The U.S. productivity slowdown: a peak through the structural break window.
Dolmas, Jim ; Raj, Baldev ; Slottje, Daniel J. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Productivity (total and labor) plays a prominent role in theories
of economic growth, business cycles and labor demand. It is also widely
accepted that productivity growth, whatever its cause, is a key
determinant of the rate of increase in per capita output and living
standards. It is thus not surprising that the productivity slowdown in
the United States and elsewhere since the early 1970s continues to be a
significant source of concern to economists and policy makers. According
to one recent estimate, the slowdown has reduced current consumption by
nearly 30%.(1) The productivity slowdown experienced in the United
States during the post-war period is far from unique since many other
industrialized countries have experienced a similar slowdown. More
important, the severity of the productivity decline in the United States
appears to be mild in comparison to other countries. While these
observations are often made to emphasize that the problem faced by the
U.S. is far from unique or severe, the concerns about competitiveness
and the perceived decline in living standards in the United States have
generated a rather pronounced and persistent negative reaction from the
media as well as from some politicians. A possible explanation for the
pronounced reaction in the United States to the productivity decline may
largely be due to the persistent trade deficits being experienced by the
country. There is a perception that the productivity slowdown will have
an adverse long term effect on living standards.
Evidence based on growth accounting methods, to be reviewed later
on in the paper, supports the view that reduced productivity growth was
the primary factor for the slowdown of output growth in the U.S. and a
number of other countries. This evidence is particularly important in
that it absolves slower growth of inputs such as capital or labor as
contributing factors of a slowdown in output growth. However, it
introduces a puzzle as to what caused a slowdown in productivity since
about 1973. While the causes and consequences of the productivity
slowdown in the United States have been extensively analyzed, the
slowdown continues to remain somewhat of a puzzle. Specifically, a wide
variety of explanations have been offered for the productivity slowdown,
with little consensus as to a clear-cut culprit. Moreover, the
productivity slowdown appears to be at odds with a number of recent
models of economic growth. We will have more to say about these issues
later on in the paper. For the time being it suffices to say that most
studies appear to informally support the view that a productivity
slowdown did take place during the 1970s. The argument is so pervasive
that the slowdown is often accepted as a stylized fact.
This paper has two objectives. The first objective is to present
empirical evidence based on post-War annual data from 1947-1992 in
support of the premise that the time series of the logarithmic level of
the labor productivity variable in the United States (hereafter labor
productivity) is not a difference-stationary process. Pretesting for
unit roots in productivity in order to assess its long-run features is
important due to the importance which the presence of a unit root can
have for economic forecasting, macroeconomic modeling using the
cointegration framework, and tests of Granger causality. We will present
formal tests evidence that both supports and refutes the claim that the
log-level labor productivity is a first-difference stationary process.
The support for the null hypothesis of a unit root process in the labor
productivity variable - against the alternative hypothesis of a linear
trend stationary process - is found when the familiar Dickey-Fuller test is applied. However, a valid use of the conventional Dickey-Fuller test
requires assumptions that the regression utilized for the test is
correctly specified, which may not hold if the premise of a productivity
slowdown is accepted. Moreover, the failure to allow a role for the
productivity slowdown can introduce an uncertainty of a unit root in the
first-difference of the labor productivity variable, especially if the
productivity slowdown had a growth rate effect on the variable.
The uncertain unit root in the labor productivity growth series
view, if true, has important implications for linear regression analysis
involving the labor productivity growth variable. Regressions involving
this variable have often been the focus of a number of recent
econometric studies. Such studies either evaluate competing theories of
business cycles (e.g., see Bernanke and Parkinson [1991]) or evaluate
the reasons for the productivity slowdown (see Shapiro [1987]). A
potential pitfall with such studies is that an uncritical use of
regression analysis may involve the problem of "near-inconsistent
regressions" according to the terminology of Mankiw and Shapiro
[1985]. In other words, regressors and dependent variables are likely to
be of different orders of integration, leading to inconsistent estimates
(see Granger and Newbold [1974] and Phillips [1986]). The significance
of the above problem follows directly from the results of analysis
corresponding to the "spurious regression" problem since the
near-inconsistent regression can be regarded as a special type of
spurious regression.
The second objective of this paper is to empirically evaluate
whether post-war annual data for the logarithm level of labor
productivity can be more accurately characterized as a trend stationary
process with a one-time shift in both the level and slope in a
deterministic trend as opposed to a unit root process. To that end, we
present some formal statistical evidence in support of the hypothesis
that the log-level of productivity is a trend stationary process with a
change in level and slope of the linear trend in the early seventies.
Since the timing of the break cannot be interpreted as independent of
the data, nor is it easy, as we argue below, to associate the structural
break to a particular event, we follow the recent literature on unit
root testing, which extends the important contribution of Perron [1989]
in treating the break point as an unknown parameter to be estimated from
the data. This treatment is designed to avoid biasing the results in
favor of the structural shift hypothesis ex post (see Banerjee,
Lumsdaine, and Stock [1992]; Christiano [1992]; Zivot and Andrews
[1992]; Perron [1997]). The conclusion of stationarity about a broken
trend has important implications for detrending the series and for
modeling comovements of productivity with related variables.
Recent empirical evidence on structural breaks includes Ben-David
and Papell [1995], who examine very long time series data for several
countries and identify trend breaks in countries' levels of real
GDP in the period spanning the two World Wars and the Great Depression.
