TESTING RENT SHARING USING INDIVIDUALIZED MEASURES OF RENT: EVIDENCE FROM DOMESTIC HELPERS.
SUEN, WING
WING SUEN [*]
The market for resident domestic helpers offers a rare opportunity
where the surplus from employment relationship can be quantitatively
measured for each individual employee. Using the difference between
employer's cost of time and employee's wage as a measure of
rent, it is found that wages for domestic helpers are positively related
to rent. However the apparent sharing of rent is better explained by
matching than by efficiency wage models. Rent sharing is observed even
in households where monitoring or turnover costs are low. Rent sharing
is not observed among newly arrived foreign domestic helpers, whose
ability remains to be revealed. (JEL J41)
I. INTRODUCTION
This article studies the pattern of wages for resident domestic
helpers in Hong Kong. No one would lure economists into paying attention to this arcane labor market were it not for one feature of the market
for housework: A measure of employment rent can be plausibly assigned to
each individual employee. Having an individualized measure of rent at
the worker level (instead of a general measure at the firm level) will
shed considerable light on the large and growing literature of rent
sharing in wage determination.
Since 1975, the Hong Kong government has allowed the importation of
foreign domestic helpers into the territory. Because of large wage
differences between Hong Kong and some of its Asian neighbors, the
program is highly popular. The Census and Statistics Department [1995]
estimates that 92,700 households, or 5.6% of all domestic households in
Hong Kong, employed domestic helpers in 1993. The figure is even more
dramatic for high-income households: 44% of households with monthly
income of over HK$50,000 had one or more domestic helpers. [1]
One consequence of the availability of market-procured housework is
that women who employ helpers have more time for market work. In Suen
[1994], I estimate that the probability of labor force participation
among married women who had domestic helpers is 22 percentage points
higher than that for women without domestic help, other things equal. If
hiring a helper enables a married woman to engage in market work, then a
plausible measure for the "rent" or surplus from this
employment relationship is the difference between the woman's wage
and her helper's wage. If a woman with a domestic helper decides to
stay home nonetheless, the size of the surplus can be measured by the
difference between the shadow value of leisure and the helper's
wage. Wage information is readily available from census data, and shadow
wages can be estimated using standard techniques. This article utilizes
this rare opportunity to impute a measure of rent for each
employer-employee pair. Studying how the wages of domestic helpers vary
wi th the magnitude of rent will provide direct evidence for rent
sharing in the labor market.
There is a large literature which documents the fact that the
characteristics of the employer, such as industry affiliation and firm
size, are significantly correlated with the employees' wages.
Krueger and Summers [19881, Brown and Medoff [1989], Groshen [1991],
Helwege [1992], and many others offer convincing evidence that
inter-industry wage differentials and employer wage effects exist. Rent
sharing is often invoked to account for such wage patterns. However, few
studies in the literature offer a plausible account for the existence of
or a measure for the size of the "rent" that is supposedly
shared. [2] At the industry level, Dickens and Katz [1987] use variables
such as concentration ratio, capital-labor ratio, research and
development expenditures, and average rate of return on capital as
covariates in wage equations. These variables provide at best an
indirect and error-prone measure of employment rent. Campbell [1993]
makes use of firm level characteristics instead of industry
characteristics, but t here is no information on profits in his firm
level data. Similarly, Groshen and Krueger [1990], Krueger [1991], and
Rebitzer and Taylor [1995] focus on wage policies within particular
industries. None of these studies contains any explicit measure of rent.
This large body of literature provides convincing evidence against a
competitive model of wage determination with no sorting on unobserved
ability, but it is not directly relevant for resolving the hypothesis
that employers share their surplus with workers.
Even if firm level data on profits are available, there are
conceptual problems in using total firm profits as the measure of
employment rent for all employees of the firm. In a bargaining model of
rent sharing, for example, the division of rent depends on threat
points, and threat points are unlikely to be the same for an airplane pilot and for a reservation clerk in the same airline (Nash [1950]).
Similarly, in a gift exchange model, producers do not simply give away
part their profits to employees as charity (Akerlof [1982]). The size of
the "gifts" to be exchanged will depend on the importance of
the job and on the potential for shirking. The ideal measure of
employment rent should therefore be specific to each employee; a general
measure of rent that pertains only to the employer would not be
sufficient for evaluating how the employer shares rent with her many
different employees. Fortunately, a distinctive feature of the market
for domestic helpers is that an employer usually hires only one
employee. Therefore, this market offers a possibly unique opportunity
where employe e-specific measures of rent can be constructed.
Note that the concept of "rent" used in this study refers
to employers' rent, and is different from the concept of
appropriable rent as in Klein, Crawford, and Alchian [1978]. I do not
suggest that employers are held hostage by their employees so that the
full employment surplus is subject to negotiation. Since there is a
market for domestic helpers, the "appropriable" part of the
employment surplus is only a fraction of the difference between
employers' wage and employees' wage. Nevertheless, in the
empirical literature on inter-industry wage differentials, rent sharing
is effectively taken to refer to the positive correlation between
employers' rent and wages, regardless of whether such rent is
appropriable by employees or not. The most common approach to test rent
sharing in the labor market is to enter various proxies for
employers' ability to pay in a reduced-form wage equation. [3]
Employees' ability to capture rent (such as union status) is not a
crucial aspect of these studies. Most studies find that more profitable
employers tend to pay higher wages, even if there are no institutional
impediments to replace their existing workers with cheaper ones. The
gift exchange model or some kind of fair wage consideration as in
Akerlof and Yellen [19901 is usually used to justify why employers
willingly share their rent with employees. The measure of rent adopted
in this article is consistent with the empirical rent sharing
literature.
