Corruption: top down or bottom up?
Waller, Christopher J. ; Verdier, Thierry ; Gardner, Roy 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Corruption takes many forms and can arise at many levels, as
pointed out by the classic study of Wade (1985). A large literature has
grown up since then, modeling various aspects of corruption; see the
surveys by Bardhan (1997), Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) (1997), and Schneider and Enste (2000). One of the
questions that this literature has yet to answer concerns the structure
of corruption. Borrowing the language of budgeting, we can think of two
structures of corruption: top-down and bottom-up, as in Gardner and von
Hagen (1996) and Cheung (1998). Top-down corruption refers to a setting
in which corruption decisions are centralized in the chief of state, who
then monitors lower-level officials in an attempt to collect corruption
rents. Bottom-up corruption refers to a setting in which corruption
decisions are decentralized at the level of lower officials. In this
form of corruption, the chief of state is simply one among many
collectors of corruption rents. A similar distin ction, using the same
language, is made by Rose-Ackerman (1999), where "bottom-up"
refers to low-level officials collecting bribes and sharing them with
superiors, while "top-down" refers to corrupt superior
officials buying the silence of subordinates by sharing their ill-gotten
gains.
There is evidence that both forms of corruption exist in practice,
especially in various parts of the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS). Quantitative evidence of the importance of corruption to
macroeconomic performance is also available. In the latest report of the
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), the states of
the CIS are found to have substantially higher levels of corruption than
the states of Central Europe, the Baltic republics, and the Balkans.
In the former, firms report paying 5.7% of all revenues as bribes;
in the latter, only 3.3% of revenues (EBRD, 1999). The report finds it
no coincidence that economic growth in the latter, less corrupt states,
is more than 2% higher on average than growth in the CIS.
It goes without saying that states exhibiting either top-down or
bottom-up corruption get low marks from the various international
surveys of corruption. For instance, according to Transparency
International, the average transparency ranking of ten Central European
countries is 46, compared to 86 for ten CIS countries. However, what is
unclear is how these different structures affect the economic
performance--efficiency and growth--of the economy. Bardhan (1997)
suggests that corruption is more acute in Russia today than in the
former Soviet Union because it is now decentralized, not under party
control as in the old days. He also compares Indonesia with India and
raises an important question:
The two countries are equally corrupt and yet the economic
performance by most accounts has been much better in Indonesia. Could it
be that Indonesian corruption is more centralized and thus somewhat
predictable ... whereas in India it is a more fragmented, often anarchic system of bribery? (Bardhan, 1997, 1325)
Bardhan's question is one of second best: Given that
corruption exists, to what extent is one structure of corruption to be
preferred to another? Informal arguments have been offered to suggest
that one or the other structure is to be preferred, as in Shleifer and
Vishny (1993) and Acemoglu and Verdier (1998, 2000), but a formal
analysis has yet to answer this question. Our objective is to build a
principal-agent model of government corruption to determine when and
under what conditions centralized corruption is better for the economy
than decentralized corruption. As we will show, the answer is not
straightforward but depends on a large number of economic fundamentals.
Our metric of preference is allocative efficiency. One of our
results is that allocative efficiency is monotonically decreasing in the
total amount of corruption in monetary terms. This provides considerable
support for allocative efficiency as a metric of preference. Another
result characterizes the distribution of corruption payments, although,
as might be expected, the relationship between distribution and
allocative efficiency is quite complex. This point is made forcefully,
albeit in a rather different model, by Bliss and Di Tella (1997).
Our main result is that we can divide the parameter space of the
model into three mutually exclusive sets and, using these parameter
sets, determine when top-down corruption is the preferred corruption
regime and when bottom-up corruption is preferable. Under one set of
circumstances (roughly, a government with high monopoly power and lower
public sector wages), centralization of corruption increases overall
corruption, because it is simply adding an additional layer of corrupt
officials at the top. By contrast, when there are high enough public
wages to motivate lower-level bureaucrats efficiently (through an
efficiency wage kind of reasoning), centralization of corruption solves
the double marginalization problem, improving the allocation of
resources.
The crucial parameters for dividing the parameter space include the
number of lower-level officials, their official wage, and their
probability of being monitored. Previous studies have pointed to the
importance of these variables. Thus, Mookherjee and Png (1995) give a
central role to the official wage and the probability of being
monitored, whereas the number of corrupt officials plays a central role
in Tirole (1996). In contrast to the latter model, however, all (not
just some) lower level officials are corrupt in our decentralized
regime.
We also study the comparative statics of total corruption with
respect to these parameters within a particular corruption regime as
well as across corruption regimes. Here again the relationship between
these parameters and allocative efficiency is complex. For instance,
increasing the official wage (a popular policy recommendation among
international donor organizations) may reduce neither the total amount
of corruption, nor the number of corrupt officials. Such a reduction
depends on the structure of corruption, as well as other parameters in
the model. Results such as this suggest how sensitive empirical studies are to the specification of corruption. They also help explain why
empirical results are so often inconclusive concerning the role of
variables, such as the official wage of lower level officials.
This article has implications as well for the closely related
literatures of crime, rentseeking, endogenous growth, common-pool
resources, and the economics of transition. Basu et al. (1992) show that
issues arise in complex corrupt settings that go well beyond the
standard economic model of crime. Rentseeking, as in Acemoglu (1995) and
Olson (1995), is what motivates officials playing in either of the
corruption structures studied here. Our officials are rent-seekers, with
rents being generated by expected gains from investments made in the
economy; the autocrat in our model is likewise a rent-seeker. To the
extent that corruption results in allocative efficiency losses--here,
lost investments--we also get endogenous growth effects. These growth
losses provide a formal explication of the concepts of social capital,
as in Putnam (1993), and social breakdown, as in Hirshleifer (1995).
Next, one can interpret the demand for investments in an economy
subject to corruption as a common-pool resource, as in Ostrom et al.
