The supply side of the digital divide: is there equal availability in the broadband Internet access market?
Prieger, James E.
I. INTRODUCTION
The Internet has transformed the way Americans work, play, and
shop. A new wave of Internet accessibility, the availability of
broadband (high-speed) access, has the potential to be as revolutionary
as the first wave. Broadband access, usually through Digital Subscriber
Line (DSL) or cable modem technology for residences and leased lines for
businesses, allows users to send and receive enormous quantities of
data, audio, video, and voice communication and relaxes the constraints of the "World Wide Wait." With every technological revolution
comes the possibility that some will be left behind. The so-called
digital divide-the well-documented gap in computer and Internet usage
between richer and poorer households, whites and certain minority
groups, and urban and rural areas (1)-has received much attention in the
past few years, both in policy circles and the popular press.
The public-policy focus on the digital divide is shifting toward
broadband Internet access. In a widely cited report, the Department of
Commerce (National Telecommunications and Information Administration
[NTIA], 2000) finds that in terms of household broadband subscription,
black and Hispanic households lag white households, rural areas lag
urban areas, and poorer households lag more affluent households. Such
findings commingle nonadoption of broadband access by households and
non-implementation of the technology by carriers. One unanswered
question, therefore, is whether groups lacking broadband access are
deprived because broadband services are not available where they live.
Preliminary findings by the Federal Communications Commission (FCC,
2000a) indicate that broadband is less likely to be available in rural
and lower-income areas. Although lacking direct evidence, the FCC
(2000a, 241) furthermore concludes that "minority customers are
vulnerable to not having access to advanced services in as timely a
fashion as most other Americans."
Faulhaber and Hogendorn (2000) conclude from a model based on
engineering data that the unconstrained market at maturity will leave at
least 12% of U.S. households without broadband availability, due to cost
and demand considerations. Findings such as these lead some observers
and interest groups to charge that market forces are leading to the
unequal availability of broadband, (2) with some advocates going as far
as charging broadband carriers with "redlining." (3)
These charges warrant careful study for three reasons. First,
federal policies currently proposed to narrow the broadband digital
divide are based on an incomplete examination of the data. Such policies
include a host of pending legislation in the 107th Congress. (4) The FCC
is also actively involved in monitoring the digital divide, because it
is charged by the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (5) to monitor and
encourage the "reasonable and timely" deployment of broadband
to "all Americans." Although it has not done so yet, the FCC
has the authority to add broadband to the list of services supported
under federal Universal Service programs if it deems necessary. Second,
because availability is a precondition for access, any analysis of the
digital divide must begin with the supply side. Third, broadband is an
important technology whose study advances the empirical literature on
the economics of diffusion.
This study explores the causes of the unequal availability of
broadband. Do the racial composition, income, and rural location of an
area affect whether broadband is available? The results contain some
surprises. Simple regressions imply that high concentrations of poor,
minority, and rural households decrease the probability of broadband
access. However, after controlling for cost conditions, other demand
factors, and competition in local telephony, the income and minority
effects largely disappear. Among racial composition factors, only those
for Native Americans and Asians have significant negative effects on
broadband availability. Those for blacks, ethnic Hispanics, and other
nonwhite races have no significant impact. Even for Native Americans and
Asians, the negative effects on access disappear in some areas when
language of the household is taken into account. Furthermore, a
nonparametric investigation shows the evidence for the disadvantage of
Native Americans and Asians is inconsistent across the ran ge of the
race variables. More important determinants of broadband availability
are demand characteristics, such as age, education, commuting time to
work, gender ratio, and size of businesses in the area.
A few studies have looked at demand for broadband services by
individuals (Madden et al., 2000; NTIA, 2000). Fewer studies have looked
at the supply side of the market, in large part due to the difficulty of
gathering data on DSL and cable modem rollouts. A new, nearly
comprehensive broadband survey by the FCC enables study of the supply of
broadband for the first time using data from the entire United States.
My approach is closest to that of Gabel and Kwan (2001), who study
broadband availability at 287 wire centers. (6) The present study, on
the other hand, covers services offered through nearly all of the more
than 22,000 wire centers. Gillett and Lehr (1999) study cable modem
access in the 3,133 U.S. counties. Counties are relatively large for the
purpose of determining broadband coverage, given, for example, that DSL
is typically available only within 3.5 miles of a central office. The
present study takes the ZIP code to be the unit of observation, yielding
a potential 29,769 observations. The next sect ion discusses
implications of using ZIP code areas.
The next section outlines the empirical strategy I use to
investigate the causes of the unequal availability of broadband. Section
III overviews broadband technology, section IV describes the data,
section V presents the results, and a final section discusses policy
implications.
II. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY
As in Berry's (1992) model of airline entry, I model the
decision by a broadband carrier to enter a geographic market as
depending on the expected demand in the area, costs, and entry by other
firms. Unlike Berry (1992), I employ reduced-form models. The main
estimations are probit models on a binary variable for broadband
availability of any type in a ZIP code area, and model entry as a
flexible function of regional demographic, economic, and competitive
information. The empirical strategy is to examine the coefficients on
the variables reflecting minority composition, rural location, and
low-income areas, because of the policy concern that these areas are
vulnerable to lagging in broadband access. Previous governmental studies
have emphasized the race, income, and rural dimensions of the digital
divide (FCC, 2000b; NTJA, 2000), but those studies examine each variable
in isolation through simple cross-tabulations without controls.
Interpreting results from such studies requires care, as the following
illustr ation shows.
Jump ahead for the moment to the first results reported in section
V, from a simple estimation including variables for minorities,
urban/rural location, and fixed effects for Bell companies and states
only. The negative and significant coefficient on % black indicates that
the higher the percentage of blacks in an area, the lower the
probability of broadband access. Studies of redlining in the mortgage
lending market, such as Tootell (1996), point out that there are three
possible reasons for such a finding. First, the relationship could be
causal, due to entrants' expectations that black households have
lower demand for broadband service. In this case, carriers do not enter
because they expect profit to be too low to support entry. Second, the
relationship could be causal, but in this case based not solely on
expected profit but on Becker's (1971) "taste for
discrimination." In this case, carriers do not enter some areas
even though they would support entry merely because of racial
discrimination. This secon d case comes closest to redlining in the
broadband market, although minority advocates using the term often do
not distinguish between these two cases.
In the third possible reason, the apparent relationship between
black household concentration and access is spurious, due to omitted
variables that are positively correlated with black concentration and
negatively correlated with entry. An example of such an omitted variable
is the quality of the telecommunications infrastructure in an area.
Areas with high concentrations of black households may tend to have
older infrastructure, and therefore higher costs of deploying DSL or
cable modem networks.
To distinguish the first two (causal relationship) hypotheses from
the third (spurious relationship) hypothesis, in a second set of
estimations I include a host of socioeconomic and competitive controls.
A major advantage that the large sample size of this study lends is the
ability to control for many demand and cost variables that previous
studies such as Gillett and Lehr (1999) and Gabel and Kwan (2001)
omitted. Adding these extra variables removes the significance of most
of the income and race coefficients, with a few exceptions discussed
later.
To distinguish between profit-based discrimination and taste for
discrimination based on racial composition of the area, I supplement the
race variables with language variables. If carriers discriminate against
minority areas, it is plausible that they would discriminate against
both nonwhite race and non-English language usage. The evidence below
shows, however, that non-English language usage tends to increase access
availability. The case for preference-based discrimination is thus weak,
and any discrimination is more likely to be profit-based (probably based
on expected demand).
In the rest of this section I explore implications of two features
of the data: lack of subscribership data and using ZIP code-level data.
First, note that the data tell us nothing about the scale of entry
within each area. Lack of information on the scale of entry is common in
entry studies in the industrial organization literature, such as
Bresnahan and Reiss (1987) and Berry (1992). Using a binary entry
variable requires using a probit model, instead of using the number of
subscribers in a tobit model. The estimates may be less precise in the
probit than in the tobit, because there is less information in a binary
variable (entry) than in a mixed continuous/discrete variable
(subscribers) but will still be consistent if the model is correctly
specified.
