Expectations, capital gains, and income.
Hill, Robert J. ; Hill, T. Peter
I. INTRODUCTION
This article argues that the distinction between expected and
unexpected capital gains (losses) is fundamental to the measurement of
income. The way capital gains are treated can have a significant impact
on major macroeconomic statistics, such as national income and saving,
the balance of payments, government income and saving, and depreciation
(see Gale and Sabelhaus, 1999; Joisce and Wright, 2001). The recent sale
of spectrum licenses is a case in point. The spectrum, a natural asset
over which governments enforce property rights, became unexpectedly
valuable as a result of the development of mobile telephones. In 2000
and 2001 some governments realized gains of $30 billion or more in a day
by auctioning licenses to use sections of the spectrum (see UN
Statistics Division, 2000).
The concept of income, although widely used, remains vague. It is
necessary to inquire why the concept of income is needed and what use it
serves. The main purpose of income is to provide guidance to households
or other economic units, including government, on the rate at which they
can afford to consume when there is uncertainty about future resources.
The more successfully measured income meets this requirement, the
greater its power as an explanatory variable for the analysis of
consumer behavior.
The treatment of expected and unexpected capital gains in income
measurement is a continuing source of controversy. (1) Even in a perfect
foresight setting, the concept of income is not straightforward. Hicks (1946) considered a number of definitions. Two in particular command
support in the literature. Hicksian income no. 1 is the maximum amount
that can be consumed while maintaining wealth intact. (2) Hicksian
income no. 2 is the maximum sustainable level of consumption. The
general consensus that emerges from the literature is that, with perfect
foresight, all capital gains are included in Hicksian income no. 1.
However, Asheim (1996) shows that some capital gains are excluded from
Hicksian income no. 2 when the interest rate varies over time. Both
income concepts coincide when the interest rate is fixed.
When the perfect foresight assumption is relaxed, a distinction
must be drawn between expected and unexpected capital gains. It is
important that we move beyond a perfect foresight setting because the
concept of income has been developed primarily to assist decision taking
under uncertainty. If income is meant to act as a budget constraint indicating the resources available for consumption each period, the
important question is how should a rational consumer react to unexpected
capital gains.
This article develops a general theoretical framework for the
measurement of Hicksian income no. 1 under uncertainty that is capable
of handling all kinds of capital gains on all kinds of assets ranging
from money market assets to mineral deposits. (3) First, the concept of
income with perfect foresight is developed and analyzed. In the
following section, uncertainty is introduced. Income depends on
expectations of future receipts that are liable to be revised with the
passage of time. The time at which income in a particular period is
measured is therefore crucial. Income can be measured at any time, but
attention has tended to focus on the beginning and end of the period.
Hicks (1946, 178-79) described income as measured at these times as ex
ante and ex post income. Ex ante income, as noted by Eisner (1990, p.
1180), is essentially the same as Friedman's (1957) concept of
permanent income. Ex post income as defined by Hicks--now usually
described as Haig-Simons income after two earlier proponents of the
concept--is a widely used objective measure familiar to most economists.
However, it is conceptually flawed because it utilizes two different and
generally inconsistent set of expectations, those held at the beginning
and end of the period. We define a family of conceptually consistent
income measures, each based only on the expectations held at the time of
measurement, that we describe as generalized-Hicksian income. This
family nests ex ante income but not Haig-Simons income.
Generalized-Hicksian income excludes unexpected capital gains, whereas
Haig-Simons includes them. Given the role that the concept of income is
intended to play in demand theory and the analysis of consumption
behavior, we conclude that the appropriate concept of income from an
economic viewpoint has to be of the generalized-Hicksian type (i.e.,
unexpected capital gains must be excluded), even though other concepts
might be more appropriate for some other purposes, such as taxation.
The same conceptual approach is then applied to financial, fixed,
and natural assets. For financial assets, we focus on fixed-term bonds.
There is controversy about the measurement of the interest on bonds
after unexpected changes in interest rates occur (see Joisce and Wright,
2001; Laliberte, 2002; Wright, 2002). We argue that the current
treatment implemented by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other
international and most national agencies is incorrect, thus potentially
causing government deficits to be mismeasured.
The measurement of income and capital gains from fixed assets, such
as buildings and equipment, hinges on the treatment of obsolescence. The
treatment of obsolescence is a longstanding source of controversy. (4)
Rapid technological progress in high-technology sectors has recently led
to a resurgence of interest in obsolescence and its impact on
depreciation and the capital stock (see Cartwright, 1986; Eisner, 1988;
Hulten et al., 1989; Jorgenson, 1989; Fraumeni, 1997; Gort and Wall,
1998). Sometimes all obsolescence is considered to be part of
depreciation (e.g., Eisner, 1988) and sometimes none (e.g., Jorgenson,
1989). In contrast, we argue that the correct treatment depends on the
extent to which it is expected. As an expected capital loss, foreseen
obsolescence should reduce income, whereas unforeseen obsolescence
should not.
For natural assets, our main focus is the huge capital gains or
losses experienced by resource-rich countries as a result of price
volatility in commodity markets. For example, Aaheim and Nyborg (1995)
find that, in certain years, changes in the value of Norway's stock
of oil exceed its gross domestic product (GDP). Hence, if these capital
gains or losses are included in income, a large fall in the price of oil
could cause Norway's national income to become negative in that
period. Unless capital gains (losses) are handled correctly, therefore,
the national income of resource-rich countries can become so distorted
and volatile as to be quite useless for analytic and policy purposes.
Our main findings are summarized in the conclusion.
II. ALTERNATIVE CONCEPTS OF INCOME AND THEIR TREATMENT OF CAPITAL
GAINS
Income is a fundamental and widely used economic concept. It
appears as an argument in demand functions and as a resource constraint
for a utility maximizing consumer. It is closely related to wealth--both
concepts depend on the same flows of expected receipts.
Income under Perfect Foresight
Throughout this article, all prices and values are measured in
constant dollars. Let [V.sub.t] denote the present value at the
beginning of period t of the stream of receipts from a stock of assets.
For purposes of income measurement, it is necessary to be able to track
the value of this stock over subsequent time periods. Let [V.sub.t,t+k]
denote the value of the stock at the beginning of period t + k, where k
[greater than or equal to] 0, assuming that no additional investment or
disinvestment has taken place up to that point. In other words,
[V.sub.t,t+k] is equal to the present value at the beginning of period t
+ k of the original stream of receipts from period t + k onwards,
assuming that none of the receipts from periods t to t + k - 1 are
reinvested. Likewise, let [R.sub.t,t+k+i] denote the receipts earned
during period t + k + i, where i, k [greater than or equal to] 0, on the
stock of assets existing at the beginning of period t. It is assumed
that receipts are paid at the end of each period.