(1994), where the commons is man-made and those using the commons are
the bureaucrats (and possibly autocrat) charging bribes. Absent
institutions to prevent tragic outcomes, one can expect such a commons
to exhibit serious efficiencies in the presence of a large number of
bribe-takers. This connection was first noticed by Shleifer and Vishny
(1993).
Finally, because some of the successor states of the former Soviet
Union rank among the most corrupt in the world, our results apply to the
economics of the transition of those states from planned to market
economies. Thus, for instance, we would expect the Tanzi
effect--increases in the price level have a negative impact on real
taxes collected due to corruption--to be present in the data generated
from such countries. Moreover, we would predict considerable transition
costs involved in restructuring a corrupt regime into a more transparent
and open economic system. The financial crisis of summer 1998, whose
effects still linger in the CIS, partly reflects the failure of
international aid programs to achieve such a restructuring of these
economies. Such is increasingly the view of the EBRD after a decade of
aid programs in the CIS.
The article is organized as follows. Section II lays out the basic
principal-agent model. Section III contains the results on bottom-up
corruption; these turn out to be straightforward compared to those on
top-down corruption. Section IV studies top-down corruption under the
assumption that the participation constraints for lower-level officials
is satisfied. Section V is devoted to a detailed examination of the
participation constraint question. Section VI concludes.
II. MODEL
Our model has three players: entrepreneurs, bureaucrats, and an
autocrat. Entrepreneurs undertake investment projects but need permits
from the government to operate. The autocrat is at the top of the
government hierarchy; the bureaucrats occupy the lower level of
government responsible for day-to-day operations. Our government
hierararchy has only two levels, and our autocrat is not accountable to
the electorate, an assumption reasonable for many developing countries.
Bag (1997) develops a model in which the public is the principal,
monitoring the autocrat who in turn monitors the bureaucrat. We abstract
from real-world complications by assuming at most two levels of
corruption. Of course, in the real world there may be many layers of
corruption. (See Guriev [1999] for an example of a three-tier
government.) We assume bureaucrats have power to grant permits that
private agents need to carry out business in the formal economy.
Corruption occurs when a bureaucrat demands a bribe from a private
agent in return for the permit. The autocrat, if involved in the
bribery, either receives a kickback from bureaucrats or chooses a level
of bribe for the bureaucrats to demand. In our model, we do not impose
any restrictions on the morality of the autocrat, that is, he or she
does not oppose corruption on moral grounds, nor do we assume that the
people are able to force the autocrat to oppose corruption via electoral
competition. Again, we do not impose any restrictions on the morality of
the bureaucrats; if taking bribes maximizes their utility, they take
bribes.
The basic question in which we are interested is whether having the
autocrat involved in the bribe process: (1) simply adds another
bribe-taker or (2) reduces some inefficiency that arises from letting
the bureaucrats determine bribes on their own.
Entrepreneurs
Individual entrepreneurs are endowed with two possible investment
projects: one in the formal sector of the economy and one in the
informal sector. The formal projects have idiosyncratic payoffs, and the
informal sector projects do not. In short, the informal projects are
homogeneous; each project offers the same fixed-return, as opposed to
the heterogeneity inherent in formal sector projects. Operating in the
formal sector requires the payment of taxes. The value of a formal
sector project drawn by entrepreneur i is
(1) [V.sup.L.sub.i] = [V.sup.L] - t + [[alpha].sub.i],
where t is a lump-sum tax paid by each entrepreneur in the formal
sector of the economy and [[alpha].sub.i] is the idiosyncratic return on
the investment project, uniformly distributed on the interval [0, a]. If
all entrepreneurs operate in the formal sector, the size of the formal
economy is 1. The assumption that [[alpha].sub.i] is uniformly
distributed is made for technical convenience only. Any continuous
distribution will lead to the same qualitative results.
The informal project has a payoff
(2) [P.sup.I.sub.i] = [V.sup.I]
for all i. Taxes do not apply to the informal sector.
To undertake investment in the formal sector, entrepreneurs need to
acquire a permit from each of n > 1 different bureaucrats in the
government. In practice, this can lead to a large number of permits.
Even for a small business in Ukraine, n = 10 is a typical number.
Consequently, the net payoff to entrepreneur i from investing in the
formal sector is given by
(3) [V.sup.L.sub.i] = [V.sup.L] - t + [[alpha].sub.i] - [B.sub.i],
where [B.sub.i] is the total amount of bribes paid by entrepreneur
i, the sum of bribes [b.sub.i,j] paid by i to each bureaucrat j. We
distinguish between taxes, t, which are determinate and predictable, and
bribes B, which even at equilibrium have an element of arbitrariness to
them. This interpretation is made forcefully by Wei (1997).
Entrepreneur i will choose to enter the formal sector of the
economy when (3) exceeds (2), which implies
(4) [[alpha].sub.i] [greater than or equal to] -([V.sup.L] - t -
[V.sup.I] - [B.sub.i]).
We will assume that [V.sup.L] - t - [V.sup.I] > 0. In the
absence of corruption, where [B.sub.i] = 0 for all i, there would be no
shadow economy, as (4) would hold for all i. This is the first-best
benchmark outcome. At this first-best outcome, given our normalization,
total taxes collected equal t, a maximum.
Bureaucrats
Each bureaucrat chooses a bribe to charge an entrepreneur who
applies for a permit from his office. He also receives a civil servant
wage, given by w. We assume w exceeds the bureaucrat's reservation
wage from non-governmental employment, which we normalize to zero. This
allows us to ignore modeling the bureaucrat's decision to work in
the civil service, as in Besley and McClaren (1993).
The bureaucrat chooses a bribe to maximize expected income. The
bureaucrat is not able to observe the idiosyncratic part of the
entrepreneur's project but does know the distribution of
[[alpha].sub.i]. By symmetry, a bureaucrat charges the same bribe to all
entrepreneurs who request permits. Furthermore, he is aware that other
bureaucrats are also demanding bribes.
Given these assumptions, the demand for permits Q, also the size of
the formal sector, is piecewise linear in bribes. Letting X = a +
[V.sup.L] - t - [V.sup.I] - [SIGMA][b.sub.j], where the latter sum is
taken over all bureaucrats j, one has Q = X/a when X does not exceed a,
and Q = 1 otherwise.
