On the third law of demand.
Razzolini, Laura ; Shughart, William F., II ; Tollison, Robert D. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The Alchian and Allen (1967, 63-64) theorem, sometimes elevated to
the status of a third law of demand, as in Bertonazzi et al. (1993), is
a clever application of the fundamental principle of economizing
behavior. As usually stated, the theorem suggests that by reducing the
price of higher quality relative to lower quality versions of the same
good, a fixed transportation charge will trigger a predictable shift in
the mix of quality grades purchased by consumers in distant markets, as
compared to the mix purchased locally. Producers will respond rationally
to this difference in behavior. Relatively more high-quality goods will
be included in outbound shipments, leaving more low-quality goods to be
sold nearer the point of origin. Hence, other things being the same, the
theorem predicts that it will be harder to find "good" apples
in the State of Washington, a prime apple-growing region, than in, say,
New York City, where "bad" apples are comparatively more
expensive. The first law of demand still holds, of co urse, in that
fewer apples of both types will be consumed in New York than in Seattle,
ceteris paribus.
Similarly, given that the cost of a babysitter will be the same no
matter where the parents of young children decide to spend the evening
Out, they are more likely than an otherwise identical childless couple
to choose an upscale restaurant over an inexpensive eatery and to go to
the theater rather than to the movies. Moreover, if both couples plan to
see a play or a concert, the couple with children will opt for better
seats.
The foregoing examples indicate that the Alchian and Allen theorem
is rich in empirical implications. In what follows, however, we show
that placed in the context of a market model, its range of applications
is narrower than has been acknowledged in the literature heretofore.
More specifically, our analysis demonstrates that a fixed charge
unambiguously reduces the price of a higher-quality good, relative to a
lower-quality version of the same good, only when that good is sold by a
perfectly competitive, constant-cost industry. Under increasing-cost
conditions or imperfectly competitive industry structures, by contrast,
it is possible for relative prices either to be unaffected by the
addition of a fixed charge or, indeed, for the lower-quality good to
become relatively cheaper in distant markets, depending on the
elasticity characteristics of relevant market demand and supply
functions.
Our analysis is in no way intended as an attack on Alchian and
Allen or their fine textbook, which has taught more than one generation
of economists to be better price theorists. We do not quarrel in the
least with the pedagogical value of their theorem, which has been
immense. Our purpose is to identify some plausible scenarios under which
the third law of demand may fail to hold.
The present article is thus in the spirit of Yang and Stitt (1995),
who show that the Ramsey (1927) rule for optimal commodity taxation is
changed in important ways when the assumption of constant production
costs is relaxed. It is organized as follows. In the next section, the
fundamentals of the Alchian and Allen theorem are described in more
detail and its predictions are situated within the existing literature.
Section III explores the theorem's operations under alternative
cost conditions and industry structures. Factors complicating the
analysis of the effects of a fixed charge on the relative prices of
high-and low-quality goods are also addressed in this section. Finally,
section IV contains some concluding remarks.
II. SHIPPING THE GOOD APPLES OUT
To borrow an example from a classic statement of the Alchian and
Allen theorem, (1) suppose that "good" Washington apples sell
for 10 cents each in Seattle and "bad" apples each cost a
nickel there. Because the price of a good apple is twice that of a bad
apple, Seattle's consumers must sacrifice the opportunity of buying
two bad apples to obtain a good one. Now suppose further that,
regardless of quality, it costs 5 cents to ship an apple to the East
Coast and, moreover, that the transportation charges are fully passed on
to consumers. Under these assumptions, good apples sell for 15 cents in
the East and bad apples sell for 10 cents. The price of a good apple in
the East is only one and a half times--not two times--the price of a bad
apple. Good apples are cheaper on the East Coast, and consumers there
will consequently want to buy more of them. Hence, although fewer apples
will be consumed overall on the East Coast than on the West Coast (to
reiterate , the first law of demand still applies), shipments to markets
in the East will include more generous mixes of good apples.
More formally, if [p.sub.H] and [p.sub.L] are the unit prices of
higher- and lower-quality versions of the same good (with [p.sub.H] >
[p.sub.L])' the Alchian and Allen theorem exploits the observation
that ([p.sub.H] + t)/([p.sub.L] + t) < [p.sub.H]/[p.sub.L], where t
is a constant unit cost of transportation or some other fixed charge
that applies equally to both quality grades. (2) The third law of demand
also works in both directions: Silberberg (1990, 386) and Bertonazzi et
al. (1993) show that the price of the higher-quality good falls relative
to the lower-quality good whether the good is shipped to the consumer or
the consumer travels to the point of purchase.
As initially expounded, the Alchian and Allen theorem did not
consider interactions with other goods entering the representative
consumer's utility function. (3) Applying the composite commodity
theorem, however, Borcherding and Silberberg (1978) prove that in a
three-good world where consumers optimize their expenditures over two
quality grades of one good plus some other, third good, the addition of
transportation costs t will indeed trigger an increase in the amount
consumed of the higher-quality good relative to that of the
lower-quality good. This result holds provided that the two quality
grades are substitutes for one another (the compensated cross-price
elasticity of demand between them is positive), (4) and that the higher-
and lower-quality versions of the one good have the same interactions
with the third good. "Same" means that ceteris paribus
increases in the prices of the higher quality and lower quality good
have identical effects on the quantities consumed of the other good
(i.e., their compen sated cross-price elasticities with respect to the
composite commodity are equal in magnitude). Stated in reverse, the
Alchian and Allen theorem fails to hold only in an asymmetrical case
where the third good is a better substitute for the higher-quality good
than it is for the lower-quality good, a possibility that seems
"empirically insignificant" to Silberberg (1990, 388). (5)
A second complication arises when t represents a charge for a
complementary good or service that enters the consumer's utility
function directly and that, in principle, can be purchased separately.
Consider, for example, the impact of the cost of traveling to New York
City on the prices of first-class versus second-class hotel
accommodations or of full-sized versus economy-sized rental cars. The
analysis of such cases would seem to depend on the extent to which
purchases of the higher- and lower-quality versions of the good in
question respond to changes in the price of a third good (airline
tickets, say). Indeed, Cowen and Tabarrok (1995) argue that the Alchian
and Allen theorem may not hold when a product with two quality grades is
bundled with some other good. However, Umbeck (1980) and, more recently,
Bertonazzi et al. (1993) reach the opposite conclusion, namely, that the
theorem helps explain some common forms of commodity bundling. Packaging
airline reservations with rental cars, hotel rooms, or cruise ship cabin
assignments not only lowers the relative prices of higher quality grades
of these goods at the traveler's destination but also ensures that
the third law of demand operates by making it less likely that the
airfare will be treated as a sunk cost on arrival, thereby nullifying
its impact on relative prices. (6)
In sum, comparative-static analyses of responses to the
introduction of a fixed charge that raises the prices of two quality
grades of the same good by the same absolute amount thus suggest that
other things being the same, the utility-maximizing consumer will tend
to buy relatively more of the higher-quality grade. This result seems to
be robust under the stated conditions, the only proviso being that, when
the prices of both quality grades rise, consumers do not substitute some
other product in greater proportion for the higher-quality good than
they substitute for the lower-quality good.
Although the usual analysis of the Alchian and Allen theorem
examines the behavior of the utility-maximizing consumer, it is silent
on the behavior of the seller. (7) The literature has failed to ask and
answer the following question: Faced with a fixed cost of shipping two
quality grades of the same good to a distant location, under what
circumstances will the profit-maximizing firm actually raise both prices
by the same absolute Amount? Does the Alchian and Allen theorem operate
generally when the firm and industry are taken into account, or is its
application restricted to particular market conditions? More
specifically, under what circumstances can the opposite of Alchian and
Allen's conjecture occur? Is it possible for more of the bad apples
to be shipped out because [p'.sub.H]/[p'.sub.L] >
[p.sub.H]/[p.sub.L], where [p'.sub.H] and [p'.sub.L] are the
new prices inclusive of transportation costs? These questions are
explored in the following section.
III. THE ALCHIAN AND ALLEN THEOREM IN A MARKET CONTEXT
The analysis of the impact of a fixed charge t on the relative
prices of higher- and lower-quality versions of the same good has much
in common with textbook treatments of the incidence of an excise
(per-unit) tax. In both cases, the critical question is, if marginal
production costs rise by t, how much of the increase will be passed on
to consumers in the form of higher prices and how much of it will be
borne by sellers in the form of lower profits (or inframarginal rents)?
Although the Alchian and Allen theorem does not require the prices
of higher- and lower-quality goods to both rise by the full amount of
the fixed charge (although this is the usual simplifying assumption),
there would seem to be two market situations in which this result would
in fact obtain. One is when shipping charges are invoiced separately,
that is, pricing is f.o.b. The other is when the good in question is
supplied by a perfectly competitive, constant-cost industry, so that the
prices to consumers in distant markets rise by the full amount of the
cost of shipping the product to them. More generally, the higher-quality
good becomes unambiguously cheaper relative to the lower-quality good
only if the two prices rise by the same absolute amount (which may be
more or less than t), or if the price of the lower-quality grade rises
proportionately more than that of the higher-quality grade.
Perfect Competition
Consider a perfectly competitive, increasing cost industry in a
simple partial equilibrium setting. The analysis is depicted in Figure
1. In absence of transportation costs, equilibrium in the two markets
for lower- and higher-quality grades of a product is attained where
supply equals demand and the equation D([p.sub.i]) = S([p.sub.i]), i =
H, L is satisfied. Any competitive producer faces a perfectly elastic
demand d at price [P.sup.*.sub.i] and initially supplies a corresponding
quantity [q.sup.*.sub.i].
Now consider the introduction of transportation costs at rate t per
unit. Such charges are added to the marginal cost of each supplier;
therefore, each will offer a smaller quantity [q'.sub.i].
Graphically, in the overall markets, the introduction of the
transportation charge can be depicted as an upward shift in the supply
curve facing consumers by the amount of t. The new equilibrium will
satisfy the condition D([P'.sub.i] - t), = S([P'.sub.i] - t),
i = H, L.
We need to characterize the changes in equilibrium that result from
the introduction of the transportation costs. Differentiating the above
equation we get d[p.sub.i] = S'/(S' - D'), where S'
= dS/d[p.sub.i], and D' = dD/d[p.sub.i]. More conveniently, we can
write this condition in terms of the elasticities of supply and of
demand for the two types of goods, viz, d[p.sub.H]/dt =
[[epsilon].sup.H.sub.S]/([[epsilon].sup.H.sub.S] -
[[epsilon].sup.H.sub.D]) and d[p.sub.L]/dt =
[[epsilon].sup.L.sub.S]/([[epsilon].sup.L.sub.S] -
[[epsilon].sup.L.sub.D]), where [[epsilon].sup.i.sub.S] > 0 and
[[epsilon].sup.i.sub.D] < 0 are, respectively, the elasticity of
supply and of demand for a good of quality i = H, L. In general, the
greater is the elasticity of supply, the larger will be the price
increase induced by the introduction of transportation costs; the
greater is the elasticity of demand, the smaller the price increase will
be.
The Alchian and Allen theorem is not about any arbitrary pair of
goods, however. It is about two quality grades of the same good whose
supplies are jointly determined. Thus the theorem applies, for example,
to a denim factory where, owing to random variations in the quality of
cotton and dyes or mistakes in cutting and sewing, some finished items
turn out to be substandard. If, consistent with the theorem, we assume
that the supply elasticities of the higher- and lower-quality versions
of the good are equal ("good" and "bad" apples come
from the same tree, say), then the higher-quality good will become
relatively cheaper either if the demand elasticities are the same or if
the demand for the lower-quality good is relatively less elastic than
the demand for the higher quality good. However, in the empirically
plausible case where the demand for the lower-quality good is relatively
more elastic than the demand for the higher-quality good, then the
effects on relative prices are reversed (i.e., the high-quality good
becomes dearer). (8)
Monopoly
The analysis of monopoly proceeds analogously. Consider a single
producer supplying two quality grades of a good. The monopolist's
cost function is C([Q.sub.H] + [Q.sub.L]) = C(Q), with marginal cost
C'. The monopolist faces demand curves [p.sub.H]([Q.sub.H]) and
[p.sub.L]([Q.sub.L]). (9) Profit maximization requires choosing
quantities to produce so that the marginal revenue in the two markets is
the same, namely, [p.sub.L][1 + (1/[[epsilon].sup.L.sub.D])] = [p.sub.H]
[1 + (1/[[epsilon].sup.H.sub.D])].
From this profit-maximizing rule, we see that the price tends to be
higher for the good with a lower price elasticity of demand. That is,
the monopolist will charge a higher price in the market with the less
elastic demand curve. Hence, [p.sub.H] > [P.sub.L] implies
[[epsilon].sup.H.sub.D] > [[epsilon].sup.L.sub.D].
Consider now the introduction of transportation costs t. The
monopolist's cost function becomes C([Q.sub.H] + [Q.sub.L]) +
t([Q.sub.H] + [Q.sub.L]) = C(Q) + t(Q). First-order conditions for
profit maximization now require that [p.sub.i] +
(d[p.sub.i]/d[Q.sub.i])[Q.sub.i] - (C' + t) = 0, i = H, L. Solving
these conditions, we get the optimal quantities and prices to charge as
a function of the transportation costs: [Q.sup.*.sub.L] = [g.sub.L](t)
and [Q.sup.*.sub.H] = [g.sub.H](t); [p.sup.*.sub.L] =
[p.sub.L]([Q.sup.*.sub.L]) and [p.sup.*.sub.H] =
[p.sub.H]([Q.sup.*.sub.H]). As before, we can investigate the effect of
the introduction of the transportation costs by calculating
d[Q.sup.*.sub.L]/dt = [g'.sub.L](t) and d[Q.sup.*.sub.H]/dt =
[g'.sub.H](t); d[p.sup.*.sub.L]/dt =
[p'.sub.L](.)[g'.sub.L](t) and d[p.sup.*.sub.H]/dt =
[p'.sub.H](.)[g'.sub.H](t).
The implicit function theorem yields [g'.sub.i](t) =
1/[2(d[p.sub.i]/d[Q.sub.i]) +
[Q.sub.i]([d.sup.2][p.sub.i]/[d.sup.2][Q.sub.i]) - C'], i = H, L.
The term [g'.sub.i](t) is negative by the second-order conditions
for profit maximization. The profit-maximizing monopolist, like the
competitive supplier, therefore reduces output when marginal costs
increase. Furthermore, d[p.sup.*.sub.L]/dt > 0 and
d[p.sup.*.sub.H]/dt > 0. That is, the prices of both the higher-and
lower-quality goods will increase after the introduction of the
transportation costs. More specifically, we have d[p.sup.*.sub.i]/dt =
(d[p.sup.*.sub.i]/d[Q.sup.*.sub.i])/[2(d[p.sub.i]/d[Q.sub.i]) +
[Q.sub.i] ([d.sup.2][p.sub.i]/[d.sup.2][Q.sub.i]) - C"], i = H, L.
With a linear cost function (i.e., C" = 0) and linear demand
schedules (i.e., [d.sup.2][p.sub.i]/[d.sup.2][Q.sub.i] = 0), the prices
of both quality grades rise by exactly one-half t (i.e.,
d[p.sup.*.sub.L]/dt = d[p.sup.*.sub.H]/dt = 1/2), and the higher quality
good becomes relatively cheaper, as the Alchian and Allen theorem
predicts. On the other hand, with a linear cost function and constant
elasticity demand schedules of the form [p.sub.i] =
A[Q.sup.1]/[[epsilon].sub.i].sub.i], where [[epsilon].sub.i] is the
constant elasticity of demand for a good of quality i, we obtain
d[p.sup.*.sub.i]/dt = [[epsilon].sub.i]/([[epsilon].sub.i] + 1), i = H,
L. In this case, the price increases by
[[epsilon].sub.i]/([[epsilon].sub.i] + 1) [greater than or equal to] 1
times the transportation costs. Therefore, the more elastic the demand
schedule is, the more the price will increase. Given our previous
observation that [[epsilon].sub.H] < [[epsilon].sub.L], we conclude
that the price will increase relatively more for the lower-quality good,
the one with the more elastic demand.
Stated in another form, the higher-quality grade becomes relatively
cheaper if the demand elasticities for the two quality grades are the
same or if the demand for the lower-quality good is relatively less
elastic than the demand for the higher-quality good. Neither of these
possibilities seems plausible empirically. In fact, the opposite is more
likely to be true, namely, that the demand for the higher-quality good
will be less elastic than the demand for the lower-quality good. (10)
There are numerous reasons for this, including investments in brand-name
capital, fewer substitutes for the higher-quality good, and so on. If
that is the case, then more "bad" apples will be shipped out
because they are relatively cheaper in distant markets.
IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Perhaps the best way of thinking about our analysis is that it
recasts the Alchian and Allen theorem as a testable proposition. In the
same spirit as Cheung's (1973) examination of apple growing and
beekeeping and Coase's (1974) inquiry into the history of
lighthouses, there is a need to replace casual observation and
conjecture with careful empirical studies of whether relatively more
good apples are in fact shipped out. (11) Although such studies await
the attentions of enterprising empiricists, we note that the
proliferation of factory outlet malls along the U.S. interstate highway
system suggests that the predictions of the Alchian and Allen theorem
are ambiguous. Most of the stores in these malls sell factory
"seconds," or dated goods; very few of them (if any) sell
"firsts," or offer consumers the range of choices available at
traditional shopping malls or department stores. Factory outlets were
literally at the factory when these stores first began to appear, as the
standard version of the theorem sugg ests they should be. Today,
however, it seems that market conditions have changed so that more of
the "bad" apples are being shipped out. Although the dominance
of seconds in factory outlet malls away from production centers is
consistent with our analysis, a systematic study would be useful.
As this article shows, such a study must take market supply and
demand conditions fully into account. In particular, the analysis
presented herein suggests that the addition of a fixed charge
unambiguously reduces the price of a higher-quality good, relative to a
lower-quality version of the same good, only when that good is sold by a
perfectly competitive, constant-cost industry. Under increasing-cost
conditions or imperfectly competitive industry structures, by contrast,
it is possible for relative prices either to be unaffected by the
introduction of the fixed charge, or, indeed, for the lower-quality good
to become relatively cheaper in distant markets. Will a fixed
transportation charge cause producers to ship the "good"
apples out? The answer is that it depends. It depends on the elasticity
characteristics of relevant market demand and supply functions. In the
empirically plausible case where the demand for the high-quality good is
less elastic than the demand for the low-quality good, more
"bad" apples will be shipped out to distant markets because
they are relatively cheaper there.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
(1.) Silberberg (1990, 386) staled the theorem in response to a
complaint published in the Troubleshooler column of the Seattle Times of
Sunday, 19 October 1975, in which an irate consumer demanded to know why
the apples available in local markets were so "small and odd
looking." "where," the writer asked, "do the big
Delicious apples go? Are they shipped to Europe, to the East or can they
be bought here in Seattle?" After explaining the impact of shipping
charges on the relative prices of good and bad apples on the East Coast,
Silberberg remarked that, "It is no conspiracy--just the laws of
supply and demand."
(2.) The assumption that transportation costs do not vary with the
quality of the good shipped is somewhat unrealistic--higher-quality
goods may be packed more securely and handled more carefully. But given
that weight and volume are the chief determinants of the costs of
transportation, the assumption does not do too much violence to reality.
Another possibility arises when transportation charges are subject to
economic regulation. In that case, the regulatory agency may promulgate rate schedules wherein shipping charges are not constant but instead
vary with the elasticities of demand for different quality grades of a
product.
(3.) Gould and Segall (1969), for example, suggested that the
theorem might not operate in a three-good world.
(4.) This is also a necessary condition for the Alchian and Allen
theorem to hold in the two-good case.
(5.) Silberberg (1990, 389) reasons that the Alchian and Allen
theorem would be expected to hold for most goods, assuming that the
higher- and lower-quality grades of the same good are "fairly close
substitutes" (so that the absolute values of their own- and
cross-price elasticities are relatively large) and that these goods are
not closely related to the composite commodity (so that the cross-price
effects with it are "fairly small, even if not approximately
equal").
(6.) The Alchian and Allen theorem, in other words, is about ex
ante decision making. It is not about two-part tariffs whereby, as a
strategy for replicating the profitability of price discrimination of
the first degree, consumers are charged nonrefundable lump-sum fees for
the right to purchase one or more products at a discount. The relative
prices of higher- and lower-quality grades of a good or service sold
under a two-part tariff are unaffected once the fee has been paid.
(7.) An exception is Barzel (1976), who explores incentives on the
part of the seller to adjust product quality in response to the
imposition of a per-unit tax. The burden of a tax levied on loaves of
bread, for example, can be reduced by increasing the size of the loaf.
Sobel and Garrett (1997) find empirical support for this proposition in
the market for cigarettes. An alternative model in which changes in
relative prices produce changes in quality is contained in Leffler
(1982), who assumes that a product's quality attributes are not
fully reflected in its price and hence requires price and quality to be
determined jointly. Such price-induced changes in product quality
obviously complicate the analysis considerably, and the corresponding
shifts in demand can easily confound the Alchian and Allen theorem.
However, our discussion stays within the theorem's original
framework, which treats quality differences as fully reflected in price
differences and holds demand curves in place.
(8.) A price increase of less than t is consistent with equilibrium
in a competitive market when producers encounter increasing costs. In
that case, demand in the away market is filled by inframarginal firms
whose supply prices (inclusive of transportation) are
[p.sup.'.sub.i] or less (see Figure 1). The impact of t on the
relative price of high-versus low-quality goods then hinges on their
respective elasticities of demand. With constant costs, by contrast, the
prices of both quality grades must rise fully by t and, hence, the
high-quality good necessarily becomes relatively cheaper.
(9.) We are assuming that the two types of good are independent, in
the sense that the price charged in one market does not influence the
demand in the other market. Assuming alternatively that high- and
low-quality grades are substitutes for one another strengthens our
results. If, for example, the introduction of transportation charges
causes a decline in the relative price of the high-quality good, then
consumers would shift their purchases even more so away from the
low-quality good in favor of the high-quality good than they would if
the two goods are independent in demand.
(10.) Barron et al. (2000, 550), for example, report that
"within the Los Angeles Basin area ... the average dealer margin
for self-service premium unleaded gasoline was 58.7% higher than the
average margin for self-service regular gasoline for the 1992-1995
period." Higher retail margins imply that the demand for premium
unleaded gasoline is less elastic than the demand for regular unleaded
gasoline, ceteris paribus.
(11.) Bertonazzi et al. (1993) and Sobel and Garrett (1997) have
gotten this literature off to a good start.
REFERENCES
Alchian, A. A., and W R. Allen. University Economics, 2d ed.
Belmont, CA: Wadsworth, 1967.
Barron, J. M., B. A. Taylor, and J. R. Umbeck. "A Theory of
Quality-Related Differences in Retail Margins: Why There Is a
'Premium' on Premium Gasoline." Economic Inquiry, 38(4),
2000, 550-69.
Barzel, Y. "An Alternative Approach to the Analysis of
Taxation." Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), 1976, 1177-97.
Bertonazzi, E., M. T. Maloney, and R. E. McCormick. "Some
Evidence on the Alchian and Allen Theorem: The Third Law of
Demand?" Economic Inquiry, 31(3), 1993, 383-93.
Borcherding, T. E., and E. Silberberg. "Shipping the Good
Apples Out: The Alehian and Allen Theorem Reconsidered." Journal of
Political Economy, 86(1), 1978, 131-38.
Cheung, S. N. S. "The Fable of the Bees: An Economic
Investigation." Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 1973, 371-84.
Coase, R. H. "The Lighthouse in Economics." Journal of
Law and Economics, 17(2), 1974, 357-76.
Cowen, T, and A. Tabarrok. "Good Grapes and Bad Lobsters: The
Alchian and Allen Theorem Revisited." Economic Inquiry, 33(2),
1995, 253-56.
Gould, J., and J. Segall. "The Substitution Effects of
Transportation Costs." Journal of Political Economy, 77(1), 1969,
130-37.
Leffler, K. B. "Ambiguous Changes in Product Quality."
American Economic Review, 72(5), 1982, 956-67.
Ramsey, F. P. "A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation."
Economic Journal, 37(145), 1927, 47-61.
Silberberg, E. The Structure of Economics: A Mathematical Analysis,
2d ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990.
Sobel, R. S., and T A. Garrett. "Taxation and Product Quality:
New Evidence from Generic Cigarettes." Journal of Political
Economy, 105(4), 1997, 880-87.
Umbeck, J. R. "Shipping the Good Apples Out: Some Ambiguities
in the Interpretation of 'Fixed Charge.' "Journal of
Political Economy, 88(1), 1980, 199-208.
Yang, C. W, and K. R. Stitt. "The Ramsey Rule Revisited."
Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 1995, 767-74.
LAURA RAZZOLINI, WILLIAM F. SHUGHART II, and ROBERT D. TOLLISON *
* We benefited from the comments of Donald Boudreaux, Dennis
Coates, Fred McChesney, Tim Sass, Russell Sobel, John Sophocles, and two
anonymous referees. Michael Reksulak supplied valuable research
assistance. As is customary, however, we take full responsibility for
any remaining errors. We acknowledge financial support from the Robert
M. Hearin Support Foundation. Laura Razzolini also acknowledges
financial support from the National Science Foundation, grant
SBR-9973731. The views expressed in this article are the authors'
and do not necessarily represent those of the National Science
Foundation.
Razzolini: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University
of Mississippi, P.O. Box 1848, University, MS 38677-1848, and Program
Director for Economics, National Science Foundation, 4201 Wilson
Boulevard, Room 995, Arlington, VA 22230. Phone 1-703-292-7267, Fax
1-703-292-9068, E-mail lrazzoli@nsf.gov
Shughart: Professor, Department of Economics, University of
Mississippi, P.O. Box 1848, University, MS 38677-1848. Phone
1-662-915-7579, Fax 1-662-915-6943, E-mail shughart@olemiss.edu
Tollison: Professor, Department of Economics, University of
Mississippi, P.O. Box 1848, University, MS 38677-1848. Phone
1-662-915-5041, Fax 1-662-915-6943, E-mail rdtollis@olemiss.edu