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [r.sub.t], is the real interest rate in period t. If the
formula for [V.sub.t,t+k] in (1) is written out in full for the cases
where k = 0 and k = 1, it can be seen that [V.sub.tt] and [V.sub.t,t+1]
are related as follows:
(2) [V.sub.t,t+1] = (1 + [r.sub.t]) [V.sub.tt] - [R.sub.tt].
The value of the actual stock of assets at the start of period t +
k, namely, [V.sub.t+k,t+k] will not be the same as [V.sub.t,t+k] when
some of the receipts earned between periods t and t + k are reinvested
or if some of the assets are sold. For the case where k = 1, the amount
of this investment is determined by the difference between receipts
[R.sub.tt] and consumption [C.sub.t] in period t. Thus,
(3) [V.sub.t+1,t+1] = [V.sub.t,t+1] + [R.sub.tt] - [C.sub.t],
([R.sub.tt] - [C.sub.t]) being the amount reinvested. Combining (2)
and (3), it follows that
(4) [V.sub.t+1,t+1] = (1 + [r.sub.t] [V.sub.tt] - [C.sub.t].
To simplify the notation for the remainder of the article, in cases
where k = 0, we will write [V.sub.t] and [R.sub.t], respectively, in
place of [V.sub.tt] and [R.sub.tt]. Using this notation, rearranging
(2), it follows that
(5) [r.sub.t][V.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [V.sub.t,t+1] - [V.sub.t].
Similarly, rearranging (4), it follows that
(6) [r.sub.t] [V.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] + [V.sub.t+1] - [V.sub.t].
As will be shown shortly, these two expressions for the interest
earned on a stock of assets provide alternative ways of measuring
income.
Following Hicks (1946, p. 173), income can be defined as either the
maximum level of consumption that will maintain wealth intact (Hicksian
income no. 1) or as the maximum sustainable level of consumption
(Hicksian income no. 2). More formally, Hicksian income no. 1, denoted
here by [Y.sub.t], is defined as follows:
(7) [Y.sub.t] [equivalent to] Max{[C.sub.t:[V.sub.t+1] [greater
than or equal to] [V.sub.t],}.
Setting [V.sub.t+1] = [V.sub.t] in (6), it follows from (7) that
(8) [Y.sub.t] = [r.sub.t] [V.sub.t].
Substituting (5) and (6) into (8), it can be seen that Hicksian
income no. 1 can also be written as follows:
(9) [Y.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [V.sub.t,t+1] - [V.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] +
[V.sub.t+1] - [V.sub.t].
In other words, Hicksian income no. 1 is equal to total receipts
[R.sub.t] plus ([V.sub.t,t+1] - [V.sub.t]), the total capital gains on
the stock of assets existing at the beginning of the period. These
capital gains are an integral part of income. Equation (9) also shows
that income is equal to consumption [C.sub.t] plus ([V.sub.t+1] -
[V.sub.t]), the actual change in the value of the stock of assets. The
latter reflects the effects of investment or disinvestment as well as
capital gains. This change can be decomposed into the capital gain on
the stock held at the start of the period, ([V.sub.t,t+1] - [V.sub.t]),
and net investment during the period, ([V.sub.t+1] - [V.sub.t,t+1]):
that is,
(10) ([V.sub.t+1] - [V.sub.t]) = ([V.sub.t,t+1] - [V.sub.t]) +
([V.sub.t+1] - [V.sub.t,t+1]).
If there is no capital gain, income equals consumption plus net
investment.
By contrast, Hicksian income no. 2, denoted by [[??].sub.t], is
defined as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
which reduces to
(11) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
[[??].sub.t]. excludes part of the capital gain (loss) arising from
interest rate changes. Hicks's two concepts of income are
equivalent only when the interest rate does not change over time. In
this case, both [Y.sub.t] and [[??].sub.t], reduce to r[V.sub.t]. A rate
of consumption equal to r[V.sub.t] maintains wealth intact and is
sustainable indefinitely if r does not change. (5)
Income under Uncertainty
An individual's planned consumption path is constrained by
expected wealth. The individual must distinguish between and react quite
differently to expected and unexpected changes in asset values because
the latter require expected wealth, and hence expected consumption
possibilities, to be changed, whereas the former do not.
In the remainder of this article we focus on generalizations and
different applications of Hicksian income no. 1. It is the simpler
concept and is widely used in the national accounting and business
accounting literatures (see, for example, Meade and Stone, 1941;
Solomon, 1961). The strategy of maintaining wealth intact (i.e.,
Hicksian income no. 1) in the presence of uncertainty can be interpreted
in several different ways, each of which leads to a different concept
and measure of income. When there is uncertainty the estimated value of
a person's wealth at any point of time depends on the time at which
the estimate is made. Define [E.sub.s] [V.sub.t] as the expectation at
time s of the value of the stock of assets existing at the beginning of
period t. Time s can precede, coincide
with, or follow t. The stream of receipts ([R.sub.s], [R.sub.s+1]
,[R.sub.s+2], ...) can extend indefinitely into the future, and this
implies that [V.sub.t], in general, is never known for certain, even if
s > t . (6)
Haig-Simons Income. The Haig (1959)--Simons (1938) definition is
widely used by economists (see, for example, McElroy, 1976; Eisner,
1988; 1990). It is an ex post version of Hicksian income no. 1.
Haig-Simons income, denoted here by [Y.sup.HS.sub.1], is defined as
follows:
(12) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] [equivalent to]
Max{[C.sub.t]:[E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t+1] [greater than or equal to]
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t]}.
The first step to solving the maximization problem in (12) is to
generalize equation (6) to allow for uncertainty. Forming expectations
at the beginning and end of period t, respectively, the following
equations are obtained:
(13) [E.sub.t]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) = [E.sub.t][C.sub.t] +
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
(14) [r.sub.t][E.t+1][V.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1]
[V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t].
Next, equations (13) and (14) can be combined as follows:
(15) [E.sub.t]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t] + [r.sub.t][E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t]
= [E.sub.t][C.sub.t]+[C.sub.t] + [E.sub.t] [V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t+1]
[V.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t] [V.sub.t].
Now it follows from (12) that we can set [C.sub.t] in (15) equal to
[Y.sup.HS.sub.t] when [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t+1] = [E.sub.t] [V.sub.t].
Making these substitutions in (15), the following expression is
obtained: (7)
(16) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [E.sub.t]([r.sub.t] [V.sub.t]) +
[r.sub.t][E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] - [E.sub.t][C.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t+1] + [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t].
Finally, using (13) and (14) to substitute for
[E.sub.t]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) and [r.sub.t][E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t],
equation (16) reduces to
(17) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t].
This is the most familiar representation of Haig-Simons income as
the sum of consumption plus the actual change in wealth over the period.
(8) An alternative expression for [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] can be obtained by
generalizing equation (5) to allow for uncertainty as follows:
(18) [r.sub.t][E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1]
[V.sub.t,t+1] = [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t].
By substituting for [E.sub.t]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) -
[E.sub.t][C.sub.t] from (13) and [r.sub.t][E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] from
(18), equation (16) reduces to
(19) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t,t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
that is, the sum of receipts and the actual change in the value of
the stock of assets existing at the start of the period.
Haig-Simons income equals the amount a person can consume in period
t and be as well off at the beginning of period t+1 as they thought they
were at the beginning of period t. The basic flaw in the concept is that
a prudent consumer has no reason to wish to preserve [E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
intact as soon as events have shown it to be wrong.
Suppose there is a very large unexpected receipt in period t, such
as a lottery win, that immediately causes an upward revision in
estimated wealth. A household using the Haig-Simons definition of income
to guide its consumption decisions would be encouraged to spend all of
its lottery winnings in the current period to return wealth to its
initial level. In addition to being irrational, such a consumption
strategy would be quite arbitrary because it would make the rate of
consumption depend on the length of the accounting period (of whose
existence the household may not even be aware). Although these
observations may appear trite, they make the Haig-Simons concept
completely unsatisfactory and unacceptable as a concept of income. (9)
If a consumer cannot treat the whole of Haig-Simons income as being
available for consumption, it cannot be used to explain the behavior of
a rational consumer. It cannot be used for purposes of demand analysis
or for economic analysis in general. The Haig-Simons concept of income
fails when a measure of income is most needed: namely, when there is
uncertainty and the consumer has to react to unexpected shocks. (10)
Generalized-Hicksian Income. None of the objections just raised to
the Haig-Simons concept of income apply to the generalized-Hicksian
income concept proposed here. Generalized-Hicksian income estimates
wealth consistently at both the beginning and the end of the period on
the basis of the same information and expectations. The expectation at
time of income in period t is
(20) [E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] [equivalent to]
Max{[E.sub.s][C.sub.t]:[E.sub.s][V.sub.t+1] [greater than or equal to]
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t]}.
Again, generalizing (5) and (6) to allow for uncertainty, we obtain
that
(21) [E.sub.s]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) = [E.sub.s][R.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t,t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][C.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t].
Now, setting [E.sub.s] [V.sub.t+1] = [E.sub.s][V.sub.t] in (21), it
follows from (20) that
(22) [E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.s]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]),
which, using (21), can be rewritten as
(23) [E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][R.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t,t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][C.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t].
It should be noted that [R.sub.t] and [C.sub.t] in (23) are known
if s> t. Income as defined in (20) depends on the time, s, at which
it is estimated. Two cases of particular interest are the start and the
end of the accounting period. When s = t, [E.sub.t][Y.sub.t] is the ex
ante definition of income discussed in Hicks (1946, p. 172). Also, it is
worth noting that Friedman's (1957) concept of permanent income is
essentially the same as ex ante Hicksian income.
(24) [E.sub.t][Y.sub.t] = Max{[C.sub.t]:[E.sub.t][V.sub.t+1]
[greater than or equal to] [E.sub.t][V.sub.t]},
so that
(25) [E.sub.t][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.t]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) =
[E.sub.t][R.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t][V.sub.t,t+1] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t]) =
[E.sub.t][C.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t]).
Ex ante income, [E.sub.t][Y.sub.t], is the maximum amount that a
person can plan to consume in the period t and expect wealth at the end
of the period to be the same as estimated at the start of the period.
Hicks argues that this is the concept of income relevant to consumer
behavior, as does Friedman (1957) in his permanent income hypothesis.
When s = t+1, the corresponding ex post concept of income is
obtained.
(26) [E.sub.t+1] [Y.sub.t] = Max{[C.sub.t]:[E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t+1]
[greater than or equal to] [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t]},
so that
(27) [E.sub.t+1][Y.sub.t] = [r.sub.t]([E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t]) =
[R.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t,t+1] - [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t) =
[C.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t]).
Measuring income ex post does not mean that all uncertainty has
been resolved, simply that measurement takes place after the end of the
period when actual receipts and consumption in period t are known. Ex
post income is still a forward-looking measure. It depends on
expectations of future receipts held at the end of the period. These are
the same expectations that determine ex ante income for the following
period. It should be emphasized that ex post income, as defined in (26)
and (27), is not the income concept labeled as ex post by Hicks in Value
and Capital. Hicks chose to identify ex post income with Haig-Simons,
defining it as "consumption plus capital accumulation." Hicks
considered it to have the advantage of being "almost completely
objective," but he also dismissed it on the grounds that it must
contain unexpected capital gains, whereas "the income which is
relevant to conduct must always exclude windfall gains" (Hicks,
1946, p. 179). We will show that unlike Haig-Simons income, ex post
income excludes unexpected capital gains.
Capital Gains
The capital gain on a given stock of assets is defined as the
change in its value between two points of time. [G.sub.(t,t+k)] is used
to denote the capital gain accruing between the start of period t and
the start of period t + k on the stock existing at the start of period
t.
(28) [G.sub.(t,t+k)] [equivalent to] [E.sub.t+k] [V.sub.t,t+k] -
[E.sub.t] [V.sub.t]
Defined this way, capital gains can be divided into expected and
unexpected components. The expected capital gain accruing between the
start of period t and t+k, based on expectations at time s is
(29) [E.sub.s][G.sub.(t,t+k)] [equivalent to] [E.sub.s]
[V.sub.t,t+k] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t].
An unexpected capital gain, denoted here by UG, occurs when the
estimated value of the stock of assets at some point of time is changed
as a result of revised expectations. The unexpected capital gain on the
stock at time t resulting from new information gained during the time
interval (h, l), where h [less than or equal to] l, is defined as
follows:
(30) [U.sub.(h,l)][G.sub.t] [equivalent to] [E.sub.l][V.sub.t] -
[E.sub.h][V.sut.t].
Of particular interest are the cases in which s = t or s = t+k
in(29) and h = t and l = t+k in (30). For these cases, it is possible to
decompose a capital gain into its expected and unexpected components (in
two different ways).
(31) [G.sub.(t,t+k)] = [E.sub.t][G.sub.(t,t+k)] +
[U.sub.(t,t+k)][G.sub.(t+k)] = [E.sub.t+k][G.sub.(t,t+k)] +
[U.sub.(t,t+k)][G.sub.t]
It can now be seen that Haig-Simons income can be written as the
sum of receipts and capital gains, that is,
(32) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t,t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [G.sub.(t,t+1)].
Similarly, generalized-Hicksian income can be written as the sum of
expected receipts and expected capital gains, specifically,
(33) [E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][R.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][V.sub.t,t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][R.sub.t] +
[E.sub.s][G.sub.(t,t+1)].
This in turn implies that ex post income and Haig-Simons income are
related as follows:
(34) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t,t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t] = ([R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t,t+1] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t] =
[E.sub.t+1][Y.sub.t] + [U.sub.(t,t+1)[G.sub.t].
Haig-Simons income is equal to ex post income plus the unexpected
capital gain or loss in period t resulting from new information that
emerged during period t. Conversely, (34) shows that the way to estimate
ex post income in practice is to start with Haig-Simons income, which
can be measured objectively, and then deduct those gains or losses that
at the end of the period are known or deemed to have been unexpected.
Returning to the example of a lottery, suppose a household wins a
lottery of value [X.sub.t] in period t and that nothing else unexpected
happens during this period. It follows that
[U.sub.(t,t+1)][G.sub.t] = [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t] = [X.sub.t], [E.sub.t+1][G.sub.(t,t+1)] =
[E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t,t+k] - [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] = [r.sub.t][X.sub.t].
Referring back to equations (32) and (33), we can see that
Haig-Simons includes the whole of the lottery winnings in income for
period t, whereas ex post generalized-Hicksian income includes only the
interest earned on the lottery win during period t.
Income and Capital Gains on Individual Assets
The distinction between [V.sub.t,t+1] and [V.sub.t+1] is applicable
to a stock of assets, which can be extended by acquisition of new assets
or depleted by the sale of existing assets. However, when tracking a
single asset through time from t to t + 1, [V.sub.t,t+1] and [V.sub.t+1]
are the same. For single assets, therefore, the formulae for Hicksian
income no. 1, Haig-Simons income and generalized Hicksian income
simplify as follows:
(35) [Y.sub.t] = [r.sub.t][V.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [V.sub.t+1] -
[V.sub.t],
(36) [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [E.sub.t-1][V.sub.t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
(37) [E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.s]([r.sub.t][V.sub.t]) =
[E.sub.s][R.sub.t] + [E.sub.s][V.sub.t+1] - [E.sub.s][V.sub.t].
Similarly, the formulae for the total and expected capital gain on
an individual asset simplify to
(38) [G.sub.(t,t+k)] = [E.sub.t+k][V.sub.t+k] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
(39) [E.sub.s][G.sub.(t,t+k) = [E.sub.s][V.sub.t+k] - [E.sub.s]
[V.sub.t].
The remaining sections of the article focus on the measurement of
income from individual assets, so these are the definitions of income
and capital gains that will be used primarily from here on.
III. CAPITAL GAINS AND INCOME FROM FINANCIAL ASSETS: THE CASE OF
FIXED-TERM BONDS
A fixed-term bond pays a coupon R for N - 1 periods and a lump sum L in period N. Hence, the only source of uncertainty is the interest
rate from period s onward.
(40) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
At any point of time, there is a firm expectation of a capital gain
(or loss) accruing to the holder (or issuer) of the bond over its
remaining life equal to the difference between the current market value
and the redemption value. This expected gain accrues gradually as the
bond approaches maturity. It is a classic example of a gain that
constitutes income, the gain being identified with interest on the bond
for this reason. The gradual growth in the value of the bond reflects
the accumulation of the reinvested interest.
There is some dispute, nevertheless, about the measurement of
income from bonds. (11) This dispute has potentially important
implications for the government's fiscal position, because it is
typically a large debtor, and interest on the national debt can account
for a large part of government expenditures. The government surplus or
deficit, as the residual between income and expenditures, is therefore
sensitive to any specification errors in the measurement of income from
interest payments. Moreover, even very small changes in the government
deficit can have significant impacts on both fiscal and monetary policy.
Within the European Monetary Union the Stability Pact imposes draconian constraints on the economic policies of the governments of its member
countries by fixing an upper limit to the government deficit as a
percentage of GDP.
The controversy relates to the treatment of an unexpected change in
the interest rate, and the resulting unexpected capital gain or loss for
the holder and the issuer. The change in the market price of the bond
automatically changes the gap between the current price and the fixed
redemption value, that is, the expected return over the remaining life
of the bond, which in turn implies that the remaining interest must also
change. This final implication is disputed by the IMF and some other
international and national agencies. The IMF argues that the total
interest over the life of a bond, and the rate at which it accrues,
cannot change, being inexorably fixed by the price at which the bond was
first issued. (12) If the same interest continues to be recorded after
the unexpected interest change as before, the total interest after the
change diverges from the sum of the coupon interest and the gain
expected by the market. To reconcile a constant rate of interest accrual with the actual current market values of the bonds, arbitrary adjustment
items have to be introduced. (13)
The interest on bonds can be derived within the theoretical
framework presented above. Consider for simplicity a zero-coupon bond issued at the beginning of period t. Also, suppose that the bond matures
in period t + N. Though it is true that the redemption value is fixed,
that is, [E.sub.t] [V.sub.t+N] = [E.sub.t+1] [V.sub.t+N] = ... =
[E.sub.t+N] [V.sub.t+N,] the value of the bond at any other time,
including the time of issue, is not. It depends on when the valuation is
made. The IMF and other agencies with similar views effectively define
the income from the bond in period t+i (where i < N) as follows:
(41) [Y.sub.t+i] = [E.sub.t][V.sub.t+i+1] - [E.sub.t][V.sub.t+i].
This is a version of generalized-Hicksian income as defined in
(37). However, it arbitrarily and irrevocably links estimates of income
in all future periods to the expectations prevailing at the time the
bond was issued. Such an estimate of income ceases to be relevant as
soon as events have shown those expectations to be wrong. Both the
issuer and the holder have the option of trading but at prices different
from those previously expected.