We also assume that the autocrat receives a kickback from each
bureaucrat, with q denoting the fraction of the bribe income paid to the
autocrat. Alternatively, one can think of q as the probability the
autocrat detects whether or not the bureaucrat charges a bribe. If the
bureaucrat is found to have taken a bribe, the autocrat takes the entire
bribe but does not fire the bureaucrat. One could also model the problem
as one in which the bureaucrat risks being fired in addition to losing
the bribe income. As long as the kickback tax rate does not exceed q,
the bureaucrats will be truthful in reporting their bribe income to the
autocrat under this scenario also.
Under either of these interpretations, we take q to be exogenous,
admittedly an extreme assumption made solely to better focus on the main
issue, centralized versus decentralized corruption. For a method of
endogenizing q, see Besley and McClaren (1993); our main results are
robust to q endogenized in this way.
The bureaucrat's problem is to maximize bribe income, given by
(5) [max.sub.[b.sub.j]] [w + (1 - q)[b.sub.j]
[[integral].sub.[X.sup.a]] (1/a)d[[alpha].sub.i]]
= [max.sub.[b.sub.j]] w + (1 - q)[b.sub.j]X/a
Notice that the bureaucrat's problem is degenerate if q = 1.
Autocrat
The autocrat levies taxes on the legal sector, pays civil servants
wages out of the budget, monitors bureaucrats, and collects bribe income
from those bureaucrats detected taking bribes. The autocrat's
income z from the bribe process is z = qn[b.sub.j] X/a. The budget
deficit G - T is given by G - T = nw - t X/a. Under our assumptions of a
fixed w and n, government expenditures G are constant across all
regimes. At the same time, taxes T are proportional to the size of the
legal economy. Thus, at the first-best outcome, where the size of the
legal economy is 1, one has G - T = nw - t = 0, where the last equality
comes from assuming a balanced budget at the first-best outcome.
Corruption, which reduces taxes collected, results in a budget deficit.
One could impose a balanced budget constraint among the corrupt regimes
as well. Because corruption leads to a smaller tax base, the need to
cover a budget deficit by taxing other sectors of the economy would only
be exacerbated in such a case.
A hallmark of corrupt regimes is the keeping of multiple sets of
books. For instance, the autocrat (or his agent) may keep one set of
books to satisfy international financial institutions that the budget is
balanced, while keeping another set of books (the accurate set) showing
the true budget imbalance. Such appears to have been the case at the
Central Bank of Ukraine, which in 2000 agreed to pay the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) a $100 million fine for bookkeeping and related
irregularities in 1997-98.
III. DECENTRALIZED CORRUPTION
Uncoordinated Bribe-Setting
In our decentralized equilibrium, the autocrat specifies q and lets
the bureaucrats choose whatever bribes they desire. At this Nash
equilibrium, bureaucrats are modeled as players choosing their bribes
simultaneously, taking the other bureaucrats' bribes as given.
Consequently, the first-order condition from (5), exploiting symmetry,
yields the following Nash equilibrium bribe per bureaucrat and total
bribes paid by each entrepreneur:
(6) [b.sup.d.sub.j] = k/(1 + n),
where k = a + [V.sup.L] - t - [V.sup.I]
[B.sup.d] = nk/(1 + n),
where the superscript d denotes the decentralized equilibrium.
These expressions have a long history in economics, going back to
Cournot's (1838; rpt. 1963) treatment of the reverse monopoly
problem. Given (6), the size of the legal economy is Q = k/(1 + n),
which we assume to be less than 1 for the remainder of the article.
Total bribes paid in the economy are
(7) total bribes = Q[B.sup.d] = [k.sup.2]n/[(1 + n).sup.2],
of which proportion q are paid to the autocrat:
(8) z = q[k.sup.2]n/[(1 + n).sup.2].
Coordinated Bribe-Taking
If the bureaucrats coordinate their bribes and choose a common
bribe, b, then the optimal bribe maximizes the representative
bureaucrat's income, now given by
(9) [max.sub.b] [w + (1 - q)b [[integral].sub.-[X.sup.a]]
(1/a)d[[alpha].sub.i]]
= [max.sub.b] w + (1 - q)bX/a,
where X = [V.sup.L] - t - [V.sup.I] - nb
Maximizing with respect the common bribe b yields
(10) b = k/(2n)
B = nb = k/2.
The size of the formal economy is Q = k/(2a), and total bribes are
(11) total bribes = BQ = [k.sup.2]/(4a).
Comparing (10) and (6) we see that the bribe price per entrepreneur
is lower in this case than in the uncoordinated case. Comparing (11) and
(7) reveals that total bribe income is larger in the coordinated case.
Furthermore, the size of the formal economy is larger when bureaucrats
coordinate their bribes. These results are shown in Figure 1.
This result generalizes that of Shleifer and Vishny's (1993)
two-bribe-setter model. The reason for the high bribe price per
entrepreneur in the uncoordinated case is that each bureaucrat fails to
take into consideration how his bribe affects other bureaucrats'
bribe choices. When bureaucrat i raises his bribe, on the margin he
knows that this will reduce the probability that an entrepreneur will
pay the higher bribe. However, he ignores the fact that by reducing the
entrepreneur's probability of paying bribes, he reduces expected
bribe income for all other bureaucrats. This negative externality results in asking for too large a bribe by all n bureaucrats in the
uncoordinated case.
In a sense, the investment demand under decentralized corruption is
like a commonpool resource, in which the entrepreneurs are an investment
commons being exploited by the bureaucrats. As a result, a typical
tragedy of the commons problem arises and the bureaucrats overuse (extract too much rent) the resource. As pointed out by Ostrom et al.
(1994), in the absence of institutional arrangements to prevent overuse
from occurring, one expects very inefficient outcomes as the number of
bureaucrats grows large. Here, as n gets large, investment demand is
extinguished--the ultimate inefficiency, as compared to the first-best
benchmark.
