret these
results, it is helpful to recall the definition of the Morish ima
elasticity, given above in (7). [M.sub.ij] is the net shift (net of the
own-price elasticity effect denoted by [[epsilon].sub.ii] in [7]) in the
compensated or utility-constant demand for good j when the price of good
i changes. If [M.sub.1j] is rising over time, then shifts in the
relative price of defense expenditures are generating larger net shifts
in the demands for consumer goods. If [M.sub.j1] is falling, then shifts
in the prices of consumer goods are inducing smaller net shifts in the
demand for defense goods. These results are consistent with the view
that with declining resource use in the defense goods sector associated
with declining defense expenditures, a given desired increase in the
consumption of consumer goods induces a smaller net decline in the
demand for defense goods than would have been true in the past.
Households may wish to shift fewer resources out of the defense sector
because resource use in this sector has fallen for many years.
Similarly, if defense goods fall in relative p rice, a rising elasticity
of substitution reflects a desire to shift relatively more resources
into the defense sector as compared to the past.
There are apparent trends in the other estimated elasticities
involving government and consumption expenditures, but these are not as
prominent or widespread as the results involving defense expenditures.
We find [M.sub.3j] rising over time for j = 4, 5, 6. These are
elasticities that involve state and local spending and the private
consumption components. These movements reflect the increasing levels of
state and local spending that have occurred in our sample. However we do
not see falling levels of [M.sub.j3] in our results for reasons that are
unclear.
As for the consumption elasticities, these series are all net
Morishima substitutes with elasticities that are significantly different
from unity. There are no striking patterns in the estimated elasticities
with the exceptions of [M.sub.54] and [M.sub.64]. These are elasticities
between either services or durable consumption and nondurable
consumption, and these elasticities decline over our sample. This
implies that if either the relative price of services or durable
services were to rise, services and durables are becoming stronger
substitutes with nondurable goods so that households would respond with
increasingly large shifts in the demand for nondurable goods. These
patterns are consistent with the fact that, measured as a share of total
consumption, nondurables expenditures decline in our sample data.
To summarize, we find that all pairs of consumption and government
expenditure series are net Morishima substitutes in use, statistically
different from one, and clearly changing over time. The elasticities
associated with federal defense spending closely correspond to movements
in defense spending over time. We now turn to our long-run results that
enable us to see if these short-run findings continue to hold once
households have fully adjusted to variations in relative prices. (12)
Long-Run Estimates
Table 2 provides summary information for the estimated long-run
elasticity estimates. The data show that all pairs of goods in our
analysis are net Morishima substitutes. As before, inspection of the
data in the table suggests that our elasticity estimates are asymmetric.
Using [M.sub.15] and [M.sub.51] for illustration, [M.sub.15] ranges from
a maximum of 1.325 to a minimum of 0.951, and the median value is
estimated to be 1.084. Regarding [M.sub.51], the estimated values range
from a maximum of 1.045 to a minimum of 0.686 with a median value of
0.918. Individual estimated elasticities and their associated standard
errors show that the elasticities are asymmetric at most sample points.
However, these numerical results actually mask a general tendency
for our results to become more homogeneous as compared to our short-run
results. This change toward homogeneity may be illustrated graphically.
Figures 3 and 4 provide time series plots of [M.sub.15] and [M.sub.51]
that may be compared to their short-run counterparts. The figures show
that the long-run results are much closer to unity than their short-run
values. At a substantial number of sample points, the estimated
elasticities are within one standard error of unity and thus are
statistically indistinguishable from unity. This tendency is quite
evident in the elasticities for other pairs of goods that we estimate.
Furthermore, although the elasticities are still asymmetric at most
sample points, each elasticity moves closer to unity when we compare
short-run and long-run versions of a given elasticity. (13) The degree
of asymmetry in our results declines as we move to the long run. The
figures also suggest that our long-run estimates often a re not as
tightly estimated as our short-run elasticities, which is also true much
of the time. When our elasticity results are statistically different
from unity, the magnitude of this departure from unity is generally
small.
It is also true that the long-run results display far fewer
examples of elasticities with distinct trends over time. Thus when we
move from the short-run to the long-run version of our results, we
eliminate a substantial degree of the heterogeneity evident in our
short-run results. (14)
Previous evidence of complementarity or substitutability between
consumption and government expenditures appears sensitive to the details
of the empirical specification used by the investigator. (15) Our
short-run and long-run results are quite consistent (consumption and
government expenditures are always found to be net Morishima
substitutes), results that are generally in agreement with the general
equilibrium analysis of Baxter and King (1993). (16) Furthermore, the
results are considerably more uniform than the results in the
literature, suggesting that our use of the flexible Fourier form
provides at least part of the explanation for the diversity of results
in previous research.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Accurate estimates of the economic welfare effects of government
expenditures must take account of the changes in household consumption
levels that occur in response to variations in government expenditures.
Toward this end it is crucially important to have reliable estimates of
substitution elasticities between consumption and government
expenditures to assess these welfare effects. We estimate Morishima
elasticities of substitution between consumption and government
expenditures. The Morishima elasticities are the theoretically
appropriate measure of substitution when there are more than two choice
variables in an optimizing model, as in our study. In addition, the
elasticities are estimated using the Fourier functional form to limit
the potential biases associated with the parametric functional forms
used in previous studies. Government expenditures are treated as
endogenous, unlike much of the macro-economics literature studying the
economic effects of government spending. By using lagged conditioning
var iables, we provide short-run and long-run elasticity estimates,
allowing us to observe any differences that might arise when the public
has completely adjusted to variations in relative prices.
The estimates show that consumption and government expenditures are
net Morishima substitutes. Further evidence indicates that elasticities
of substitution are not equal to unity in the short run, nor are these
elasticities constant over our sample data. There is a general tendency
for elasticities of substitution between consumption and government
expenditures to rise and fall with the level of federal government
defense expenditures, suggesting that defense goods and private
consumption goods have become weaker substitutes in response to
variations in the price of consumer goods. In the long-run version of
our results, we find evidence that elasticities of substitution become
somewhat less heterogeneous, approaching unitary elasticities for some
goods. Thus our long-run results move towards but are still different
from the results one would find if the optimization problem were solved
using a Cobb-Douglas utility function with no lagged data.
The virtue of our results is that they are quite uniform compared
to the literature, consistently implying that consumption and government
expenditures are net Morishima substitutes. This fact would seem to be
relevant information for government policy makers making government
expenditure decisions.
APPENDIX
A series of Wald tests were used to determine the number of lags of
the goods in the utility function and the parameters A and J. The share
equations were estimated using maximum likelihood in version 43 of TSP with a convergence criterion of 0.00001. The number of lags was set to
four with A = 4 and J = 1. Because the Fourier flexible form is
nonlinear, we searched over a wide range of starting values. The
estimated parameters are given in Table A1.
Table A1
Parameter Estimates of Fourier Share Equations
Parameter Estimate Standard Error
[b.sub.1] .013378 .020531
[b.sub.2] .013199 .015228
[b.sub.3] -.006461 .010212
[b.sub.4] .057732 .024753
[b.sub.5] -.108541 .019809
[u.sub.01] .000119 .000027
[u.sub.11] .000005 .000008
[v.sub.11] .000003 .000008
[u.sub.02] .000097 .000026
[u.sub.12] -.000006 .000008
[v.sub.12] .000004 .000008
[u.sub.03] -.000198 .000034
[u.sub.13] .000014 .000006
[v.sub.13] -.000003 .000006
[u.sub.04] .000126 .000030
[u.sub.14] -.000005 .000009
[v.sub.14] -.000021 .000009
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
TABLE 1
Short-Run Morishima Elasticities of Substitution
[M.sub.14] [M.sub.15]
Consumption and government expenditures
Mean 1.080 1.094
Median 1.085 .0064 1.095
Max 1.159 .0108 1.199
Min 1.023 .0025 1.019
[M.sub.34] [M.sub.35]
Mean 1.014 1.031
Median 1.009 .0037 1.029
Max 1.057 .0080 1.057
Min 0.996 .0031 1.017
[M.sub.42] [M.sub.52]
Mean 0.651 0.791
Median 0.663 .0221 0.795
Max 0.776 .0398 0.887
Min 0.388 .0165 0.639
[M.sub.45] [M.sub.46]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 1.021 0.996
Median 1.021 .0021 0.999
Max 1.053 .0033 1.081
Min 0.990 .0015 0.960
[M.sub.16]
Consumption and government expenditures
Mean 1.073
Median .0068 1.076 .0064
Max .0121 1.165 .0113
Min .0016 0.992 .0022
[M.sub.36]
Mean 1.013
Median .0048 1.011 .0050
Max .0083 1.046 .0086
Min .0042 1.000 .0043
[M.sub.62]
Mean 0.691
Median .0163 0.698 .0192
Max .0265 0.800 .0345
Min .0110 0.471 .0130
[M.sub.54]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 0.990
Median .0013 0.990 .0009
Max .0025 1.015 .0017
Min .0011 0.965 .0007
[M.sub.24] [M.sub.25]
Consumption and government expenditures
Mean 1.191 1.208
Median 1.185 .0233 1.206
Max 1.368 .0400 1.376
Min 1.104 .0171 1.117
[M.sub.41] [M.sub.51]
Mean 0.901 0.909
Median 0.896 .0061 0.908
Max 0.971 .0106 0.984
Min 0.804 .0022 0.804
[M.sub.43] [M.sub.53]
Mean 0.969 0.981
Median 0.980 .0027 0.981
Max 0.999 .0077 0.994
Min 0.896 .0023 0.959
[M.sub.56] [M.sub.64]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 0.982 1.007
Median 0.982 .0012 1.004
Max 0.984 .0019 1.041
Min 0.968 .0009 0.987
[M.sub.26]
Consumption and government expenditures
Mean 1.188
Median .0244 1.185 .0236
Max .0405 1.361 .0398
Min .0172 1.101 .0164
[M.sub.61]
Mean 0.909
Median .0065 0.907 .0055
Max .0116 1.006 .0108
Min .0013 0.799 .0013
[M.sub.63]
Mean 0.983
Median .0026 0.987 .0021
Max .0053 1.003 .0045
Min .0022 0.945 .0019
[M.sub.65]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 1.023
Median .0006 1.022 .0017
Max .0025 1.039 .0026
Min .0004 1.008 .0013
Notes: Table entries are short-run Morishima elasticities of
substitution, denoted by [M.sup.ij], between consumption and government
expenditures. Summary measures of estimated standard errors are given
adjacent to summary data on elasticity estimates. Subscript notation: 1
= defense, 2 = nondefense, 3 = state and local, 4 = nonduable goods, 5 =
services, and 6 = the stock of durable goods.
TABLE 2
Long-Run Morishima Elasticities of Substitution
[M.sub.14] [M.sub.15]
Consumption and government
expenditures
Mean 1.084 1.097
Median 1.077 0.0356 1.084 .0376
Max 1.300 0.0663 1.325 .0732
Min 0.936 0.0135 0.951 .0082
[M.sub.34] [M.sub.35]
Mean 1.018 1.035
Median 1.011 0.0204 1.032 0.0239
Max 1.141 0.0492 1.121 0.0432
Min 0.936 0.0157 0.959 0.0194
[M.sub.42] [M.sub.52]
Mean 0.629 0.771
Median 0.629 .1157 0.775 .1196
Max 1.111 .2089 1.382 .2060
Min 0.010 .0828 0.202 .0792
[M.sub.45] [M.sub.46]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 1.019 0.994
Median 1.019 .0044 0.999 .0026
Max 1.074 .0089 1.029 .0096
Min 0.964 .0031 0.928 .0017
[M.sub.16] [M.sub.24]
Consumption and government
expenditures
Mean 1.076 1.211
Median 1.062 .0340 1.206 .1430
Max 1.304 .0676 1.781 .2358
Min 0.940 .0053 0.640 .1010
[M.sub.36] [M.sub.41]
Mean 1.017 0.898
Median 1.013 0.0208 0.911 0.0294
Max 1.109 0.0435 1.029 0.0569
Min 0.946 0.0154 0.686 0.0110
[M.sub.62] [M.sub.43]
Mean 0.671 0.963
Median 0.682 .1100 0.976 .0157
Max 1.171 .1900 1.031 .0423
Min 0.096 .0733 0.809 .0116
[M.sub.54] [M.sub.56]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 0.992 0.982
Median 0.993 .0038 0.984 .0023
Max 1.045 .0094 1.001 .0062
Min 0.944 .0026 0.949 .0014
[M.sub.25] [M.sub.26]
Consumption and government
expenditures
Mean 1.228 1.208
Median 1.218 .1448 1.199 .1422
Max 1.782 .2326 1.768 .2320
Min 0.663 .0966 0.649 .0940
[M.sub.51] [M.sub.61]
Mean 0.907 0.907
Median 0.918 0.0353 0.924 0.0294
Max 1.045 0.0703 1.031 0.0583
Min 0.686 0.0075 0.691 0.0043
[M.sub.53] [M.sub.63]
Mean 0.977 0.980
Median 0.979 .0179 0.984 .0149
Max 1.058 .0382 1.044 .0341
Min 0.868 .0146 0.870 .0108
[M.sub.64] [M.sub.65]
Consumption expenditures
Mean 1.009 1.023
Median 1.005 .0027 1.021 .0029
Max 1.076 .0098 1.057 .0064
Min 0.976 .0018 1.003 .0020
Notes: Table entries are long-run Morishima elasticities of
substitution, denoted by [M.sub.ij], between consumption and government
expenditures. Summary measures of estimated standard errors are given
adjacent to summary data on elasticity estimates. Subscript notation: 1
= defense, 2 = nondefense, 3 = state and local, 4 = nondurable goods, 5
= services, and 6 = the stock of durable goods.
(1.) Ni (1995, 595) surveys estimates of substitution elasticities
between consumption and government expenditures. Seater (1993) describes
the literature on Ricardian equivalence and the economic effects of
government expenditures.
(2.) Baxter and King (1993) and Ni (1995) do have explicit utility
functions underlying their analyses. However, Ni (1995) uses functional
forms that restrict the range of substitution elasticities. The Baxter
and King (1993) study is the most complete analysis of the relation
between consumption and government expenditures in a general equilibrium
framework, but they only provide a simulation study giving quantitative
measures of substitution between consumption and government
expenditures.
(3.) It wilt be assumed that the labor supply decision is separable from other choices made by the household, which follows the bulk of the
literature in this area. Relaxing this separability assumption is thus
left as a possible avenue for future research.
(4.) For example, Cobb-Douglas, CES, or quadratic forms for the
utility function impose a constant Morishima elasticity of substitution
at all sample points.
(5.) See, for example, Dunn and Singleton (1986), Eichenbaum et al.
(1988), and Eichenbaum and Hansen (1990).
(6.) See, for example, Deaton and Muellbauer (1980) and Eichenbaum
and Hansen (1990).
(7.) Elbadawi et al. (1983) define a semi-nonparametric function as
a series expansion dense in a Sobolov norm. We could use the
asymptotically ideal model specification (Barnett and Jonas, 1983) but
the dimensionality of our economic model precludes the use of this
approach. See Fleissig and Swofford (1997) for further discussion.
(8.) This user cost is [p.sub.it] - [(1 + [R.sub.t]).sup.-1] (1 -
[delta]) [E.sub.t][p.sub.it] + 1 where R is the nominal interest rate,
[delta] is the depreciation rate, [p.sub.it] is the price of good i, and
[E.sub.t][p.sub.it] + 1 is the expected price of good i. Following
Diewert (1974), we use static expectations.