Section II of this article begins with a brief description of the
data used in the analysis. Then, in section III, I show that the wage of
a domestic helper is higher, the higher the wage of the female head of
household. Assuming the surplus from the employment relationship is the
difference between the female employer's wage and the domestic
helper's wage, this finding is consistent with the rent sharing
hypothesis. Section IV extends this finding to families whose female
heads are not in the labor force. I use a standard selection model to
impute the reservation wages for the female employers. Again the wage of
a domestic helper is found to be positively correlated with the
reservation wage of her female employer.
What seems to be rent sharing can potentially be explained by
efficiency wage models or by competitive models with sorting on
unobserved quality. Section V of this article argues that the
relationship between employer's wage and employee's wage
cannot be reconciled with efficiency wage models. I assume there are
systematic differences in monitoring costs between employers who work
and employers who do not work, and that there are systematic differences
in turnover costs between households with young children and households
without young children. I find that employers with high wages (or high
reservation wages) still pay their helpers more even when monitoring
costs or turnover costs are relatively low. This observation is
inconsistent with efficiency wage models.
In section VI the employer wage effect in the market for domestics
is analyzed in the context of a matching model. McLaughlin [1994]
describes a model of efficient matching in thin markets which may give
rise to employer wage effects, and Murphy and Topel [1990] offer
empirical evidence which suggests that sorting by observed
characteristics is significant across industries. In the market for
domestic helpers, if high wage employers desire to hire better domestic
helpers (a positive income elasticity of demand for quality), and if
some dimensions of the helper's ability are unobserved by the
econometrician, there will be a positive relationship between
employer's wage and employee's wage. In Hong Kong most
domestic helpers have come from foreign countries with no prior
experience in the trade. Among domestic helpers who are newly arrived in
Hong Kong, therefore, there is little information available for
matching. Consistent with the matching model, rent sharing is not
observed for this group of domestics.
II. DATA DESCRIPTION
Data for the analysis come from the 5% random sample file of the
1991 Hong Kong Population Census. Because the Hong Kong government
requires employers of foreign domestic helpers to provide them with
accommodation, most domestic helpers reside in the same household with
their employers. This allows easy identification of employer-employee
pairs in the census data. I selected for analysis all individuals aged
15 to 64 whose relationship to the household head is coded
"resident domestic helper (including private chauffeur or
gardener)." Ninety-eight percent of these 2,860 individuals are
female. Since men are more likely to work as chauffeurs or gardeners
than as domestic helpers, they are excluded from the subsequent
analysis. This article requires information about the employers as well
as the domestic helpers. Therefore, only those records with both the
household head and his/her spouse present are used. Finally, a few
records where the domestic helper shows no earnings are excluded. The
resulting sample co nsists of 2,184 observations. [4]
Table I shows selected descriptive statistics on the sample of
domestic helpers and their employers. The most noteworthy aspect of this
market is that 98% of the domestic helpers were not permanent residents
of Hong Kong. Of these foreign helpers, 92% were from the Philippines.
These domestic helpers had very limited labor market experience in Hong
Kong. Only 6% had resided in Hong Kong for 10 years or more, and the
average duration of residence in Hong Kong for the remaining group was
2.6 years. About 20% of them could speak the local Cantonese dialect.
The census records do not have information about work hours, and
wages are measured by reported monthly income from main employment.
Since the sample only contains live-in domestics, it can safely be
presumed that they all worked full-time. In Hong Kong most full-time
domestics are paid a monthly salary, so the monthly income figure is a
good measure of the wage rate. The average monthly wage of a domestic
helper was $2,922, which was slightly less than half the wage of an
average woman in Hong Kong. Although the nature of domestic work is
quite homogeneous, there is a fair amount of dispersion in wages. The
standard deviation of wages was $499, with a range from $700 to $17,000.
[5]
The households employing domestic helpers on average had four
family members. Sixty percent of the female heads reported positive
earnings. Among households without helpers, the comparable figure was
38%. This indicates that by hiring domestic helpers to do the housework,
married women will have more time to engage in market work. [6] Not only
are married women more likely to work if they have domestic helpers,
they also tend to earn higher wages. The average wage of wives in
households with domestic helpers was $15,8322; wives in households
without domestic earned $3,250.
The majority of the households in the sample (94%) hire only one
helper, and the sample contains 1,999 unique employer-employee pairs.
For households that hire more than one helper, the employer variables
are duplicated while the employee variables are unique. It may be,
however, conceptually less attractive to use the difference between the
wife's wage and the domestic helper's wage as a measure of
employment rent in such households, because the allocation of work among
the many helpers is unclear. In the subsequent analysis, results are
presented using observations on all employees. I have also performed the
analysis using only observations where employer-employee pairs are
unique. The results are virtually the same as the ones reported here.