Suppose that the interest rate rises unexpectedly in period t+i,
that is, [r.sub.t+i] > [E.sub.t+i][r.sub.t+i]. The market value of
the bond drops instantaneously and bond holders incur an unexpected
capital loss. More formally, [E.sub.t+i+1] [V.sub.t+i] <
[E.sub.t+i][V.sub.t+i], which implies from equation (30) that
[U.sub.(t+i,t+i+1)[G.sub.t+i] < 0. Somewhat less intuitive is the
fact that [E.sub.t+i+1] [Y.sub.t+i] > [E.sub.t+i][Y.sub.t+i] (see
equation [37]), that is, the income earned from the bond rises. However,
in the alternative treatment advocated by the IMF and others the
interest (and hence income) received from the bond is assumed not to
rise. It is necessary, therefore, to record part of the subsequent
expected rise in the value of the bond as if it were unexpected and not
income, even though one point on which there is some consensus in the
economics literature is that expected gains of this kind are income.
This means that interest payments by governments, and hence government
expenditure and the budget deficit (surplus), will be underestimated
(overestimated) after a rise in interest rates. Conversely, savings by
the sectors holding the government debt will also be underestimated.
IV. CAPITAL GAINS AND INCOME FROM FIXED ASSETS
Depreciation and Income
The concepts of depreciation and income are closely linked. In a
perfect foresight setting, Hotelling (1925) defines the depreciation on
an asset of vintage k (i.e., produced in period k) used in production
during period t as the decrease in its value between the beginning and
end of the period.
(42) [D.sup.k.sub.t] [equivalent to] [V.sup.k.sub.t] -
[V.sup.k.sub.t+1]
Using equation (35), the Hicksian income no. 1, [Y.sub.t], derived
from a fixed asset in period t, is linked to depreciation as follows:
(43) [Y.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] + [V.sup.k.sub.t+1] - [V.sup.k.sub.t] =
[R.sub.t] - [D.sup.k.sub.t].
[R.sub.t] is often described as the gross income from an asset and
[Y.sub.t] as the net income, the difference between gross and net being
identified with depreciation at all levels of aggregation up to GDP and
net domestic product (NDP).
When there are unexpected shocks, competing definitions of
depreciation exist in the economics literature, each of which is
consistent with a different concept of income. One definition of
depreciation, [D.sup.k,HS.sub.t], is consistent with the Haig-Simons
concept of income.
(44) [D.sup.k,HS.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t+1] [??] [Y.sup.HS.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] -
([E.sub.t][V.sup.k.sub.t] - [E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t+1]) = [R.sub.t] -
[D.sup.k,HS.sub.t]
Comparing (44) with (38) shows that Haig-Simons depreciation,
[D.sup.k,HS.sub.t] equals--[G.sub.(t,t+1), the actual capital loss on
the asset in period t, including any unexpected loss due to revised
expectations or unexpected events, such as wars or natural disasters,
unconnected with production.
A second definition values [V.sub.t] and [V.sub.t+1] consistently
on the basis of the same information and expectations. It is associated
with the generalized-Hicksian concept of income.
(45) [E.sub.s][D.sup.k.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[E.sub.s][V.sup.k.sub.t] - [E.sub.s][V.sup.k.sub.t+1] [??]
[E.sub.s][Y.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][R.sub.t] - (E.sub.s][V.sup.k.sub.t] -
[E.sub.s][V.sup.k.sub.t+1] = [R.sub.t] - [E.sub.s][D.sup.k.sub.t],
where [E.sub.s][D.sup.k.sub.t] denotes the expectation at time s of
depreciation of an asset of vintage k in period t. Comparing (45) with
(39) shows that [E.sub.s][D.sup.k.sub.t] = [E.sub.s][G.sub.(t,t+1)], the
expected capital loss on the asset in period t. Two important special
cases are when s = t and s = t+1, referred to here as ex ante and ex
post depreciation, respectively. (14) The relationship between
Haig-Simons depreciation and ex post depreciation is given in (46). (15)
(46) [-D.sup.k,HS.sub.t] = [E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t+1] -
[E.sub.t][V.sup.k.sub.t] + ([E.sub.t+1] [V.sup.k.sub.t+1] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t] - ([E.sub.t][V.sup.k.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.1] = -[E.sub.t+1][D.sup.k.sub.t] +
[U.sub.(t,t+1][G.sub.t].
Hence ex post depreciation excludes unexpected capital gains or
losses, whereas the Haig-Simons definition includes them.
Unexpected Capital Losses on Fixed Assets
The main source of unexpected capital losses on fixed assets is
unanticipated obsolescence. It can result from unforeseen scientific or
technological advances, price shocks (especially to oil), or changes in
tastes that reduce the demand for the services of existing assets.
Spectacular examples are provided by railways and oceanliners. Even
buildings and structures may be eventually retired on grounds of
unforeseen obsolescence, especially as such assets may continue to be
used almost indefinitely with suitable maintenance. Major unexpected
capital losses can also result from the physical damage to assets caused
by wars, terrorist attacks, earthquakes, floods, or other natural
disasters.
There is still some controversy over the treatment of unexpected
capital losses on fixed assets in national accounts. The international
System of National Accounts implicitly adopts the ex post definition of
income and depreciation and hence excludes them. However, Eisner (1988)
has argued in favor of a Haig-Simons concept of depreciation that
includes unexpected losses (such as those due to natural disasters) even
though these losses are unconnected with processes of production. The
U.S. national accounts have also used the Haig-Simons concept in the
past (see Katz and Herman, 1997). It follows from (46) and the fact that
unexpected capital losses on fixed assets tend to far exceed capital
gains that Haig-Simons will tend to overestimate depreciation, thus
imparting a downward bias to net national income and net saving.
Depreciation, income, and saving will also tend to be unduly volatile.
Expected Capital Losses on Fixed Assets
The depreciation on an asset over a period of time can be
decomposed into wear and tear and expected obsolescence. Wear and tear
measures the expected decline in the value of an asset due to the fact
that its actual use reduces the total quantity of services that it is
expected to be capable of delivering over the rest of its life and
possibly also the rate at which they can be delivered. It is essentially
a function of the age of the asset.