The data use ZIP code areas as the boundary for the unit of
observation. Although ZIP codes are an improvement over previous studies
using larger areas, it is still true that broadband may not be available
to all parts of the ZIP code area, which creates potential difficulty in
interpreting the results. Unequal availability within an area is not
from carriers choosing individual households to which to offer
broadband; once the local cable network or central office has been
upgraded to offer broadband, the service is available to most
subscribers in the service area. (7) Instead, uneven availability within
a ZIP code area is due to the irregular overlap with service areas.
Thus, one consequence of using ZIP code areas is that broadband
diffusion is overstated. To see this, note that from Table 1, 70% of ZIP
code areas in the sample have broadband access. However, various sources
indicate that at the beginning of 2000, cable modem service was
available to only about one-third of households and DSL to only one-q
uarter of households in the United States. (8)
Uneven availability within a ZIP code is a problem mostly in rural
areas, where both service areas and ZIP code areas are large. This is
one reason why the coefficients for the urban/rural indicators need to
be interpreted with care, as will be further discussed. The coefficients
for minorities would be biased due to unequal availability within an
area only if minorities are consistently more likely to live in the
uncovered part of the area. However, most minorities live in dense urban
areas, (9) where the local exchange companies central offices are close
together, implying that if DSL is implemented at all, it would probably
be available to all households in the area. For example, San Francisco has 24 ZIP code areas and 12 central offices, none of which are more
than four miles from each other. DSL is typically available within 3.5
miles from the central office, resulting in potentially complete
coverage if DSL were implemented at each central office. Cable modem
service areas are even larger.
III. BROADBAND TECHNOLOGY
Broadband access to the Internet comprises several steps. Consider
DSL first. Starting from the Internet backbone (the left side of Figure
1), data flows through various networks and providers (the "middle
mile") until it reaches the local exchange carrier s central
office. In the "last mile" of the network, data passes over a
DSL connection residing physically on the existing telephone line
between the central office and the residential or business user's
computer (top right, Figure 1). Local exchange carriers have also leased
high-speed access lines (such as T-1 lines) to residences and businesses
for some time (middle right, Figure 1), but their high prices (at least
$450 per month) generally restrict them to high-volume business use. In
cable data networks, data flows from the Internet through the cable
company's head-end (a cable service provider's version of the
local exchange carrier's central office) and on to regional
high-capacity data networks (the middle mile; bottom, Figure 1). In the
last mile o f a cable modem network, data travels through local fiber
optic networks and finally over coaxial cable to the end user (bottom
right, Figure 2). Wireless and satellite carriers also offer broadband
capability, although such firms typically focus on the business market
and have small market share. Thus for residential subscribers, cable
modem service and DSL are currently the broadband options of choice (see
Figures 2 and 3), with cable modems enjoying a three-to-one advantage.
The FCC (2000a) has found that Internet backbone and the middle
mile facilities are generally adequate to provide broadband access. The
last mile, the focus of this article, is currently the limiting factor on the supply side of the market.
IV. DATA
The data for the study come from three major sources: the FCC,
Census, and a telecommunications wire center database. A complete list
of variables and summary statistics for the data are in Table 1.
Broadband Availability Data and Summary
The dependent variable, broadband availability from any source
within a ZIP code, is taken from the FCC's (2000b) broadband survey
reflecting conditions on 30 June 2000. The dependent variable covers all
ZIP codes in the mainland states. (10) Every facilities-based
telecommunications carrier (incumbent and competitive local exchange
carriers, wireless carriers, cable companies, and others) with more than
250 broadband lines in a given state is required to provide basic
information about its operations in that state via the FCC survey. (11)
Carriers not meeting this reporting threshold may submit information
voluntarily, and some did so. Note that this definition raises a
selection issue: The smallest rural carriers may not show up in the
survey even if they offer broadband, which in turn will mean that the
ZIP codes from those areas may falsely be recorded as not having
broadband access. The selection bias is likely to be minor because few
broadband providers would fall below the threshold. For example, curre
nt market analysis indicates that unless there are about 200 lines in a
DSL service area (which is much smaller than a whole state), the
investment will not pay off (Paradyne, 2000, 5-6). Nevertheless, the
coefficients pertaining to rural areas, which may be served by small
rural local exchange carriers with few customers, must be interpreted
with this potential measurement error in mind.
The publicly available data do not indicate the type of company
offering the service. In particular, DSL service is not distinguishable
from cable modem service. The dependent variable in the estimations,
then, is binary: whether there is at least one broadband customer in a
ZIP code.
Table 1 shows that 70% of ZIP code areas in the sample have
broadband access. These ZIP codes include 95% of the population of the
United States; recall from the discussion in section II that this does
not imply that broadband is available to 95% of households. See Figure 4
for a map depicting broadband availability.
Market Characteristics Data
Demand Variables. Factors influencing carriers' expected
subscriber demand for broadband are captured by socioeconomic statistics
at the ZIP code area level. The personal and household data are from the
1990 census. (12) The business data are also from the Census Bureau.
(13)
Race and ethnicity variables include the percentages of black,
Native American (including Eskimo, Aleut, etc.), Asian, and other (white
is the excluded category) persons in the area and the percentages of
persons claiming Hispanic ethnicity. Closely related to race and
ethnicity is language. Non--English-speaking groups may have lower
demand for broadband if they perceive the Internet to consist largely of
English-language content. On the other hand, non--English speakers may
value the opportunities that the Internet affords to connect with
similar speakers across the nation and world. I include variables for
percentages of Spanish-, Asian-, and other language-- speaking
households, and also the percentage of linguistically isolated
households, in which no one speaks English as a first language nor very
well as a second language.
There are two income variables in the study: median income and the
percentage of households below the poverty threshold. Next are controls
for the size of the residential and business markets. The type of firm
may also matter; in other studies manufacturing, finance, insurance, and
real-estate and service-oriented (e.g., management consultants) firms
have proven to be heavy users of telecommunications. I include the
percentage of firms of these types as controls. Because large firms may
have higher demand for broadband, I include two measures of firm size:
log average employment per firm and the percentage of firms with fewer
than 50 employees.
Households are categorized as inside an urbanized area, urban but
outside an urbanized area (mostly smaller towns), rural nonfarm, or
rural farm. Taking urban/outside urbanized area as the excluded
variable, I include variables for the percentage of households of each
of the other types, where the rural areas are split into those served by
Bell operating companies and those served by other local exchange
carriers. Rural non-Bell carriers are often characterized as
technological laggards (although their industry group refutes this
assertion [National Exchange Carrier Associations, 1999]), so Bell
operating companies may act differently in rural areas than other
carriers.
I include variables describing the age profile of an area: the
percentage of individuals in various age groups, relative to the
excluded group of seniors (age 65 and above). Controls for education
levels include percentages of persons whose highest degree is a high
school diploma, a four-year college degree, and a graduate degree.
Commuting time will be positively correlated with broadband demand, if
telecommuting is more popular in areas where commutes are longer. I
include variables for the percentage of employed individuals who work at
home and who have commutes of various lengths (0-15 minutes is the
excluded category). Other demographic controls included are the
percentage of females in the area, fraction of households with children
under 18 years, and fraction of households with a telephone.
Given the focus on entry, and not competition after entry, I follow
authors such as Berry (1992) in omitting price variables. (14) The
demand variables described above provide the information that potential
entrants use to determine their price, should they decide to enter.
Including these demand variables in the estimations therefore proxies
for the expected postentry price and profit.
Costs. Various studies and industry sources suggest that relevant
cost considerations for broadband deployment are fixed costs, subscriber
density, and the vintage of the telecommunications infrastructure. (15)
The fixed costs are from installing the necessary equipment in the wire
center to enable DSL (16) or in the headend to enable cable modem
service. To the extent that average fixed costs vary among regions only
through the number of subscribers (the denominator) and that
subscription is a function of demographic variables, the inclusion of
demographic variables will indirectly control for difference in average
fixed costs.
Costs are lower in areas where subscriber density is higher. In
denser areas the same investment at the wire center (for DSL) or the
middle mile network (for cable modem service) reaches more potential
subscribers. Also, in areas with low subscriber density, the average DSL
customer is farther from the central office and requires stronger (and
therefore more expensive) carrier signals to be sent. I include two
density measures: the number of occupied housing units with telephone
access and population, both per square kilometer. The former may be a
better measure for DSL deployment costs, because DSL requires a phone
line, and the latter may be better for cable modem deployment costs.