All bureaucrats would benefit from forming a cartel and acting as a
monopoly bribe-setter. In addition, the legal economy would be larger
under the cartel arrangement. However, the usual problems with enforcing
cooperation apply here. Thus an institutional arrangement that enforces
the monopoly bribe-setting outcome is needed. This is where the
hierarchical structure of the government comes into play--the autocrat
can serve as the institutional enforcement mechanism to maximize total
bribe income. It is to this arrangement that we now turn.
IV. CENTRALIZED EQUILIBRIUM
Now consider the case where the autocrat mandates that the
bureaucrats charge a bribe of a certain size, which is to be turned over
to the autocrat. The autocrat can then redistribute all or part of the
bribe income back to the bureaucrats in the form of a lumpsum transfer.
However, bureaucrats may decide to disobey orders by charging more than
the mandated bribe and keeping the difference. Hence, the autocrat and
bureaucrats are involved in a standard principal agent problem. To
enforce compliance, the autocrat threatens dismissal if a bureaucrat is
caught charging more than the mandated bribe. If the bureaucrat is
caught taking an extra bribe, the bribe is confiscated and he is fired
from his civil service job. Though the threat of job loss is a standard
argument for inducing honest behavior on the part of civil servants, in
our model, the threat of job loss is not used as a tool to eliminate
corruption. Rather, it is used to ensure that bureaucrats produce the
autocrat's desired amount of corruption.
By locating the bribe decision at the top of the hierarchy, we are
confronted with a dilemma. Does centralizing the bribe decision at the
top increase total corruption by simply adding a layer of corruption to
the process? Or, by internalizing the effect of total bribes on legal
activity, does centralization at the top reduce total corruption? In the
next section, we show that either outcome can be generated, depending on
the parameters of the model.
The Bureaucrat's Problem
In the centralized equilibrium, the autocrat tells each bureaucrat
to charge b per permit and return the proceeds back to the autocrat.
Each bureaucrat must then decide whether or not to charge more than b at
the risk of getting fired. If the bureaucrat does not charge an amount
above b, his income is simply w plus his lump sum transfer [tau]. If he
does charge more than the mandated bribe b his problem is
(12) [max.sub.[b.sub.j]] [(1 - q)(w + [tau]) + (1 - q)[b.sub.j]
[[integral].sub.-[X.sup.a]] (1/a) d[[alpha].sub.i]]
= max(1 - q)[w + [tau] + [b.sub.j] X/a],
where X = [V.sup.L] - t - [V.sup.I] - nb - [SIGMA] [b.sub.j], b is
the mandated bribe per bureaucrat and [b.sub.j] is the additional bribe
demanded by bureaucrat j over and above that mandated by the autocrat.
The first-order condition for this problem yields the following Nash
solution for [b.sub.j] in the centralized equilibrium
(13) [b.sup.c.sub.j] = (k - nb)/(1 + n)
where the superscript c denotes the centralized equilibrium.
If k - nb < 0, the net value of the project is zero and no
entrepreneurs will be in the legal sector, which means no bribe income
or tax revenues for the government. Thus, we will only consider
solutions for which (13) is positive. The bureaucrats will only choose
to demand [b.sup.c.sub.j] if their expected equilibrium income from
asking for additional bribes exceeds their civil service salary.
Otherwise [b.sup.c.sub.j] = 0. The condition for the bureaucrats to
comply with the mandated bribe and set [b.sup.c.sub.j] = 0 is
(14) nb [greater than or equal to] k - (1 + n)[[aq(w + [tau])/(1 -
q)].sup.1/2].
Note that (14) is more likely to hold, the larger are q, w, [tau],
and b. Intuitively, bureaucrats are more likely to do what the autocrat
tells them to do the larger the probability of getting caught and the
more costly it is getting fired. Furthermore, the larger the mandated
bribe b, the smaller the expected number of entrepreneurs applying for
permits. Because this reduces the expected payoff from asking for even
more bribes, the bureaucrats are more likely to comply with the
autocrat's orders. Because the bureaucrat cares about the sum w +
[tau], we set [tau] = 0 and simply rescale the value of w to account for
this. As we argue later, the autocrat has strong incentives to reward
the bureaucrats in this fashion.
The Autocrat's Problem
The autocrat wants to choose b to maximize his expected bribe
income, denoted Y(nb), taking the bureaucrat's bribe decision as
given. However, from (14) we see that his choice of b affects the
bureaucrat's decision to cheat on the mandated bribe or not.
Let n[b.sub.0] = [B.sub.0] denote the value that makes (14) hold
with equality,
(15) [B.sub.0] = k - (1 + n)[[aq(w + [tau])/(1 - q)].sup.1/2].
This is the value of n[b.sub.0] that makes the bureaucrat
indifferent between cheating or not. Hence, the bureaucrat's bribe
decision is
(16) [b.sub.j] = (k - nb)/(1 + n) when nb < [B.sub.0]
[b.sub.j] = 0 otherwise.
Now, depending on whether bureaucrats ask for bribes or not, the
autocrat's expected income can be computed as follows. When
bureaucrats comply with the autocrat's bribe orders, [b.sub.j] = 0,
the autocrat becomes a monopolist bribe-setter. In this case, his
expected income [Y.sub.m](nb) is given by
(17) Y(nb) = [Y.sub.m](nb) = [(k - nb)/a](nb).
The first term in (17) is the measure of entrepreneurs who apply
for permits (k - nb)/a and the second term nb is the level of mandated
bribes.
When bureaucrats charge more than the mandated bribe, the autocrat
merely becomes the n + 1 bribe-setter. Hence his expected income in this
case, denoted [Y.sub.2](nb), is the sum of his expected mandated bribe
income plus his expected income from confiscating the additional bribes
from bureaucrats he catches cheating:
(18) Y(nb) = [Y.sub.2](nb)
= [(k - nb)/(a(1 + n))]
x [(qn[k - nb]/[1 + n]) + nb].