(9.) The equations were estimated in International TSP version 4.3
with the cross-equation restrictions imposed.
(10.) Evaluating regularity conditions for different functional
forms is discussed in detail by Christensen et al. (1975) and Fisher et
al. (2001). Briefly, nonnegativity requires that the estimated demand
functions are nonnegative for all data points. The gradient vector of
the estimated indirect utility function is used to determine if the
indirect utility function is monotonically decreasing. Quasi-convexity
of the indirect utility function is evaluated from the parameter
estimates of the estimated indirect utility function, provided
monotonicity holds.
(11.) In fact, this temporal pattern is also found in the Morishima
elasticities for federal defense spending and the other two government
expenditure series.
(12.) There are no consistent cyclical patterns in the estimated
elasticities that we can observe. For example, looking at postwar peak-to-trough values of the estimated elasticities using NBER reference
dates, the estimated elasticities display different time patterns across
recessions and differ in their behavior in a given recession.
(13.) A unitary value for the Morishima elasticity would arise if
economic agents were solving a static utility optimization problem
without any lags entering into the optimizing framework and if they had
a Cobb-Douglas utility function.
(14.) The only elasticities that unambiguously display trends over
time are [M.sub.43], [M.sub.45], [M.sub.46], [M.sub.54], and [M.sub.64].
(15.) Ni (1995) provides a discussion of the sensitivity in
estimation results to various elements of specification.
(16.) As pointed out by an anonymous referee, there is an important
difference between our analysis and that of Baxter and King (1993)
regarding the mechanism that generates substitution or complementarity
between consumption and government expenditures. In this earlier study,
consumption choices by the public respond to the income effects
associated with variations in exogenous government expenditures, whereas
in our analysis variations in relative prices are the driving forces
behind the consumption and government expenditure choices of the public.
REFERENCES
Aschauer, D. "Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand."
American Economic Review, 75(1), 1985, 117-27.
Barnett, W, and A. B. Jonas. "The Muntz-Szatz Demand System:
An Application of a Globally Well-Behaved Series Expansion."
Economics Letters, 11(4), 1983, 337-42.
Barnett, W., D. Fisher, and A. Serletis. "Consumer Theory and
the Demand for Money." Journal of Economic Literature, 30(4), 1992,
2086-119.
Barten, A. "Maximum Likelihood Estimates of a Complete System
of Demand Equations." European Economic Review, 1(1), 1969, 7-73.
Barro, R. "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" Journal of
Political Economy, 82(6), 1974, 1095-117.
_____. "On the Determination of the Public Debt." Journal
of Political Economy, 87(5), 1979, 940-71.
_____. "Output Effects of Government Purchases." Journal
of Political Economy, 89(6), 1981, 1086-121.
Baxter, M., and R. G. King. "Fiscal Policy in General
Equilibrium." American Economic Review, 83(3), 1993, 315-34.
Bean, C. "The Estimation of Surprise Models and the Surprise
Consumption Function." Review of Economic Studies, 53(4), 1986,
497-516.
Bernanke, B. "Adjustment Costs, Durables, and Aggregate
Consumption." Journal of Monetary Economics, 15(1), 1985, 41-68.
Berndt, E., and N. E. Savin. "Estimation and Hypothesis
Testing in Singular Equation Systems with Autoregressive
Disturbances." Econometrica, 43(5- 6), 1975, 937-57.
Blackorby, C., and R. R. Russell. "Will the Real Elasticity of
Substitution Please Stand Up? (A Comparison of the Allen/Uzawa and
Morishima Elasticities)." American Economic Review, 79(4), 1989,
882-88.
Campbell, J., and N. G. Mankiw. "Permanent Income, Current
Income, and Consumption." Journal of Business & Economic
Statistics, 8(8), 1990, 265-79.
Christensen, L., D. W Jorgenson, and L. J. Lau,
"Transcendental Logarithmic Utility Functions." American
Economic Review, 65(3), 1975, 367-83.
Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer. Economics and Consumer Behavior.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980.
Diewert, W "Intertemporal Consumer Theory and the Demand for
Durables." Econometrica, 42(3), 1974, 497-516.
Dunn, K, and K J. Singleton. "Modelling the Term Structure of
Interest Rates under Nonseparable Utility and the Durability of
Goods." Journal of Financial Economics, 17(1), 1986, 27-55.
Eichenbaum, M., and L. Hansen. "Estimating Models with
Intertemporal Substitution Using Aggregate Time Series Data."
Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 8(1), 1990, 53-69.
Eichenbaum, M., L. Hansen, and K Singleton. "A Time Series
Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and
Leisure." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 1988, 51-78.
Elbadawi, I., A. R. Gallant, and G. Souza. "An Elasticity Can
Be Estimated Consistently without Prior Knowledge of Functional
Form." Econometrica, 51(6), 1983, 1731-51.
Fisher, D., and A. R. Fleissig. "Monetary Aggregation and the
Demand for Monetary Assets." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
29(4), 1997, 458-75.
Fisher, D., A. R. Fleissig, and A. Serletis. "An Empirical
Comparison of Flexible Demand System Functional Forms." Journal of
Applied Econometrics, 16(1), 2001, 59-80.
Feldstein, M. "Government Deficits and Aggregate Demand."
Journal of Monetary Economics, 9(1), 1982, 1-20.
Fleissig, A. "The Consumer Consumption Conundrum: An
Explanation." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29(2), 1997,
177-91.
Fleissig, A., and J. Swofford. "A Dynamic Asymptotically Ideal
Demand for Money." Journal of Monetary Economics, 37(2), 1996,
371-80.
-----. "Dynamic Asymptotically Ideal Models and Finite
Approximation." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15(4),
1997, 482-92.
Gallant, A. "On the Bias in Flexible Functional Forms and an
Essentially Unbiased Form: The Fourier Flexible Form." Journal of
Econometrics, 15(2), 1981, 211-45.
Graham, F. "Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand: Comment."
American Economic Review, 83(3), 1993, 659-56.
Graham, F., and D. Himarios, "Fiscal Policy and Private
Consumption: Instrumental Variables Tests of the Consolidated
Approach." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 23(1), 1991,
53-67.
Hall, R. "The Stochastic Implications of the Life-Cycle
Permanent Income Hypothesis." Journal of Political Economy, 6(6),
1978, 971-87.
Kormendi, R. "Government Debt, Government Spending, and
Private Sector Behavior." American Economic Review, 73(5), 1983,
994-1010.
Musgrave, J. "Durable Goods Owned by Consumers in the United
States, 1925-77." Survey of Current Business, 59(3), 1979, 17-25.
Ni, S. "An Empirical Analysis on the Substitutability between
Private Consumption and Government Purchases." Journal of Monetary
Economics, 36(3), 1995, 593-605.
Pollak, R., and T Wales. Demand System Specification and
Estimation. New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.
Reid, B. "Aggregate Consumption and Deficit Financing: An
Attempt to Separate Permanent from Transitory Effects." Economic
Inquiry, 23(3), 1985, 475-86.
Seater, J. "Ricardian Equivalence." Journal of Economic
Literature, 31(1), 1993, 142-90.
RELATED ARTICLE: ABBREVIATIONS
CES: Constant Elasticity of Substitution
NIPA: U.S. National Income and Product Accounts
ADRIAN R. FLEISSIG and ROBERT J. ROSSANA *
* We are indebted to Basma Bekdache, Shawn Ni, and John J. Seater
for comments on an earlier draft of this article. Two anonymous referees
provided many useful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies regarding
the limitations of our analysis.
Flessig: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, California
State University at Fullerton, Fullerton, CA 92834, Phone
1-714-278-3816, Fax 1-714-278-1387, E-mail afleissig@fullerton.edu
Rossana: Professor, Department of Economics, 2074 FAB, Wayne State
University, Detroit, MI 48202. Phone 1-313-577-3760, Fax 1-313-577-0149,
E-mail r.j.rossana@wayne.edu