The older the vintage of the local telecommunications and cable
networks, the more expensive is broadband implementation. (17) Lacking
direct data, I proxy the age of installed networks with the median age
of the housing structures in the area. A final cost variable is the cost
of connecting to the nearest Internet backbone. In rural areas without
nearby access, connection costs may be higher than in urban areas. Also,
rates for connecting to the Internet backbone tend to be lower in urban
areas, due to competition among backbone access providers. Data on
backbone access cost is not readily available, and so the rural and
urban dummy variables will absorb systematic difference in these costs
among regions. An NTIA and Rural Utilities Service (2000, 9) study,
however, downplays the importance of Internet backbone availability as
an important difference between urban and rural areas, so perhaps these
cost data are not crucial.
Local Telecommunications Competition. Although cable companies
mostly still enjoy monopolies within their service areas, local
telecommunications competition has started to spring up since the
passage of the Telecommunications Act of 1996. Anecdotal evidence from
the industry suggests that incumbent local exchange carriers are more
likely to offer advanced services in areas in which they face
competition. Some facilities-based competitors offer DSL themselves (and
therefore appear in the dependent variable).
The FCC makes available a list of ZIP codes in which there is local
competition. In one specification I include a dummy for the presence of
at least one competing local exchange company (CLEC) in the area. That
specification models jointly the availability of broadband and local
telephony competition (see the appendix).
Telecommunications Carriers' Operating Areas. Industry reports
suggest that some Bell carriers were more aggressive than others in
deploying DSL. Indicator variables for the presence of one of the four
remaining Bell firms as the incumbent local exchange carrier in the ZIP
code are included: BellSouth, Qwest (fka U.S. West), SBC (Southwestern
Bell Telephone, Pacific Bell, Nevada Bell, and Ameritech), Verizon (fka
Bell Atlantic and NYNEX). (18) The excluded dummy is all nonBell
carriers. (19)
V. THE EVIDENCE FOR UNEQUAL AVAILABILITY OF BROADBAND
Here I present two sets of estimations. In Table 2, simple probit
estimations including only race, income, and geographic variables are
presented. Table 3 includes expanded estimations investigating the
impact of including cost and demand variables omitted from the simpler
estimations.
Consider the first estimation reported in Table 2, with race,
ethnicity, and geographic variables only (urban/rural indicators, and
Bell territory and state fixed effects). The results accord with the
common perception of the digital divide: the coefficients for blacks,
Native Americans, and Hispanics. and the rural variables are all
negative and significant. The coefficient on the fraction of Asians in
the area is significantly positive. Before imputing causality to these
findings, however, note that once income variables are added (last
columns of Table 2) the race and ethnicity coefficients lose all
significance. Apparently income is an omitted variable in the first
estimation that leads to spurious correlation between the race variables
and broadband access. The results show that once additional omitted
variables are included, the significance of the coefficient on income is
also lost.
Table 3 has the results of three estimations, expanded to include
the full set of demand and cost variables. The first estimation leaves
out the language variables and the CLEC presence variable. The second
adds the language variables, and the third includes all variables. (20)
The coefficient, average marginal effect on the mean, and robust
standard error are reported for each variable. (21) The fit appears to
be quite good for cross-sectional data; the [R.sup.2] is about 0.45 and
many of the estimated coefficients are statistically significant at the
1% level. The results from the models are remarkably consistent; none of
the statistically significant coefficients changes sign between
estimations. (22) Except when specifically discussing race, ethnicity,
and language, I discuss the results of the second estimation (language
variables but no CLEC variable). At the end of this section, I touch on
the estimation with the CLEC presence included.
Race and Ethnicity
The race, ethnicity, and language coefficients in the second
estimation (middle columns of Table 3) reveal interesting countervailing
effects. The nonwhite race and Hispanic ethnicity coefficients are
negative (with the exception of percentage black households) but the
non-English language coefficients are positive. These results for
language may bolster theories, current in other social sciences, that
individuals use the Internet to seek out a community of interest
(Elkins, 1997). If so, then carriers may expect higher demand for
broadband in areas with more non-English speakers and be more likely to
implement access. As discussed in section II, positive non-English
language effects imply that preference-based discrimination against
minorities is unlikely.
The net effects from race and language can go either way. Table 4
illustrates the net effects of the race and language variables,
presenting the fraction of observations for which various groups of
race-related variables lead to a decreased probability of availability,
ceteris paribus. If carriers' profit considerations adversely
affect minorities, then the net effects of these race-related variables
will be negative. For example, the first row summarizes the net effects
from the % Asian, % language Asian, and the Asian: language Asian and
Asian/linguistically isolated interactions, when calculated at sample
values. In 95% of the observations, the net impact of these
Asian-specific variables decreases access probability (compared to
white, English-speaking households). When weighted by the Asian
population in the area (the next column), the figure drops to about 74%.
The figure drops further to about 54% if statistical significance is
required of the evidence. Thus adverse access possibilities for Asians
appe ar to be present in areas where 54% of the Asian population lives.
Native Americans are the other racial group that suffers nearly
universal lower probability of access than white, English-speaking
households. The evidence for unequal access is statistically strong in
areas in which 89% of Native Americans live. Thus, for these two groups,
the appearance of unequal availability warrants further investigation.
However, the evidence for unequal access is weak for any other group.
The black, Hispanic, and other-race net effects are significantly
negative in virtually no areas. The net effect from all race and
language variables combined (the last row in the table) is significantly
negative in areas where only 13.5% of nonwhites live.
The race, ethnicity, and language variables are highly correlated,
and one may suspect that multicollinearity is driving these results. The
first estimation in Table 3, in which the language variables are
omitted, lends evidence that this is not the case. The results show that
removing the language variables does not result in significant race and
ethnicity coefficients, except for Native Americans. Therefore, this
estimation further corroborates that race and ethnicity generally play
little role in the broadband entry decision.
Here I further explore unequal broadband access opportunities for
Asians and Native Americans, the groups for which the pessimists'
case is strongest. The specifications above constrain the coefficients
on the racial variables to be constant, which may not be the case. To
explore this possibility, I estimate a generalized additive model in
which % Asian and % Native American enter the broadband equation
nonparametrically. In particular, the model for the observed binary
availability variable y (taking value one if broadband is available,
zero if not) is
(1) [y.sup.*] = x'[beta] + f([z.sub.natamer]) +
g([z.sub.asian]) + [[epsilon].sub.i],
(2) y = 1 if [y.sup.*] > 0, 0 otherwise;
where x includes all the variables in the first column of Table 3
(except interaction terms), and the z's are the % Native American
and % Asian variables. The error [[epsilon].sub.i] is assumed to be
i.i.d. standard normal; if functions f and g in (1) were linear, the
model would be a standard probit. Instead, f and g are nonparametric
smoothing functions (cubic B-splines). (23) The resulting partial fits
are shown in Figure 5. When the fitted curve slopes down in these
graphs, the marginal effect of the variable on availability is negative.
For comparison, if the variable were constrained to enter the model in
linear form, the partial fit would be a line with slope equal to the
estimated coefficient.
If Asians and Native Americans faced consistent discrimination (of
any sort), the fitted curves would be negatively sloped everywhere.
However, the effects of these variables are clearly not monotonic. In
only 50% of the areas does % Asian have a negative effect. When weighted
by Asian population, this figure is 72%. For % Native American, the
effect is negative in only 12% of areas (44% when weighted by Native
American population), although that subset includes the areas with the
highest concentrations (mainly reservations). (24) So even without
taking into account the countervailing effects of language, (25) the
evidence indicates that unequal availability for Asians and Native
Americans is not uniform across areas. In fact, in 50% of the areas,
naving marginally more Asians increases the probability of broadband
access-this is probably why the linear coefficient for % Asian was
positive in the simple estimations in Table 2. Similarly, in 88% of the
areas, having marginally more Native Americans increases the probability
of broadband access.
Income
There is no statistically significant evidence for unequal access
based on income. The income coefficients have the expected signs--access
is more likely the higher is median income and less likely the more
households are in poverty-but neither is significant. (26) The reason
why the income coefficient was significant in the simple estimation in
Table 2 but not here is again likely to be due to omitted variables.