Another related paper by Bai, Lumsdaine and Stock [1991] focuses on
obtaining relatively more efficient estimates of the year of break. In
our analysis, the relative efficiency of the estimate of the break point
is secondary to the main issues addressed.
One of the implications of our result is that only a large shock
occurring around 1973 had a permanent effect on labor productivity,
while all other shocks had transitory effects. This result contrasts
with the view, widely held since the study by Nelson and Plosser [1982],
wherein most shocks have permanent effects on macroeconomic time series.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section II we
present some background on the productivity slowdown, briefly reviewing
some stylized facts, suggested causes and relation to theory. In section
III, after introducing the definition and source of data, we present
empirical results from the tests of the hypotheses of stationarity and
unit root for the labor productivity growth series. We discuss the
motivation for testing the null hypothesis of a unit root in the
log-level of labor productivity against the alternative of trend
stationarity when the deterministic trend is subjected to a one-time
crash-cum-growth change at an unknown point in time, as well as the test
methodology, in section IV. In section V we present the empirical
results for this test, both for the entire sample as well as for some
sub-samples. The results for the subsamples help to provide evidence of
robustness of the results from the full sample to excluding other
possible large shocks. We offer some conclusions in section VI.
II. SOME BACKGROUND: STYLIZED FACTS, EXPLANATIONS, AND THEORY
The issue of whether business-sector output and labor productivity
experienced a slowdown in the United States, and virtually all
industrialized countries has been the subject of considerable debate and
analysis. The investigation of causes of this slowdown and its
consequences for economic policy has generated a considerable amount of
literature (see Williamson [1991]). Some of the issues related to this
paper were reviewed and summarized by two recent symposiums, one
symposium organized by the Journal of Economic Perspectives (see Fischer
[1988]) and the second sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City (see Shigehara [1992]).
The use of growth accounting methods for annual data from 1960-1990
for the United States and a number of OECD countries has produced a
number of stylized facts. One stylized fact is that sources of growth in
the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in the United States and several other
OECD countries have changed over time. A second stylized fact is the
productivity slowdown occurred in the United States in early seventies.
Also, the slowdown in the rate of growth of GDP is due largely to the
slowdown in productivity. Lastly, the slowdown in productivity was not
unique to the United States but shared by several OECD countries.(2)
The existence of a productivity slowdown raises several important
questions. What caused the widespread slowdown in productivity? Is
productivity a trend stationary or a difference stationary process? The
latter question is related to the issue of whether shocks to
productivity have permanent or transitory effects, an issue of some
importance both in econometric modeling involving the labor productivity
series and in some areas of economic theory. Whether shocks to
productivity have permanent or transitory consequences has
ramifications, for example, for the construction and calibration of
models of business cycles in which exogenous shocks to technology serve
as a source of fluctuations.
As to the question of cause, there have been many candidate
explanations proposed for the observed slowdown in productivity growth
in the United States. The international scope of the slowdown as well as
its apparent coincidence with the first oil price shock of 1973 led
early observers to look for the source of the slowdown in the higher
price of oil, though the past decade of cheap oil has not been
accompanied by a return to pre-1973 rates of productivity growth (see,
for example, Hulten, Robertson and Wycoff [1987], and Jorgenson [1988]).
Among the other suspects which have been investigated are: measurement
problems (Baily and Gordon [1982], or Darby [1992]); changes in the
legal environment, such as environmental legislation and worker health
and safety regulations (Denison [1982]); changes in the growth rate of
the labor force or its quality (Bishop [1989]); a slower rate of
innovation or a failure to translate innovation into
productivity-enhancing technologies (Nordhaus [1982] and Griliches
[1994]); a slower adaptation to high-tech production methods resulting
from the information technology revolution (David [1990] and Greenwood
and Yorukoglu [1997]).
Most of these investigations have been conducted outside the
context of explicit models of economic growth, whether of the
neoclassical variety or models of the "new growth theory." In
fact, many of the proposed explanations pre-date the new growth theory,
which began with the contributions of Romer [1986] and Lucas [1988]. By
the same token, though, few models in the new theory have attempted to
tackle the productivity slowdown.(3)
It is important to point out that the productivity slowdown is not
necessarily incongruent with the neoclassical growth theory, which takes
the path of technological change as exogenously given. Still, the fact
that the neoclassical model does not explain technological change does
not mean that we cannot have presumptions about what are plausible or
implausible paths for it to take. For example, in a reasonably
parametrized Solow model, a near-total cessation of exogenous
technological progress is needed in order to reduce the average growth
rate of labor productivity from an initial steady state growth rate of
2.2% down to .4% over the subsequent 17 years - i.e., in order to
replicate the U.S. experience for the two periods 1960-1973 and
1973-1990. This is due to the model's transitional dynamics -
because the economy adjusts gradually to the new steady state, if labor
productivity is to average .4% per year over a short transitional
period, the new growth rate of technological progress must be much less
than .4% per year. Few observers of the U.S. economy would conclude that
technological progress stopped sometime in the mid-1970s.
Also, as Griliches [1988] has noted, the fact that the slowdown is
less pronounced in manufacturing - where one would imagine that
technological progress plays a more important role - makes it difficult
to accept explanations based on hitting the limits of technological
advance.