At the time of the census, employers who hired a foreign domestic
helper were required to pay a monthly wage of at least $2,800 before the
contract would be approved by the Labour Department. However, this
minimum wage requirement was hardly enforced. Figure 1 shows the
distribution of the wages reported by domestic helpers in the census
(outliers are not shown in the figure). Although the figure shows a
spike of observations with a wage of $2,800, about 23% of the domestic
helpers reported receiving less than the minimum wage and 46% reported
receiving more than the minimum wage. I have not found an instance where
an employer was prosecuted for violating the minimum wage provision.
III. DO HIGH-WAGE EMPLOYERS PAY HIGH WAGES?
In a competitive model with no sorting on unobserved ability, the
wage of an employee is independent of the identity of her employer. Rent
sharing models do not have this independence property. However the mere
finding that employees' wages depend on the characteristics of
their employers constitutes little support for the rent sharing
hypothesis, unless these characteristics are systematically related to
the magnitude of the employment surplus. In this section I use a direct
measure of employment surplus based on the female employer's market
wage and analyze how this measure of rent is related to the
employee's wage. This section only focuses on households where the
wives work so that direct observations on market wages are available.
The next section deals with the case where the wife does not participate
in the labor market.
Consider a simple Nash bargaining model where the employee's
utility function is u([cdotp]) and the employer's utility function
is v([cdotp]). Both utility functions are assumed to be weakly concave.
Let [W.sub.i] be the wage that domestic helper i receives from her
employer, and let [[bar{W}].sub.i] be her alternative wage. If the
employment relationship continues, the domestic helper will take care of
the housework and her female employer can engage in market work at wage
[Y.sub.i]. The employer's utility level is v([Y.sub.i] -[W.sub.i]).
If the relationship terminates, the wife would either have to stop
working or she would have to consume less leisure. For working
individuals, the value of leisure is equal to the market wage [Y.sub.i]
at the margin. Therefore v([Y.sub.i] - [W.sub.i]) - v(0) represents the
wife's surplus, regardless of whether she will continue to work or
not when she does not have a helper.
Let [gamma] represent the relative bargaining strength of the
domestic helper. Then the Nash bargaining solution will solve:
(1) [max.sub.[W.sub.i]] [[u([W.sub.i]) -
u([[bar{W}].sub.i])].sup.[gamma]] X [v([Y.sub.i] - [W.sub.i]) - v(0)].
The first-order condition to this problem satisfies:
(2) [gamma]u'([W.sub.i])[v([Y.sub.i] - [W.sub.i]) - v(0)] -
v'([Y.sub.i] - [W.sub.i])[u([W.sub.i]) - u([[bar{W}].sub.i])] = 0.
Let [W.sub.i] = f([[bar{W}].sub.i], [Y.sub.i] be the implicit
solution to the above equation. It can be shown that [f.sub.1] [greater
than] 0 and [f.sub.2] [greater than] 0. Alternatively, one can define
[R.sub.i] = [Y.sub.i] - [W.sub.i] to be a measure of rent. Then equation
(2) can be solved for [W.sub.i] in terms of [[bar{W}].sub.i] and
[R.sub.i]. This implicit solution can be written as [W.sub.i] =
g([[bar{W}].sub.i], [R.sub.i]), with [g.sub.1] [greater than] 0 and
[g.sub.2][greater than] 0. The dependence of [W.sub.i] on the rent
variable [Y.sub.i] or [R.sub.i] will provide direct evidence for rent
sharing in the market for domestics. [7]
The purpose of this bargaining model is to illustrate one reason
why employers with greater surplus may pay higher wages to employees.
Obviously, there are other models (such as efficiency wage models) that
will deliver a similar result. Moreover, a full analysis of the
bargaining problem would require greater attention to search and
turnover costs. To the extent that turnover costs are not zero, a
fraction of the surplus [R.sub.i] will be subject to bargaining and the
preceding analysis will apply with minor modifications. Even in a
perfectly competitive market, where the alternative to not hiring a
certain domestic helper is to hire another helper in the market, there
may be noncompetitive reasons (such as gift exchange or fair wage) for
the employer to share the surplus with her domestic helper. Indeed, the
empirical literature on inter-industry wage differentials tends to
emphasize these reasons. The extent to which rent sharing is significant
in the market for domestic helpers is a matter to be determin ed
empirically.
In the empirical analysis, I assume that the domestic helper's
alternative wage depends on her personal characteristics and on the
characteristics of her job. These personal characteristics include
education, potential experience, marital status, whether the person is a
permanent local resident, and her duration of stay in Hong Kong. The job
characteristics include house_size, children and elderly (Table I
contains variable descriptions). Large household size may indicate more
work for the domestic helper, and jobs in such households may command a
compensating differential. Similarly, the presence of young children or
elderly persons in the household may make work for a domestic helper
more or less desirable, and hence affect wages.
Column (1) of Table II shows the log wage regression for domestic
helpers without using rent variables. In this particular labor market,
education and potential experience have insignificant effects
(statistically and economically) on wages. Most of the workers in the
sample received their schooling in the Philippines, which may be of
limited relevance for their job as a domestic helper in Hong Kong.