Wealthier areas are likely to have lower costs of providing broadband,
due to better infrastructure, higher phone density, and higher
population density. It appears carriers' lower costs may induce them to roll out broadband earlier in wealthier locations, not
necessarily income per se.
Rural Location
The geographic coefficients are all negative (compared to
"urban but outside urbanized area"). That rural and inner city
areas lag in access has been found in other studies (FCC, 2000b); this
estimation shows that this result persists even after controlling for
demographics. The areas least likely to have access are rural nonfarm
areas served by a non-Bell local exchange carrier. Access probabilities
are statistically indistinguishable between rural areas served by Bell
operating companies and other local exchange carriers--evidence that
small rural carriers are not lagging behind the Bell operating
companies, controlling for other factors. Given the potentially poor
measurement of the entry variable in rural areas due to the reporting
threshold, however, these conclusions remain tentative.
Effects of Other Market Characteristics
The market size coefficients for households and firms are positive
and significant. The marginal effect of 0.034 for log number of
households means that if the number of households nearly tripled, there
would be about a 3.5-percentage-point increase in the probability of
broadband access. (27) The marginal effect of the size of the business
market (number of firms) is about twice as strong.
Of the significant age coefficients, each age group's effect
is positive compared to the excluded senior group. Similarly, the
education coefficients are all positive, compared to the excluded group
lacking a high school degree or equivalent. The commuting distance
coefficients have the expected signs for the most part. A larger
fraction of workers at home increases access likelihood. For commuters,
the longer the commute, the higher the access probability (with the
exception of the longest commuters, one hour plus).
The fraction of households with a telephone has a nonmonotonic
effect on access. Because DSL requires a phone line to function, it is
not surprising that in the region where most of the observations lie,
the interval (0.925-1.0), the marginal effect is positive. Of the
business coefficients, only the fraction of small firms--a negative
effect--is significant.
Exploratory analysis revealed that the cost variables have
nonmonotonic relationships to broadband access. In the estimations in
Table 3, I used linear spline functions for the cost variables. The
ordinates of the knots were chosen based on visual inspection of
nonparametric partial fits; the knots are close to the first and third
quartiles in each case. Phone density has the expected positive sign in
the region in which most of the data appear (>0.4). None of the
population density coefficients is significant, probably because the set
of urban and rural dummy variables are closely related. The age of
housing structures, as a proxy for network infrastructure vintage, has
the expected negative sign in the ranges up to 17.5 years and greater
than 35 years, but not in the middle range.
All Bell operating company indicators are significant and positive,
probably because the Bell companies are rolling Out broadband faster
than other local exchange carriers, even after controlling for
differences in demand characteristics among regions. (28)
Local Telecommunications Competition
The third estimation in Table 3 contains the CLEC presence
variable. Because CLEC presence is endogenous, I estimate the CLEC and
broadband entry decisions jointly in a bivariate probit model in which
CLEC presence appears as an explanatory variable in the broadband
equation and as a dependent variable in a second equation. Further
details are in the appendix. The table contains the coefficients from
the broadband entry equation only. The estimated effect of competition
in local telephony is relatively large but statistically insignificant.
The marginal effect is 0.267, implying that when there is local
competition the probability of broadband access rises by 26.7 percentage
points. The other estimates from the broadband entry part of the model,
including those for race and income, are very close to those from the
previous estimation.
VI. IMPLICATIONS
This study contributes a better understanding of the determinants
of the availability of broadband Internet access. Notwithstanding that the market is well on its way toward full diffusion on the supply side,
there has been concern at the FCC and elsewhere about broadband
availability for minority, low-income, and rural households. Careful
research into these issues is warranted given the federal mandate to
deploy broadband to all Americans and the demonstrated willingness of
the FCC to spend significant resources to encourage universal service.
(29)
The results above give no statistically significant evidence of
unequal availability based on income. There is some evidence for unequal
availability for Asians and Native Americans; the case to be made for
discrimination (profit-based or otherwise) against any other racial or
ethnic group is very weak. Even for Asians and Native Americans, the
evidence for unequal availability is inconsistent across the range of
the variables. In particular, for both groups the nonparametric analysis
shows that there are many ranges of concentration that exhibit positive
marginal effects on broadband availability. Finally, after noting that
Asian households are more likely to subscribe to broadband than any
other racial group (NTIA 2000), Native Americans remain the sole group
of possible concern. Race-focused rhetoric about the broadband digital
divide appears to be largely unwarranted, at least on the supply side.
More important determinants of broadband availability are rural
location and demand characteristics such as age, education, commuting
time, sex, and size of businesses in the area. Therefore, universal
service policies (if deemed necessary at all) should focus less on the
supply side (with the possible exception of rural areas) and more on the
demand side, perhaps through targeted subsidies to lower-income
individual subscribers and small businesses.
The implementation of new technology may change the course of
future broadband access policy discussions. For example, DirecPC and
StarBand, two satellite broadband Internet access providers, began
nationwide service in 2001 (after the time frame of the data examined
here). Theoretically, any household with a clear view of the southern
sky could access these services. Satellite broadband is currently much
more expensive than DSL or cable modem service, (30) and so the question
switches from availability versus unavailability to low-price access
versus high-price access.
Further study of broadband diffusion will be aided by the
FCC's ongoing data collection. The FCC broadband survey is given
every six months, which will allow panel data methods to be used in
future explorations. Given that income and racial composition vary much
more over the cross-section than over time, however, panel data may not
add much to the investigation.
APPENDIX
This appendix contains details on the third estimation presented in
Table 3. The model is a bivariate probit with dependent variables
broadband presence and CLEC presence in the ZIP code, and correlation
parameter [rho]. The CLEC presence variable also appears as a
right-hand-side variable in the broadband equation. This is
Maddala's (1983, 122) model 6, which requires that the CLEC
presence equation contain at least one variable that is not in the
broadband equation for identification when [rho] = 0. I estimated the
model by maximum likelihood estimation.
The instrument in the CLEC equation is the proxy cost for local
telecommunications service in the local exchange area, as calculated by
the FCC's Hybrid Cost Proxy Model in January 2000. The Hybrid Cost
Proxy Model is an economic engineering model that calculates the cost of
providing local telecommunications service using efficient technology,
given an area's geographic terrain and subscriber density. Proxy
costs are not available from the model for about one-third of the wire
centers (mostly for smaller carriers); in these cases I used the proxy
cost of the nearest wire center for which cost was available. Wire
center boundaries were matched to ZIP code areas as described in the
text for the Bell operating company indicator variables. Proxy costs
should be highly correlated with competitors' entry decisions, and
indeed are significant in the CLEC equation. The proxy cost coefficient
is insignificant if the variable is added to a univariate estimation of
the broadband equation when CLEC presence is already i ncluded, which
lends credibility to excluding proxy costs from the broadband equation.