The first bracketed term in (18) is the measure of entrepreneurs
who apply for permits, and the second bracketed term is the sum of
confiscated bribes and mandated bribes. Figure 2 plots the two functions
[Y.sub.2](nb) and [Y.sub.m](nb). The autocrat's expected income
with bureaucrats' corruption [Y.sub.2](nb) has a maximum at
[B.sup.^] = n[b.sup.^] = [gamma]k/2, where [gamma] = (1 + n - 2qn)/(1 +
n - qn) < 1.
His monopolistic expected income [Y.sub.m](nb) has a maximum at
[B.sup.*] = n[b.sup.*] = k/2 > [B.sup.^]. Because being a monopolist
is clearly better than being an n + 1 bribe setter, one also gets that
[Y.sub.m]([B.sup.*]) [greater than or equal to] [Y.sub.2]([B.sup.^]).
Figure 2 plots these two payoff functions for the autocrat. Let
[B.sup.~] be the value of B for which the autocrat's income in the
monopolistic bribe-setting regime equals his maximum income in the
bureaucratic corruption regime. Any value of B in [k/2, [B.sup.~]]
yields higher bribe income for the autocrat than the regime with
bureaucratic corruption.
The problem of the autocrat is then to maximize his payoff function
Y (nb) over B = nb given the incentive constraint for bureaucrats given
by (14). Three possible regimes can emerge, depending on where the
boundary point of the incentive constraint lies. It turns out that the
optimal value of B can be reached at [B.sup.^] = [gamma]k/2, [B.sup.*] =
k/2, or the threshold point [B.sub.0]. We consider each regime in turn.
Regime 1: Bribes at Both Levels of Government
This case, represented in Figure 3, occurs when [B.sub.0] >
[B.sup.~] > k/2. The autocrat maximizes his expected income at
[B.sup.^]. As a result, this is a regime with corruption at both levels
of government. Because entrepreneurs pay bribes to both bureaucrats and
the autocrat, total bribes per entrepreneur are
(19) total bribes per entrepreneur
= n[b.sup.c] + n[b.sup.^] = (2n + [gamma])k/(2[1 + n]).
Total bribes paid in this regime equal
(20) total bribes = (n[k.sup.2])/(a[[1 + n].sup.2])
- [gamma][k.sup.2](n - 1 + [gamma]/2)
/(2a[[1 + n].sup.2]),
and the autocrat's bribe income in this regime is
[Y.sub.2]([B.sup.^]) = [k.sup.2]/(4a[1+n(1-q)]).
Comparing (19) to (6) we see that total bribes per entrepreneur is
higher than in the decentralized corruption case. However, the total
amount of bribes paid to the government in this regime is lower than in
the decentralized corruption equilibrium. The reason is that the total
number of entrepreneurs applying for permits falls enough to more than
offset the increase in bribe payments per entrepreneur, that is, the
demand for permits is bribe-elastic at this level of equilibrium bribes
per entrepreneur. This is a result of the distributional assumption on
[[alpha].sub.i], permit demand is elastic for B > k/2. Thus, the
formal economy is smaller in this regime than in the decentralized
regime. Adding a layer of government to the corruption problem leads to
a worse outcome than in the uncoordinated decentralized equilibrium.
Regime 2: Monopolistic Bribe-Setting by the Autocrat
Figure 4 shows this regime, which occurs when [B.sup.*] = k/2
[greater than or equal to][B.sub.0]. The autocrat has a maximum income
at the point: [B.sup.*] = n[b.sup.*] = k/2, which is also the total
bribe per entrepreneur, as this is the regime with monopoly corruption.
The autocrat sets a higher mandated bribe if he is a monopolist
bribe-setter than he does in the regime in which bureaucrats cheat and
charge additional bribes. However, despite the fact that the autocrat
mandates a higher bribe in regime 2 than regime 1, comparing [B.sup.*]
to (10) and (20) shows that total bribes actually paid per entrepreneur
are lower in this case than in regime 1 or the decentralized corruption
equilibrium. Nevertheless, equilibrium bribe income is highest in this
regime. By centralizing the bribe process and becoming a monopolist
bribe-setter, the autocrat internalizes the externality associated with
uncoordinated decentralized bribe-setting into account. As a result,
total bribes per entrepreneur are reduced.
Regime 3: The Constrained Monopolist Bribe-Setter
This is the regime that reflects the fact that the autocrat is
constrained in his maximization of monopolist bribes and is shown in
Figure 5. This regime occurs when [B.sup.~] > [B.sub.0] > k/2. The
autocrat cannot choose the monopolist bribe because it is not high
enough to deter the bureaucrats from charging an additional bribe.
However, by choosing [B.sup.*] = [B.sub.0] in this case, the autocrat
makes the mandated bribe high enough to deter additional bribes and
still earn more income as a monopolist bribe-setter that reverting to
being the n + 1 bribe-setter. Consequently, in the regime the autocrat
is at a corner. Total bribes paid per entrepreneur are higher than in
the case where [B.sup.*] = k/2. The total bribes paid per enterpreneur
will be lower than in the decentralized case when 2(1+n)[(aqw/[1 -
q]).sup.1/2] < k < [(1 + n).sup.2] [(aqw/[1 - q]).sup.1/2].
Figure 6 summarizes the ordinal ranking of each regime compared to
the decentralized Nash bribe-setting regime. We see that the two-level
bribe equilibrium is the worst outcome, followed by the decentralized
Nash equilibrium, the constrained equilibrium and the monopoly
bribe-setter equilibrium.
Discussion of the Three Regimes
It is useful to investigate the parameters' conditions under
which the different regimes prevail. To do this, let y = [(aqw/[1 -
q]).sup.1/2] and thus [B.sub.0] = k - (1 + n)y.
The conditions for regime 1 are [B.sub.0] > k/2 and (k -
[B.sub.0])[B.sub.0]/a < [k.sup.2]/(4a[1 + n - qn]). These can be
rewritten as k > 2(1 + n)y and k > 2(1 + n)A(q, n)y, where A(q, n)
= 1/[1 - [[n(1 - q)/(1 + n[1 - q])].sup.1/2]] > 1. Hence the
two-level bribe regime will prevail under the condition
(A) k > 2(1 + n)A(q, n)y.
Similarly, the condition for the monopolistic centralized bribe
regime (regime 2) is given by [B.sub.0] < k/2, which can be rewritten
as
(B) k < 2(1 + n)y.
Finally the constrained monopolist regime (regime 3) occurs when
(C) 2(1 + n)y < k < 2(1 + n)A(q, n)y.
The three regions (A), (B), and (C) are represented in Figure 7 in
the plane (y, k). The value of k represents the measure of how many high
return investment projects there are in the economy. When this number is
large, asking for a bribe has a small effect on driving entrepreneurs
into the informal sector. The value of y reflects the expected cost of
getting fired. The monopolist bribe regime is more likely to prevail
when y is large relative to k, which is likely to be satisfied when the
cost of getting fired is relatively high. In this region, the autocrat
is able to implement the monopolist bribe because he is able to
efficiently monitor his bureaucrats through the stick (the probability
of control q) or the carrot (the wage rate w).
On the other hand, the regime with bribes at both levels is more
likely to occur when k is large--namely, when the after-tax relative
return of the legal sector as compared to the informal sector is high or
there are many high-value investment projects in the economy (a large
value of a). In this region, the temptation for bureaucrats to ask for
an additional bribe is quite high, making it difficult for the autocrat
to fight corruption at that level of the bureaucracy. Hence his optimal
response is to choose the two-level corruption regime. Finally, for
intermediate values of k and y, the constrained monopolist bribe regime
prevails. The autocrat would ideally want to be a monopolist briber but,
given the fundamentals of the economy, his monopolistic bribe level is
not high enough to deter bribe-taking at the lower level of the
bureaucracy. Therefore he prefers to choose a constrained monopolistic
bribe level.
An increase in the size of the bureaucracy n shifts
counterclockwise the two rays k = 2(1 + n)y and k = 2(1 + n)A(q, n)y in
Figure 7. This has the effect of enlarging the monopolistic bribe region
and reducing the two-level bribe region. The effect on the constrained
monopolist bribe region is ambiguous. The reason is that as n increases,
bribing becomes less profitable for bureaucrats, as fewer entrepreneurs
choose to enter the formal sector by paying bribes. Hence it is easier
for the autocrat to sustain the monopolistic bribe regime or the
constrained monopolistic regime.
The previous discussion provides also some cross-country
predictions on the implications of having an additional layer of corrupt
administration on corruption and its efficiency costs. In particular, it
suggests that an additional layer of corrupt bureaucracy is more likely
to have corruption efficiency costs on output for rich economies, which
presumably are also the ones with large corporate opportunities for
business in the formal sector. On the other hand, poor economies in this
second-best world may be better off in terms of production with a
corrupt autocratic government hierarchy able to capture monopolistic
rents and deter lower-level corruption.
Interestingly, this also suggests that any liberalization or
economic reform, which increases the profitability of the private legal
sector, should be accompanied by intensive administrative reforms
against corruption. Otherwise, liberalization without reform at the top
level of the bureaucracy may well move the corruption equilibrium from a
monopolistic bribe region (B) to a two-level bribe situation (A),
increasing corruption-induced inefficiencies and thereby stripping away
the potential economic gains of the liberalization process.
The Correlation of Corruption with Economic Activity
Which of the bribe equilibria has the lowest level of corruption?
To answer this question, we must construct a metric of corruption.
However, such a construction is problematic given the above results. If
we measure corruption as the bribes paid per entrepreneur (or investment
project), then corruption is highest in the centralized regime 2 and
lowest in the centralized regime 1. On the other hand, if we measure
corruption as total bribe income, then corruption is lowest in regime 1
and highest in regime 2. Hence, depending on how one wants to measure
corruption, the monopoly bribe-setting equilibrium may be viewed as the
lowest- or the highest-corruption equilibrium. But regardless of how
corruption is measured, the legal sector of the economy is largest in
this regime, as is per capita income.
This result is interesting because it ties into a long-standing
debate regarding the efficiency implications of corruption. On the one
hand, it is argued that corruption reduces private market efficiency by
creating frictions that inhibit private sector investment. Hence,
corruption is sand in the wheels. On the other hand, it is also argued
that corruption is often the only way to get things accomplished;
without it, nothing gets done. According to this line or argument,
corruption greases the wheels.
Our results show that whether or not corruption is correlated with
private sector investment depends to some extent on how one measures
corruption. In the monopoly bribe-setting equilibrium, bribes per
investment project are the lowest, hence there is more private sector
investment. But because more entrepreneurs choose to operate in the
legal sector and acquire permits from the government, total bribe
payments in the economy are high. Hence, by the first measure,
corruption exhibits a negative correlation with private sector activity;
by the second measure, corruption is positively correlated with private
sector activity. This suggests that empirical studies purporting to
estimate the correlation between corruption and private sector activity
must be very careful in how they measure corruption.
For our purposes, because the regime with the lowest bribe per
entrepreneur has the largest legal sector and, thus, the largest level
of per capita income, we believe this is the most relevant measure of
corruption. Consequently, in regime 1 we find that adding a layer of
government to the bribe process simply leads to more corruption, whereas
in regime 2 we find that adding a layer of government actually lowers
the amount of corruption.
Welfare Analysis of the Different Regimes
Clearly the regime with corruption at both levels is the worst
equilibrium possible for all involved, except the bureaucrats. In this
equilibrium, bribes per entrepreneur and the shadow economy are at their
highest values and tax revenues and the autocrat's bribe income are
at their lowest values. Adding the autocrat into the bribe process
simply adds a layer of corruption that worsens economic efficiency. On
the other hand, the monopolist regime may be welfare-improving compared
to the decentralized (one-layer) corruption equilibrium. As we already
noticed, in a second-best world in which corruption is unavoidable,
centralized corruption internalizes the negative externality of
corruption by other bureaucrats on investment decisions in the formal
economy. This tends to improve the efficiency of allocation of resources
in the economy. On the other hand, a monopolist in corruption has more
monopoly power to set bribes, hence asking for a larger bribe per
project. Whether the centralized monopolist corruption e quilibrium is
more efficient than the decentralized corruption equilibrium depends on
which effect is stronger. Here the externality effect is stronger than
the monopolization effect, as total bribes per project in the
decentralized equilibrium nk/(1 + n) is larger than total bribes per
project under monopolization. Hence, from an efficiency point of view,
centralized regime 2 provides the best corruption equilibrium.
The third corruption regime can be analyzed similarly. Total bribe
per project is [B.sub.0], which is smaller than the bribe with
centralized corruption, nk/(1 + n), as long as k < [(1 + n).sup.2]y
holds. In this case, this regime provides a larger legal economy than
does decentralized corruption and so leads to a more efficient
allocation of resources.
V. ENSURING BUREAUCRATIC COMPLIANCE
Up until now we have assumed that the parameters affecting the
bureaucrats' compliance with the bribe mandate, q, w, n, and k,
were constant. However, all four of these parameters are under the
control of the autocrat to some extent. The parameter q is a function of
the autocrat's monitoring technology and effort. The civil
servant's salary, w, can be set by the autocrat. The size of the
bureaucracy, n, is also under the control of the autocrat. Finally, k is
affected by the taxes imposed on entrepreneurs by the autocrat.
Because the autocrat's most preferred bribe equilibrium is the
interior monopolist bribe-setting solution, he has a strong interest in
ensuring that bureaucrats comply with the mandated bribes. Combining the
equilibrium bribe under monopoly [B.sup.*] with the incentive
compatibility constraint (14) yields
(21) k [less than or equal to] 2(1 + n)y.
Because he has control of the parameter values of k, q, n, and w,
the autocrat can adjust these four parameters to ensure that (21) always
holds. He can do this by
1. raising tax rates to lower k (the net value of legal projects);
2. increasing the bureaucrats' salary;
3. increased monitoring of bureaucrats (increase q); or
4. increasing the size of the bureaucracy (increase n).
Although the autocrat can ensure that (21) holds using any one of
these instruments, he will not be indifferent to which of these
parameters is used. In the sections that follow we discuss the
attractiveness of using each of these variables to ensure the
bureaucrats' compliance with the mandated bribes.
Raising Taxes
Increasing taxes on firms will lower the value of all projects and
the demand for legal projects. By lowering the expected bribe income for
bureaucrats, the autocrat ensures that they are less willing to ask for
bribes and risk being fired. Unfortunately, lowering k also reduces the
autocrat's bribe income. Sacrificing income to induce bureaucrats
to behave seems to us to be an unattractive method for inducing
cooperation.
Raising Civil Servant Salaries
By raising civil servant salaries, the autocrat increases the
penalty of getting caught taking an additional bribe. Because civil
servant salaries are paid for out of the public budget rather than the
autocrat's bribe income, this is essentially a free tool for the
autocrat to ensure compliance with his bribe orders. In a sense, this is
a key difference between an autocrat and a mafia chieftain. Mafia
chieftains are the residual claimants to enterprise profits whereas
autocrats are not typically the residual claimants on government tax
surpluses. Increasing the pay of underlings reduces the residual profits
of the mafia enterprise and thus the income of the chieftain, but paying
higher salaries to civil servants out of public revenues does not reduce
the autocrat's income. So unless the autocrat is able to use tax
revenue surpluses for his own use, raising civil servant salaries to
induce compliance with his demands seems to be a relatively costless
method for maximizing his bribe income.
Of course, if the autocrat gets utility from public spending
projects, such as more education, highways, or monuments glorifying him,
then the reallocation of tax revenues from these types of projects to
civil servant salaries will impose a cost on the autocrat. The form of
corruption and preventive measures may affect the allocation of
government revenues on public goods. Mauro (1998) finds that corruption
is negatively correlated with government spending on education. Thus,
the question becomes, Which is more important, his personal bribe income
or the warm glow he gets from improving the government capital stock?
Our suspicion, based on casual observation of autocratic governments
around the world, is that the former is more important to autocrats than
the latter.
Increased Monitoring
The autocrat can also undertake more intensive monitoring of the
bureaucrats to ensure that they abide by his bribe mandate. But if this
requires expending utility reducing effort by the autocrat, he may opt
for another method of enforcement, as in Bac (1996a, 1996b). On the
other hand, if the autocrat can use public funds to increase compliance,
then we have the same situation as with raising salaries. For example,
if he creates a watchdog group of civil servants responsible for
enforcing compliance with the autocrat's demands and pays them with
tax revenues, then the autocrat has a free method of increasing
monitoring. However, this simply creates another principal-agent problem for the autocrat because the bureaucrats may pay bribes to the internal
police to avoid dismissal. In short, who monitors the monitors?
Increasing the Size of the Civil Service
By increasing the size of the bureaucracy, the total amount of
bribes increases, thereby reducing the demand for permits and the
expected bribe income of an individual bureaucrat. Hence, as an
individual bureaucrat becomes a smaller part of the government
bureaucracy, he is less likely to risk being fired to receive a small
amount of bribe income. Once again, the bureaucracy is paid for out of
public funds, so this is a free method for the autocrat to ensure
compliance with his orders. However, this assumes that the probability
of detection remains the same as the number of bureaucrats increases. In
general, this is not true; as the size of the bureaucracy increases,
detection of additional bribe-taking is reduced. Hence, increasing n
will typically be associated with a reduction in detection, which
increases the payoff from asking for an additional bribe. As a result,
increasing the size of the bureaucracy may actually backfire and lead to
a greater likelihood of an individual bureaucrat asking for additional
bribes.
VI. CONCLUSION
In summary, it appears that increasing civil servant salaries is
the best option for the autocrat to ensure that bureaucrats ask only for
the bribes they are told to collect. All of the other methods appear to
impose nontrivial costs on the autocrat.
