Computers and productivity: Are aggregation effects important?
McGuckin, Robert H. ; Stiroh, Kevin J.
KEVIN J. STIROH (*)
This article examines the empirical implications of aggregation
bias when measuring the productive impact of computers. To isolate "aggregation in variables" and "aggregation in
relations" problems, we compare production function estimates
across specifications, econometric estimators, and data levels. The
results show both sources of bias are important, especially when moving
from sectors to the economy level, and when the elasticity of all types
of non-computer capital are restricted to be equal. The elasticity of
computers is surprisingly stable between industry and sector regressions
and does not appear biased by incorporating a restrictive measure of
non-computer capital. The data consistently show that computers have a
large impact on output. (JEL 03)
I. INTRODUCTION
Economic research relies heavily on aggregated data, and there are
good reasons for this. Aggregation combines details to give a clearer
picture of performance. It also simplifies analysis because it is much
easier to work with a small set of aggregate variables than to try to
model the myriad of details that lie beneath. A third reason is that
aggregation enables survey organizations to collect data in broad
categories, which limits processing and collection costs. Finally,
aggregation protects confidential microdata, although this is becoming
less important as new institutions are developed to maintain secrecy while still allowing access by researchers.
Aggregation, however, also has important problems and the
possibility of systematic bias from the use of aggregate data has long
been recognized. In an early paper, Theil (1954) formally examined the
possibilities for biased estimates of economic relationships when
aggregates were used in place of information on individuals or firms.
Similarly, the long debate over the "existence" of an
aggregate production function or an aggregate measure of capital is
essentially about the difficulties when aggregate data and relationships
are used to represent the underlying microeconomic production
relationships. (1) Although much has been learned about how aggregation
should be done and what conditions are required for meaningful
aggregates, for example, Diewert (1976), aggregation remains an
important issue.
The recent availability of microdata, for example, has led to a
host of studies documenting widespread differences in the
characteristics of economic units within seemingly homogeneous groups or
industries, for example, Baily et al. (1992), Jensen and McGuckin
(1996), and Haltiwanger (1997). Arguably, the common practice of using a
"representative firm" model to justify use of aggregates is
not appropriate in these situations and recent empirical work supports
this in a wide variety of situations, for example, productivity growth,
investment dynamics, and employment movements as surveyed in Haltiwanger
(1997). As a concrete example of how aggregation may be misleading,
McGuckin and Nguyen (1999) find an impact of ownership change on
productivity in plant-level data, but the relationship becomes obscured
when firm-level observations are used.
This article examines the empirical implications of using different
types of aggregate data in a specific context-measuring the productive
impact of computers. This application is of particular interest in light
of the widespread discussion and controversy concerning the so-called
computer productivity paradox. This puzzle can be traced to the
observation by Robert Solow (1987) that, although computers were
becoming ubiquitous, aggregate productivity remained sluggish. One
potential explanation, presented by Oliner and Sichel (1994) and Sichel
(1997), emphasized that computers represent a relatively small portion
of economy-wide capital. Because computer capital was small, it is not
surprising that it did not have a large impact on aggregate productivity
or growth in earlier years. (2)
Though certainly true in an aggregate growth accounting framework,
this doesn't explain the disparity of findings at lower levels of
aggregation that analyzed data for same period of the 1980s and early
1990s. Berndt and Morrison (1995), for example, found that computers
were having little impact on productivity in the 1980s, while Morrison
(1997) reports evidence of overinvestment in high-tech capital. In
contrast, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (1995), Lehr and Lichtenberg (1999),
Lichtenberg (1995), Siegel (1997), and Steindel (1992) found that
computers had a significant impact on productivity and output.
One factor that may be contributing to this divergence is the
different degree of aggregation across studies. The purpose of this
article, therefore, is to use a common econometric approach and data set
to isolate the impact of aggregation effects. By comparing econometric
results using the same specification at three distinct levels of
aggregation--the private business economy, ten major sector groups, and
55 detailed industries-we can quantify the importance of bias from
"aggregation of relations" problems.(3) Similarly, by
comparing estimates from different decompositions of capital, we can
quantify the importance of bias from "aggregation of
variables" problems.
We begin by documenting widespread differences in computer
intensity across business sectors and component industries. We then use
a continuous measure of computer intensity--measured either as the stock
of computer capital or the share of equipment capital in the form of
computers--in various production function specifications. Comparison of
the estimated elasticity from the different regressions provides
insights about the relationship between computers, productivity, and
output and the importance of aggregation effects.
Our results suggest that both sources of bias are important in
general, although the estimated computer elasticity is surprisingly
robust across different levels of data and alternative specifications.
The level of aggregation has a direct impact on the estimated elasticity
of other types of capital, most notably structures, while the
decomposition of noncomputer capital matters because the marginal
products of different types of capital are clearly not equal.
In terms of computers, the estimated elasticity is quite large and
stable, typically in the range of 0.15, across both the industry and the
sector regressions and does not appear to be biased by the use of a
restrictive measure of noncomputer capital. Because computers experience
rapid depreciation and large capital losses due to obsolescence, they
must earn a large gross rate of return to cover these costs; this
explains the relatively large output elasticity for computers. We
conclude that despite the presence of aggregation bias, previous
estimates of a large elasticity of computers appear reasonable and are
entirely consistent with economic theory.
II. EMPIRICAL APPROACH
Research on computers and productivity has generally followed two
empirical traditions. Jorgenson and Stiroh (1995; 1999; 2000b), Sichel
(1999), Haimowitz (1998), Stiroh (1998), and Oliner and Sichel (1994,
2000) use growth accounting techniques to compare the growth rate of
output to the share-weighted growth rates of inputs and estimate the
contribution of each input to economic growth. In contrast, Gera et al.
(1999), Lehr and Lichtenberg (1999), Morrison (1997), Siegel (1997),
Berndt and Morrison (1995), Brynjolffson and Hitt (1995), Lichtenberg
(1995), and Steindel (1992) estimate production or cost functions for
firms or industries that explicitly include some measure of computer
capital or computer-related labor. (4)
The empirical work typically begins with a production function,
such as
(1) [Y.sub.i,t] = [A.sub.t] * f([K.sup.computer.sub.i,t],
[K.sup.other.sub.i,t] [L.sub.i,t], i),
where [Y.sub.i,t] is output, [K.sup.computer.sub.i,t] is capital in
the form of computers, [K.sup.other.sub.i,t] is other capital, and
[L.sub.i,t], is labor for firm, industry, or sector i at time t.
[A.sub.t] represents total factor productivity or disembodied technical
change that depends solely on time.
The econometric studies take some version of equation (1), assume a
functional form, transform the relationship into a regression, and
estimate that regression with the data at hand. Our empirical work
follows this tradition and estimates various specifications of equation
(1) at different levels of aggregation using several different
econometric estimators to quantify the importance of two different types
of aggregation errors. (5)
Aggregation Issues
Broadly speaking, aggregation bias is a special case of
specification error, but ascertaining the bias in any particular
application is not straightforward. Maddala (1977) divides the topic of
aggregation bias into two broad sets of questions--problems in the
"aggregation of variables" and problems in the
"aggregation of relations." We examine both issues and,
although we do not formally derive or model these aggregation biases
here, it is useful to put our comparisons in this context. See Maddala
(1977) for details.
Aggregation of variables includes the whole area of index number
construction in which an index variable is created to represent the
movement of a set of prices or quantities over time. This area has a
rich history, and we focus on one example relating to incorrectly
specifying the inputs to a production function.
To fix ideas, consider the example in Lichtenberg (1990) where the
true structural relationship is y = [[beta].sub.1][X.sub.1] +
[[beta].sub.2][X.sub.2] + u, but the econometrician incorrectly
estimates y = [beta]([X.sub.1] + [X.sub.2]) + [epsilon]. Lichtenberg
shows that the probability limit of the estimate of [beta] is a weighted
average of [[beta].sub.1] and [[beta].sub.2], but the weights need not
be between zero and one, so perverse effects are possible. In his
application, Lichtenberg (1990) examines the consequences of using an
aggregate measure of research and development (R&D) in place of a
disaggregated specification that explicitly includes federal government
R&D and private R&D. Because the productivity impact of federal
R&D was less than private R&D, the estimated impact of aggregate
R&D understated the true impact. (6) Aizcorbe (1990) makes an
important contribution to this literature by developing tests of the
validity of particular aggregates in the context of generalized production functions that are discussed below.
Aggregation of relations includes many issues that deal with the
interaction between micro- and macrorelationships. The seminal work of
Theil (1954) studied one specific case dealing with the conditions
needed for the preservation of the parameters of microrelations when
estimation is carried out using macrovariables. (7) We examine a very
specific form of this question and compare differences in the
coefficients of the same production function that are estimated at
various levels of aggregation. Morrison-Paul and Siegel (1999) undertake
a similar exercise in the context of measuring economies of scale in
manufacturing and find that the aggregation bias from moving between
four-digit, two-digit, and total manufacturing data is not substantive.
In the case of computers and productivity, we speculate that both
types of aggregation issues are important. Regarding aggregation of
variables, the marginal productivity of different forms of capital can
be quite varied, so aggregating heterogeneous types of capital may be an
important source of bias. For example, econometric work that simply
includes an aggregate measure of "noncomputer capital" as in
equation (1) may generate the exact bias described by Lichtenberg
(1990). Regarding aggregation of relations, both production structure
and computer intensity vary widely across industries and combining these
disparate industries into aggregates may lead to biased coefficient estimates. Thus the level of aggregation may have a direct impact on the
estimated parameters of a production function and create a misleading
picture of the productive role of computers.
Econometric Framework
The remainder of this section outlines three related empirical
specifications that can be used to examine how production function
coefficients vary when they are estimated with different data. In
particular, we focus on how the estimated elasticity of computer capital
changes across different decompositions of capital (aggregation of
variables) and across different levels of aggregation (aggregation of
relations).
Simple Production Function. In the empirical literature on the role
of computers, it is standard practice to decompose capital into two
parts-computer capital and noncomputer capital as in equation (1)-and
econometrically estimate a production function. A common Cobb-Douglas specification, for example, yields the following model:
(2) Y = [e.sup.A(t)] * [e.sup.[phi](i)] * [L.sup.[[beta].sub.0]] *
[K.sup.[[beta].sub.1].sub.c] * [K.sup.[[beta].sub.2].sub.n] *
[e.sup.[epsilon]],
where L is labor, [K.sub.c] is computer capital, [K.sub.n] is
noncomputer capital, A(t) and [phi](i) are general time and industry
variables that simply shift the production function but do not interact
with the inputs, and [epsilon] is a random error term. (8)
To estimate equation (2), take logs and include time and industry
effects as dummy variables, T and I, to allow flexibility in A(t) and
[phi](i), respectively. This implies the following simple production
function regression:
(3) ln Y = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.0] ln L + [[beta].sub.1] ln
[K.sub.c] +[[beta].sub.2] ln [K.sub.n] + [[theta].sub.t]T +
[[theta].sub.i]I + [epsilon].
This regression provides the first way to estimate the impact of
computers on output and productivity. Specifications of this type are
common in the literature, for example, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (1995),
Lichtenberg (1995), and Steindel (1992). (9)
We emphasize that although equation (3) isolates computers from
other forms of capital, there are still problems relating to aggregation
of variables. [K.sub.n] contains many heterogeneous assets across many
vintages, for example, cars, structures, and machine tools, which likely
do not have the same elasticity. Moreover, [K.sub.c] is an aggregate
that includes mainframes, personal computers, displays, printers,
storage devices, and other peripheral equipment, and these components
may have different production characteristics that may make aggregation
inappropriate. We do not focus on bias at this level to provide
comparability with earlier studies and to maintain tractability of our
results. (10)
Extended Production Function. The implicit assumption in the simple
production function of equation (2) is that all forms of non-computer
capital are perfect substitutes and have the same output elasticity. To
examine the impact of this assumption, we consider a more general
production function that explicitly includes four types of
capital--computer capital, [K.sub.c], other high-tech equipment,
[K.sub.h], other equipment, [K.sub.o], and structures, [K.sub.s]-- and
allows the output elasticity to vary across each asset class. As shown
in Lichtenberg (1990), incorrectly imposing a common elasticity can lead
to biased estimates due to the aggregation of variables problem.
The extended production function, again in Cobb-Douglas form, is
(4) Y = [e.sup.A(t)] * [e.sup.[phi](i)] * [L.sup.[[beta].sub.0]] *
[K.sup.[[beta].sub.1].sub.c]
* [K.sup.[[beta].sub.2].sub.h] * [K.sup.[[beta].sub.3].sub.o] *
[K.sup.[[beta].sub.4].sub.s] * [e.sup.[epsilon]],
which implies the following extended production function
regression:
(5) ln Y = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.0] ln L + [[beta].sub.1] ln
[K.sub.c]
+ [[beta].sub.2] ln [K.sub.h] + [[beta].sub.3] ln [K.sub.o] +
[[beta].sub.4] ln [K.sub.s]
+ [[theta].sub.t]T + [[theta].sub.i]I + [epsilon].
The regression in equation (5) provides a second way to evaluate
the impact of computers. By allowing a more general specification that
removes a particular form of aggregation error, these regressions may
provide better estimates. Moreover, by comparing the estimated
elasticities from equation (3) to the estimated elasticities from
equation (5), we can directly assess the practical importance of the
aggregation of variables bias.
Alternative Production Function. The two approaches described above
estimate the impact of computers by explicitly decomposing capital into
different types. As an alternative, we also examine a specification
similar to Berndt and Morrison (1995) and Lehr and Lichtenberg (1999).
This approach uses capital shares to identify differences in the
productive impact of equipment capital in general and computer capital
in particular.
Consider the slightly modified Cobb-Douglas production function
(6) Y = A * [L.sup.[[beta].sub.0]]
[([K.sup.*]).sup.[[beta].sub.1]],
where [K.sup.*] is "effective" capital that is measured
as
(7) [K.sup.*] = K * [([K.sub.e]/K).sup.[delta]] *
[([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]).sup.[gamma]],
so that
(8) ln [K.sup.*] = ln K + [delta] * ln([K.sub.e]/K) + [gamma] *
ln([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]),
where [K.sub.e] is total equipment capital and [K.sub.c] is
computer capital.
Aizcorbe (1990) provides a formal justification and defense of this
type of approach. She shows that, under reasonable conditions, a general
production function Y = f([X.sub.1], [X.sub.2], ... [X.sub.K]) can be
restated as Y = f(X, [M.sub.1], [M.sub.2], ... , [M.sub.K-1]) where X is
some aggregate of the individual inputs and [M.sub.i] =
[M.sub.i]([X.sub.i], [X.sub.K]) is a "mix function" that
relates the two arguments. To test if the aggregate X is valid, one can
test if [[partial]]Y/[[partial]][M.sub.i] = 0, [for all]i.
In this framework, [delta] and [gamma] measure the compositional
effects associated with different types of capital. That is, [delta]
> 0 implies that a larger proportion of capital in the form of
equipment increases the amount of effective capital relative to the
measured aggregate. Likewise, [gamma] > 0 implies that a larger
proportion of equipment in the form of computers increases the effective
amount of capital.
Note that this specification only captures composition effects
because individual capital stock series are calculated with
quality-adjusted price indexes for computers to account for improvement
embodied in more recent vintages and all series are aggregated using a
Divisia index. Thus vintage differences and traditional index number
problems are eliminated.
Combining equations (6) and (8) yields the following alternative
production function regression:
(9) In Y = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.0] ln L
+ [[beta].sub.1] ln K + [[beta].sub.1][delta]ln([K.sub.e]/K)
+ [[beta].sub.1][gamma]([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]) + [[theta].sub.t]T +
[[theta].sub.i]I + [epsilon].
Again, the interpretation of [delta] and [gamma] is clear. If
equipment and computer capital do not have any differential impact and
the composition of the capital stock does not matter, then [delta] =
[gamma] = 0. If this is true, then [[beta].sub.1][delta] =
[[beta].sub.1][gamma] = 0 in equation (9). Conversely, if composition
effects do matter, then the estimated coefficients on the shares will be
statistically significant different from zero (assuming the
[[beta].sub.1] [not equal to] 0 as implied by standard production
theory). Of course, the coefficients on the two shares need not be the
same and none, either one, or both of the share effects could matter.
The regressions in equations (3), (5), and (9) provide the means
for assessing the practical important of biases from aggregation of
variables and aggregation of relations. By comparing estimates from the
simple production function to the extended or alternative production
functions, we can assess the bias created from a restrictive measure of
capital (aggregation of variables). Likewise, by estimating each
regression at differ levels of aggregation, for example, industry,
sector, and private business economy, we can assess the bias from
incorrectly imposing the same relationship (aggregation of relations).
III. DATA ISSUES
Data comes from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and include
gross product originating (GPO) by industry and capital stock by
industry and asset.
BEA GPO
GPO represents each industry's contribution to gross domestic
product as calculated by BEA. These data, also called value-added data,
equal gross output less intermediate inputs and thus equal payments to
labor and capital. The GPO data include current and chain-weighted
constant dollar data for 62 detailed private industries. The current
dollar GPO is from 1948-1996, and the constant dollar GPO is only from
1977-1996. Data on full-time equivalent employees is available for the
same industries from 1947-1996. (11) Details are provided by Lum and
Yuskavage (1997), Lum and Moyer (1998), and Yuskavage (1996).
BEA Tangible Wealth Survey
Investment and capital stock are estimated by the BEA (1998) as
part of their tangible wealth study. These data include current dollar
net capital stocks and corresponding chain-weighted quantity indexes for
62 private industries and 57 assets from 1947-1996. Details on the
estimation and data sources can be found in Katz and Herman (1997) and
these data correspond to those reported in the September 1997 Survey of
Current Business.
Creating Consistent Data
The data used in this article represent consolidated data based on
1987 SIC codes. To focus on the private business economy, we excluded
government enterprises, general government, real estate, and private
households from our econometric analysis. Aggregation of output and
capital stocks was done as a Divisia quantity index, which has the
desired exact aggregation properties, whereas labor series are simple
sums. This procedure resulted in 55 detailed industries that comprise
ten major sectors with data on GPO, labor, and capital stock by asset.
To measure the composition of the capital stock, we created several
aggregates from the detailed capital stock series. Computers include
mainframes, personal computers, direct access storage devices, printers,
terminals, tape drives, and other storage devices. Other high-tech
equipment includes communications equipment, instruments, and photocopy
equipment. Other equipment includes all other producers' durable
equipment. Structures include all nonresidential structures. Thus our
capital measure excludes residential structures, land, and inventories
and includes only fixed, reproducible tangible assets owned by the
business sector.
Descriptive Statistics
Table 1 shows the evolution of computer capital for major sectors
and the detailed industries from 1970-1996. These data show the rapid
accumulation of computers throughout the economy as documented in the
aggregate work of Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000b) and Oliner and Sichel
(2000). (12)
More important for our purposes, there is wide variation across
major sectors and industries. The private business sector shows a
nominal computer share in the capital stock of 1.8% in 1996, for
example, and only 0.002% of farm capital is computers but more than 20%
of business services capital is in the form of computers. Even within
major sectors like services or manufacturing, there is substantial
variation in computer shares of the total capital stock.
Table 1 also shows wide variation in the accumulation rates of
computers across major sectors, ranging from 8.34% in mining to 28.84%
in wholesale trade in the 1990s. These growth rates far exceed the
growth in other forms of capital, typically by a factor of ten. Again,
variation widens significantly at lower levels of aggregation and
remains large within major sectors. Because capital stocks are
calculated using the same methodology and the same underlying deflators,
this reflects enormous differences in investment patterns across
industries.
Table 2 presents the distribution of capital by type--computers,
other high-tech, other equipment, and structures--within major sectors
and detailed industries. As expected, there is wide variation in all
forms of capital because different industries have fundamentally
different production techniques. This suggests that the simple
production function approach may be quite misleading because it does not
account for the wide heterogeneity in capital.
Table 3 presents the distribution of capital in a different way by
reporting the distribution of total computer and high-tech capital
across major sectors. As reported in Triplett (1999) and Stiroh (1998),
computers are highly concentrated in service-related sectors with
wholesale trade, retail trade, finance insurance and real estate, and
services owning over $120 billion of computer equipment, which accounts
for over 78% of the U.S. business total. Manufacturing, on the other
hand, holds only $26 billion, or 17% of the total.
IV. PRODUCTION FUNCTION ESTIMATES
Our empirical results focus on three regressions--equations (3),
(5), and (9)--that are estimated at different levels of aggregation with
different econometric methods. The structure of aggregation coincides
with Tables 1 and 2 and includes three nested levels.
"Aggregate" is the private business economy, (13) which
consists of ten major "sectors," which in turn consist of 55
detailed "industries" at roughly the two-digit SIC level. All
aggregation is done with a Divisia index so the 55 detailed industries
sum to the ten major sectors and the ten major sectors sum to the
aggregate in current dollars. (14)
We estimate the production functions in several different ways. We
first perform ordinary least squares (OLS) on the aggregate, sector, and
industry data. These regressions include year dummy variables for the
sector and industry regressions and a linear time trend in the aggregate
regression. We then estimate a traditional fixed effect (FE)
specification that allows each industry or sector to have a unique
intercept to account for unobserved heterogeneity. Because the aggregate
data is a single series and cannot be estimated using the panel methods,
only an OLS estimate is reported.
Although regressions of these types are quite common in the
literature, there are important econometric concerns. There is an
endogeneity problem because output and inputs, particularly variable
inputs such as labor, are likely to be chosen simultaneously. There is
also an omitted variable problem because we cannot observe all factors
that determine output or productivity, for example, technology, R&D,
efficiency, and input quality. Inclusion of FEs in a panel framework can
control for unobservable factors that are constant over time, but to the
extent that unobservable factors vary and are correlated with particular
inputs, those coefficients will be biased. Finally, there are
multicollinearity issues because all inputs are likely to be correlated,
particularly at higher levels of aggregation with less cross-sectional
variation. (15)
To control for both the unobserved heterogeneity and simultaneity
problems, we also employ more sophisticated econometric tools developed
by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998), and applied
to production function estimates by Blundell and Bond (1999). Their
system generalized method of moments (SYS-GMM) estimator utilizes a
combination of regressions in levels and first-differences with lagged
first-differences as instruments for the equations in levels and lagged
levels as instruments for equations in first-differences. Simulation
results in Blundell and Bond (1998) show this estimator offers
efficiency gains relative to the basic first-differenced GMM estimator.
(16)
A second data limitation forces us to use a measure of capital
stock rather than the preferred flow of capital services. This
difference has been recognized at least since Solow (1957) and has been
an important part of the growth accounting literature. Jorgenson and
Stiroh (2000b) provide details on the conceptual and empirical
distinction.
A final issue is our use of GPO as the output concept. Ideally, we
would prefer to use a measure of gross output, which includes the value
of intermediate inputs, but we did not have the corresponding data for
intermediate inputs. Such is data is available for manufacturing
industries, for instance, National Bureau of Economic Research
Grey-Bartelsman database, or for relatively high levels of aggregation,
for example, Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000a), but they do not provide the
comprehensive coverage of computer-intensive industries or the nested
Levels of disaggregation required for this exercise. (17) With these
caveats in mind, we proceed to the empirical results.
Simple Production Function
Table 4 reports estimates of the simple production function in
equation (3) for different levels of aggregation and econometric
methods. For the most part, the sector and industry results are
reasonable with a large, positive, and significant coefficient on labor
in the 0.5 range and capital coefficients that are typically
statistically significant. (18) Consistent with Blundell and Bond
(1999), the FE (within) estimator produces coefficients that appear to
be biased downward, while the SYS-GMM estimators are more reasonable. In
both the sector and industry SYS-GMM regression, the coefficient on
computer capital is large and statistically significant.
These estimates of the computer elasticity are typically around
0.18 in the OLS and SYS-GMM models, somewhat larger than earlier
estimates in Brynjolfsson and Hitt (1995) and Lichtenberg (1995). Those
papers estimate a similar regression with firm-level data for earlier
periods and report a statistically significant elasticity for computer
capital in the range of 0.05-0.12. The larger impact in our data likely
reflects the growing importance of computers in our sample relative to
their earlier samples.
The large change in coefficients when sector or industry dummy
variables are included in the FE estimates suggests that deviations in
output over time from the mean for a particular sector or industry are
not highly correlated with deviations in computer capital. Similarly,
the elasticity of noncomputer capital falls and is actually
significantly negative at the industry level. This is unexpected,
although low and insignificant capital coefficients in FE regressions
are common in empirical work and were an important motivation behind the
more sophisticated GMM approaches. Griliches and Mairesse (1998),
particularly page 178, discuss this phenomenon and suggest that the loss
in variance of the right-hand-side variables is responsible as other
errors like measurement and random noise dominate the remaining
information.
In general, there appear to be small differences in the estimated
coefficients when the industry- and sector-level regressions are
compared. Consistent with Morrison-Paul and Siegel (1999), bias from
aggregation of relations appears small. When the aggregate regression is
compared, however, there are large changes in the estimated
coefficients, suggesting the aggregation of relations problem becomes
large at the aggregate level.
Extended Production Function
Table 5 reports estimates of the extended production function
regressions in equation (5). The results, again except for the aggregate
OLS regression, are generally well behaved with a coefficient on labor
typically in the 0.5 range and mostly reasonable capital coefficients.
Again, the SYS-GMM estimates appear the most reasonable, and the FE
results appear biased downward.
In terms of comparison across levels of aggregation and biases from
aggregation of relations, the computer coefficient is again quite stable
across the industry and sector regressions using all estimators. The
other capital coefficients show more variability. The estimated
elasticity of structures, for example, increases from 0.048 in the
sector regression to 0.194 in the industry SYS-GMM regression.
To assess the aggregation in variables bias, we compare the results
in Table 5 to those in Table 4 and find evidence of an important
problem. That is, the estimated elasticities on the different types of
noncomputer capital are quite different and it appears inappropriate to
impose a common elasticity on all types of noncomputer capital. (19) The
point estimates of the computer elasticities, however, typically remain
in the range of 0.15. This suggests that any bias introduced by
incorrect restrictions on other forms of capital does not substantially
change the estimated elasticity of computers.
Alternative Production Function
Table 6 presents estimates of equation (9), which includes
aggregate capital and two share variables, as opposed to each type of
capital separately. As discussed above, Aizcorbe (1990) shows this to be
an equivalent representation of the production function if aggregation
across variables is valid. Again, we report estimates from the OLS, FE,
and SYS-GMM estimators.
The results are consistent with the earlier findings and mostly
appear reasonable. Labor elasticities are in the 0.5 range, the capital
elasticity is between 0.3-0.4 in the OLS and SYS-GMM estimates, and the
FE estimates appear biased downward. These estimates are broadly
consistent with expected income shares. As in the earlier
specifications, the capital elasticity drops in the FE regression and
the aggregate regression appears the least reasonable with a large,
negative elasticity on capital and a labor elasticity that appears too
large.
When comparing the sector and industry regressions, some estimated
coefficients vary a great deal, but others do not. For example, labor
elasticity in the FE regressian was estimated at 0.04 at the sector
level and 0.46 at the industry level. In contrast, the computer share
coefficient varies little across levels of aggregation but falls
dramatically in the FE regression. This suggests that between-industry
rather than within-industry variation is the primary source of output
variation associated with computers.
These results imply that the composition of the capital stock
matters with regard to computers, but not necessarily with regard to
equipment in general. That is, a higher share of equipment in the form
of computers is typically associated with higher output, while a larger
share of capital in the form of equipment is not. More formally, in the
sector and industry regressions, [delta] in equation (9) is typically
small and insignificantly different from zero, while [gamma] is
typically positive and often significant. The implied estimates and
[delta] and [gamma] and the associated p-value are reported in Table 6.
(20)
Lehr and Lichtenberg (1999) estimate a similar specification and
find results that are broadly consistent. Their coefficient estimates
are not directly comparable, however, because they do not include the
equipment to capital ratio in their regression and estimate an
approximation without taking logs of the computer share. Despite these
differences, they also find that the share of computers is positively
and significantly related to output across a panel of firms in the late
1980s and early 1990s.
It is important to recognize that our evidence that computers
appear very productive does not necessarily imply that computers earn
excess returns. In a neoclassical framework, for example, an
asset's output elasticity equals its nominal income share. This
income share is typically derived from a user-cost approach that
includes tax factors, depreciation, capital gains/losses, and the
acquisition price of the asset. In the case of computer equipment, rapid
obsolescence and massive price declines yield a high user-cost, which
makes a high marginal product necessary simply to make the computer a
worthwhile investment.
Lichtenberg (1995) explicitly tests the hypothesis that computer
equipment has excess returns by comparing the ratio of marginal products
to user-costs for different types of capital and finds evidence of
excess returns to computers. We do not perform this type of test, but
one can get a rough sense by comparing the average income share reported
in Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000b) and Oliner and Sichel (2000) to our
estimated elasticity. Both studies use aggregate data for the United
States and report relatively small income shares for computer hardware
and software: about 2.5% in Jorgenson and Stiroh for 1990-96 and 3.4% in
Oliner and Sichel for 1991-95. Both shares are considerably below our
estimated coefficient, although the results are not directly comparable
because we do not have detailed capital service data for all assets, we
use a different vintage of capital stock data, and the output concepts
are not identical.
Robustness Checks
One concern in estimating these types of regressions is measurement
error. The recent divergence in productivity growth between
manufacturing and nonmanufacturing industries, for example, has led some
to believe that measurement problems cause output, and therefore
productivity, to be understated in certain industries. Dean (1999, 24),
for example, concludes, "there are important measurement problems
in some service activities."
These difficulties may reflect inadequate data, conceptual problems
in defining service sector output, or an inability to accurately
decompose nominal changes into prices and quantities. In the specific
context of measuring the impact of computers, Siegel (1997) finds that
computers lead to both quality change and productivity growth, after
accounting for potential measurement errors. Using a different
framework, McGuckin and Stiroh (2001) conclude that measurement error
associated with computer investment may be contributing to an
underestimate of aggregate productivity growth.
To examine whether our results are robust to such potential
problems, we split the industry data into manufacturing and
nonmanufacturing industries. Table 7 reports OLS results for the simple
production function and SYS-GMM estimators for all three specifications.
In all cases, the coefficient related to computer capital is larger in
the manufacturing regression, but typically less precisely estimated.
This is similar to McGuckin and Stiroh (2001), but contrasts
Brynjolfsson and Hitt (1995) who report a larger estimated coefficient
on computers in the service sector compared to manufacturing. If one
believes that manufacturing output is better measured than
nonmanufacturing, these results suggest that the estimates for all
industries and sectors may be understating the productive impact of
computers. The pattern of coefficients, however, is similar to that
found earlier, suggesting that the qualitative results are not being
driven by service sector mismeasurement.
V. CONCLUSIONS
The purpose of this article is to examine the empirical importance
of aggregation effects in the context of estimating production functions
that include computer capital as a distinct asset. Drawing together the
results from alternative specifications that were estimated at different
levels of aggregation, several conclusions stand out.
It is clear that the economy-wide specification provides very
unstable results and gives a misleading picture of computer
productivity. In contrast, both the sector and the industry estimates
show a very stable estimated elasticity for computers, typically around
0.15, across specifications in OLS and SYS-GMM regressions. Estimates
are typically smaller in FE regressions, consistent with previous
econometric work that documents a downward bias in this type of
estimate. These findings also echo results of our earlier work in
McGuckin and Stiroh (1998), which found that because computer use was
concentrated in a small number of industries, the impact was obscured at
higher levels of analysis.
The stability of the estimated impact of computers between the
industry and sector regressions and across specifications was somewhat
surprising but also reassuring. Because these estimates are robust to
the specification and aggregation level, it suggests that computers are
having a real impact on output. This does not mean, however, that
aggregation of relations problems are not important because the
estimated elasticities of the noncomputer aggregate, particularly
structures, varied substantially between the industry and sector
regressions. Thus, empirical work must still be careful when choosing
the level of aggregation.
The bias from aggregation in variables was also generally found to
be important. There is wide variation in the productivity of different
types of capital, and it is inappropriate to include a single capital
index in many cases. When included individually, structures showed a
large and significant elasticity, and the impact from other forms of
noncomputer equipment was harder to estimate. The estimated computer
elasticity, however, did not change when more disaggregated capital
variables were included, which suggests that the bias was not
transmitted to all coefficients.
These results show a large and robust elasticity of computer
capital across a wide range of specifications, estimation techniques,
and aggregation levels. Despite the clear presence of other aggregation
problems, our results suggest that computers are quite productive. This
is entirely consistent with economic theory; computers must earn a high
gross rate of return to offset the rapid depreciation and capital
losses. These results support the growing body of work at both the micro
and the aggregate level that shows computers are indeed an important
source of growth and productivity.
ABBREVIATIONS
BEA: Bureau of Economic Analysis
FE: Fixed Effect
GPO: Gross Product Originating
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
R&D: Research and Development
SYS-GMM: System Generalized Method of Moments
(*.) The authors thank Ana Aizcorbe, Charles Waite, participants of
the Innovations in Economic Measurement session at the 1999 Joint
Statistical Meetings, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments,
as well as Michael Fort and Jennifer Poole for excellent research
assistance. This article represents the views of the authors only and
does not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, the Federal Reserve System, or their staffs.
McGuckin: Director of Economic Research, The Conference Board, New
York, NY 10045. Phone 1-212-339-0303, E-mail
robert_mcguckin@conferenceboard.org
Stiroh: Senior Economist, Banking Studies Function, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, New York, NY 10022. Phone 1-212-720-6633, Fax
1-212-720-8363, E-mail kevin.stiroh@ny.frb.org
(1.) Fisher (1992) provides details on both capital and production
function aggregation, and Jorgenson (1990) discusses the stringent
assumptions needed to move from a sectoral production function to an
aggregate production function.
(2.) More recent estimates for the late 1990s in Jorgenson and
Stiroh (2000b) and Oliner and Sichel (2000) show that information
technology played an important role in the U.S. productivity revival
after 1995.
(3.) Note, however, that data limitations prevent us from extending
this comparison to include analysis of aggregation effects that move
from the firm or plant level to the industry level. Microdata is
available for manufacturing industries from the Longitudinal Research
Database but is not available outside of manufacturing.
(4.) Brynjolfsson and Yang (1996) survey this field.
(5.) Some authors, for example, Lichtenberg (1995), also decompose
labor into a information technology and noninformation technology
portion. He finds evidence of excess return to labor associated with
information technology.
(6.) The true coefficient of the aggregate variable is a weighted
sum (equal to 1.0) of the true coefficients for the individual impacts
with the bias depending on the ratio of the variances of each component
of aggregate R&D and the correlation between the individual
components. See Lichtenberg (1990) for details.
(7.) There is a technically similar class of problems that Madalla
(1977) includes in aggregation of relations. These problems question
whether aggregate or micro-based relationships give thc "best"
prediction or forecast when both types of variables are available. We do
not investigate this.
(8.) Time and industry subscripts have been dropped from the inputs
and outputs for ease of exposition.
(9.) Under the assumption of constant returns to scale, it is
straightforward to transform this output regression into a labor
productivity regression, and this has been done in several of the
studies cited. We estimated these types of labor productivity
regressions and found similar results, so we focus on the output-level
regressions.
(10.) There are also important differences across vintages for each
detailed asset, for example, faster processor speed in more recent
personal computers. The Bureau of Economic Analysis data, however,
account for these vintage differences through constant-quality price
deflators that implicitly makes investment across vintages perfect
substitutes and allows aggregation across vintages.
(11.) As a consistency check, we compared alternative labor series
available from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and hours by industry data
from Gullickson and Harper (1999) and found very high correlations.
(12.) These studies use a later vintage of capital data and are
thus not directly comparable to these industry estimates.
(13.) Real estate and private households are not included.
(14.) The series do not sum exactly in constant dollars, which is
an artifact of Divisia aggregation. A similar property exists in the new
chain-weighted indexes in the national accounts. See Landefeld and
Parker (1997) for details.
(15.) Griliches and Mairesse (1998) provide a detailed review of
the econometric difficulties associated with production function
estimation and common approaches designed to mitigate the problems.
(16.) The SYS-GMM estimator was generated using the DPD98 Gauss
software described by Arellano and Bond (1998). All reported SYS-GMM
estimates are from the one-step GMM estimator, with standard errors
corrected for heteroskedasticity. To avoid overfitting biases that are
possible in our relatively small cross-sectional samples, we report
estimates with two lags for the instruments in the sector regressions
and three lags in the industry regressions.
(17.) We did combine our data with the real gross output series
available from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Employment Projections
division and estimated the regressions with gross output as the
dependent variables and the same explanatory variables. Though not the
proper specification, the results were similar to those reported.
(18.) Not surprisingly, the estimates from the aggregate regression
are the least reasonable with a labor coefficient of 1.074 and a
negative (though not significant) coefficient on noncomputer capital.
(19.) Econometric tests of the null hypothesis of a common
coefficient on all types of noncomputer capital are reported at the
bottom of Table 5.
(20.) The p-value is associated with the null hypothesis that
[delta] or [gamma] is equal to zero.
REFERENCES
Aizcorbe, Ana M. "Testing the Validity of Aggregates."
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 8(4), 1990, 373-83.
Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. "Dynamic Panel Data
Estimation Using DPD98 for Gauss: A Guide for Users." CEMFI,
Madrid, Spain, December 1998.
Arrellano, Manuel, and Olympia Bover. "Another Look at the
Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models."
Journal of Econometrics, 68, 1995, 29-51.
Baily, Martin Neil, Charles Hulen, and David Campbell.
"Productivity Dynamics in Manufacturing Plants." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 2, 1992, 187-267.
Berndt, Ernst R., and Catherine J. Morrison. "High-Tech
Capital Formation and Economic Performance in U.S. Manufacturing
Industries: An Exploratory Analysis." Journal of Econometrics, 65,
1995, 9-43.
Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. "Initial Conditions and
Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 87, 1998, 115-43.
-----. "GMM Estimation with Persistent Panel Data: An
Application to Production Functions." Institute for Fiscal Studies,
Working Paper Series no. W99/4, 1999.
Brynjolffson, Erik, and Lorin Hitt. "Information Technology as
a Factor of Production: The Role of Differences among Firms."
Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 3(3-4), 1995, 183-200.
Brynjolffson, Eric, and Shinkyu Yang. "Information Technology
and Productivity: A Review of the Literature." Advances in
Computers, 43, 1996, 179-214.
Bureau of Economic Analysis. "Fixed Reproducible Tangible
Wealth of the United States, 1925-96." NCN0136, 1998.
Dean, Edwin R. "The Accuracy of the BLS Productivity
Measures." Monthly Labor Review, 122(2), 1999, 24-34.
Diewert, Erwin W. "Exact and Superlative Index Numbers."
Journal of Econometrics, 4, 1976, 115-46.
Fisher, Franklin M. Aggregation--Aggregate Production Functions and
Related Topics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1992.
Gera, Surendra, Wulong Gu, and Frank C. Lee. "Information
Technology and Labour Productivity Growth: An Empirical Analysis for
Canada and the United State." Canadian Journal of Economics, 32(2),
1999, 384-407.
Griliches, Zvi, and Jaques Mairesse. "Production Functions:
The Search for Identification." In Econometrics and Economic Theory
in the 20th Century, edited by Steinar Strom. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1998.
Gullickson, William, and Michael J. Harper. "Possible
Measurement Bias in Aggregate Productivity Growth." Monthly Labor
Review, 122(2), 1999, 47-67.
Haltiwanger, John C. "Measuring and Analyzing Aggregate
Fluctuations: The Importance of Building From Microeconomic
Evidence." Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 79(3), 1997,
55-85.
Haimowitz, Joseph H. "Has the Surge in Computer Spending
Fundamentally Changed the Economy?" Economic Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 83(2), 1998, 27-42.
Jensen, J. Bradford, and Robert H. McGuckin. "Firm Performance
and Evolution: Empirical Regularities in the U.S. Microdata."
Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(1), 1997, 25-47.
Jorgenson, Dale W. "Productivity and Economic Growth." In
Fifty Years of Economic Measurement, edited by Ernst R. Berndt and Jack
E. Triplett. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990, 19-118.
Jorgenson, Dale W., and Kevin J. Stiroh. "Computers and
Growth." Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 3(3-4), 1995,
295-316.
-----. "Information Technology and Growth." American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 89(2), 1999, 109-15.
-----. "U.S. Economic Growth at the Industry Level."
American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 90(2), 2000a, 161-67.
-----. "Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic Growth in the
Information Age." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 2000b,
125-211.
Katz, Arnold J., and Shelby W. Herman. "Improved Estiamtes of
Fixed Reproducible Tangible Wealth, 1929-95." Survey of Current
Business, May 1997, 69-92.
Landefeld, J. Steven, and Robert P. Parker. "BEA's Chain
Index, Time Series, and Measures of Long-Term Economic Growth."
Survey of Current Business, May 1997, 58-68.
Lehr, Bill, and Frank Lichtenberg. "Information Technology and
Its Impact on Firm-Level Productivity: Evidence from Government and
Private Data Sources, 1977-1993." Canadian Journal of Economics,
32(2), 1999, 335-62.
Lichtenberg, Frank R. "Aggregation of Variables in Least
Squares Regression." American Statistician, 44(2), 1990, 169-71.
-----. "The Output Contributions of Computer Equipment and
Personnel: A Firm-Level Analysis." Economics of Innovation and New
Technology, 3(3-4), 1995, 201-18.
Lum, Sherlene K. S., and Brian C. Moyer. "Gross Product by
Industry, 1995-97." Survey of Current Business, November 1998,
29-40.
Lum, Sherlene K. S., and Robert E. Yuskavage. "Gross Product
by Industry, 1947-1996." Survey of Current Business, November 1997,
20-34.
Maddala, G. S. Econometrics. New York: McGraw Hill, 1977.
McGuckin, Robert H., and Sang V. Nguyen. "Exploring the Role
of Acquisition in the Performance of Firms: Is the 'Firm' the
Right Unit of Analysis?" in Micro- and Macrodata of Firms:
Statistical and International Comparison, edited by Silvia Biffigandi.
Physical-Verlag, 1999, 1-23.
McGuckin, Robert H., and Kevin J. Stirob. "Computers,
Productivity, Growth: Explaining the Computer Productivity
Paradox." Economic Research Report 1213-98-RR, Conference Board,
1998.
-----. "Do Computers Make Output Harder to Measure?"
Journal of Technology Transfer, 26, 2001, 295-321.
Morrison, Catherine J. "Assessing the Productivity Information
Technology Equipment in U.S. Manufacturing Industries." Review of
Economics and Statistics, 79(3), 1997, 471-81.
Morrison-Paul, Catherine J., and Donald Siegel. "Estimation of
Scale Economies Underlying Growth and Productivity: The Empirical
Implications Data Aggregation." Southern Economic Journal, 65(4),
1999, 739-56.
Oliner, Stephen D., and Daniel E. Sichel. "Computers and
Output Growth Revisited: How Big Is Puzzle?" Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 2, 1994, 273-317.
-----. "The Resurgence of Growth in the Later 1990s: Is
Information Technology the Story?" Journal Economic Perspectives.
Forthcoming 2000.
Sichel, Daniel E. The Computer Revolution: An Economic Perspective.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1997.
-----. "Computers and Aggregate Economic Grow An Update."
Business Economics, 34(2), 1999, 18-24.
Siegel, Donald. "The Impact of Computers on Manufacturing
Productivity Growth: A Multiple-Indicators Multiple-Causes
Approach." Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(1), 1997, 68-78.
Solow, Robert M. "Technical Change the Aggregate Production
Function." Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 1987, 312-20.
Steindel, Charles. "Manufacturing Productivity and High-Tech
Investment." FRBNY Quarterly Review, summer 1992, 39-47.
Stiroh, Kevin J. "Computers, Productivity, and Input
Substitution." Economic Inquiry, 36(2), 1998, 175-91.
Theil, Henri. Linear Aggregation of Economic Relations. Amsterdam:
North Holland, 1954.
Triplett, Jack E. "Economic Statistics, the New Economy, and
the Productivity Slowdown." Business Economics, 34(2), 1999, 13-17.
Yuskavage, Robert E. "Improved Estimates of Gross Product by
Industry, 1959-95." Survey of Current Business, August 1996,
133-55.
TABLE 1
Change in Computer Intensity by Major Sectors and Detailed Industries,
1970-1996
Nominal Computer
Capital Share
Industry 1970 1980
Agriculture, forestry, and 0.000 0.011
fishing
Farms 0.000 0.002
Agricultural services, 0.000 0.131
forestry and fishing
Mining 0.082 0.169
Metal mining 0.000 0.039
Coal mining 0.000 0.004
Oil and gas extraction 0.104 0.203
Nonmetallic minerals, 0.000 0.008
except fuels
Construction 0.416 0.147
Manufacturing 0.905 0.926
Durable manufacturing 1.146 1.346
Lumber and wood products 0.311 0.869
Furniture and fixtures 0.000 0.966
Stone, clay, and glass 0.144 1.688
products
Primary metal industries 0.420 0.283
Fabricated metal products 0.811 0.464
Industrial machinery 4.566 3.664
and equipment
Electronic and other 0.525 2.130
electric equipment
Transportation equipment 0.779 0.862
Instruments and related 1.751 1.324
products
Miscellaneous manufacturing 0.751 0.685
industries
Nondurable manufacturing 0.620 0.452
Food and kindred products 0.580 0.360
Tobacco products 0.000 0.527
Textile mill products 0.812 0.262
Apparel and other 2.354 1.191
textile products
Paper and allied products 0.181 0.392
Printing and publishing 1.436 1.388
Chemicals and allied products 0.465 0.289
Petroleum and coal products 0.453 0.385
Rubber and miscellaneous 1.123 0.664
plastic products
Leather and leather products 0.495 0.851
Transportation, comm., and 0.068 0.106
utilities
Railroad 0.012 0.013
transportation
Local and interurban 0.155 0.112
passenger transit
Trucking and 0.108 0.047
warehousing
Water transportation 0.149 0.057
Transportation by air 0.430 0.438
Pipelines, except 0.054 0.050
natural gas
Transportation services 0.214 0.163
Communications 0.141 0.153
Utilities 0.027 0.112
Wholesale trade 2.427 3.113
Retail trade 0.406 0.592
Finance, insurance, and 0.977 1.322
real estate
Depository institutions 3.664 4.439
Nondepositoiy; 4.388 3.576
holding and
investment offices
Security and 8.345 9.442
commodity brokers
Insurance carriers 7.732 6.381
Insurance agents, 11.521 8.572
brokers, and services
Real estate 0.174 0.164
Services 1.361 1.582
Hotels and other 0.031 0.236
lodging places
Personal services 0.000 0.619
Business services 4.408 12.458
Auto repair, services, 0.106 0.970
and garages
Miscellaneous repair 0.000 0.986
shops
Motion pictures 0.000 1.554
Amusement and 0.000 0.481
recreation services
Health services 0.610 0.600
Legal services 6.877 2.199
Educational services 11.940 2.450
Other 3.636 2.446
Private business sector 0.550 0.678
Nominal Computer
Capital Share
Industry 1990 1996
Agriculture, forestry, and 0.020 0.016
fishing
Farms 0.004 0.002
Agricultural services, 0.156 0.099
forestry and fishing
Mining 0.233 0.140
Metal mining 0.041 0.020
Coal mining 0.016 0.030
Oil and gas extraction 0.274 0.158
Nonmetallic minerals, 0.122 0.241
except fuels
Construction 0.238 0.113
Manufacturing 1.758 1.747
Durable manufacturing 2.291 2.097
Lumber and wood products 0.494 0.899
Furniture and fixtures 1.893 1.570
Stone, clay, and glass 2.353 1.354
products
Primary metal industries 0.474 0.492
Fabricated metal products 0.986 1.037
Industrial machinery 4.557 3.255
and equipment
Electronic and other 3.200 3.585
electric equipment
Transportation equipment 1.962 1.801
Instruments and related 3.742 3.348
products
Miscellaneous manufacturing 1.519 2.034
industries
Nondurable manufacturing 1.170 1.382
Food and kindred products 0.842 1.069
Tobacco products 1.128 1.318
Textile mill products 0.517 0.640
Apparel and other 0.864 1.914
textile products
Paper and allied products 0.982 0.685
Printing and publishing 4.469 3.943
Chemicals and allied products 0.854 1.531
Petroleum and coal products 0.659 0.857
Rubber and miscellaneous 1.120 1.376
plastic products
Leather and leather products 1.344 1.482
Transportation, comm., and 0.332 0.300
utilities
Railroad 0.023 0.009
transportation
Local and interurban 0.170 0.030
passenger transit
Trucking and 0.060 0.051
warehousing
Water transportation 0.098 0.100
Transportation by air 0.869 0.404
Pipelines, except 0.026 0.198
natural gas
Transportation services 1.261 0.316
Communications 0.441 0.575
Utilities 0.359 0.283
Wholesale trade 4.636 6.948
Retail trade 1.705 1.853
Finance, insurance, and 2.277 2.285
real estate
Depository institutions 5.314 3.273
Nondepositoiy; 5.626 6.981
holding and
investment offices
Security and 7.411 8.712
commodity brokers
Insurance carriers 7.979 5.170
Insurance agents, 5.062 4.295
brokers, and services
Real estate 0.452 0.928
Services 4.083 4.966
Hotels and other 0.338 0.167
lodging places
Personal services 2.979 1.099
Business services 20.406 36.25
Auto repair, services, 3.870 0.907
and garages
Miscellaneous repair 2.660 2.454
shops
Motion pictures 3.069 1.868
Amusement and 0.841 0.856
recreation services
Health services 1.423 1.924
Legal services 7.869 5.852
Educational services 1.166 0.685
Other 4.936 5.849
Private business sector 1.575 1.847
Real Computer Capital
Growth Rates
Industry 1970-80 1980-90
Agriculture, forestry, and 22.77 20.11
fishing
Farms 0.00 20.26
Agricultural services, 21.70 20.15
forestry and fishing
Mining 36.62 18.83
Metal mining 22.54 18.14
Coal mining 0.00 14.48
Oil and gas extraction 36.99 18.72
Nonmetallic minerals, 0.00 30.34
except fuels
Construction 16.67 19.52
Manufacturing 27.61 23.58
Durable manufacturing 28.94 22.40
Lumber and wood products 26.83 10.01
Furniture and fixtures 29.95 24.98
Stone, clay, and glass 37.05 19.78
products
Primary metal industries 21.18 19.78
Fabricated metal products 23.54 24.50
Industrial machinery 27.92 20.49
and equipment
Electronic and other 40.23 23.68
electric equipment
Transportation equipment 28.49 25.04
Instruments and related 27.39 30.47
products
Miscellaneous manufacturing 15.15 23.79
industries
Nondurable manufacturing 24.08 26.76
Food and kindred products 25.21 25.20
Tobacco products 12.70 24.80
Textile mill products 13.54 21.98
Apparel and other 17.40 11.85
textile products
Paper and allied products 25.76 28.05
Printing and publishing 29.11 31.89
Chemicals and allied products 25.78 26.82
Petroleum and coal products 25.54 22.66
Rubber and miscellaneous 21.85 23.84
plastic products
Leather and leather products 10.88 17.30
Transportation, comm., and 24.59 27.77
utilities
Railroad 17.37 20.26
transportation
Local and interurban 9.51 18.44
passenger transit
Trucking and 9.97 19.90
warehousing
Water transportation 5.84 18.15
Transportation by air 25.16 26.31
Pipelines, except 11.16 2.13
natural gas
Transportation services 13.49 36.78
Communications 29.79 28.12
Utilities 28.52 28.54
Wholesale trade 34.17 25.01
Retail trade 31.57 29.08
Finance, insurance, and 32.10 27.07
real estate
Depository institutions 35.51 24.94
Nondepositoiy; 29.13 28.43
holding and
investment offices
Security and 28.97 20.70
commodity brokers
Insurance carriers 31.18 32.49
Insurance agents, 29.11 10.41
brokers, and services
Real estate 26.50 29.89
Services 28.44 28.29
Hotels and other 29.10 23.07
lodging places
Personal services 37.52 32.84
Business services 27.63 29.46
Auto repair, services, 35.51 34.09
and garages
Miscellaneous repair 29.54 27.42
shops
Motion pictures 47.04 28.99
Amusement and 35.62 21.08
recreation services
Health services 24.75 30.94
Legal services 19.08 35.82
Educational services 18.50 13.05
Other 20.92 25.46
Private business sector 29.97 26.17
Real Computer Growth in
Capital
Growth Rates Total Capital
Industry 1990-96 1970-96 1970-96
Agriculture, forestry, and 15.36 19.93 0.96
fishing
Farms 8.13 15.71 0.59
Agricultural services, 16.50 19.83 4.65
forestry and fishing
Mining 8.34 23.25 1.77
Metal mining 8.46 16.70 1.50
Coal mining 29.37 17.83 2.98
Oil and gas extraction 7.16 23.08 1.67
Nonmetallic minerals, 26.41 28.86 1.47
except fuels
Construction 7.77 15.71 0.90
Manufacturing 19.77 24.25 2.27
Durable manufacturing 18.17 23.94 2.21
Lumber and wood products 27.94 20.62 1.44
Furniture and fixtures 16.59 24.54 2.54
Stone, clay, and glass 9.79 24.12 0.77
products
Primary metal industries 18.49 20.02 -0.15
Fabricated metal products 20.28 23.16 2.15
Industrial machinery 14.06 21.86 3.50
and equipment
Electronic and other 23.88 30.09 4.96
electric equipment
Transportation equipment 17.90 24.72 2.11
Instruments and related 18.03 26.41 4.69
products
Miscellaneous manufacturing 24.43 20.61 1.95
industries
Nondurable manufacturing 22.74 24.80 2.35
Food and kindred products 23.99 24.93 1.86
Tobacco products 19.14 19.35 3.68
Textile mill products 21.61 18.65 0.15
Apparel and other 31.10 18.43 2.09
textile products
Paper and allied products 13.70 23.86 2.61
Printing and publishing 17.12 27.41 3.39
Chemicals and allied products 29.78 27.10 2.93
Petroleum and coal products 24.72 24.24 1.76
Rubber and miscellaneous 25.75 23.52 3.38
plastic products
Leather and leather products 19.06 15.24 -0.64
Transportation, comm., and 18.55 24.42 2.07
utilities
Railroad 4.92 15.61 -0.83
transportation
Local and interurban -10.77 8.27 -1.24
passenger transit
Trucking and 20.18 16.15 3.20
warehousing
Water transportation 18.44 13.48 0.26
Transportation by air 10.36 22.19 3.24
Pipelines, except 51.93 17.09 1.09
natural gas
Transportation services 2.88 20.00 2.24
Communications 24.73 27.98 4.54
Utilities 15.96 25.63 2.40
Wholesale trade 28.84 29.42 6.38
Retail trade 23.48 28.75 3.61
Finance, insurance, and 21.33 27.68 4.39
real estate
Depository institutions 14.01 26.48 7.40
Nondepositoiy; 26.67 28.29 7.48
holding and
investment offices
Security and 21.00 23.95 6.77
commodity brokers
Insurance carriers 19.42 28.97 11.17
Insurance agents, 16.10 18.91 3.24
brokers, and services
Real estate 31.00 28.84 3.09
Services 25.22 27.64 4.41
Hotels and other 8.98 22.14 2.74
lodging places
Personal services 6.03 27.70 1.77
Business services 31.37 5.34
Auto repair, services, 3.18 27.50 5.22
and garages
Miscellaneous repair 20.22 26.33 3.16
shops
Motion pictures 19.37 31.97 6.06
Amusement and 23.56 26.15 2.37
recreation services
Health services 27.38 27.74 5.67
Legal services 12.89 24.09 4.74
Educational services 15.80 15.78 8.22
Other 23.96 23.37 4.97
Private business sector 22.96 26.89 2.90
Source: BEA (1998) and authors' calculations.
Note: Shares and growth rates are percentages.
TABLE 2
Distribution of Capital within Major Sectors and Detailed Industries,
1996
Shares (%)
Other Other
Industry Computers High Tech Equipment
Agriculture, forestry and fishing 0.02 0.87 41.76
Farms 0.00 0.04 38.22
Agricultural services, forestry,
and fishing 0.10 5.95 63.35
Mining 0.14 1.89 16.88
Metal mining 0.02 0.99 19.78
Coal mining 0.03 0.42 33.89
Oil and gas extraction 0.16 2.17 13.22
Nonmetallic minerals, except fuel 0.24 1.34 43.03
Construction 0.11 0.81 59.31
Manufacturing 1.75 6.30 51.47
Durable manufacturing 2.10 5.98 51.71
Lumber and wood products 0.90 2.05 47.03
Furniture and fixtures 1.57 1.81 36.76
Stone, clay, and glass products 1.35 4.94 51.33
Primary metal industries 0.49 2.76 58.89
Fabricated metal products 1.04 2.23 62.95
Industrial machinery and
equipment 3.26 6.61 51.76
Electronic and other electric
equipment 3.59 12.87 45.54
Transportation equipment 1.80 3.23 54.43
Instruments and related product 3.35 13.23 33.44
Miscellaneous manufacturing
industries 2.03 3.28 43.11
Nondurable manufacturing 1.38 6.64 51.19
Food and kindred products 1.07 4.64 49.47
Tobacco products 1.32 3.47 46.96
Textile mill products 0.64 2.95 52.71
Apparel and other textile
products 1.91 2.81 39.85
Paper and allied products 0.68 4.69 69.13
Printing and publishing 3.94 9.66 42.69
Chemicals and allied products 1.53 11.13 48.87
Petroleum and coal products 0.86
Rubber and miscellaneous 5.16 41.35
plastics products 1.38 2.07 61.77
Leather and leather products 1.48 0.84 31.12
Transportation, comm., and
utilities 0.30 12.42 23.81
Railroad transportation 0.01 1.77 11.93
Local and interurban passenger
transit 0.03 6.56 21.39
Trucking and warehousing 0.05 3.61 72.73
Water transportation 0.10 4.04 76.74
Transportation by air 0.40 7.94 72.31
Pipelines, except natural gas 0.20 1.71 8.68
Transportation services 0.32 12.16 71.34
Communications 0.58 36.83 7.44
Utilities 0.28 5.04 23.51
Wholesale trade 6.95 10.34 33.21
Retail trade 1.85 1.85 22.68
Finance, insurance, and real estate 2.28 5.11 16.95
Depository institutions 3.27 8.14 30.79
Nondepository; holding and
investment offices 6.98 11.52 55.51
Security and commodity brokers 8.71 5.62 13.89
Insurance carriers 5.17 8.79 27.36
Insurance agents, brokers, and
services 4.29 6.79 29.91
Real estate 0.93 2.87 6.55
Services 4.97 8.83 30.19
Hotels and other lodging places 0.17 1.28 9.20
Personal services 1.10 6.31 28.96
Business services 20.41 14.20 37.01
Auto repair, services, and garages 0.91 2.87 83.21
Miscellaneous repair shops 2.45 2.13 59.37
Motion pictures 1.87 23.21 22.24
Amusement and recreation services 0.86 1.29 25.84
Health services 1.92 14.30 12.64
Legal services 5.85 11.48 26.79
Educational services 0.69 1.46 6.93
Other 5.85 12.56 18.01
Private business sector 1.85 7.32 28.87
Shares (%) Total Value of
Capital Stock
Industry Structures (Millions US$)
Agriculture, forestry and fishing 57.38 366,430
Farms 61.69 315,425
Agricultural services, forestry,
and fishing 30.53 51,276
Mining 81.05 436,641
Metal mining 79.20 35,165
Coal mining 65.67 36,171
Oil and gas extraction 84.45 344,343
Nonmetallic minerals, except fuel 55.42 20,745
Construction 39.80 88,188
Manufacturing 40.49 1,480,426
Durable manufacturing 40.23 759,300
Lumber and wood products 50.05 29,331
Furniture and fixtures 59.87 13,316
Stone, clay, and glass products 42.41 43,403
Primary metal industries 37.80 127,819
Fabricated metal products 33.76 81,906
Industrial machinery and
equipment 38.33 128,598
Electronic and other electric
equipment 38.01 128,802
Transportation equipment 40.55 139,315
Instruments and related product 49.98 53,024
Miscellaneous manufacturing
industries 51.59 14,001
Nondurable manufacturing 40.77 721,018
Food and kindred products 44.86 145,868
Tobacco products 48.27 9,182
Textile mill products 43.74 37,655
Apparel and other textile
products 55.41 13,332
Paper and allied products 25.47 98,503
Printing and publishing 43.72 60,044
Chemicals and allied products 38.47 206,387
Petroleum and coal products
Rubber and miscellaneous 52.64 92,578
plastics products 34.81 54,711
Leather and leather products 66.51 2,629
Transportation, comm., and
utilities 63.51 2,301,741
Railroad transportation 86.24 360,656
Local and interurban passenger
transit 72.00 19,912
Trucking and warehousing 23.59 108,208
Water transportation 19.10 36,002
Transportation by air 19.36 110,141
Pipelines, except natural gas 89.38 48,361
Transportation services 16.20 42,660
Communications 55.17 562,226
Utilities 71.15 1,014,044
Wholesale trade 49.47 402,858
Retail trade 73.67 540,565
Finance, insurance, and real estate 75.62 1,960,245
Depository institutions 57.81 370,374
Nondepository; holding and
investment offices 26.02 151,641
Security and commodity brokers 71.78 11,542
Insurance carriers 58.67 180,296
Insurance agents, brokers, and
services 59.01 6,449
Real estate 89.64 1,239,803
Services 56.06 754,670
Hotels and other lodging places 89.37 127,093
Personal services 63.63 26,266
Business services 28.34 126,464
Auto repair, services, and garages 13.01 114,535
Miscellaneous repair shops 36.00 11,987
Motion pictures 52.73 29,366
Amusement and recreation services 71.96 48,536
Health services 71.16 153,883
Legal services 55.87 18,922
Educational services 91.00 18,221
Other 63.60 79,647
Private business sector 61.99 8,328,842
Source: BEA (1998) and authors' calculations.
TABLE 3
Distribution of Computer and High-Tech Capital across Major Sectors,
1996
Computer Capital
Industry Nominal Value Percent of Total
Agriculture, forestry and fishing 58 0.04
Mining 612 0.40
Construction 100 0.06
Durable manufacturing 15,919 10.35
Non durable manufacturing 9,965 6.48
Transportation, comm., and 6,905 4.49
utilities
Wholesale trade 27,991 18.20
Retail trade 10,018 6.51
Finance, insurance and real estate 44,789 29.11
Services 37,475 24.36
Private business sector 153,833 100.00
High-Tech Capital
Industry Nominal Value
Agriculture, forestry and fishing 3,243
Mining 8,874
Construction 811
Durable manufacturing 61,278
Non durable manufacturing 57,829
Transportation, comm., and 292,832
utilities
Wholesale trade 69,677
Retail trade 20,009
Finance, insurance and real estate 144,988
Services 104,160
Private business sector 763,700
High-Tech Capital
Industry Percent of Total
Agriculture, forestry and fishing 0.42
Mining 1.16
Construction 0.11
Durable manufacturing 8.02
Non durable manufacturing 7.57
Transportation, comm., and 38.35
utilities
Wholesale trade 9.12
Retail trade 2.62
Finance, insurance and real estate 18.99
Services 13.64
Private business sector 100.01
Source: BEA (1998) and authors' calculations.
Notes: Shares are percentages and values are millions of current
dollars. High-tech capital includes computers, scientific instruments,
photocopy equipment, and communications equipment.
TABLE 4
Simple Production Function Regressions, 1980-96
OLS FE
Aggregate Sector Industry Sector
ln(L) 1.074 (***) 0.511 (***) 0.493 (***) 0.051
(0.104) (0.025) (0.020) (0.075)
ln([K.sub.c]) 0.052 (**) 0.188 (***) 0.178 (***) 0.046
(0.018) (0.016) (0.010) (0.038)
ln([K.sub.n]) -0.227 0.154 (***) 0.256 (***) 0.030
(0.291) (0.033) (0.015) (0.097)
Year 0.003
(0.003)
[R.sup.2] 0.99 0.89 0.85 0.87
No. of obs. 17 170 935 170
FE SYS-GMM
Industry Sector Industry
ln(L) 0.468 (***) 0.554 (***) 0.340 (***)
(0.062) (0.053) (0.114)
ln([K.sub.c]) -0.018 0.171 (***) 0.305 (***)
(0.018) (0.064) (0.084)
ln([K.sub.n]) -0.122 (**) 0.123 -0.020
(0.056) (0.120) (0.081)
Year
[R.sup.2] 0.50
No. of obs. 935 160 880
Notes: All regressions include year dummy variables, except for
aggregate OLS. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. [R.sup.2] is
adjusted-[R.sup.2] for OLS and within-[R.sup.2] for FE. Dependent
variable is log of real value-added; L is labor; [K.sub.c] is computer
capital; [K.sub.n] is noncomputer capital.
(***), (**), and (*)denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and
10% level, respectively.
TABLE 5
Extended Production Function Regressions, 1980-96
OLS
Aggregate Sector Industry
ln(L) 1.299 (***) 0.533 (***) 0.505 (***)
(0.126) (0.028) (0.021)
ln([K.sub.c]) 0.073 (*) 0.161 (***) 0.142 (***)
(0.034) (0.024) (0.013)
ln([K.sub.h]) -0.028 0.057 0.070 (***)
(0.388) (0.044) (0.012)
ln([K.sub.o]) -0.752 (***) -0.050 -0.015
(0.184) (0.051) (0.013)
ln([K.sub.s]) -0.441 0.096 (*) 0.210 (***)
(0.609) (0.056) (0.017)
Year 0.011 (**)
(0.004)
[R.sup.2] 0.99 0.88 0.86
No. of obs. 17 170 935
p-value 0.013 0.116 0.000
FE SYS-GMM
Sector Industry Sector
ln(L) -0.001 0.465 (***) 0.557 (***)
(0.089) (0.060) (0.072)
ln([K.sub.c]) 0.069 (*) 0.001 0.132 (*)
(0.037) (0.019) (0.073)
ln([K.sub.h]) 0.122 (***) 0.071 (***) 0.123
(0.041) (0.023) (0.098)
ln([K.sub.o]) -0.190 (**) -0.223 (***) -0.105
(0.088) (0.060) (0.105)
ln([K.sub.s]) 0.246 (**) 0.059 0.048
(0.115) (0.070) (0.203)
Year
[R.sup.2] 0.89 0.52
No. of obs. 170 935 160
p-value 0.019 0.000
SYS-GMM
Industry
ln(L) 0.485 (***
(0.102)
ln([K.sub.c]) 0.177 (**)
(0.076)
ln([K.sub.h]) 0.105 (*)
(0.061)
ln([K.sub.o]) -0.170 (**)
(0.078)
ln([K.sub.s]) 0.194 (**)
(0.075)
Year
[R.sup.2]
No. of obs. 880
p-value
Notes: All regressions include year dummy variables, except for
aggregate OLS. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. [R.sup.2] is
adjusted-[R.sup.2] for OLS and within-[R.sup.2] for FE. Dependent
variable is log of real value-added; L is labor; [K.sub.c] is computer
captial; [K.sub.h] is other high-tech capital; [K.sub.o] is other
equipment capital; and [K.sub.s] is structures. p-value is associated
with null hypothesis of equal elasticities for all types of noncomputer
capital.
(***), (**) and (*)denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and
10% level, respectively.
TABLE 6
Alternative Production Function Regressions, 1980-96
OLS
Aggregate Sectors Industry
ln(L) 1.342 (***) 0.539 (***) 0.512 (***)
(0.094) (0.032) (0.021)
ln(K) -1.056 (***) 0.318 (***) 0.417 (***)
(0.235) (0.031) (0.013)
ln([K.sub.e]/K) -0.503 (***) 0.061 0.006
(0.134) (0.082) (0.032)
ln([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]) 0.092 (***) 0.181 (***) 0.182 (***)
(0.015) (0.016) (0.010)
year 0.015 (***)
(0.004)
Implied [delta] 0.476 0.191 0.015
p-value 0.001 0.454 0.841
Implied [gamma] -0.087 0.568 0.437
p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000
[R.sup.2] 0.99 0.89 0.86
No. of obs. 17 170 935
FE SYS-GMM
Sectors Industry Sectors
ln(L) 0.040 0.463 (***) 0.577 (***)
(0.078) (0.061) (0.102)
ln(K) 0.217 (**) -0.035 0.344 (***)
(0.098) (0.057) (0.116)
ln([K.sub.e]/K) -0.256 (**) -0.313 (***) -0.007
(0.103) (0.086) (0.273)
ln([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]) 0.066 (*) 0.003 0.141 (**)
(0.039) (0.020) (0.058)
year
Implied [delta] -1.179 8.921 -0.020
p-value 0.009 0.570
Implied [gamma] 0.303 -0.078 0.410
p-value 0.128 0.901
[R.sup.2] 0.88 0.51
No. of obs. 170 935 160
SYS-GMM
Industry
ln(L) 0.484 (***)
(0.086)
ln(K) 0.281 (***)
(0.085)
ln([K.sub.e]/K) -0.063
(0.121)
ln([K.sub.c]/[K.sub.e]) 0.231 (***)
(0.056)
year
Implied [delta] -0.224
p-value
Implied [gamma] 0.821
p-value
[R.sup.2]
No. of obs. 880
Notes: All regressions include year dummy variables, except for
aggregate OLS. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. [R.sup.2] is
adjusted-[R.sup.2] for OLS and within-[R.sup.2] for FE. Dependent
variable is log of real value-added; L is labor; [K.sub.c] is total
capital; [K.sub.e] is equipment capital; [K.sub.c] is computer capital.
Implied [delta] and implied [gamma] from equation (9), and p-value is
associated with null hypothesis that the implied coefficient equals
zero.
(***), (**), and (*) denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and
10% level, respectively.
TABLE 7
Comparison of Manufacturing and Nonmanufacturing Results, 1980-96
Simple OLS Simple SYS-GMM
Mfg Non-Mfg Mfg
ln(L) 0.128 0.565 (***) 0.178
(0.205) (0.058) (0.195)
ln(K)
ln[(K.sub.c)] 0.262 (***) 0.164 (***) 0.458 (***)
(0.112) (0.032) (0.232)
ln[(K.sub.n)] 0.299 (***) 0.261 (***) 0.038
(0.108) (0.066) (0.231)
ln[(K.sub.h)]
ln[(K.sub.o)]
ln[(K.sub.s)]
ln[(K.sub.e/K)]
ln[(K.sub.c/K.sub.e)]
No. of obs. 340 595 320
Simple SYS-GMM Extended SYS-GMM
Non-Mfg Mfg Non-Mfg
ln(L) 0.412 (***) 0.197 0.582 (***)
(0.085) (0.155) (0.085)
ln(K)
ln[(K.sub.c)] 0.228 (***) 0.191 0.143 (***)
(0.066) (0.126) (0.061)
ln[(K.sub.n)] 0.098
(0.082)
ln[(K.sub.h)] 0.365 (***) 0.054
(0.140) (0.069)
ln[(K.sub.o)] 0.147 -0.135 (*)
(0.209) (0.073)
ln[(K.sub.s)] -0.398 0.231 (***)
(0.328) (0.066)
ln[(K.sub.e/K)]
ln[(K.sub.c/K.sub.e)]
No. of obs. 560 320 560
Alternative SYS-GMM
Mfg Non-Mfg
ln(L) 0.127 0.602 (***)
(0.152) (0.089)
ln(K) 0.384 (***) 0.265 (***)
(0.082) (0.085)
ln[(K.sub.c)]
ln[(K.sub.n)]
ln[(K.sub.h)]
ln[(K.sub.o)]
ln[(K.sub.s)]
ln[(K.sub.e/K)] 1.512 (***) -0.266 (**)
(0.528) (0.132)
ln[(K.sub.c/K.sub.e)] 0.358 (**) 0.169 (***)
(0.159) (0.046)
No. of obs. 320 560
Notes: All regressions includes year dummy variables. Robust standard
errors are in parentheses. Variables are defined in Tables 4-6.
(***), (**), and (*) denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and
10% level, respectively.