Obsolescence, however, is a function of time and independent of the
rate at which the asset is used. An asset will be scrapped if there is
no demand for its services, even if it still functions perfectly. This
often happens with high-technology assets, such as computers, whose
service lives are determined by obsolescence and not by declining
performance. Because obsolescence is a common and familiar phenomenon,
it will be built into the present value of the flow of services expected
from the asset at the time it is acquired and thereby affect the rate at
which it subsequently depreciates.
Ex post depreciation is decomposed into expected obsolescence,
[E.sub.t+1][[OMEGA].sup.k,k+1.sub.t,t+1], and wear and tear,
[E.sub.t+1][[LAMBDA].sup.k,k+1.sub.t+1], components as follows:
(47) [E.sub.t+1][D.sup.k.sub.t] = [E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t+1] = [[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k+1.sub.t+1]] + [[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k+1.sub.t+1] -
[E.sub.t+1][V.sup.k.sub.t+1]] = [E.sub.t+1][[OMEGA].sup.k,k+1.sub.t,t+1]
+ [E.sub.t+1][[LAMBDA].sup.k,k+1.sub.t+1]
[E.sub.t+1][[LAMBDA].sup.k,k+1].sub.t+1] (wear and tear) in (47)
measures the difference between the values of assets of vintages k and
k+1 at the end of period t+1, while
[E.sub.t+1][[OMEGA].sup.k,k+1.sub.t,t+1] (expected obsolescence)
measures the decline in value from period to period of identical assets
of the same age, namely, the difference between the value of vintage k
in period t and vintage k+1 in period t+1. In practice, the situation
may be complicated by the fact that successive vintages may not be
homogeneous--each vintage being more efficient than its predecessor. In
this case, the different vintages have to be adjusted to convert them
into units of constant quality to measure wear and tear.
Recently, an old controversy over obsolescence has reemerged.
Within the framework of vintage accounting used for capital stock
measurement, Jorgenson (1989) defines depreciation not as the change in
the value of an individual asset over time but as the difference between
the values of successive vintages of otherwise identical assets at the
same point of time. Obsolescence is thereby excluded because it does not
affect the relative values of the different vintages. Depreciation is
restricted to wear and tear as already defined. This concept is used,
for example, by Hulten and Wykoff (1996) and Fraumeni (1997).
To measure the income from an individual asset, however, it is
necessary to know the expected change in its value over time, which
logically must include the effects of expected obsolescence as well as
wear and tear. This expected change has long been understood to be the
appropriate concept of depreciation for income measurement. For example,
in a debate with Pigou (1941), Hayek (1941) strongly advocated the
inclusion of expected obsolescence, citing an example in which
depreciation is entirely attributable to obsolescence, a common enough
occurrence today with computers and other high-tech equipment. He was
subsequently backed by Hicks (1942, p. 178) and Samuelson (1961, p. 36).
We conclude that to be consistent with the generalized Hicksian
concept of income, depreciation must include expected obsolescence and
exclude unexpected obsolescence together with other unexpected capital
losses. This is the position adopted in national accounts. The fact that
there is now some dispute and confusion with two different concepts of
depreciation in circulation is symptomatic of the fact that there is
still no consensus over the underlying concept of income. If expected
obsolescence were to be omitted, depreciation would be underestimated,
thus imparting a systematic upward bias to net national income and
saving.
V. CAPITAL GAINS AND INCOME FROM NATURAL CAPITAL ASSETS
Exploration and Capital Gains
Should additions to the natural capital stock due to exploration
activities be treated as unexpected capital gains or as produced
investment? The answer to this question can have a profound effect on
estimates of national income for resource-rich countries, because if
treated as investment they are part of income, whereas if treated as
unexpected capital gains they are not.
The answer depends on the extent to which the fruits of exploration
activities are expected or unexpected. Clearly, they are not completely
expected, because exploration involves a significant amount of
uncertainty. On the other hand, an oil company would not invest in
exploration if it did not expect to find something. Scientific
exploration is a productive activity, undertaken by specialist
consultants, with an outcome that is predictable over the longer term
even though individual exploration projects may be subject to
considerable uncertainty. For each exploration project an oil company
undertakes or commissions, it must have prior expectations as to how
much oil it will find. The expenditures on exploration incurred by an
oil or mining company are a form of investment and should provide a
lower bound to the estimated value of the expected find. If the reserves
discovered are significantly greater than expected the oil company
experiences an unexpected capital gain, and if they are smaller it
incurs an unexpected capital loss. (16)
Capital Gains and Spurious Fluctuations in Income and Output
An interesting example in which the discovery of new stock created
a large capital gain occurred in Indonesia in 1974. Changes in U.S. tax
law and Indonesian contracts favorable to exploration activities led to
a large increase in reported reserves of oil in Indonesia in 1974. As a
result, Indonesia experienced a huge unexpected capital gain on its
stock of natural capital. Repetto et al. (1989) estimate national income
for Indonesia between 1971 and 1984. However, they use the Haig-Simons
definition of income, [Y.sup.HS.sub.t]. As a result, Indonesia's
national income experiences a huge upward spike in 1974, which has
nothing whatever to do with the level of productive activity in
Indonesia or with the sustainability of its consumption. A similar but
even more spectacular example is provided by the exceptional oil finds
in Alaska in 1970. According to Nordhaus and Kokkelenberg (1999), these
finds augmented U.S. oil assets by nearly 50%, or almost $100 billion at
1987 prices. If the Haig-Simons definition of income were to be used and
the additional reserves included in output and income, this would have
changed the growth of U.S. GDP between 1969 and 1970 from 0.03% to
3.14%. As Nordhaus and Kokkelenberg (1999, p. 81) observe, "The
trend in real non-minerals GDP growth would have been seriously
distorted, wiping out the 1970 recession and causing an apparent
recession in 1971."
Even larger spurious fluctuations can be caused by including in GDP
and national income the capital gains or losses caused by fluctuating commodity prices for small countries with large reserves. For example,
suppose the price of oil rises unexpectedly during period t, and that
this price rise is perceived as reasonably long-term. This implies that
for an oil-rich country, [E.sub.t+1][V.sub.t] > [E.sub.t][V.sub.t],
and hence it experiences an unexpected capital gain, that is,
[U.sub.(t,t+1)][G.sub.t] > 0. For a country with large oil reserves,
this capital gain could be huge relatively to GDP. In fact, it could
exceed GDP. Aaheim and Nyborg (1995) find that, in some years, this is
exactly what happened to Norway (see also Aslaksen et al., 1990). If
national income is measured using the Haig-Simons definition,
[Y.sup.HS.sub.t], and full account is taken of capital gains (losses) on
natural capital, then the income series for a resource-rich country may
be so volatile as to be virtually useless for policy purposes and may
indeed occasionally go negative. (17) The ex post income,
[E.sub.t+1][Y.sub.t], of a resource-rich country, by contrast, will be
relatively insensitive to unexpected changes in the stock or price of
commodities because it excludes unexpected capital gains.