If the economically optimal amount of corruption is not zero, then
an interesting question is where should the corruption be allocated--at
the top of the government hierarchy or the bottom? Having built a
hierarchical model of government, we explored the question of whether
centralizing corruption at the top simply increases the total amount of
corruption in an economy or reduces it by generating an organizational
efficiency gain (via a principal-agent relationship between levels of
government). We have argued that if corruption is measured by the amount
of bribes paid per investment project, then centralizing corruption at
the top of the government may lead to a more efficient allocation of
corruption. Furthermore, the top level of governmental hierarchy has
many tools at its disposal to ensure that this outcome prevails.
However, if corruption is measured as the total volume of bribes paid in
the economy, then centralizing bribe decisions at the top of the
hierarchy leads to more corruption in the economy, even though there is
a larger private sector in this corruption regime. Thus, our theoretical
results provide an important caveat for doing empirical work on the
effects of corruption on private sector activity. In either event, the
EBRD's concern with the amount of corruption in the CIS is well
founded. Indeed, the CIS would seem to be an area where centralizing
corruption does not seem to yield good economic results.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D. "Reward Structures and the Allocation of
Talent." European Economic Review, 30(1), 1995, 17-33.
Acemoglu, D., and T. Verdier. "Property Rights, Corruption,
and the Allocation of Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach."
Economic Journal, 108(450), 1998, 1381-403.
-----. "The Choice between Market Failure and
Corruption." American Economic Review, 90(1), 2000, 194-211.
Bac, M. "Corruption and Supervision Costs in
Hierarchies." Journal of Comparative Economics, 22(1), 1996a,
99-118.
-----. "Corruption, Supervision, and the Structure of
Hierarchies." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 12(2),
1996b, 277-98.
Bag, P. K. "Controlling Corruption in Hierarchies."
Journal of Comparative Economics, 25(2), 1997, 322-44.
Bardhan, P. "Corruption and Development: A Review of
Issues." Journal of Economic Literature, 35(3), 1997, 1320-46.
Basu, K., B. Sudipto, and A. Mishra. "Notes on Bribery and the
Control of Corruption." Journal of Public Economics, 48(2), 1992,
349-59.
Besley, T, and J. McClaren. "Taxes and Bribery: The Role of
Wage Incentives." Economic Journal, 103(416), 1993, 119-41.
Bliss, C., and R. Di Tella. "Does Competition Kill
Corruption?" Journal of Political Economy, 105(5), 1997, 1001-23.
Cheung, S. "The Curse of Democracy as an Instrument of Reform
in Collapsed Communist Economics." Contemporary Economic Policy,
16(2), 1998, 247-49.
Cournot, A. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the
Theory of Wealth, with Irving Fisher's Original Notes. Homewood:
Richard D. Irwin, 1963.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Transition Report
1999. London: EBRD, 1999.
Gardner, R., and J. von Hagen. "Sequencing and the Size of the
Budget," in Understanding Strategic Interaction: Essays in Honor of
Reinhard Selten, edited by W. Albers, W. Guth, P. Hammerstein, B.
Moldovanu, and E. van Damme. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1996, 464-74.
Guriev, S. "A Theory of Informative Red Tape with an
Application to Top-Level Corruption." New Economic School Working
Paper, Moscow, 1999.
Hirshleifer, J. "Anarchy and Its Breakdown." Journal of
Political Economy, 103(1), 1995, 26-52.
Mauro, Paulo. "Corruption and the Composition of Government
Expenditure." Journal of Public Economics, 69(2), 1998, 263-79.
Mookherjee, D., and I. Png. "Corruptible Law Enforcers: How
Should They Be Compensated?" Economic Journal, 105(428), 1995,
145-59.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
"Corruption: The Issues." Development Center Technical Papers
No. 122, OECD, Paris, 1997.
Olson, M. "Why Poor Economic Policies Must Promote Corruption:
Lessons from the East for All Countries." Unpublished manuscript,
University of Maryland, 1995.
Ostrom, E., R. Gardner, and J. Walker. Rules, Games, and
Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994.
Putnam, R. Making Democracy Work: Civic Tradition in Modern Italy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993.
Rose-Ackerman, S. Corruption and Government. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1999.
Schneider, F, and D. Enste. "Shadow Economies: Size, Causes,
and Consequences." Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 2000,
77-114.
Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. "Corruption." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 108(3), 1993, 599-618.
Tirole, J. "A Theory of Collective Reputations (with
Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and of Firm
Quality)." Review of Economic Studies, 63(1), 1996, 1-22.
Wade, R. "The Market for Public Office: Why the Indian State
Is Not Better at Development." World Development, 13(4), 1985,
467-97.
Wei, S.-J. "Why Is Corruption so Much More Taxing than Taxes?
Arbitrariness Kills." NBER Working Paper No. 6255, Washington, DC,
1997.
RELATED ARTICLE: ABBREVIATIONS
CIS: Commonwealth of Independent States
EBRD: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
ROY GARDNER *
* We would like to thank Krister Andersson, Kaushik Basu, Steve
Lewarne, Rob Masson, Michael McGinnis, Bruce J. Bueno de Mesquita,
Elinor Ostrom, Eric Rasmusen, and an anonymous referee for helpful
comments. Any remaining imperfections are the sole responsibility of the
authors, who wrote this article as visiting faculty members at Economics
Education and Research Consortium, National University of Ukraine,
Kyiv-Mohyla Academy.
Waller: Gatton Chair, Department of Economics, University of
Kentucky, Lexington, KY 40506-0034. Phone 1-859-257-6226, Fax
859-323-1920, E-mail cjwall@pop.uky.edu
Verdier: Professor, Department and Laboratory of Theoretical and
Applied Economics (DELTA), 75014 Paris, France. Phone 33-1-43 13 63 98,
Fax 33-1-43 13 63 10, E-mail tv@delta.ens.fr
Gardner: Chancellor's Professor, Departments of Economies and
West European Studies, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405. Phone
1-812-855-6383, Fax 1-812-855-3736, E-mail gardner@indiana.edu