Barring extreme changes in the growth rate of exogenous
technological progress, there is not much scope for even fairly
complicated variants of the neoclassical model to rationalize the
productivity data. This is because growth rates in the neoclassical
model are largely robust to exogenous interventions. There are many
conceivable changes in economic conditions which will yield level
effects, but not growth rate effects, except in transition. If
transitional dynamics are rich enough, one can get fairly persistent
changes in growth rates along transitions between steady states, but
most computational evidence suggests the transitional dynamics in the
neoclassical model are fairly weak. There is a trade-off here, too, in
that for a given change in conditions which creates a level effect, the
magnitude of the resulting transitional changes in growth rates is
inversely related to the persistence of the transitional period.(4)
More disconcerting for the neoclassical model is the negative
correlation between labor force growth and productivity growth when one
looks at 10 to 20 year averages - sufficient time, one would suspect, to
imagine that we are viewing at the least close approximations to steady
states.(5) According to almost any version of the neoclassical model,
productivity growth and labor force growth should be uncorrelated at
that low a frequency. As Romer [1987] notes, even allowing for the
possibility that we are not observing steady states, the response of the
growth rate of labor productivity to a change in the growth rate of the
labor force should still be small, if the elasticity of output with
respect to the labor input is taken to be on the order of 2/3, the
standard figure based on labor's share of national income. Romer
offers some suggestions - based on a model where labor force size
affects the incentives to invest in knowledge which substitutes for,
rather than complements labor - as to why the elasticity of output with
respect to labor may be quite a bit smaller than labor's share of
national income. This suggests a possible explanation for the
productivity slowdown as a consequence of an exogenous change in the
growth rate of the labor force.
While the scope for changes in economic conditions to have growth
rate effects is wider in 'endogenous growth' models, the
productivity slowdown must still be viewed as something of a stumbling
block for a number of them, particularly the R&D-based
"endogenous technological change" models a la Romer [1990] and
Aghion and Howitt [1992]. As is now well-known, these models contain
'scale effects' - ceteris paribus, increases in the level of
resources devoted to R&D imply increases in growth rates. Given the
continual increase in the amount of resources devoted to R&D
activities in the U.S. throughout the post-World War II period, these
models actually predict increasing rates of growth, other factors equal
of course. If we assume that these models are even approximate
descriptions of reality, then the magnitude of the offsetting changes in
"other factors," which are not held equal in the data, must be
quite large.
A recent exception in the endogenous technological change
literature is the R&D-based model of Jones [1995], which is
potentially consistent with the productivity data. In Jones's
model, a permanent increase in R&D's share of output triggers a
transitional path with an initially increasing, then declining rate of
growth of labor productivity. Eventually, the growth rate of labor
productivity falls back to its initial level. The immediate postwar
period did coincide with a rough doubling in the measured share of
R&D expenditures in U.S. output.(6) According to this
interpretation, the decline in the rate of labor productivity growth
from the high levels experienced in the first two decades of the
post-war period can be understood as transitional dynamics rather than
the result of a break in the process generating the productivity
data.(7)
A second strand of endogenous growth models are the so-called
"broad capital" models, which follow Lucas [1988] and
Romer's original [1986] paper in achieving endogenous growth by
broadening the definition of capital, typically by adding "human
capital" as a reproducible factor of production, and arguing that
diminishing returns do not set in for the resulting broader concept of
capital.8 Here too, the models in principle have a good deal of room for
changes in conditions to generate sizable changes in growth rates. The
bulk of the comparative dynamics exercises performed thus far for models
of this sort have focused on the growth effects of fiscal policies,
particularly factor income taxes, and inflation.9 If the models ascribed
large growth consequences to inflation, for example, we would have at
least one potential explanation for the slowdown within this class of
models. Another mig[h.sub.t] lie in the models' responses to factor
income taxes, which can sometimes be viewed more broadly as proxies for
aspects of the legal or regulatory environment which weaken property
rights.
The latitude for growth rate effects in these models, however, does
not always translate into substantial effects of changes in either taxes
or inflation when the models are given particular parametrizations. For
example, if, to be consistent with the U.S. growth experience, models of
this class are parametrized to be robust to a large intervention like
the permanent and sizable increase in income taxes which occurred in the
1940s, it is difficult to imagine a single, isolated change in tax rates
or the legal environment in the 1970s which could lead to changes in
growth rates of the magnitude actually observed.(10) Likewise, Dotsey
and Ireland [1996], using a variant of Romer's [1986] model, find
only modest growth rate effects of inflation.
One conclusion which we might draw from this discussion is that
while for many models of economic growth few exogenous changes in
conditions, taken in isolation, seem capable of generating a
quantitatively significant decline in productivity growth. It is
possible that the confluence of several such changes - agglomerated into
a 'shock' on a large scale could have a significant
quantitative effect. Moreover, for some of the models - he 'scale
effect' R&D models - rationalizing the productivity slowdown
most likely demands a very large shock with effects at some deep level.
As Griliches [1988] states in reviewing some of the evidence for
competing explanations, "Of course, there may not be a single cause
- one murderer. Perhaps it is more like the Murder on the Orient Express - they all did it!" The idea of a confluence of more than one event
is in line with our empirical methodology, which considers a large shock
at an a priori unknown date; if we knew at the outset on the basis of
theory that the oil price shock of 1973 was the only possible candidate
shock, then we would certainly know its timing. The possibility that the
slowdown had multiple causes thus buttresses the econometric case -
based on the known biases in hypothesis tests of a unit root against a
broken trend with an exogenously specified break date - in favor of
estimating the timing of the shock from the data.
Our perspective, then, is this: we view the oil price shock of 1973
as but one dimension of a large composite shock to productivity - where
the other dimensions might involve changes in the legal or regulatory
environment, changes in the growth rate of the labor force, inflation,
and so forth. We follow recent literature in treating the occurrence
date of this shock as an unknown parameter to be estimated from the data
instead of exogenously selected after the data has been observed or
referring to past studies. One of our objectives as stated in the
introduction is to analyze the time series properties of productivity
when the occurrence of this shock is treated as an episodic event. In
summary, we treat two types of shocks to productivity - a large, rare
shock and other regular shocks - from two different distribution
functions. We provide some formal evidence in support of the premise
that the trend in the log-level of productivity is linear except for a
sudden change in its level and slope around 1973. In addition, it is
argued that once the break in the trend function is allowed and the
"demeaned" growth in productivity is obtained for calculating
a measure of persistence as suggested by Cochrane [1988], it is easily
shown that the effects of all shocks except for the large shock are
largely transitory (see Perron [1993] for some related evidence).
III. THE DATA ON LABOR PRODUCTIVITY AND THE UNCERTAIN UNIT ROOT
HYPOTHESIS
The annual time series data from 1947-1992 used in this study were
obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and are reported in the
Economic Report of the President. Labor productivity is defined as
output per hour of all persons in the non-farm business sector (this
sector includes everything except government operations, non-profit
organizations and agriculture). Growth in productivity, from a growth
accounting standpoint, depends upon growth of the capital-labor ratio
and growth in total factor productivity. We do not consider total-factor
(or multi-factor) productivity (TFP) - where trends have generally moved
in line with labor productivity in the United States - in this paper,
since its measurement is more controversial. Moreover, while the use of
the TFP measure is often preferred at the conceptual level by
economists, its use is less popular in policy circles. Moreover, data on
TFP are sometimes not available at all, and even when the data are
available, a long time series is not available and they are slow to be
updated.
The time plot of logarithmic level of labor productivity,
[y.sub.t], is given in Figure 1. The plot shows that the productivity
variable has considerable persistence. Moreover, the persistence is
inadequately represented by the canonical empirical representation for
the variable as a linear deterministic trend. This is evidenced from the
behavior of the first eight sample autocorrelations of the residuals
from a regression of the log-level of labor productivity variable on a
linear trend, which are: 0.89, 0.77, 0.64, 0.55, 0.48, 0.40, 0.33 and
0.25. These sample autocorrelations decay very slowly, suggesting that
labor productivity in the United States is more likely characterized as
a unit root process instead of a linear trend stationary process.
This conjecture is confirmed when the familiar Dickey-Fuller test
of the null of a unit root against the alternative of trend stationarity
is performed. The use of this test yields a test statistic value of
[[Tau].sub.[Tau]] = -0.886 for the truncation lag value of k equal to
six, which is smaller than the critical value for the asymptotic
distribution of the test statistic of -3.53. In performing this test,
the value of the truncation lag was determined using the data-dependent
method called the 't-sig' by Ng and Perron [1995]. This
data-dependent method for selecting the lag length k has been shown to
lead to the unit root test statistic having stable size and good power
as compared to other data-based selection methods based on the
information criterion such as the AIC (Hall, 1994). The
't-sig' procedure for the selection of k follows a
general-to-specific recursive method, starting with a regression
including lags up to some maximum - order say, k = 8 - and eliminating
lags until the t-statistic on the last lag is significant at some level
and all greater (up to the maximum order) are insignificant.
Significance of the last lags is determined from a two-sided 10% test
based on the asymptotic normal distribution.
It is important to note that a failure to reject the null
hypothesis of a unit root result is not sensitive to the method of lag
order selection of just used. Both the Schwartz (SC) and Aikake (AIC)
information criteria for selecting the lag length are minimized at zero
lags, in which case the value of the test statistic is [[Tau].sub.[Tau]]
= -1.40. In fact, the sample values of [[Tau].sub.[Tau]] are well within
the 5% acceptance region for all truncation lag lengths from zero to
eight.
This result is hardly surprising given that many macroeconomic time
series have been known to have this characteristic, as shown by Nelson
and Plosser [1982], using Dickey-Fuller-type tests. If the result that
the labor productivity variable is difference stationary is true, then
it would imply that all shocks to productivity have a permanent effect.
Furthermore, it would suggest that fluctuations in the first-difference
of labor productivity are stationary around a constant mean.
The evidence presented above is, however, in conflict with other
empirical evidence showing that productivity in the United States
experienced a structural break during the early seventies. Failure to
model the influence of a productivity slowdown may have biased the test
results in favor of a unit root hypothesis, if we use arguments similar
to those in Perron [1989]. Below we present two kinds of formal test
evidence to show that productivity in the United States has an uncertain
unit root.
One kind of evidence utilizes the test framework proposed by Dickey
and Pantula [1987], who have emphasized the need to ensure that the
variable does not have a second unit root before accepting the test
evidence of a unit root. Their advice requires first testing the null of
a unit root in the first-difference of the labor productivity variable.
The test of the null hypothesis of a unit root in the first-difference
against the alternative of trend stationarity with an intercept, using
an augmented Dickey-Fuller test, rejects the null hypothesis.
Specifically, the sample value of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is
obtained for the first-difference productivity variable, which is less
than the critical value of -2.93 for the asymptotic distribution at a
0.05 significance level for a truncation lag of k = 0. Once again we
have used the 't-sig' sample-based method for selecting the
truncation lag; the null is also rejected if k is selected using the AIC
(k = 2) or SC (k = 0).
However, an opposite conclusion is obtained when the test framework
developed by Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin [1992] is used.
These authors recommend testing the null of level stationarity against
the alternative of a unit root for the variable. The use of Kwiatkowski
[1992] et al.'s testing framework produced a value for the test
statistic of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] corresponding to
truncation lag-length of k = 0, analogous to the choice of lag for the
Dickey- Fuller test. The use of this test rejects the null of trend
stationarity at the 0.05 significance level since the sample value of
the test statistic exceeds the asymptotic critical value of this test
statistic of 0.463 as tabulated by Kwiatkowski [1992] et al. This
conclusion is robust to any choice of lag length up to a maximum of k =
8.
Thus, the use of two different testing frameworks yields opposite
conclusions about the time series properties of the first-difference of
labor productivity, casting doubt about the validity of the unit root
test result in labor productivity. One interpretation of the conflicting
test results is that the labor productivity variable has an uncertain
unit root. Another interpretation of the apparent conflict in test
results from two different methods is that the underlying data
generation process for the alternative hypothesis used for testing the
null of a unit root in labor productivity is inappropriate or
misspecified. The misspecification of the underlying data generation
process for the first-difference variable (that is productivity growth)
is evidenced from the plot of recursive residuals given in Figure 2 for
the regression of the variable ([y.sub.t] - [y.sub.t-1]) on an intercept
and its lagged value ([y.sub.t-1] - [y.sub.t-2]); the residuals are
shown along with a two standard error band. This model has adequate
model diagnostics with the exception of a failure to pass the
one-step-ahead predictive test criterion. This is evidenced from the
plot in Figure 2, which shows two points lying outside the two standard
error band in the sense that the t-statistic is numerically greater than
two in the absolute sense. The evidence in Figure 2 indicates that the
model for the first-difference of labor productivity conditional on the
variable being trend stationary is misspecified based on the criterion
of one- period-ahead prediction errors. The prediction failure of the
trend stationary first-difference of labor productivity, we conjecture
is due to the failure to model the role of the productivity slowdown
episode.
In the following section, we will briefly outline the testing
framework used for testing the null of a unit root in labor productivity
against the alternative of the variable being trend stationary with one
possible break point in its intercept and in its slope. The use of this
test framework is motivated by the historical evidence on the
productivity slowdown hypothesis presented in Section II as well as the
evidence presented above.
IV. UNIT ROOT, TREND AND STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN THE LABOR
PRODUCTIVITY: METHODOLOGY
It can be argued that the lack of support for the null hypothesis
that labor productivity is a difference-stationary process presented in
the previous section could be the direct result of inappropriate use of
the alternative hypothesis for the test. The relevant alternative should
be a linear trend with a change in the level and slope at an unknown
point in time rather than a linear trend stationarity. This view is
consistent with the nature of the trend in the series, which has one
sudden decrease in its level as well as a sudden change in slope around
the time of the first oil price shock. The series also exhibits other
changes in pattern around the time of the Korean War and the second oil
price shock but the magnitude of these changes is small compared to the
change described earlier. This observation supports the use of a linear
trend with a onetime change in the trend function,(11) Another feature
of interest is that the transition path to the new trend function
following the change in the level around the first oil price shock is
gradual rather than sudden. This suggests that the "innovation
outlier" framework might be more appropriate (for more details see
Perron [1997]).
After inspecting the plot of the series, it would be tempting to
choose the timing of the break to be a year such as 1973. However, the
exogenous choice of the break year would be inappropriate given that
this date has to be viewed as correlated with the data. In an ex post
sense - that is, after inspecting the data and its plot - we might be
able to postulate that other exogenous events are unlikely to have had a
major impact on productivity growth. However, this premise would not be
plausible ex ante. In addition, as we have argued above in discussing
the possible explanations of the slowdown, it would be difficult to
assign to 1973 a particular event which caused the slowdown. In view of
this we follow the recent literature for using the methodology where the
year of the break is estimated from the data. This is done by treating
the year of the break as an unknown parameter of the model, using the
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] method for this purpose as suggested
by Perron [1997]. This method is a slight variation of the Zivot and
Andrews [1992] method. For recent applications in different contexts see
Raj [1992] and Raj and Slottje [1994]. Finally, the choice of the date
of the break is an important problem in the testing for the unit root
since both finite sample and asymptotic distributions of the test
statistic depend upon the extent of correlation between the break year
and the data.
Modeling the one-time structural break requires a choice among a
number of alternative models of the nature of the break. A number of
models have been suggested in the literature. These include the
"crash," the "growth change" and the "crash-cum
growth change" models. In what follows we use the crash-cum growth
change model, which encompasses the other models. This choice is
consistent with the plot of the variable. It is true that the use of a
more restricted model can be advantageous in some instances since it
avoids the use of irrelevant regressors; however, the use of the
constrained model could also imply substantial loss of power of the
test, and could even make the testing framework inconsistent. We also
need to make a choice between the "additive outlier" and the
"innovation outlier" framework for performing the test
described above. This choice is concerned with how the transition to the
new growth path occurs. In the former framework the change to the new
trend occurs instantaneously while in the latter case the change to the
new trend occurs gradually. The latter framework is more appealing and
plausible as argued before, and will be used in the testing framework.
The formulation of the model under the null hypothesis of the unit
root is:
(1) [y.sub.t] = b + [y.sub.t-1] + [Psi](L)([e.sub.t] +
[Delta]D[([T.sub.b]).sub.t] + [Mu][DU.sub.t]),
where D[U.sub.t] = 1 if t [greater than] [T.sub.b] and 0 otherwise,
and D[([T.sub.b]).sub.t] = 1 if t = [T.sub.b] + 1 and 0 otherwise. The
lag polynomial [Psi](L) is possibly of infinite order with [Psi](0) = 1.
This model specifies the first-difference of the variable as a moving
average process. Accordingly, if [z.sub.t] is the noise function of the
series, then [z.sub.t] = A[(L).sup.-1] B(L)[e.sub.t] = [Psi](L)[e.sub.t]
where the finite-order polynomials A(L) and B(L) are assumed to have
roots outside the unit circle, and [e.sub.t] is assumed to be i.i.d. (0,
[[Sigma].sup.2]). In this framework the immediate effect of the change
in the intercept is [Delta] while the long-run impact is given by
[Psi](1)[Delta]. In the same vein, the immediate impact of the change in
the slope is [Mu] while the long run impact is given by [Psi](1)[Mu].
The underlying data generation process under the alternative
hypothesis is:
(2) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
where [Phi](L) = [(1-[Alpha]L).sup.-1] A[(L).sup.-1] B(L), with
A(L) and B(L) defined as before, and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
if t [greater than] [T.sub.b] and 0 otherwise. Here the immediate impact
of the shock on the intercept under the alternative hypothesis is given
by the parameter [Theta], while the long-run impact is measured by
[Phi](1)[Theta]. Similarly, the immediate impact of the change in a
slope is [Gamma], while the long-run impact is [Phi](1)[Gamma].
The null and the alternative hypothesis can be nested in the
following model:
(3) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where the [c.sub.i]'s are the coefficients corresponding to
the autoregressive representation of the moving average polynomial.
Moreover, the polynomial is of infinite order whenever the moving
average components are present. In order to implement this test the
infinite lag [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] order must be
approximated with a finite number of lags. The empirical implementation
of the test requires making choices for the truncation lag length
(represented by the parameter k) to approximate the infinite sum and the
year of the break, [T.sub.b]. There are many methods for choosing the
break points (e.g. Banerjee, Lumsdaine and Stock [1992]; Zivot and
Andrews [1992] and Christiano [1992]). One popular method of choosing
the break year minimizes the t-statistic for testing the hypothesis that
[Alpha] = 1. This method requires that the investigator estimate all
possible values of the break date [T.sub.b], with trimming - that is,
for the range of values (0.15T, 0.85T), where T is the sample size
(Zivot and Andrews [1992]).
The methods of selecting the lag parameter k are also many (for an
overview, see Perron [1997]). One popular data-dependent method of
selecting k is the 't-sig' method. This method selects the
value of k, say [k.sup.*], such that the last lag in an autoregression
of order [k.sup.*] is significant and the last coefficient of order
greater than [k.sup.*] is insignificant.(12)
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND THEIR INTERPRETATIONS
The empirical results from using the testing methodology briefly
outlined in the previous section are given in Table I. In column 1 the
sample period is given. The main points of interest are the results from
the entire sample. The sub-sample results are also useful in the sense
that they provide an assessment of the robustness of the main results of
the test procedure to excluding the influence of other potential
"large" shocks to the variable. These other large shocks are
those corresponding to either the Korean War or the second oil price
shock or both of these shocks. To anticipate one of the conclusions of
the robustness analysis, it is found that the null hypothesis of a unit
root is rejected in favor of the alternative of a segmented trend for
the entire sample as well as for all sub-samples. Moreover, the estimate
of the break year is fairly robust to the choice of the sample period
except where the sample size is smallest.
The estimates of the lag length and the break year are presented in
columns 2 and 3, respectively. The estimates of other key parameters of
the model (3) along with the t-statistics are given in columns 4 to 6.
Specifically, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the estimate of the
pre-break slope coefficient, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the
estimate of the change in the intercept and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] is the estimate the change in the slope of the trend function.
The parameters relating to the test of the unit root hypothesis are
given in columns 7 and 8. For example, [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
is the estimate of coefficient [Alpha], while the t-statistic for the
null hypothesis that [Alpha] = 1 is [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The last column gives the p-values for the test based on the asymptotic
distribution of the test statistic given in Zivot and Andrews [1992].
The outcome of the test statistic can be described as follows. The
unit root, or [Alpha] = 1 is rejected against the alternative of trend
stationarity with a one-time change at an endogenous point in time for
the full sample period, 1947-1992. This conclusion is robust to
excluding the other potential shocks, which may also have had similar
large effects ex ante. Specifically, the sample period 19471978 excludes
the second oil price shock, the sample period 1950-1992 excludes the
Korean War shock, and the sample period 19501978 excludes both shocks.
The estimate or selection of the break year [T.sub.b] yields the year
1973 of the break for the entire sample and the sub-sample excluding
only the Korean War (1950-1992). The break year estimate is 1972 for the
other two sub-samples, 1947-1978 and 1950-1978. The estimate of the
break year turns out to be around the year of the first oil price shock,
although other events closer to this event may have also contributed to
the break.
In the autoregressive model (3) the t-statistics of the level,
change in level, trend, and change in trend are asymptotically normally
distributed since the unit root is rejected for the variable. The change
in the level and slope of the trend in labor productivity are both
highly significant at the 5% significance level. The evidence supports
the premise that a productivity slowdown did take place in the United
States during the post-War II period. In summary, it is likely that
events of the early 1970s, including the many-fold rise in price of oil
and other structural changes, have had a permanent effect on the long
term behavior of the productivity series.
The evidence presented above should not be taken as saying that the
trend function in productivity is deterministic, but rather something
quite different. The notion of the onetime break in the deterministic
trend function implies that the coefficients of the trend function are
determined by factors which do change, albeit only infrequently -
factors which might include aspects of technology, the inflation
environment and other aspects of macroeconomic policy, institutional and
legal arrangements for organizing economic activity, population growth
rates and perhaps even tastes, customs or norms. In contrast the
innovations or smaller shocks which affect the stationary or cyclical
components of the series are frequent. The one-time structural break in
the deterministic trend framework is essentially a convenient or
parsimonious way for removing the influence of the infrequent large
shock from the noise function and placing it in the deterministic
function without a specific model for the stochastic behavior of the
relevant parameters such as the intercept and the slope.
The support for the framework of a onetime change in the
deterministic trend has implications for detrending the series.(13) The
use of the innovation outlier framework, which translates into a
nonlinear trend function showing that a gradual adjustment to the new
growth path takes place, is a little more cumbersome in comparison with
the additive outlier model. In the latter case the trend function is
segmented and it is more straightforward to compute. The precise method
of calculating the nonlinear trend is explained by Perron [1994], which
we have used here. It involves first estimating the following model:
(4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where the least-squares estimates [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
are used to obtain estimates of ([Mu], [Beta], [Phi]) in (2). The lag
length p is chosen endogenously in the same procedure that selected the
break point [T.sub.b]. The estimates of the parameters [Mu], [Beta],
[Phi] are then obtained as follows:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
is the mean lag and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted];
and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
These relations correspond to approximating the general ARMA
process for the noise component by a finite sample approximation. The
final step is to compute the trend function:
(5) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
In Figure 3, we have plotted this trend function along with the
original values of the log of the labor productivity variable. As is
evident from the graph, the general pattern of the trend function fits
the general pattern of the data. Besides the informal investigation of
the possible stationarity of the noise component or the cyclical
component - the difference between the actual and trend values plotted
in Figure 3 - one might calculate the sample autocorrelation function of
the detrended series. These sample autocorrelations (not shown) show
rapid decay. In contrast, the sample autocorrelations of the residuals
from a least-squares regression of the series on a constant and linear
time trend show slow decay. This latter pattern of autocorrelations for
linearly detrended productivity parallels those found by Nelson and
Plosser [1982] for most macroeconomic series.
The results of this paper also have implications for multivariate
time series analysis involving the productivity variable with other
co-moving variables. In particular, models of multivariate dynamics
involving labor productivity and other variables in cointegrating or
common-trend relations might more accurately depict equilibrium
relationships by allowing for a regime shift than by not allowing for
such a break. Such analysis is not pursued here since it is beyond the
scope of this paper.
VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The view that labor productivity growth can be characterized as
having a stochastic trend rather than a deterministic trend is
prevalent. This view is in agreement with the seminal result of Nelson
and Plosser [1982] who found that most macroeconomic variables have a
univariate time series structure with a unit root. This view is also
embodied in many applications of the neoclassical growth model, in
particular applications to business cycle theory (see, for example, King
et al. [1991]). However, the observed evolution of productivity taken
from a long-run perspective of a century or longer indicates a linear
trend in productivity, subjected to an occasional episodic shock which
can alter both the intercept and slope of the trend function. We
followed some recent trends in time series research and modeled the
timing of this shock as a parameter to be estimated from the data. Our
empirical results indicate that such a change in the slope and intercept
of the trend function in U.S. labor productivity occurred sometime
around 1973. It is easy to show, following calculations similar to those
by Perron [1993], who used a measure due to Cochrane [1988] of the
persistence of shocks, that all regular shocks other than the episodic
shock of 1973 have a small permanent effect.
This result has several macroeconomic implications. First, our
result can be viewed as a formal statistical justification for
detrending the labor productivity variable with a break in the linear
trend in 1973. Moreover, our result supports an alternative position
between the two extremes that all shocks to productivity have a
permanent effect or that all shocks have a transitory effect. We show
that occasional major events such as those of the early 1970s can have a
permanent effect, though such events are quite rare. Most shocks to
productivity have only a transitory effect. This, in turn, would seem to
have implications for the construction of those business cycle models in
which fluctuations are driven at least in part by exogenous changes in
technology. Such models are typically calibrated or their parameters
estimated using the generalized method of moments (GMM) under the
assumption that the logarithm of the technology variable follows either
a linear trend with stationary disturbances or a random walk with
positive drift. Both calibration and estimation exercises are performed
assuming that postwar U.S. data are generated by one of the two types of
process.
Our result also has important implications for econometric modeling
involving the productivity variable. Failure to model the influence of
the large shock can produce misleading or biased results or even lead to
spurious regressions. Misspecification due to failure to adequately
model structural break in the deterministic trend component may bias the
results in favor of the lack of equilibrium or cointegrating
relationships between productivity and variables related to it, even if
such relationships existed. Finally, our results suggest that
extrapolating a deterministic trend for the purpose of long-horizon
forecasting can yield inaccurate results since it is based on the
assumption that no major break in the trend would occur.
ABBREVIATIONS
AIC: Aikake Information Criterion
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GMM: Generalized method of moments
SC: Schwartz Criterion
TFP: Total Factor Productivity
WLU: Wilfrid Laurier University
Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the Canadian
Economics Association Meetings, Montreal, Canada, June 1995, the
Australasian Meeting of the Econometric Society, Perth, Australia, July
1996, and the Camp Econometrics Texas, Port Aransas, Texas, USA,
February 15-16, 1997. The paper was also presented at the faculty
seminars of the Institute of Advanced Studies, Vienna, Austria, McMaster
University and University of Windsor, Canada during 1995, and National
Council of Applied Research, New Delhi, India, December 26, 1996. We
gratefully acknowledge that financial support for this research was
received from grants partly funded by Wilfrid Laurier University (WLU)
Operating funds, and partly by the SSHRC General Research Grant awarded
to WLU. We also acknowledge helpful discussions with Pierre Perron. We
have also benefited from comments of the participants at the conferences
and faculty seminars, and two referees of this journal. The usual
disclaimer for the remaining errors or misinterpretations applies.
1. See De Long and Summers [1992].
2. See, for example, Shigehara [1992], Table 1.
3. To put things in perspective, recall that Romer's initial
increasing returns model was motivated by the very long run observation
that rates of output growth in countries such as the United States,
recent decades excepted, have been accelerating.
4. See Plosser's contribution to the Kansas City Fed symposium
(Plosser [1992]). On the scope of transitional dynamics for explaining
observed growth more generally, see King and Rebelo [1993].
5. This fact is noted in Romer [1987].
6. As Jones notes, though, it is not entirely clear whether or not
that increase in R&D's share was simply a measurement artifact.
In particular, some portion of that increase may just reflect a
re-labeling of job titles.
7. See also Young [1998]. In Young's model, if R&D leads
to an increased variety of solutions to the same problem, additional
resources devoted to R&D will lead to higher welfare but not faster
growth.
8. For example, the papers of King and Rebelo [1990], Rebelo
[1991], and Jones, et al. [1993].
9. See the papers of Stokey and Rebelo [1995] or Dotsey and Ireland
[1996], and the references therein, for recent analyses of factor income
taxation and inflation, respectively.
10. This parametrization exercise is carried out in Stokey and
Rebelo [1995].
11. This approach also seems to be supported by the longer
historical record. As observers such as Lord Kaldor [1961] have noted,
labor productivity in economies such as the U.S. has historically grown
at fairly constant rates over very long intervals of time. See, for
example, Figure 2.1 in Maddison [1982].
12. See Ng and Perron [1995].
13. Our focus here is purely on what is the appropriate
transformation to render the series stationary. In particular, we do not
identify the resulting stationary component as the "business
cycle" component of the series. This would be futile in any case,
as we are only considering annual data.
REFERENCES
Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. "A Model of Growth through
Creative Destruction." Econometrica, March 1992, 323-351.
Bai, Jushan, Robin L. Lumsdaine, and James H. Stock. "Testing
for and Dating Breaks in Integrated and Cointegrated Time Series."
Mimeograph, 1991.
Baily, Martin N., and Robert J. Gordon. "The Productivity
Slowdown, Measurement Issues, and the Explosion of Computer Power."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 1982, 347-420.
Banerjee, Anindya, Robin L. Lumsdaine, and James H. Stock.
"Recursive and Sequential Tests of the Unit-Root and Trend-Break
Hypotheses: Theory and International Evidence." Journal of Business
and Economic Statistics, July 1992, 271-287.
Ben-David, Dan, and David H. Papell. "The Great Wars, the
Great Crash, and Steady State Growth: Some New Evidence about an Old
Stylized Fact." Journal of Monetary Economics, December 1995,
453-475.
Bernanke, Ben, and Martin L. Parkinson. "Procyclical Labor
Productivity and Competing Theories of Business Cycles: Some Evidence
from Interwar and Manufacturing Industries." Journal of Political
Economy, June 1991, 439-459.
Bishop, John H. "Is the Test Score Decline Responsible for the
Productivity Growth Decline?" American Economic Review, March 1989,
178-197.
Christiano, Lawrence J. "Searching for a Break in GNP."
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, July 1992, 237-250.
Cochrane, John H. "How Big is the Random Walk in GNP?"
Journal of Political Economy, October 1988, 893-920.
Darby, Michael R. "Causes of Declining Growth," in
Policies for Long-Run Economic Growth: A Symposium Sponsored by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1992, 5-13.
David, