THE EFFECTS OF SMOKING LAWS ON SEATING ALLOCATIONS OF RESTAURANTS, BARS, AND TAVERNS.
DUNHAM, JOHN ; MARLOW, MICHAEL L.
MICHAEL L. MARLOW [*]
Supporters of smoking laws often argue that they do not harm
restaurants, bars, and taverns and may even raise their profits.
Opponents argue that owners cater to customer preferences regarding
smoking and that laws mandating specific smoking policies will therefore
negatively impact profits of some firms. This article tests hypotheses
regarding how smoking laws affect seating allocations, using data from a
nationwide survey of restaurant and bar owners. The empirical evidence
indicates that smoking laws exert no significant effect on seating
allocations. Firms are shown to allocate greater shares of seating to
nonsmoking use when customers exhibit stronger preferences for such
seating. (JEL K2, H0)
I. INTRODUCTION
Laws restricting smoking in restaurants have been enacted in 32
states. Supporters of these laws often argue that they do not harm firms
and may even raise their profits. [1] Recent studies, for instance,
argue that outright bans on smoking in eating and drinking places have
not adversely affected these establishments, suggesting that smoking
bans either do not reduce demand or lower costs for firms, which offsets
sales losses, thus leading to no adverse changes in profits. Opponents
of smoking restrictions argue that owners cater to customer preferences
regarding smoking. Some owners would find it profitable to allow smoking
throughout their establishments, others to forbid all smoking, and still
others to accommodate both smokers and nonsmokers by investing in
partitions, designating areas, creating smoking patios or rooms, and/or
investing in air filtration systems. They argue that laws that mandate
specific smoking policies will therefore negatively impact profits of
some firms.
Little economic research has been published on the effects of
smoking laws on revenues of restaurants, bars, and taverns, and none has
been directed toward the issue of smoking/nonsmoking seating
allocations. [2] This article provides a framework for examining how
customer preferences influence smoking and nonsmoking seating
allocations by owners--the primary policy that firms unilaterally adopt
in their attempts to deal with the issue. Hypotheses regarding how
smoking laws affect seating allocations are then tested using data from
a nationwide survey of 1,300 restaurant, bar, and tavern owners. The
empirical evidence indicates that smoking laws exert no significant
effect on seating allocations.
II. ECONOMIC MODEL AND TESTABLE HYPOTHESES
Without legal restrictions, policies adopted by restaurants, bars,
and taverns toward smoking are determined in much the same manner as
decisions regarding menus, prices, and hours of operation.
Profit-maximizing firms optimize on the basis of customer demand and
costs. Decisions pertaining to smoking policies simply allocate the air
space within firms between smoking and nonsmoking customers. [3] The air
space within an establishment is considered just like any other
resource, and owners decide to cater solely to smokers, to nonsmokers,
or to both by providing patrons with rights to smoke while accommodating
others through smoking/nonsmoking areas and air filtration systems. The
choice depends on customer preferences and relative marginal costs. [4]
Predictably, market segmentation naturally evolves where firms cater
more to smokers in markets dominated by smokers than in those markets
dominated by nonsmokers.
There may also be broad differences between how owners of
restaurants and bars or taverns allocate seating. Customers of
restaurants are likely to prefer that owners adopt different
accommodation strategies than would patrons of bars and taverns.
Restaurant customers tend to dine in one location within firms, and
therefore it is possible for owners to designate sections for smokers
and nonsmokers, and this predictably leads to a relatively high
allocation of nonsmoking seating. In contrast, customers of bars and
taverns may prefer to participate in various activities (dining,
drinking, listening to music, dancing, and playing pool, darts, and
billiards) whereby they move to different locations within the
establishment during their visit and interact with different patrons. It
is relatively more difficult and therefore costly to designate areas for
smokers and nonsmokers in bars and taverns, and this predictably leads
to a relatively low allocation of nonsmoking seating. Moreover, because
of the interactive atmosphere of bars and taverns, it is unlikely that
all nonsmokers wish to remain separated from their smoking friends (and
vice versa), and therefore many bar and tavern owners may find it
relatively unprofitable (and unpopular) to segregate these two groups.
This reasoning leads to the testable hypothesis that the mix of
smoking/nonsmoking seating is influenced by the smoking preferences of
customers so that nonsmoking seating allocations are inversely related
to the percentage of customers who smoke. It is also possible that the
smoking characteristics of state populations may be a significant factor
explaining whether state governments pass smoking restrictions. We
expect that states with relatively few smokers are more likely to pass
smoking laws.
III. DESCRIPTION OF DATA
Survey data collected by Roper Starch for the National Licensed
Beverage Association is used to examine how smoking laws influence
seating allocations. The survey was conducted by telephone interviews
during the period of September 5--12, 1996. All interviewing was
conducted from the Roper Starch central interviewing facility. The
sample consisted of owners/managers of 1,300 randomly drawn restaurants
(650) and bars or taverns (650) across the United States. Samples were
drawn in a statistically random manner from national lists provided by
Survey Sampling, Inc., a major supplier of survey samples to research
organizations. To the extent that the Survey Sampling lists include most
full-service restaurants and bars or taverns in the United States, the
survey results are applicable to all such establishments with a maximum
sampling error of approximately plus or minus four percentage points for
each sample of establishments. The survey instrument was developed by
Roper Starch and includes questions pertaining to seating allocations,
attitudes toward smoking laws, strategies to deal with
smoking/nonsmoking customers, revenues, and projections of effects of
smoking laws on revenues.
IV. TESTING WHETHER SEATING ALLOCATIONS ARE INFLUENCED BY CUSTOMER
PREFERENCES
Selected summary statistics demonstrate that firms in the sample
differentiate themselves by a number of characteristics, including chain
affiliation, age, and size. The range of employment in bars and taverns
is 0-158 workers, and for restaurants it is 0-300 workers. [5] Firms
also differentiate themselves on how they cater to smoking and
nonsmoking preferences of customers. Allocations range from strict
prohibition, mixes of smoking and nonsmoking seating, and smoking
allowed throughout establishments. For restaurants, the average
percentage of seating that is allocated to nonsmoking is 54%, while for
bars and taverns it is 5%--this difference is consistent with
expectations. Both types of establishments have cases where smoking is
entirely prohibited, and both have cases where smoking is allowed
throughout the establishment. Of owners/managers of restaurants who
offer a nonsmoking seating section, more than two-thirds indicate that
this is a product of their own policy. For bars offering partial
nonsmoking seating, more than half of managers/owners indicate that this
is a result of their own policy. The data indicate that both complete
and partial nonsmoking environments exist in private markets with and
without smoking laws. [6]
Table I displays means and standard deviations associated with
three variables: percent of seating allocated to nonsmoking use, percent
of smokers in the adult population, and the percent change in the adult
smoker population over 1989-95, and for three samples: all states,
states with a smoking law, and states without a smoking law. While the
average nonsmoking seating allocation from states with and without a
smoking law does not differ significantly, significant differences exist
for the other two variables (significance at 5% level). That is, states
with smoking laws tend to have fewer smokers and tend to have much
larger reductions in smoking populations.
Figure 1 displays distributions of the shares of seats devoted to
nonsmoking in the states with and without smoking laws. For instance,
57% of firms in the states without smoking laws devote 0%-20% of their
seating to nonsmoking use, as opposed to 62% of firms in states with
smoking laws. Within this grouping, 52% of firms in states without
smoking laws actually devote 0% of their seating to nonsmoking use, and
59% of firms in states with smoking laws devote 0% of their seating to
nonsmoking use. At the other extreme, 16% of firms in states without
laws devote 81%-100%, as opposed to 18% of firms in states with laws.
Within this grouping, 14% of firms in states without smoking laws
actually devote 100% of their seating to nonsmoking use, and 16% of
firms in states with smoking laws devote 100% of their seating to
nonsmoking use. Assuming that the distribution surrounding firms in
no-law states is the expected distribution, the chi-square test
indicates at the 5% level that we cannot reject the hypothesis that the
distribution surrounding firms in smoking law states does not differ
significantly from that of firms in no-law states. Therefore, the
distribution of the shares of nonsmoking seating does not appear to
differ between these two samples. It is important to note that this data
set was developed in 1996 and may not reflect the implications of de
facto complete smoking bans such as the one that now exists in
California.
Many other factors may also influence allocations of seating into
smoking/nonsmoking designations. The size of a firm (e.g., number of
employees) may influence decisions when scale economies exist in
catering to both smoking and nonsmoking populations. A positive
relationship between firm size and nonsmoking seating allocations may
occur if larger firms may more easily separate smokers from nonsmokers.
Whether an establishment is a member of a
corporate chain or an independent firm may also affect the allocation
decision. Chain members may offer greater accommodation as an element in
their overall corporate strategy. If this is the case, then chain
members would offer greater nonsmoking seating allocations than
independents. Years in business may also influence seating allocations,
since established reputations may attract a different mix of customers,
and there may be differential accommodation costs related to age of
buildings. It is possible that older businesses may tend to accommodate
less, given that t heir owners tend to cater to more established and
stable customer bases than newer businesses.
Table II displays estimates from three regression equations. [7]
Column 1 contains estimates of an ordinary least squares regression of
nonsmoking seating on smoking laws.
(1) [NS.sub.i] =f([Smoklaw.sub.i]),
where [NS.sub.i] = percentage of seating that is nonsmoking
[Smoklaw.sub.i] = 1 if smoking law present; = 0 otherwise.
No significant relation is determined by this simple regression,
thus indicating that smoking laws do not appear to influence seating
allocations of owners.
In column 2 of Table II, we instrument for smoking laws with
tobacco manufacturing in the state because there are various factors
relating to the social acceptability of smoking that may influence the
smoking law variable that are hypothesized to separately influence
seating allocations as well. The presence of a tobacco manufacturing
facility in a state serves as a good proxy for these factors, since
these facilities tend to be concentrated in states where tobacco growing
and employment make up a large part of the economy. States with a larger
percentage of people involved in the tobacco industry may be less likely
to pass severe restrictions on tobacco use in general. Equation (2) is
estimated by ordinary least squares:
(2) [Smoklaw.sub.i] = f([Tobman.sub.i]),
where [Tobman.sub.i] = dollar value of state tobacco manufacturing
in 1994 ($M). The tobacco-manufacturing variable, which exerts a
statistically significant and negative influence on the smoking law
variable, indicates that states with sizeable tobacco manufacturing will
tend to not pass smoking laws.
Ordinary-least-squares estimation of equation (3) tests the
hypothesis that private markets allocate nonsmoking seating subject to
the following variables: smoking law (instrument), incidence of smoking
in the adult population, changes in smoking incidence, whether the firm
is part of a corporate chain or independent, firm size, years in
business, and whether the firm is a restaurant or a bar or tavern. [8]
(3) [NS.sub.i] = f([Smoklaw.sub.i], [S95.sub.i], [S9589.sub.i],
[Chains.sub.i], [Years.sub.i], [Size.sub.i], [Bar.sub.i]), where
[S95.sub.i] is the percentage of adult population that smokes,
[S9589.sub.i] is the change in percentage of adult population that
smokes from 1989 to 1995, [Chain.sub.i] is 1 if firm is part of
corporate chain; = 0 otherwise [Size.sub.i] is the number of full- and
part-time employees, [Years.sub.i] is the number of years in business,
[Bar.sub.i] is 1 if bar or tavern; = 0 if restaurant.
Equation (3) assumes that smoking laws do not directly influence
smoking behavior in a way that would separately influence the
owners' allocation of nonsmoking seating. A
counter-hypothesis--that state smoking laws themselves may cause fewer
citizens to smoke--implies a simultaneous equations bias in our
estimation. However, while the intent of some smoking laws is to
decrease smoking, the primary intent is to control smoking, and
especially exposure to second-hand smoke, within restaurants, bars and
taverns. [9] While many advocates of smoking laws might also prefer that
smoking decline outside of these establishments as well, this is clearly
of secondary importance for these particular types of restrictions.
Moreover, we are unable to test whether smoking laws lead to less
smoking by customers (and therefore leads owners to allocate less
seating to smokers) simply because this requires time-series data that
is unavailable. Such data may become available in the future, but at
this point we know of no other data that measures seating allocations
and none that provides such a series over time.
It is also unclear that smoking laws would significantly affect
smoking behavior because of less-than-perfect enforcement. Anecdotal
evidence appears to suggest that those businesses that would be most
adversely affected by smoking laws (i.e., those catering to relatively
high numbers of smokers) would also prefer relaxed enforcement of
smoking laws. [10] To the extent that this is true, smoking laws may not
be particularly effective in lowering smoking--both within and outside
restaurants, bars and taverns--and in this case may not be particularly
effective in changing owners' allocation of nonsmoking seating.
[11]
Estimation results of equation (3) are presented in the third
column of Table II. [12] The smoking law instrument does not exert a
significant effect on seating allocations. The incidence of smoking in
the adult population, however, exerts a negative and statistically
significant effect on nonsmoking seating. That is, firms allocate less
seating to nonsmoking use as the percentage of smokers rise in the
population--a relationship consistent with expectations. Change in the
nonsmoking population exerts no statistically significant influence on
seating allocations. As hypothesized, affiliations with a chain and firm
size are significantly and positively related to the percentage of
nonsmoking seating. As hypothesized, years in business exert a negative
effect on nonsmoking seating but is only significant at the 10% percent
level. Finally, the dummy variable for bars and taverns exerts a
significant and negative influence on seating allocations, as consistent
with expectations.
That smoking laws are not significant determinants of nonsmoking
seating deserves further discussion. The data for this analysis were
developed in 1996, prior to the establishment of many highly restrictive
local smoking ordinances. In the case where smoking is banned (and
enforced) throughout establishments--or is limited so that it becomes
extremely inconvenient to smoke--the results of the analysis will not
apply. However, when smoking laws allow for the accommodation of both
smokers and nonsmokers, states with relatively high percentages of
nonsmokers also tend to have relatively high allocations of space
devoted to nonsmoking uses. This suggests that, in many cases, smoking
laws are enacted "after the fact" in the sense that they
appear after the private market has already reallocated resources in
profit-maximizing ways. That is, firms find it profitable to allocate
more space to nonsmokers, as these customers become more important to
their overall revenues. A smoking law will not alter allocation of sp
ace when firms themselves have already met smoking preferences of
customers, provided that the laws do not mandate that nonsmoking space
significantly exceed that provided voluntarily by owners. Of course,
another interpretation may be that restrictive laws are simply not
highly enforced and are therefore ineffective in altering nonsmoking
space within restaurants, bars or taverns. [13]
V. CONCLUSIONS
Proponents of laws restricting smoking within restaurants, bars,
and taverns argue that they are necessary based on the belief that
owners will underallocate nonsmoking seating in their establishments.
This article provides the following insights into this issue. First, in
the absence of outright smoking bans, firms allocate greater shares of
seating to nonsmoking use when their customers exhibit stronger
preferences for such seating. In other words, the private market
allocates air space resources within firms with or without smoking
restrictions, and it is unlikely that removal of smoking laws would
overturn this result. In fact, there is no evidence that smoking laws
themselves affect the seating allocation decisions, thus indicating that
private markets have already dealt effectively with the smoking issue in
the sense that, in the absense of outright smoking bans, firms tend to
voluntarily allocate in excess of government mandates or that
enforcement of smoking laws is imperfect.
Second, the article suggests that the continued decline of smokers
as a share of the population will encourage the owners of hospitality
establishments to allocate more space to nonsmoking customers. This
reallocation arises because of the profit motive and appears to be an
active process within the restaurant, bar, and tavern industries.
Economic examination of the timing of these decisions--how quickly do
owners reallocate their seating space to changes in numbers of
nonsmokers--would be a useful addition to our research. At this point,
however, timeseries data are unavailable that would allow us to examine
the speed of seating reallocations by owners toward nonsmokers.
Dunham: Manager of Fiscal Issues, Philip Morris Management
Corporation, New York, New York, Phone 917-663-2835, Fax 917-663-5379,
E-mail john120@idt.net
Marlow: Professor, Department of Economics, California Polytechnic
State University, San Luis Obispo, California, Phone 805-756-1764, Fax
805-756-1473, E-mail mmarlow@calpoly.edu
(*.) This article is based on an earlier study that was conducted
for Philip Morris Management Corporation. The authors thank William J.
Boyes, Frank J. Chaloupka, and two anonymous referees for helpful
comments.
(1.) Proponents of smoking bans also often argue that, absent such
restrictions, taxpayers are forced to pick up part of the higher health
care costs of smokers in Medicaid, Medicare and private insurance
programs. However, Lee [1991a, 1991b] suggests that smoking bans can not
be expected to lower this type of externality. See also a recent
Congressional Research Service report for Congress [Gravelle and
Zimmerman 1994], which argues that it is likely that passive smoke risk
has been overestimated by the Occupational Safety and Health
Administration. The July 1998 decision by U.S. District Judge William L.
Osteen also concluded after five years of court proceedings that the EPA had wrongly labeled secondhand smoke a class A carcinogen and that the
agency relied on faulty science to reach the conclusion it wanted.
(2.) See, for instance, M. K. Evans [unpublished data], Glantz and
Smith [1994, 1997], and Sciacca and Ratliff [1998] for studies of the
effects of smoking laws on revenues of restaurants.
(3.) Lee [1991b] argues that owners of private establishments have
an incentive to internalize externalities associated with smoking; see
also Tollison and Wagner [1992] and Boyes and Marlow [1996].
(4.) Smoking policies may also be influenced by preferences of
owners, managers, and employers, but it is unclear that their
preferences would override those of customers when owners profit
maximize and hire in competitive labor markets.
(5.) Zero workers means that the firm is entirely run by the owner
and/or family.
(6.) The data are limited in that they test the knowledge of owners
about the source of the smoking law. There were many local smoking
restrictions in place during the period when the survey was conducted;
however, most of the more restrictive laws were put in place after 1996.
(7.) Significant relations are assumed to be those meeting
statistical significance at 5% (two-tailed) levels or greater.
(8.) Variables obtained outside of the survey are: smoking law is
obtained from the Tobacco Institute's "State Smoking
Restriction Laws" [unpublished data]; all other data obtained from
the Center for Disease Control. The smoking rate data measure the
prevalence of current cigarette smoking among adults, and are generated
by the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System. The tobacco
manufacturing variable measures cash receipts from tobacco large enough
to be separately reported by the Center for Disease Control.
(9.) Sciaca and Ratliff [1998], writing in the American Journal of
Health Promotion, mention reduction in exposure of nonsmokers to ETS (environmental tobacco smoke) first in the reasons for why laws
prohibiting smoking in restaurants are approved. They also suggest that
these laws provide an additional incentive and a supportive environment
for smokers to quit, but this reasoning appears secondary in importance.
Moreover, California approved a total smoking ban in all restaurants and
bars based on protection of employees from ETS, once again indicating
that any effects on smoking behavior outside of these establishments to
be secondary.
(10.) Newspaper articles on the smoking ban in California, for
example, document widespread civil disobedience; see, Blankstein [1998],
Canto [1998], and Risling [1998].
(11.) Chaloupka and Saffer [1992] find no evidence that state-wide
smoking bans in restaurants have any effect on smoking as measured by
cigarette consumption.
(12.) We included cross-effects between numbers of employees and
smoking law variables and between smoking law and bar variables, but
neither exerted statistically significant effects. In addition, while it
would be appropriate to control for intrastate correlation in our
regressions, this is not possible given the small number of observations
of many states.