Only the coefficients from the broadband equation are reported in
Table 3. The variables included in the CLEC equation are state fixed
effects, proxy cost, Bell operating company indicators, and the market
size, geographic composition, and income variables. The estimate of
[rho] is 0.13, with a p-value of 0.047. The p-value of the likelihood
ratio test for [rho] = 0 is 0.037, so it is likely that the CLEC
presence variable is endogenous in the broadband equation.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
FIGURE 2
Choice of Broadband Technology by Residences and Small Businesses
ADSL 771,311 lines 25%
Other Wireline 104,647 lines 3%
Satellite & Fixed Wireless 64,320 lines 2%
Coaxial Cable 2,179,749 lines 70%
Fiber 323 lines 0.01%
Total lines 3,120,350
Note: Table made from pie chart
FIGURE 3
Choice of Broadband Technology by Larger Business
ADSL 15% 179,279 lines
Other Wireline 53% 642,381 lines
Sateiiite & Fixed Wireless 0% 1,295 lines
Coaxial Cable 6% 69,232 lines
Fiber 26% 306,828 lines
Note: Table made from pie chart
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics of the Data
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Dependent variable
Broadband availability (1 = yes) 0.708 0.454
Independent variables
% age < 13 years 0.205 0.052
% age 14-18 years 0.071 0.025
% age 19-24 years 0.074 0.044
% age 25-29 years 0.074 0.031
% age 30-34 years 0.083 0.027
% age 35-39 years 0.078 0.027
% age 40-49 years 0.127 0.037
% age 50-64 years 0.143 0.047
% Asian 0.010 0.029
% below poverty line 0.146 0.100
% black 0.072 0.159
% college degree 0.102 0.076
% commute 15-29 minutes 0.323 0.124
% commute 30-44 minutes 0.172 0.095
% commute 45-59 minutes 0.064 0.057
% commute 60+ minutes 0.060 0.059
% female 0.505 0.038
% FIRE firms 0.000 0.030
% graduate degree 0.052 0.055
% high school degree 0.590 0.127
% Hispanic 0.044 0.114
% inside urbanized area 0.247 0.415
% kids in household 0.356 0.099
% language Asian 0.005 0.013
% other language 0.045 0.058
% language Spanish 0.037 0.072
% linguistically isolated 0.016 0.042
% manufacturing firms 0.004 0.064
% Native American 0.011 0.055
% other race 0.018 0.057
% phone in household 0.929 0.076
% rural (farm), BOC telco 0.014 0.048
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco 0.055 0.109
% rural (nonfarm), BOC telco 0.224 0,373
% rural (nonfarm), non-BOC telco 0.375 0.426
% services firms 0.043 0.204
% small firms (<50 employees) 0.988 0.106
% work at home 0.056 0.072
Average employment per firm 2.078 0.785
BellSouth 0.096 0.295
households (log) 7.056 1.582
median income (log) 0.147 0.381
number of firms (log) 4.100 1.862
phone density (log) 2.449 2.335
population density (log) 3.529 2.303
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.068 0.252
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.164 0.370
Structure age (years) 28.372 12.268
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 0.170 0.376
Notes: BOC is Bell operating company. FIRE is Finance, insurance, and
real estate. All percentages expressed as fractions.
TABLE 2
Probit Estimations for the Availability of Broadband Service within a
ZIP Code Area
Probit
(Race and Ethnicity Variables)
Variable Coefficient Robust SE
Race and ethnic composition
% black -0.438 0.083 ***
% Native American -0.748 0.158 ***
% Asian 3.661 1.365 ***
% other race -0.126 0.330
% Hispanic -0.539 0.174 ***
Income and poverty
median income (log)
% below poverty line
Geographic composition 0.070 ***
% rural (nonfarm), BOC telco -1.711 0.075 ***
% rural (nonfarm), non-BOC telco -2.071 0.231 ***
% rural (farm), BOC telco -3.499 0.123 ***
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco -3.364
Bell operating companies 0.096 *
BellSouth 0.145 0.125 ***
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.963 0.086 **
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.167 0.119 ***
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 1.411 0.196 ***
Intercept 1.951 0.083 ***
Log likelihood -10,860.8
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2] 0.349
Probit
(Race, Ethnicity,and Income
Variables)
Variable Coefficient
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.079
% Native American -0.150
% Asian 1.540
% other race -0.101
% Hispanic -0.114
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.752
% below poverty line -0.202
Geographic composition
% rural (nonfarm), BOC telco -1.629
% rural (nonfarm), non-BOC telco -1.957
% rural (farm), BOC telco -3.362
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco -3.230
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.096
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.941
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.152
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 1.477
Intercept -6.599
Log likelihood -10,636.5
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2] 0.363
Probit
(Race,
Ethnicity,and
Income
Variables)
Variable Robust SE
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.090
% Native American 0.164
% Asian 1.015
% other race 0.343
% Hispanic 0.180
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.062 ***
% below poverty line 0.207
Geographic composition
% rural (nonfarm), BOC telco 0.071 ***
% rural (nonfarm), non-BOC telco 0.075 ***
% rural (farm), BOC telco 0.233 ***
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco 0.123 ***
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.098
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.127 ***
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.087 **
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 0.120 ***
Intercept 0.790 ***
Log likelihood
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2]
Notes: 27,623 observations. Dependent variable is 1 if there is at least
one broadband customer in the ZIP code, 0 if not. Both estimations
include state fixed effects. The sample includes all states except AK,
HI, DC, and DE (latter two dropped because there is no variation in the
dependent variable). BOC is Belloperating company, See text for variable
definitions.
* Significant at the 10% level.
** Significant at the 5% level.
*** Significant at the 1% level.
TABLE 3
Probit Estimations for the Availability of Broadband Service within a
ZIP Code Area
Probit
(No Language Variables)
Marginal
Variable Coef. Effect
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.157 0.029
% Native American -0.484 -0.090
% Asian -0.488 -0.091
% other race 0.122 0.023
% Hispanic -0.206 -0.038
Linguistic composition
% language Spanish
% language Asian
% other language
% linguistically isolated
Race and language interactions
Native American: other language
Native American: ling. isolated
Asian: language Asian
Asian: other language
Asian: ling. isolated
Hispanic: language Spanish
Hispanic: other language
Hispanic: ling. isolated
Other race: other language
Other race: ling. isolated
Black: other language
Black: ling. isolated
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.043 0.008
% below poverty line -0.365 -0.068
Size of market
households (log) 0.182 0.034
number of firms (log) 0.394 0.073
Geographic composition
% inside urbanized area -0.382 -0.071
% rural (nonfarm), BOG telco -0.555 -0.103
% rural (nonfarm),
non-BOC telco -0.624 -0.116
% rural (farm), BOC telco -0.491 -0.092
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco -0.104 -0.019
Age profile of population
% age < 13 years 0.640 0.119
% age 14-18 years -0.074 -0.014
% age 19-24 years 1.222 0.228
% age 25-29 years -0.456 -0.085
% age 30-34 years 0.675 0.126
% age 35-39 years 1.093 0.204
% age 40-49 years 1.021 0.190
% age 50-64 years 0.694 0.129
Education profile of population
% high school degree 0.448 0.084
% college degree 1.066 0.199
% graduate degree 0.396 0.074
Commuting profile
% work at home 0.119 0.022
% commute 15-29 minutes 0.570 0.106
% commute 30-44 minutes 0.698 0.130
% commute 45-59 minutes 1.104 0.206
% commute 60+ minutes 0.581 0.108
Other demographics
% female -1.290 -0.240
% kids in household 0.088 0.016
% phone in household (<0.925) -0.332 -0.062
% phone in household (>0.925) 0.405 0.076
Composition of business market
% manufacturing firms 0.139 0.026
% FIRE firms -0.128 -0.024
% services firms 0.166 0.031
% small firms (<50 employees) -0.754 -0.140
Average employment per firm 0.050 0.009
Cost variables (linear splines)
phone density (log, <0.4) -0.217 -0.040
phone density (log, 0.4-4.25) 0.170 0.032
phone density (log, >4.25) 0.122 0.023
population density (log, <1.5) 0.104 0.019
population density (log, 1.5-4.8) -0.027 -0.005
population density (log, >4.8) -0.209 -0.039
structure age (<17.5 years) -0.010 -0.002
structure age (17.5-35 years) 0.005 0.001
structure age (>35 years) -0.004 -0.001
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.307 0.056
Qwest (U.S. West) 1.214 0.195
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.290 0.054
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 2.082 0.297
Local Telecom Competition
CLEC presence
Intercept -2.310
State-level fixed effects yes
Number of observations 27,623
Log likelihood -9,154.5
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2] 0.452
Probit Probit
(No With Language
Language Variables
Variables)
Robust Marginal
Variable SE Coef. Effect
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.101 0.158 0.029
% Native American 0.198 ** -0.703 -0.131
% Asian 0.586 -4.167 -0.775
% other race 0.367 -0.749 -0.139
% Hispanic 0.202 -0.835 -0.155
Linguistic composition
% language Spanish 1.201 0.223
% language Asian 0.567 0.105
% other language 0.010 0.002
% linguistically isolated 0.575 0.107
Race and language interactions
Native American: other language -0.011 -0.002
Native American: ling. isolated 1.677 0.312
Asian: language Asian 73.194 13.613
Asian: other language -24.648 -4.584
Asian: ling. isolated 6.983 1.299
Hispanic: language Spanish -0.388 -0.072
Hispanic: other language 4.378 0.814
Hispanic: ling. isolated -0.796 -0.148
Other race: other language 2.835 0.527
Other race: ling. isolated 4.134 0.769
Black: other language -3.451 -0.642
Black: ling. isolated 9.270 1.724
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.077 0.042 0.008
% below poverty line 0.232 -0.349 -0.065
Size of market
households (log) 0.019 *** 0.183 0.034
number of firms (log) 0.017 *** 0.387 0.072
Geographic composition
% inside urbanized area 0.106 *** -0.388 -0.072
% rural (nonfarm), BOG telco 0.095 *** -0.558 -0.104
% rural (nonfarm),
non-BOC telco 0.085 *** -0.633 -0.118
% rural (farm), BOC telco 0.259 * -0.519 -0.097
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco 0.169 -0.127 -0.024
Age profile of population
% age < 13 years 0.430 0.780 0.145
% age 14-18 years 0.560 0.021 0.004
% age 19-24 years 0.413 *** 1.293 0.241
% age 25-29 years 0.444 -0.313 -0.058
% age 30-34 years 0.466 0.756 0.141
% age 35-39 years 0.512 ** 1.189 0.221
% age 40-49 years 0.379 *** 1.127 0.210
% age 50-64 years 0.346 ** 0.758 0.141
Education profile of population
% high school degree 0.123 *** 0.469 0.087
% college degree 0.260 *** 1.119 0.208
% graduate degree 0.385 0.503 0.093
Commuting profile
% work at home 0.192 0.570 0.106
% commute 15-29 minutes 0.116 *** 0.688 0.128
% commute 30-44 minutes 0.130 *** 1.097 0.204
% commute 45-59 minutes 0.207 *** 0.589 0.110
% commute 60+ minutes 0.211 *** 0.586 0.176
Other demographics
% female 0.312 *** -1.326 -0.247
% kids in household 0.229 0.015 0.003
% phone in household (<0.925) 0.278 -0.260 -0.048
% phone in household (>0.925) 0.574 0.332 0.062
Composition of business market
% manufacturing firms 0.146 -0.093 -0.017
% FIRE firms 0.335 0.192 0.036
% services firms 0.070 ** 0.138 0.026
% small firms (<50 employees) 0.103 *** -0.789 -0.147
Average employment per firm 0.017 *** 0.032 0.006
Cost variables (linear splines)
phone density (log, <0.4) 0.110 ** -0.208 -0.039
phone density (log, 0.4-4.25) 0.109 0.150 0.028
phone density (log, >4.25) 0.141 0.114 0.021
population density (log, <1.5) 0.111 0.095 0.018
population density (log, 1.5-4.8) 0.112 -0.011 -0.002
population density (log, >4.8) 0.126 * -0.199 -0.037
structure age (<17.5 years) 0.008 -0.011 -0.002
structure age (17.5-35 years) 0.002 ** 0.005 0.001
structure age (>35 years) 0.003 -0.004 -0.001
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.091 *** 0.298 0.054
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.125 *** 1.221 0.195
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.081 *** 0.285 0.052
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 0.118 *** 2.086 0.296
Local Telecom Competition
CLEC presence
Intercept 0.844 *** -2.380
State-level fixed effects yes
Number of observations 27,623
Log likelihood -9,135.2
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2] 0.453
Bivariate
Probit
Probit (Broadband
Entry
With and CLEC
Language Presence)
Variables
Robust
Variable SE Coef.
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.113 0.113
% Native American 0.302 *** -0.711
% Asian 1.891 *** -3.693
% other race 0.594 -0.744
% Hispanic 0.484 * -0.839
Linguistic composition
% language Spanish 0.452 *** 1.205
% language Asian 1.857 0.419
% other language 0.250 0.018
% linguistically isolated 0.717 0.454
Race and language interactions
Native American: other language 0.812 0.070
Native American: ling. isolated 1.732 1.821
Asian: language Asian 27.30 *** 72.576
Asian: other language 17.057 -23.450
Asian: ling. isolated 13.803 7.437
Hispanic: language Spanish 0.796 -0.336
Hispanic: other language 4.984 4.099
Hispanic: ling. isolated 1.520 -0.704
Other race: other language 8.779 3.537
Other race: ling. isolated 2.470 * 3.903
Black: other language 1.855 * -3.195
Black: ling. isolated 4.872 * 9.630
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.077 0.076
% below poverty line 0.234 -0.310
Size of market
households (log) 0.019 *** 0.179
number of firms (log) 0.017 *** 0.390
Geographic composition
% inside urbanized area 0.106 *** -0.398
% rural (nonfarm), BOG telco 0.095 *** -0.559
% rural (nonfarm),
non-BOC telco 0.085 *** -0.626
% rural (farm), BOC telco 0.262 *** -0.719
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco 0.168 -0.169
Age profile of population
% age < 13 years 0.433 * 0.569
% age 14-18 years 0.559 -0.128
% age 19-24 years 0.415 1.122
% age 25-29 years 0.443 -0.387
% age 30-34 years 0.465 0.651
% age 35-39 years 0.506 *** 0.928
% age 40-49 years 0.379 *** 0.935
% age 50-64 years 0.346 *** 0.662
Education profile of population
% high school degree 0.128 *** 0.434
% college degree 0.263 *** 1.043
% graduate degree 0.382 0.545
Commuting profile
% work at home 0.117 *** 0.102
% commute 15-29 minutes 0.132 *** 0.504
% commute 30-44 minutes 0.207 *** 0.621
% commute 45-59 minutes 0.213 *** 1.023
% commute 60+ minutes 0.205 *** 0.587
Other demographics
% female 0.314 *** -1.322
% kids in household 0.231 0.079
% phone in household (<0.925) 0.279 -0.233
% phone in household (>0.925) 0.581 0.314
Composition of business market
% manufacturing firms 0.124 0.153
% FIRE firms 0.168 -0.120
% services firms 0.087 0.169
% small firms (<50 employees) 0.100 *** -0.724
Average employment per firm 0.017 0.040
Cost variables (linear splines)
phone density (log, <0.4) 0.109 ** -0.192
phone density (log, 0.4-4.25) 0.108 0.168
phone density (log, >4.25) 0.142 0.098
population density (log, <1.5) 0.110 0.092
population density (log, 1.5-4.8) 0.111 -0.039
population density (log, >4.8) 0.127 -0.182
structure age (<17.5 years) 0.008 -0.011
structure age (17.5-35 years) 0.002 * 0.005
structure age (>35 years) 0.002 -0.003
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.092 *** 0.301
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.125 *** 1.188
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.081 *** 0.269
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 0.119 *** 2.074
Local Telecom Competition
CLEC presence 0.159
Intercept 0.828 *** -2.617
State-level fixed effects
Number of observations
Log likelihood
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2]
Bivariate Probit
(Broadband Entry
and CLEC Presence)
Marginal Robust
Variable Effect SE
Race and ethnic composition
% black 0.021 0.114
% Native American -0.131 0.302 **
% Asian -0.680 1.945 *
% other race -0.137 0.603
% Hispanic -0.154 0.489 *
Linguistic composition
% language Spanish 0.222 0.461 ***
% language Asian 0.077 1.907
% other language 0.003 0.251
% linguistically isolated 0.084 0.727
Race and language interactions
Native American: other language 0.013 0.813
Native American: ling. isolated 0.335 1.734
Asian: language Asian 13.36 27.80 ***
Asian: other language -4.316 17.161
Asian: ling. isolated 1.369 13.894
Hispanic: language Spanish -0.062 0.803
Hispanic: other language 0.754 5.102
Hispanic: ling. isolated -0.129 1.535
Other race: other language 0.651 9.134
Other race: ling. isolated 0.718 2.418
Black: other language -0.588 1.848
Black: ling. isolated 1.772 4.950 *
Income and poverty
median income (log) 0.017 0.078
% below poverty line -0.053 0.237
Size of market
households (log) 0.034 0.019 ***
number of firms (log) 0.074 0.019 ***
Geographic composition
% inside urbanized area -0.068 0.109 ***
% rural (nonfarm), BOG telco -0.104 0.096 ***
% rural (nonfarm),
non-BOC telco -0.117 0.087 ***
% rural (farm), BOC telco -0.139 0.263 ***