Similarly, many of these workers worked in a different occupation before
they came to Hong Kong and their prior experience may have limited
effect on earnings. Local experience, on the other hand, turns out to be
highly significant. For those who have resided in Hong Kong for less
than ten years, each additional year of residence is accompanied by a 1%
increase in earnings. Permanent residents of Hong Kong also earn 15%
higher wages than imported foreign domestic helpers. Among the job
characteristics variables, only the number of elderly persons in the
household has a statistically significant negative effect ( at the 0.05
level) on wages. One interpretation is that elderly people can help out
in the domestic chores and make work less burdensome for the maids. The
overall goodness-of-fit of the wage regression is modest: Variations in
personal and job characteristics account for less than 7% of the
variations in log wages.
The remaining four columns of Table II investigate the effect of
rent variables on wages. Column (2) shows that high wage employers pay
higher wages to their helpers. This relationship remains in column (3),
which controls for personal and job characteristics. The elasticity of
employee's wage with respect to employer's wage is 0.024. This
elasticity may seem "small," but variations in employers'
wages are much greater than variations in the wages for domestic
helpers. According to the estimate, a domestic helper whose
employer's log wage is one standard deviation above the mean would
earn a log wage which is 0.13 standard deviation above the average
domestic helper. [8] Notice, however, that introducing employer's
wage into the wage regression increases the [R.sup.2] by only about
0.016. A substantial dispersion in wages remains. [9]
In columns (4) and (5) of Table II, I use log R instead of log Y as
the measure of rent. Since R is defined as Y - W, it will be correlated
with the regression error. The estimates are obtained by instrumental
variables regressions, with log Y as the instrument for log R. The
coefficient on log R is 0.027, and it is statistically significant at
the 0.01 level. These results indicate that wages of domestic helpers
are positively correlated with direct measures of employment rent.
IV. NON-WORKING EMPLOYERS
In the sample of domestic helpers, 40% have female employers who do
not participate in the labor force. For these employers, hiring servants
helps relieve the burden of housework and allows more time for leisure.
Let Y' represent the value of leisure. Then the non-working
employer's surplus from the employment relationship is v(Y' -
W) - v(0). Rent variables can be constructed by using Y' or by
using R' = Y' - W. Although the value of leisure is not
directly observable, the value of leisure at zero hours of work (the
reservation wage) can be estimated using standard techniques. This
section proposes to use the imputed reservation wage as a proxy for
rent.
Let the reservation wage and the market wage for employer i be,
respectively:
(3) log [Y'.sub.i] = [X.sub.1i][[beta].sub.1] + [u.sub.1i];
(4) log [Y.sub.i] = [X.sub.2i][[beta].sub.2] + [u.sub.2i];
where [X.sub.1] and [X.sub.2] refer to the characteristics of the
employer, [[beta].sub.1] and [[beta].sub.2] are the corresponding
vectors of coefficients, and the disturbance terms [u.sub.1] and
[u.sub.2] are jointly normal. Define an index variable [I.sub.i] = log
[Y.sub.i] - log [Y'.sub.i]. Then
(5) [I.sub.i] = [Z.sub.i][delta] + [e.sub.i],
where Z is the union of the [X.sub.1] and [X.sub.2] variables,
[delta] is the coefficient vector conformable to Z, and e = [u.sub.1] -
[u.sub.2]. For labor force participants, [I.sub.i] [greater than] 0 and
[Y.sub.i] can be observed. For nonworking women, [I.sub.i] [leq] 0 and
[Y.sub.i] is not observed. The parameters [[beta].sub.2] and [delta] in
equations (4) and (5) can be estimated using a standard Heckman [1976]
sample selection model.
The maximum likelihood estimates of equations (4) and (5) are
presented in Table III. Most of the variables are highly significant and
have the expected signs. Two points are worth mentioning, however.
First, in contrast to usual labor supply models, the presence of young
children in the family does not reduce the probability of labor force
participation. Suen [1994] argues that this is because women in this
sample all have domestic helpers to take care of their children; the
finding does not extend to Hong Kong women in general. Second, as Lam
and Liu [1995] point out, a married woman who lives with her parents or
parents-in-law can often receive help from her (usually retired) parents
in performing household chores. Thus the presence of elderly persons in
the household is found to significantly increase the probability of
labor force participation.
Using the estimated coefficients in Table III, the reservation wage
for a nonworking employer (i.e., the predicted value of log
[Y'.sub.i]) can be obtained by:
(6) [[hat{y}]'.sub.i] = [X.sub.2i][[hat{[beta]}].sub.2] -
[Z.sub.i][hat{[delta]}] -
[[sigma].sub.1e][[phi](-[Z.sub.i][hat{[delta]}])/
[Phi](-[Z.sub.i][hat{[delta]}])],
where [[sigma].sub.1e] is the covariance between [u.sub.1] and e.
[10] The last term in equation (6) is the correction for selectivity bias. The variable [hat{y}]' is used to measure rent for the sample
of domestic helpers who work for nonworking employers.
Table IV presents log wage regressions for domestic helpers with
nonworking employers. Since the rent variable [hat{y}]' is
estimated from an auxiliary model, OLS standard errors are wrong. The
standard errors shown in the table are derived from Murphy and
Topel's [1985] method of calculating asymptotically correct
standard errors in two-step models. The results of the regressions are
quite similar to those obtained from the sample of domestic helpers with
working employers shown in Table II. Column (1) of Table TV indicates
that employers with higher reservation wages tend to pay significantly
higher wages to their domestic helpers. In column (2), an alternative
measure of employment rent is defined:
(7) [hat{r}]' = log(exp([hat{y}]') - W).
Again, since [hat{r}]' is correlated with the regression
error, the equation is estimated using instrumental variables
regression, with [hat{y}]' as the instrument for [hat{r}]'.
The conclusion remains unchanged. Wages of the domestic helpers are
positively related to either measure of employment rent.
V. MONITORING AND TURNOVER COSTS
What explains the observed relationship between employer's
wage (or reservation wage) and employee's wage? It is insufficient
to invoke "rent sharing" as the explanation for the
phenomenon: the explanation is the observation. In order to understand
why employers seem to share rent with their employees, more detailed
models of wage determination are required. This section discusses two
versions of efficiency wage models--the monitoring model and the
turnover model--and analyzes their relevance to the market for domestic
helpers. [11]
In the monitoring models of Eaton and White [1983] and Shapiro and
Stiglitz [1984], employers pay their employees more than the competitive
wage to reduce supervision costs and to deter shirking or theft. If high
time cost employers have more to lose from nonperformance on the part of
their domestic helpers, they are expected to pay their helpers higher
wages. Note, however, that this relationship obtains only if direct
supervision is costly.
It is not difficult to imagine that employers who stay at home face
a much lower cost in monitoring their domestic helpers than do employers
who participate in market work. If this is the case, rent sharing
between employers and their helpers should be much less pronounced in
the sample of nonworking employers than in the sample of working
employers. The evidence in the previous section, however, fails to
confirm this prediction. The coefficient on the rent variable is
positive and significant even in the nonworking employers sample.
More formally, the monitoring model can be tested by introducing an
interaction term between rent and monitoring costs in the wage
regression for domestic helpers. I assume monitoring costs are
relatively high when the wife engages in market work (wife_work = 1).
Rent is measured by the opportunity cost of time:
(8) log V = {log Y, if Y [greater than] 0; [hat{y}]',
otherwise,
where the imputed value of time [hat{y}]' is given by equation
(6).
In Table V, column (1), the coefficient on the dummy variable for
the wife's employment status (wife_work) is statistically
indistinguishable from zero. Thus, although working employers face a
higher cost of supervising their domestic helpers, they do not pay a
wage premium. [12] Moreover, the interaction between monitoring costs
and rent is negative and statistically insignificant. Contrary to the
prediction of the monitoring model, the degree of rent sharing does not
increase when monitoring costs are high, as when the female employer has
to work and cannot directly supervise her helper.
It is also possible that elderly parents or parents-in-law present
in the household may help monitor the domestic helper. Monitoring costs
are therefore particularly likely to be high if both the employer works
and there is no elderly person in the household. In column (2) of Table
V, the rent variable is interacted with wife--work X no--elderly. The
monitoring hypothesis would predict that the coefficient on this
interaction term is positive, but the data do not support such a
prediction.
Another possible explanation for the observed relationship between
rent and wages is Salop's [1979] turnover model of efficiency
wages. According to this model, employers pay their employees
above-competitive wages in order to discourage labor quits. If high time
cost employers have more incentive to reduce labor turnover, they will
pay their domestic helpers higher wages. The extent of this rent sharing
will depend on, among other things, the costs of disruptions caused by
domestic helpers quitting their jobs. In families with young children,
especially if the wife works, it is reasonable to assume that the
disruptions will be more substantial. The turnover model can therefore
be tested by introducing an interaction term between rent and the number
of young children in the wage regression for domestic helpers.
Column (1) of Table VI shows the regression estimates using the
full sample of domestic helpers. The number of children in the household
does not significantly increase the wage of a domestic helper. Moreover,
families with more children do not share a greater proportion of the
employment rent with their helpers: The coefficient on the interaction
term is negative and statistically insignificant. This conclusion
remains unchanged if the sample is restricted to families where the wife
works [column (2)] or to families where the wife stays home [column
(3)]. The evidence therefore does not support the turnover model of rent
sharing, which predicts that rent sharing should be more pronounced in
households where the wife works and where young children have to be
taken care of. [13]
VI. UNOBSERVED ABILITY AND MATCHING
The apparent sharing of rent need not reflect efficiency wages; a
competing hypothesis is sorting on unobserved worker ability. Recently
McLaughlin [1994] has proposed a model of rent sharing that is
consistent with labor market efficiency. He argues that when worker
quality is heterogeneous and employer-employee matching is important,
labor markets are naturally thin. In such markets the wage of a worker
will depend on the identity of her employer for two reasons. First,
different employers will hire workers with systematically different
abilities for efficient matching. Second, there is room for bargaining
over rent within the efficient match. Rent sharing in this model is not
associated with involuntary unemployment.
In the market for domestic helpers, worker qualities such as
obedience, courtesy, dependability, and devotion to children are
unobservable to the econometrician but are at least partly observable by
employers. If high-wage employers demand domestic helpers with high
ability, then efficient sorting on unmeasured ability may explain the
correlation between the wife's wage and the domestic helper's
wage.
There are at least two reasons why high-wage employers may demand
better domestic helpers. Both reasons are related to the fact that
high-wage employers tend to have high income. First, the quality of a
domestic helper and market goods may be complementary inputs in the
production of domestic services. As in Kremer's [1993] O-ring
production function, for example, a wealthy family is willing to pay to
a premium for a careful domestic helper lest she break the expensive
furniture and antiques. Second, the quality of a domestic helper may
simply be a normal good. These two explanations are not mutually
exclusive, and it is difficult to distinguish between them with the
available data.
The matching hypothesis requires that employers know the ability of
their employees, though such ability may be unobservable to the
econometrician. For domestic helpers who have been in Hong Kong for a
number of years, on the one hand, this assumption is reasonable. Direct
observation of work behavior and referrals from former employers can
provide good information about worker ability. Efficient matching is
facilitated by the frequent turnover of domestic helpers. [14] For
domestic workers who have just arrived in Hong Kong, on the other hand,
information about their ability is much more limited. Many employers
hire their domestics from overseas through specialized employment
agencies. These agencies may perform some initial screening, but because
of the nature of the job, formal qualifications such as education are of
limited value in predicting work ability. Attributes which are important
in this trade cannot be revealed without a period of close supervision.
Moreover, since most foreign domestic helpers w orked in other
occupations before they came to Hong Kong, past experience may not be a
good indicator of their ability as a domestic helper. The matching
hypothesis then predicts that employer's wage will have little or
no effect on the wages of newly arrived foreign domestic workers.
I divide the sample of domestic helpers into two groups: those who
have lived in Hong Kong for not more than one year, and those who have
been in Hong Kong for over one year. Because of employers' lack of
information about the ability of the former group of workers, matching
is expected to be relatively unimportant. If the relationship between
the wife's wage and the helper's wage is a result of sorting
on unobserved ability, such a relationship should be weaker among the
newly arrived helpers than in the other group. Table VII shows the
regression results. The coefficient on log V in the group who have lived
in Hong Kong for more than one year [column (2)] is 0.032 and is
significant at the 0.01 level. In contrast, the coefficient on log V in
the newly arrived group [column (1)] is 0.012 and is statistically
insignificant at the 0.05 level. Therefore, when employers do not have
the opportunity to observe worker ability, there is no evidence of rent
sharing. [15]
Another piece of evidence that corroborates the matching hypothesis
is that the domestic helper's wage seems to be positively
correlated with the husband's wage as well as with the wife's
wage. In 89% of the households in the sample, the husband's wage is
greater than the wife's wage. In the absence of a domestic helper,
it is expected that the wife would have to shoulder the bulk of the
household chores because of different time costs. As the husband will
concentrate on market work with or without a domestic helper, his market
wage is a poor measure of employment surplus. Therefore, if bargaining
over the employment surplus is the main reason behind the positive
correlation between the wife's wage and the employee's wage,
the correlation should be much weaker between the husband's wage
and the employee's wage. On the other hand, if the positive
correlation is driven by matching between high-income households and
high-ability domestic helpers, both the husband's wage and the
wife's wage should be correlated with their maid's pay.
I have estimated a log wage regression for domestic helpers that
includes, besides personal and job characteristics, both the time cost
of the wife (log V) and the wage of the husband (log( husband-wage)) as
independent variables. The coefficient on log V is 0.016 (t = 2.97), and
the coefficient on log (husband_wage) is 0.024 (t = 5.83). [16] The
hypothesis that these two coefficients are equal cannot be rejected.
There is no evidence that the husband's wage has a smaller impact
than the wife's wage on the pay of their domestic helper. Instead,
the evidence suggests apparent rent sharing is the result of a positive
income elasticity for (unobserved) quality.
If high-income households prefer to hire helpers with greater
unobserved ability, it seems plausible that they prefer to hire helpers
with greater observed ability as well. Evidence to the contrary would
then cast doubt on the matching hypothesis. Murphy and Topel [1990]
indeed find that industries which pay higher wages tend to employ
workers with more desirable observable characteristics. In the market
for domestic helpers, one observable characteristic that proves to be an
important indicator of labor quality is the duration of residence in
Hong Kong. The variables duration_0-9 and duration_10 (see Table I for
definition) are consistently found to have positive and significant
effects on the wage of domestic helpers. I therefore regress these two
quality variables on the wages of the employers. Table VIII displays the
results. Column (1) shows clearly that high-wage employers are more
likely to hire domestic helpers with more local experience. Similarly,
column (2) suggests that high-wage employers are mo re likely to be
matched with domestics who have ten or more years of residence in the
territory.
To obtain a more comprehensive measure of observable ability, I
estimate a wage regression on three sets of variables: the personal
characteristics of the domestic helper ([C.sub.1]), the characteristics
of her job ([C.sub.2]), and the wages (or reservation wages) of the male
and female heads of household ([C.sub.3]). I denote the corresponding
vector of estimated coefficients by [[hat{[alpha]}].sub.1],
[[hat{[alpha]}].sub.2] and [[hat{[alpha]}].sub.3]. Then the linear
combination [C.sub.1][[hat{[alpha]}].sub.1] can be considered as an
index of the domestic helper's observable ability. This index is
used as the dependent variable in the regression shown in column (3) of
Table VIII. The result again indicates that high-ability helpers are
more likely to be associated with high-wage employers.
VII. CONCLUSION
Although the market for resident domestic helpers is a relatively
special segment of the labor market, it provides a unique opportunity
for researchers to investigate rent sharing models of wage
determination. Because the employer of a resident domestic helper can
easily be identified in census records, direct measurement of employment
surplus can be obtained using information about the employer's wage
or reservation wage. This article shows that the employee's wage is
clearly positively related to such measures of employment rent.
The reason behind the observed relationship between rent and wages,
however, is less obvious. Monitoring and turnover models do not seem to
explain the observed relationship, as wages are found to be positively
related to rent even when monitoring costs or turnover costs are low.
The matching hypothesis, in contrast, is not rejected by the data. Among
newly arrived foreign domestic helpers, whose ability remains largely
unknown to employers, there is no evidence of rent sharing, as predicted
by the matching model. There is also some evidence that high-wage
employers tend to hire employees with higher observed ability. What
seems to be rent sharing in this market is therefore not inconsistent
with competitive wage determination when heterogeneity in unobserved
worker quality is taken into account.
Unlike most labor markets, the output of domestic helpers
(housework) are not sold to consumers. Instead, the employer consumes
the output herself. The scale of the "firm" in this market is
also much smaller than firms in other markets: Each employer typically
hires only one worker. It is hard to determine to what extent the
conclusions from the market for domestic helpers will carry over to
other labor markets. For example, the income effect on the demand for
worker quality is probably not a concern for profit-making firms.
However, Kremer's [1993] production complementarities model implies
that firms with high-quality inputs will also demand high-quality
workers, so matching is still an important consideration in these labor
markets away from the household. Every labor market has its own
idiosyncrasies. If rent sharing is supposed to be a general model of
wage determination, the evidence presented in this article cannot be
lightly dismissed.
Suen: Senior Lecturer, School of Economics and Finance, The
University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, Phone 852-2859-1052, Fax
852-2548-1152, E-mail hrneswc@hkusua.hku.hk
(*.) I am indebted to Doug Allen, Yoram Barzel, Steven Cheung,
Curtis Eaton, Alan Siu and Junsen Zhang for their comments. Mrs. Doris
Bote Chung, manager of a local employment agency, provided me with
valuable information about the market for domestic helpers.
(1.) The value of the Hong Kong dollar is pegged at the exchange
rate of one U.S. dollar to 7.8 Hong Kong dollars.
(2.) A notable exception is Rose [1987]. She uses the deregulation of the trucking industry as a natural experiment to study how a
reduction in industry rent affects labor earnings.
(3.) Examples of such proxies include per capita profitability
(Blanchflower, Oswald, and Sanfey [1996]), productivity growth (Bell and
Freeman [1991]), market power in the product market (Dickens and Katz
[1987]), and rate of technical innovation (Van Reenen [1996]).
(4.) Because of the way domestic helpers are identified in the
census records, domestics who worked part time or who did not live with
their employers are not included. According to a Census and Statistics
Department [1995] survey conducted in 1993, 85% of all domestics were
live-in helpers.
(5.) Another source of wage variation is differences in unmeasured
in-kind amenities. For live-in helpers, the most significant components
of such amenities are food and shelter. Because there are economies of
scale in the preparation of food and because there is a public good
aspect to shelter within the household, in-kind amenities are probably
better in more wealthy families than in less wealthy ones. Introducing
inkind benefits is therefore likely to reinforce any positive
relationship between employers' income and employees' pay.
(6.) The causation can also be reversed: working women are more
likely to hire domestics than nonworking women. See Suen [1994] for a
more detailed analysis.
(7.) Using the wife-servant wage difference as a measure of rent
abstracts from the direct utility or disutility from housework. To the
extent that the wife derives direct utility from housework (e.g.,
spending time with children), the wage difference overestimates the
surplus from hiring a helper. To the extent that the wife prefers
pursuing market work to performing household chores, the wage difference
underestimates the surplus from hiring a helper.
(8.) I have also estimated regression (3) in linear form instead of
double-log form. The coefficient of Y on W is 0.0047 (s.e. = 0.0008).
Thus a one standard deviation ($12,888) increase in the employer wage is
accompanied by a 0.12 standard deviation ($61) increase in the
maid's pay.
(9.) The previous section indicates that the distribution of
dependent variable has a spike at the legal minimum wage (for foreign
domestic helpers) of $2,800. To test the robustness of the results, I
recoded the wages of domestic helpers into three categories: below
minimum wage, at minimum wage, and above minimum wage. This recoded wage
variable is then used as the dependent variable in an ordered probit
model. The estimated coefficient on log Y remains positive and
statistically significant.
(10.) Since [u.sub.1] = [u.sub.2] - e, we have [[sigma].sub.1e] =
[[sigma].sub.2e] -[[[sigma].sup.2].sub.e] = 0.2788 X 0.6863 - 1 =
-0.8087.
(11.) Another variant of efficiency wage models is the Akerlof
[1982] gift exchange model. I fail to derive any testable implications
from that model.
(12.) It is reasonable to assume that women who stay at home will
spend more time doing housework than women who work. Domestic helpers
are then likely to have more household duties if the wife participates
in market work, and their job will command a positive compensating
differential. Compensating differences therefore cannot explain the
absence of a wage premium.
(13.) The evidence is also inconsistent with Klein, Crawford, and
Alchian's [1978] model of appropriable rent, which suggests that
families with young children may be held up by the resident domestic
helper.
(14.) There are many small employment agencies in Hong Kong
specializing in helping employers to find domestic helpers in Hong Kong.
Notice boards in local supermarkets are filled with advertisements by
domestic helpers trying to find new jobs.
(15.) In the sample of newly arrived helpers, the duration_0-9
variable is either 0 or 1 year. The negative coefficient on duration_0-9
in column (1) of Table VII shows that persons who had arrived in Hong
Kong for less than one year received higher wages than those who arrived
a year earlier. This is a clear indication of Taylor's [1980]
staggered wage setting effect, for employers in Hong Kong are required
to sign a two-year contract with newly arrived foreign domestic helpers.
(16.) In another regression I restrict the sample to households
where both the husband and the wife report positive earnings. The
results are essentially the same. The coefficient on log(wife_wage) is
0.015 and that on log(husband_wage) is 0.026.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, George A. "Labor Contracts as Partial Gift
Exchange." Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1982, 543-69.
_____, and Janet L. Yellen. "The Fair Wage-Effort Hypothesis
and Unemployment." Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1990,
255-83.
Bell, Linda A., and Richard B. Freeman. "The Causes of
Increasing Interindustry Wage Dispersion in the United States."
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, January 1991, 275-87.
Blanchflower, David G., Andrew J. Oswald, and Peter Sanfey.
"Wages, Profits, and Rent-Sharing." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, February 1996, 227-51.
Brown, Charles, and James Medoff. "The Employer Size Wage
Effect." Journal of Political Economy, October 1989, 1027-59.
Campbell, Carl M., III. "Do Firms Pay Efficiency Wages?
Evidence with Data at the Firm Level." Journal of Labor Economics,
July 1993, 442-70.
Census and Statistics Department. Social Data Collected by the
General Household Survey: Special Topics Report No. 11. Hong Kong:
Government Printer, 1995.
Dickens, William, and Lawrence Katz. "Inter-Industry Wage
Differences and Industry Characteristics," in Unemployment and the
Structure of Labor Markets, edited by K. Lang and J. Leonard. New York:
Basil Blackwell, 1987, 48-89.
Eaton, Curtis, and William D. White. "The Economy of High
Wages: An Agency Problem." Economica, May 1983, 175-81.
Groshen, Erica L. "Sources of Intra-Industry Wage Dispersion:
How Much Do Employers Matter?" Quarterly Journal of Economics,
August 1991, 869-910.
_____, and Alan B. Krueger. "The Structure of Supervision and
Pay in Hospitals." Industrial and Labor Relations Review, February
1990, S134-46.
Heckman, James J. "The Common Structure of Statistical Models
of Truncation, Sample Selection, and Limited Dependent Variables and a
Simple Estimator for Such Models." The Annals of Economic and
Social Measurement, 5, 1976, 475-92.
Helwege, Jean. "Sectoral Shifts and Interindustry Wage
Differentials." Journal of Labor Economics, January 1992, 55-84.
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian.
"Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive
Contracting Process." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1978,
297-326.
Kremer, Michael. "The O-Ring Theory of Economic
Development." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1993, 551-75.
Krueger, Alan, and Lawrence Summers. "Inter-Industry Wage
Differentials." Econometrica, March 1988, 259-93.
Lam, Kit Chun, and Pak Wai Liu. "Non-Working Parents and Labor
Force Participation of Married Women with Children." Working paper,
Hong Kong Baptist University, 1995.
McLaughlin, Kenneth J. "Rent Sharing in an Equilibrium Model
of Matching and Turnover." Journal of Labor Economics, October
1994, 499-523.
Murphy, Kevin M., and Robert H. Topel. "Estimation and
Inference in Two-Step Econometric Models." Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, October 1985, 370-79.
_____, "Efficiency Wages Reconsidered: Theory and
Evidence," in Advances in the Theory and Measurement of
Unemployment, edited by Y. Weiss and G. Fishelson. London: MacMillan,
1990, 204-40.
Nash, John F. "The Bargaining Problem." Econometrica,
April 1950, 155-62.
Rebitzer, James B., and Lowell J. Taylor. "Efficiency Wages
and Employment Rents: The Employer-Size Wage Effect in the Job Market
for Lawyers." Journal of Labor Economics, October 1995, 678-708.
Rose, Nancy L. "Labor Rent Sharing and Regulation: Evidence
from the Trucking Industry." Journal of Political Economy, December
1987, 1146-78.
Salop, Steven C. "A Model of the Natural Rate of
Unemployment." American Economic Review, March 1979, 117-25.
Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. "Equilibrium
Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device." American Economic
Review, June 1984, 433-44.
Suen, Wing. "Market-Procured Housework: The Demand for
Domestic Servants and Female Labor Supply." Labour Economics,
September 1994, 289-302.
Taylor, John B. "Aggregate Demand Dynamics and Staggered
Contracts." Journal of Political Economy, February 1980, 1-24.
Van Reenen, John. "The Creation and Capture of Rents: Wages
and Innovation in a Panel of U.K. Companies." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, February 1996, 195-226.