(13.) In this event, however, it would appear that if these laws
were enforced, they would tend to lower profits of some owners.
REFERENCES
Blankstein, Andrew. "Enforcement Clouds Issue of Smoking
Ban," Los Angeles Times, September 21, 1998, 3.
Boyes, William J., and Michael L. Marlow. "The Public Demand
for Smoking Bans." Public Choice, July 1996, 57-67.
Canto, Minerva, "Californians Puff on Despite Ban,"
Washington Post, September 24, 1998, Sec. A., p. 7.
Chaloupka, Frank J., and Henry Saffer. "Clean Indoor Air Laws
and the Demand for Cigarettes." Contemporary Policy issues, April
1992, 72-83.
Glantz, Stanton A., and Lisa R. A. Smith. "The Effect of
Ordinances Requiring Smoke-Free Restaurants on Restaurant Sales."
American Journal of Public Health, July 1994, 1081-85.
-----. "The Effect of Ordinances Requiring SmokeFree
Restaurants and Bars on Revenues: A Follow-Up." American Journal of
Public Health, October 1997, 1687-93.
Gravelle, Jane G., and Dennis Zimmerman. "Cigarette Taxes to
Fund Health Care Reform: An Economic Analysis." March 8, 1994,
Congressional Research Service Report for Congress.
Lee, Dwight, R. "Environmental Economics and the Social Cost
of Smoking." Contemporary Policy Issues, January 1991a, 83-91
-----. "Government v. Coase: The Case of Smoking." Cato
Journal, Spring 1991b, 151-65.
Risling, Greg. "Law Hasn't Completely Barred Smoking in
Taverns. Los Angeles Times, September 23, 1998, A3.
Sciacca, John P., and Michael I. Ratliff. "Prohibiting Smoking
in Restaurants: Effects on Restaurant Sales." American Journal of
Health Promotion, January 1998, 176-84.
Tollison, Robert D., and Richard E. Wagner. The Economics of
Smoking. Norwell, Mass: Kluwer Academic, 1992.
Means and Standard Deviations
All States States with Smoking Laws
(n = 1300) (n = 968)
Nonsmoking seating 29.5 29.1
(% of total seating) (39.5) (39.9)
Smokers 21.6 20.8
(% of population) (3.2) (3.2)
Smoker change -2.1 -2.9
(% change, 1989-95) (2.4) (2.2)
States without Smoking Laws
(n = 332)
Nonsmoking seating 30.6
(% of total seating) (38.3)
Smokers 23.8
(% of population) (2.0)
Smoker change -.003
(% change, 1989-95) (1.6)
Note: Standard deviations are
displayed in parentheses below the means.
Non-Smoking Seating Distributions
Law vs. No-Law Samples
No Law With Law
0%-20% 57 62
21%-40% 8 5
41%-60% 10 8
61%-80% 10 7
81%-100% 16 18
Ordinary-Least-Squares Results
% Nonsmoking % Nonsmoking
Dependent Variable seating Smoking Law Seating
Constant 30.57 [a] 0.76 [*] 111.14 [a]
(14.10) (62.75) (9.09)
Smoking law -1.47
(Yes = 1, No = 0) (-0.58)
Tobacco manufacturing -.0001 [*]
(-6.86)
Smoking law instrument -3.17
(-0.31)
Smokers -2.17 [a]
(-7.96)
% change in smokers 0.26
(0.57)
Chain member 5.68 [a]
(Yes = 1, No = 0) (3.08)
Years in business -0.09
(-1.83)
Number of employees 0.26 [a]
(6.60)
Bar -45.14 [a]
(Yes = 1, No = 0) (-25.89)
Adjusted R-squared 0.00 0.03 0.45
Mean dependent variable 29.48 0.74 29.48
F-statistic 0.34 47.02 155.95
Observations 1,300 1,300 1,300
Note: t-statistics in parentheses.
(a.)Significance at 1% level.