% rural (farm), non-BOC telco -0.032 0.170
Age profile of population
% age < 13 years 0.105 0.436
% age 14-18 years -0.024 0.570
% age 19-24 years 0.206 0.418 ***
% age 25-29 years -0.071 0.455
% age 30-34 years 0.120 0.466
% age 35-39 years 0.171 0.513 *
% age 40-49 years 0.172 0.381 **
% age 50-64 years 0.122 0.347 *
Education profile of population
% high school degree 0.080 0.129 ***
% college degree 0.192 0.267 ***
% graduate degree 0.100 0.383
Commuting profile
% work at home 0.019 0.193
% commute 15-29 minutes 0.093 0.118 ***
% commute 30-44 minutes 0.114 0.132 ***
% commute 45-59 minutes 0.188 0.206 ***
% commute 60+ minutes 0.108 0.212 ***
Other demographics
% female -0.243 0.315 ***
% kids in household 0.015 0.236
% phone in household (<0.925) -0.043 0.281
% phone in household (>0.925) 0.058 0.583
Composition of business market
% manufacturing firms 0.028 0.145
% FIRE firms -0.022 0.333
% services firms 0.031 0.070 **
% small firms (<50 employees) -0.133 0.102 ***
Average employment per firm 0.007 0.017 **
Cost variables (linear splines)
phone density (log, <0.4) -0.035 0.109 *
phone density (log, 0.4-4.25) 0.031 0.110
phone density (log, >4.25) 0.018 0.142
population density (log, <1.5) 0.017 0.110
population density (log, 1.5-4.8) -0.007 0.113
population density (log, >4.8) -0.034 0.127
structure age (<17.5 years) -0.002 0.008
structure age (17.5-35 years) 0.001 0.003 *
structure age (>35 years) -0.001 0.003
Bell operating companies
BellSouth 0.058 0.093 ***
Qwest (U.S. West) 0.193 0.127 ***
SBC-PacBell-Ameritech 0.056 0.082 ***
Verizon (Bell Atlantic-NYNEX) 0.297 0.119 ***
Local Telecom Competition
CLEC presence 0.267 0.116
Intercept 0.831 ***
State-level fixed effects yes
Number of observations 27,392
Log likelihood -18,163.0
Kullback-Leibler [R.sup.2] 0.48
Notes: Dependent variable is 1 if there is at least one broadband
customer in the ZIP code, 0 if not. In the bivariate probit estimation,
the other dependent variable is 1 if there is at least one CLEC in the
ZIP code, 0 if not (coefficients from this equation, are not reported
here). The sample includes all states except AK, HI, DC, and DE. In the
third estimatio n, Idaho is dropped from the sample well, due to lack
of variation in the CLEC presence variable. Marginal effect is the
average marginal effect on the mean in the sample; for dummy variables
these are discrete changes. CLEC is competing local exchange company.
See also notes to Table 2.
* Significant at the 10% level.
** Significant at the 5% level.
*** Significant at the 1% level.
TABLE 4
Net Effects of the Race, Ethnicity, and Language Variables on the
Probability of Broadband Availability in a ZIP Code Area
Percentage of
Areas in Which
There Is Evidence
of a Lower
Probability of
Broadband Access
Variables in Calculation Raw
Asian, Asian language, Asian: Asian 94.8
language, and Asian:
linguistically isolated
Black, black: other language, 43.6
and black: linguistically isolated
Hispanic, Spanish language, 25.7
Hispanic: Spanish, and Hispanic:
linguistically isolated
Native American, Native American: 99.9
other language, and Native
Native American: linguistically
isolated
Other race, other race: other 97.1
language, and other race:
linguistically isolated
All race, ethnicity, language, and 48.9
interaction variables
Percentage of Areas in
Which There Is Evidence
of a Lower Probability of
Broadband Access
Weighted by
Variables in Calculation Minority Population
Asian, Asian language, Asian: Asian 73.8
language, and Asian:
linguistically isolated
Black, black: other language, 2.6
and black: linguistically isolated
Hispanic, Spanish language, 58.4
Hispanic: Spanish, and Hispanic:
linguistically isolated
Native American, Native American: 99.8
other language, and Native
Native American: linguistically
isolated
Other race, other race: other 63.2
language, and other race:
linguistically isolated
All race, ethnicity, language, and 51.1
interaction variables
Percentage of Areas in
Which There Is Evidence
of a Lower Probability of
Broadband Access
Weighted and Significant
Variables in Calculation at the 5% Level
Asian, Asian language, Asian: Asian 54.3
language, and Asian:
linguistically isolated
Black, black: other language, 0.00
and black: linguistically isolated
Hispanic, Spanish language, 0.06
Hispanic: Spanish, and Hispanic:
linguistically isolated
Native American, Native American: 89.2
other language, and Native
Native American: linguistically
isolated
Other race, other race: other 0.00
language, and other race:
linguistically isolated
All race, ethnicity, language, and 13.5
interaction variables
Notes: "Evidence of a lower probaility of broadband access" in an area
means that the combined marginal effect of the variables in the first
column on access probability is negative. Raw figures are calculated as
[[SIGMA].sub.i]1{[x'.sub.i]b < 0}/N, where 1{a} is the indicator
function taking a value of 1 if a is true and 0 otherwise, i indexes
observations, and the variables included in vector [x.sub.i] are given
in the row headings. Variables of the form a:b are interactions. Sample
values are used for [x.sub.i]; coefficient estimates b are taken from
the probit with state fixed effects in Table 3. In the second column,
the summand is weighted by the relevant minority population (the first
variable listed in the row headings) in the ZIP code. In the third
column, an area is counted (and weighted, as in previous column) if it
has a negative effect large enough to reject the null hypothesis that
[x'.sub.i]b > 0 at the 5% level.
(1.) See Cooper (2000) and NTIA (2000).
(2.) "The problem is not that the disconnected do not
participate in physical space, it is that they cannot participate in
cyberspace" (Cooper, 2000). "[Broadband is] not being deployed
to all Americans because of the realities of the marketplace, which by
its nature cannot serve all customers equally.... Rural, minority,
low-income populations and people with disabilities are some of those
groups who are not able to fully access the technology" (comments
filed by the Alliance for Public Technology in the 2nd FCC Notice of
Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications
Capability, CC Dkt No. 98-146, March 2000). See also National
Association of State Telecommunications Directors (2001).
(3.) See Olson (1999) and Trujillo (1999). Redlining originally
referred to the practice of a lending institution denying home loans to
households in certain areas of a community. It has come to be used by
some advocates as a pejorative to refer to price or availability
discrimination that is correlated with race or income in any line of
business.
(4.) Pending bills allow Bell carriers more flexibility in carrying
broadband traffic across regulatory boundaries and require them to
deploy broadband capability in all their local exchanges within five
years (H.R. 1542), attempt to strengthen antitrust laws to open
telecommunications markets (including broadband) to competition (H.R.
1697, 1698, and 2120), and provide tax credits (S. 88, S. 150, S. 426,
H.R. 267, H.R. 1415) or grants and loans (S. 428, H.R. 1416, H.R. 1697)
to promote broadband deployment.
(5.) See sec. 706 of the 1996 Telecommunications Act, Pub. L.
104-104, Title VII, 9 Feb, 1996, 110 Stat. 153.
(6.) I will use the terms wire center and central office
interchangeably. They are the primary points at which local exchange
carriers connect subscribers to the public switched telephone network.
(7.) FCC (2000a, 81).
(8.) See FCC (2000a, 195, n. 236).
(9.) 86.1% of blacks and 91.2% of Hispanics live in urban areas.
(10.) ZIPs that do not correspond to a geographic area (post office
boxes and single-entity ZIPs) are excluded.
(11.) Broadband is defined in the survey as transmission speed in
excess of 200 kbps in at least one direction. The FCC considers a
carrier to be "facilities based" if it provides broadband
access over its own local loop, or over unbundled network elements or
leased lines that it obtains from other carriers and equips as broadband
(FCC, 2001).
(12.) Bureau of the Census, Census of Population and Housing, 1990:
Summary Tape File 3, CD-ROM.
(13.) Bureau of the Census, ZIP Code Business Patterns CD-ROM, 1997
data.
(14.) Prices arc not observed if entry does not occur. Even if
prices arc observed, they may not vary much among areas. As of November
2001, each of the Bells offers DSL service for the same price everywhere
in their service regions. Furthermore, all of the companies except Qwest
charge $50/month for basic DSL. Cable modem prices may show more
regional variation (Hausman et al., 2001).