VI. CONCLUSION
The concept of income, although fundamental to economics, continues
to generate controversy and confusion, especially with regard to the
treatment of unexpected capital gains. This article developed a general
theoretical framework for measuring national and household income and
the income derived from individual assets in the presence of unexpected
capital gains. In particular, our analysis raises a number of important
issues for the treatment of financial, fixed, and natural assets. These
issues are of more than merely technical interest because they can
significantly affect a number of major macroeconomic aggregates,
including national income and saving, balance of payments deficits,
government deficits, and depreciation.
ABBREVIATIONS
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
IMF: International Monetary Fund
(1.) See, for example, the debate among Eisner (1990). Scott
(1990), and Bradford (1990) and between Laliberte (2002) and Wright
(2002).
(2.) This concept, although often attributed to Hicks (1946), has a
long history. For example, in 1832, German economist Hermann wrote:
"Income is that portion of an individual's receipts which that
individual may consume without injury to his capital stock" (quoted
in Wueller, 1938).
(3.) Although Hicksian income no. 2 has received mo attention in
the environmental accounting literature (due to its emphasis on
sustainability), here we focus on Hicksian income no. 1 because it is
the concept more familiar to households, firms, and government. Anyway,
the choice between the two concepts under perfect foresight is not the
issue of this article. We focus on the fact that economic agents face
considerable uncertainty about the future resources and have to revise
their expectations unexpected events occur. The conclusions we reach
about the treatment of capital gains would be the same, irrespective of which of the two income concepts is used.
(4.) See, for example, the debate between Pigou (1941), Hayek
(1941), and Hicks (1942).
(5.) Equations (9) and (10) show that if there is no capital gain,
Hicksian income no. 1 equals consumption plus net investment.
Weitzman's (1976) seminal paper on national accounting showed that
under the assumption of a constant interest rate in an economy with a
single consumption and investment good, national income, defined as the
sum of consumption and net investment, can be interpreted as a measure
of welfare. In our context, what is interesting is the absence of
capital gains in Weitzman's welfare measure. A natural way of
incorporating capital gains into Weitzman's model is by assuming
that the price of capital changes over time in a specified way (as for
example might be the case for an open economy exporting a nonrenewable
natural resource whose price follows the Hotelling rule) rather than
being determined endogenously. In this case, the price of capital itself
becomes a state variable in the Hamiltonian, and hence the resulting
capital gains are part of income (and welfare).
(6.) The estimation of [V.sub.t] is not considered here. Useful
references are Jorgenson (1996) for fixed assets. Miller and Upton
(1985) for natural assets, and Deaton (1992) for human capital assets.
(7.) Equation (16) clearly illustrates that Haig-Simons income
cannot be expressed as the return (interest) earned on wealth.
(8.) Although consumption plus the actual change in wealth is a
valid measure of income under perfect foresight, as shown by equation
(9), the corresponding ex post version under uncertainty using
end-of-period expectations is not Haig-Simons but equation (27) as will
be explained later.
(9.) Notice that when a large receipt is foreseen with certainty
during some period--for example, an inheritance held in trust or the
redemption of a bond--its discounted value is already included in the
household's wealth at the start of the period. When the receipt
occurs, the household's asset portfolio changes, but its total
wealth is unaffected.
(10.) Although Haig-Simons income is, in general, a misleading
guide to household consumption decisions, it could nevertheless be
useful for determining the tax base. Its chief attraction in this
context is that it is relatively easy to mea sure or assess (a matter of
critical importance to tax collectors). However, its use in this context
has some unfortunate consequences. In particular, as noted by Kaldor
(1955), when the tax system is progressive, it discriminate against
households with volatile receipts streams.
(11.) This dispute has been going on for some years. A
comprehensive survey of the issues can be found in Joisce and Wright
(2001).
(12.) More precisely, the IMF in its Balance of Payments Manual
(1995) recognizes a change in interest when a bond is traded after a
change in the interest rate has occurred. However, in the international
System of National Accounts (1993), used by the IMF and national
statistical offices and for which it is jointly responsible with a
number of other international agencies, no change of interest is
recorded whether the bond is traded or not. A paper posted on the
IMF's Web site in March 2002 (see Laliberte, 2002) sets out the
IMF's position. A further paper by Wright (2002), which is broadly
consistent with our approach, replying to Laliberte was posted on the
IMF's Web site in July 2002.
(13.) The same issues are currently under debate in commercial
accounting. Under "fair value accounting," the interest would
be recorded as proposed in this article and not on the basis of the
original issue price. See Joint Working Group of Standard Setters:
"Draft Standard and Basis for Conclusion on Financial Instruments
and Similar Items," International Accounting Standards Committee,
Dec. 2000, paragraphs 6.58 to 6.62, quoted in Wright (2002).
(14.) Hicks(1942. p. 177) proposed a definition of ex post
depreciation that coincides with [E.sub.s] [D.sup.k.sub.t] when s = t +
1. However, this concept does not figure anywhere in the widely quoted
chapter on income in Value and Capital (1946) and is not consistent with
ex post income as defined there.
(15.) Because depreciation is defined as a decrease in the value of
an asset over time, whereas an unexpected capital gain is an increase in
the value of an asset, it is convenient (following Hotelling) to
multiply through by--1 to reverse the signs in (46).
(16.) In practice, the potential capital gains or losses are
asymmetrical as the possible gains are unlimited while the losses are
constrained by the costs of the exploration.
(17.) To see why this is the case, see equation (34).
REFERENCES
Aaheim, A., and K. Nyborg. "On the Interpretation and
Applicability of a Green National Product." Review of Income and
Wealth, 41(1), 1995, 57-71.
Asheim, G. B. "Capital Gains and Net National Product in Open
Economies." Journal of Public Economics, 59(3), 1996, 419-34.
Aslaksen, I., K. A. Brekke, T. A. Johnsen, and A. Aaheim.
"Petroleum Resources and the Management of National Wealth,"
in Recent Modelling Approaches in Applied Energy Economics, edited by O.
Bjerkholt, O. Olsen, and J. Vislie. London: Routledge, Chapman &
Hall, 1990.
Bradford, D. F. "Comment on Scott and Eisner." Journal of
Economic Literature, 28(3), 1990, 1183-86.
Cartwright, D. W. "Improved Deflation of Purchases of
Computers." Survey of Current Business, 66(3), 1986, 7-9.
Deaton, A. Understanding Consumption. Oxford:Clarendon Press, 1992.
Eisner, R. "Extended Accounts for National Income and
Product." Journal of Economic Literature, 26(4), 1988, 1611 84.
--. "Extended Accounts for National Income and Product:
Reply." Journal of Economic Literature, 28(3), 1990, 1179-83.
Fraumeni, B. M. "Depreciation in the NIPA's." Survey
of Current Business, 77(7), 1997, 7-23.
Friedman, M. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1957.
Gale, W. G., and J. Sabelhaus. "Perspectives on the Household
Saving Rate." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1999,
181-214.
Gort, M., and R. A. Wall. "Obsolescence, Input Augmentation,
and Growth Accounting." European Economic Review, 42(9), 1998,
1653-65.
Haig, R. M. "The Concept of Income: Economic and Legal
Aspects," in Readings in the Economics of Taxation, edited by R. A.
Musgrave and C. S. Shoup. Homewood, IL: Irwin (originally published in
1921), 1959, 54-76.
Hayek, F. A. "Maintaining Capital Intact: A Reply."
Economica, 8, 1941, 276-78.
Hicks, J. R. "Maintaining Capital Intact: A Further
Suggestion." Economica, 9, 1942, 174-79.
--. Value and Capital, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1946.
Hotelling, H. "A General Mathematical Theory of
Depreciation." Journal of the American Statistical Association,
September 1925, 340-53. (Reprinted in Readings in the Concept and
Measurement of Income, edited by R. H. Parker and G. C. Harcourt.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969, 261-75.)
Hulten, C. R., and F. C. Wykoff. "Issues in the Measurement of
Economic Depreciation: Introductory Remarks, Symposium on
Depreciation." Economic Inquiry, 34(1), 1996, 10-23.
Hulten, C. R., J. W. Robertson, and F. C. Wykoff. "Energy,
Obsolescence, and the Productivity Slowdown," in Technology and
Capital Formation, edited by D. W. Jorgenson and R. Landau. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press, 1989, 225-58.
International Monetary Fund. Balance of Payments Manual.
Washington, DC: IMF, 1995.
Joisce, J., and C. Wright. "Statistical Treatment of Accrual
of Interest on Debt Securities." IMF Working Paper 01/132, 2001.
Jorgenson, D. W. "Capital as a Factor of Production," in
Technology and Capital Formation, edited by D. W. Jorgenson and R.
Landau. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989, 1-35.
--. "Empirical Studies of Depreciation." Economic
Inquiry, 34(1), 1996, 24-2.
Kaldor, N. "The Concept of Income in Economic Theory," in
An Expenditure Tax, 54-78. London: Allen and Unwin, 1955. (Reprinted in
part in Readings in the Concept and Measurement of Income, edited by R.
H. Parker and G. C. Harcourt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1969, 161-82.)
Katz, A. J., and S. W. Herman. "Improved Estimates of Fixed
Reproducible Tangible Wealth 1929-95." Survey of Current Business,
77(5), 1997, 69-92.
Laliberte, L. "Income from Bonds: The 1993 SNA Treatment." Mimeo, Statistics Department, International Monetary
Fund, Washington, DC, 2002.
McElroy, M. B. "Capital Gains and Social Income."
Economic Inquiry, 14(2), 1976, 221-40.
Meade, J. E., and R. Stone. "The Construction of Tables of
National Income, Expenditure, Savings and Investment." Economic
Journal June-September 1941, 216-33. (Reprinted in Readings in the
Concept and Measurement of Income, edited by R. H. Parker and G. C.
Harcourt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969, 329-46.)
Miller, M. H., and C. W. Upton. "A Test of the Hotelling
Valuation Principle." Journal of Political Economy, 93(1), 1985,
1-25.
Nordhaus, W. D., and E. C. Kokkelenberg, eds. "Nature's
Numbers: Expanding the National Income Accounts to Include the
Environment." Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1999.
Pigou, A. C. "Maintaining Capital Intact." Economica, 8,
1941, 271-75.
Repetto, R., W. McGrath, M. Wells, C. Beer, and F. Rossini. Wasting
Assets: Natural Resources in the National Income Accounts. Washington,
DC: World Resources Institute, 1989.
Samuelson, P. A. "The Evaluation of 'Social Income':
Capital Formation and Wealth," in The Theory of Capital Proceedings
of an IEA Conference, edited by F. A. Lutz and D. C. Hague. New York:
St. Martin's Press, 1961.
Scott, M. "Extended Accounts for National Income and Product:
A Comment." Journal of Economic Literature, 28(3), 1990, 1172-79.
Simons, H. Personal Income Taxation. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1938. (Reprinted in part in Readings in the Concept and
Measurement of Income, edited by R. H. Parker and G. C. Harcourt.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969, 63-73.)
Solomons, D. "Economic and Accounting Concepts of
Income." Accounting Review, 36, 1961, 374-83. (Reprinted in
Readings in the Concept and Measurement of Income, edited by R. H.
Parker and G. C. Harcourt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969,
106-19.)
System of National Accounts. Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris,
Washington, DC: Commission of the European Communities, International
Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,
United Nations, World Bank, 1993.
United Nations Statistics Division. SNA News and Notes, 12, 2000.
Weitzman, M. L. "On the Welfare Significance of National
Product in a Dynamic Economy." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
90(1), 1976, 156-62.
Wright, C. "Income from Bonds: The 1993 SNA Treatment--A
Response." Mimeo, Bank of England, London, 2002.
Wueller, P. H. "Concepts of Taxable Income: The German
Contribution." Political Science Quarterly, 53, 1938, 83-110.
ROBERT J. HILL and T. PETER HLL *
* We thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments.
Hill. R. J.: Associate Professor. School of Economics, University
of New South Wales, Sydney 2052, Australia. Phone 61-2-93853076, Fax
61-2-93136337, E-mail r.hill@unsw.edu.au
Hill, T. P.: Formerly Professor, School of Economics and Social
Studies, University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ, England, and Head
of Economic Statistics and National Accounts, Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development, Paris. Phone 44-1508-470372, Fax
44-1508-471311, E-mail peter.hill@flordon.freeserve.co.uk