(15.) See Faulhaber and Hogendorn (2000) and Gabel and Kwan (2001),
for example.
(16.) Chiefly, a DSLAM (DSL access multiplexer), a mechanism at the
wire center that links many end-user's DSL connections to a single
high-speed ATM line. The DSLAM involves both fixed and variable costs.
(17.) In older networks, frayed insulation or poorly spliced loops
may degrade transmission quality. Other problems include load coils
(devices that were used to enhance the quality of voice traffic over
copper lines) and bridged taps (any portion of the local loop that is
not in the direct path between the central office and the end
user's terminating equipment). DSL requires these coils and taps to
be removed on a line-by-line basis, which is costly. Best-practice local
loop design for the past 20 to 30 years has excluded excessive bridge
taps and load coils (Public Utilities Commission of Nevada, 2000, 46;
FCC, 2000a, 39).
(18.) Given the rapid changes in the Bell operating companies'
coverage areas due to mergers, the variables reflect only the
traditional Bell operating company service areas (for example, Southern
New England Telephone's area is not included with SBC, nor is GTE,s
area with Verizon).
(19.) To construct the Bell operating company service area
variables, ZIP code areas were matched to wire center areas. These areas
overlap irregularly; wire center boundaries tend to be larger than ZIP
code areas. I matched the population-weighted geographic centroid of the
ZIP code area to the closest wire center location. The centroids are
from OSEDA (www.oseda.missouri.edu/jgb/ZIP.resources.html). The wire
center locations are from Stuff Software's May 2001 C.O. Finder!
database.
(20.) A likelihood ratio test convincingly rejects specifications
without state fixed effects.
(21.) White's standard errors are robust to
heteroscedasticity, although the coefficient estimates are biased in
that case. The main conclusions do not change if the usual standard
errors are employed.
(22.) Similarly, none of the statistically significant coefficients
change sign if a logit specification is used instead of probit.
(23.) The model (Hastic and Tibshirani, 1990) is estimated with the
gain command in S-Plus, where the S smoother is used for the z's.
(24.) It is not surprising that Indian reservations lag in
broadband access: only 47% of households on reservations have telephone
service. The FCC currently has initiatives in place to extend universal
service to reservations (FCC Consumer Facts: Increasing Telephone
Service in Indian Country, 3 August 2001).
(25.) The generalized additive model does not allow inclusion of
interaction effects.
(26.) Inclusion of the population density and urban/rural variables
may obscure the effects of income, if low-density, rural areas have
lower incomes. However, even when these variables are removed, the
income and poverty variables remain insignificant.
(27.) The marginal effect of a variable that is in logs corresponds
to the effect of multiplying the variable in levels by c ([congruent to]2.7).
(28.) An alternative explanation (not one that survives
Occam's razor) is that other broadband carriers (cable modem,
wireless, etc.) are entering the Bells' territories to establish
market presence in anticipation of future competition for broadband
customers.
(29.) Despite telephone penetration of over 94%, over $4.5 billion
was collected for universal service funding in 2000 (FCC, 2001).
(30.) For example, Earthlink's DirecPC service has 600 in
start-up costs for the subscriber, and a $70/month fee. Most of the
Bells offer DSL service for $50/month r less and waive the installation
and equipment fees prices as of February 2002).
REFERENCES
Becker, G. S. The Economics of Discrimination, 2d ed. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1971.
Berry, S. T. "Estimation of a Model of Entry in the Airline
Industry." Econometrica, 60(4), 1992, 889-917.
Bresnahan, T F., and P. C. Reiss. "Do Entry Conditions Vary
across Markets?" Brookings Papers in Economic Activities, 18, 1987,
833-82.
Cooper, M. "Disconnected, Disadvantaged, and Disenfranchised:
Explorations in the Digital Divide." Consumers Union and Consumer
Federation of America Joint Report, online document available at
www.consumersunion.org/pdf/disconnect.pdf, 11 October 2000.
Elkins, D. J. "Globalization, Telecommunication, and Virtual
Ethnic Communities." International Political Science Review, 18(2),
1997, 139-52.
Faulhaber, G. R., and C. Hogendorn. "The Market Structure of
Broadband Telecommunications." Journal of Industrial Economics,
48(3), 2000, 305-29.
Federal Communications Commission. Deployment of Advanced
Telecommunications Capability: Second Report. FCC 00-290. Online
document available at
www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Orders/2000/fcc00290.pdf, August
2000a.
Federal Communications Commission, Common Carrier Bureau, Industry
Analysis Division. High-Speed Services for Internet Access:
Subscribership as of June 30, 2000. Online document available at
www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Reports/FCC-State_Link/IAD/hspd100
0.pdf, October 2000b.
Federal Communications Commission, Federal-State Joint Board on
Universal Service. Universal Service Monitoring Report. Online document
available at www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Reports/FCC-State.Link/Monitor/mrs 01-0.pdf, October 2001.
Gabel, D., and F. Kwan. "Accessibility of Broadband
Telecommunication Services by Various Segments of the American
Population," in Communications Policy in Transition: the Internet
and Beyond, edited by B. M. Compaine and S. Greenstein. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2001, 295-320.
Gillett, S. E., and W. Lehr. "Availability of Broadband
Internet Access: Empirical Evidence." Manuscript, September 1999.
Hastie, T, and R. J. Tibshirani. Generalized Additive Models. New
York: Chapman and Hall, 1990.
Hausman, J. A., J. G. Sidak, and H. J. Singer. "Cable Modems
and DSL: Broadband Internet Access for Residential Customers."
American Economic Review, 91(2), 2001, 302-7.
Maddala, G. S. Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in
Econometrics. Econometric Society Monographs. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1983.
Madden, G., S. J. Savage, G. Coble-Neal, P. Bloxham. "Advanced
Communications Policy and Adoption in Rural Western Australia."
Telecommunications Polley, 24(4), 2000, 291-304.
National Association of State Telecommunications Directors.
"Our Digital Nation: Separate and Unequal?" NASTD Backgrounder, 4(5), 2000, 1-4.
National Exchange Carrier Association. Access Market Survey of
NECA's Traffic Sensitive Pool Members, Keeping America Connected:
The Broadband Challenge. December 1999.
National Telecommunications and Information Administration. Falling
through the Net: Toward Digital Inclusion: A Report on Americans'
Access to Technology Tools. Online document available at
www.ntia.doc.gov/ntiahome/fttn00/contents00.html, October 2000.
Olson, D. C. "Open Access on Internet High Seas: Where the FCC
Is Loathe to Sail." Journal of Municipal Telecommunications, 1(1),
April 1999. Available online at munitelecom.org/v1i1/Olson.html.
Paradyne Corp. The DSL Sourcebook. Online document available at
www.paradyne.com/sourcebook_offer/sb_1file.pdf, 2000.
Prieger, James E. "The Supply Side of the Digital Divide: Is
There Redlining in the Broadband Internet Access Market?" Working
Paper 01-16, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, December
2001.
Public Utilities Commission of Nevada. Order in Docket No. 99-12033
and Docket No. 00-4001. 9 November 2000.
Tootell, G. M. B. "Redlining in Boston: Do Mortgage Lenders
Discriminate against Neighborhoods?" Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 111(4), 1996, 1049-79.
JAMES E. PRIEGER *
Trujillo, S. D. Testimony before the U.S. Senate Committee on
Commerce, Science and Transportation. Online document available at
www.senate.gov/~commerce/hearings/04l3tru.pdf, 13 April 1999.
RELATED ARTICLE: ABBREVIATIONS
CLEC: Competing Local Exchange Company
DSL: Digital Subscriber Line
FCC: Federal Communications Commission
NTLA: National Telecommunication and Information Administration
JAMES E. PRIEGER *
* An early version of this article was presented under the title
"Who's Jumping on the Broadband Wagon" at the 2001
Western Economics Association International Annual Meeting. A later
version circulated as Prieger (2001). I gratefully acknowledge a grant
from the Institute of Governmental Affairs at University of California at Davis that supported this work. I thank Alyson Ma, Neill Norman, and
Shehzad Ibrahim for research assistance.
Prieger: Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University
of California, One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA 95616. Phone
1-530-752-8727, Fax 1-530-752-9382, E-mail jeprieger@ucdavis.edu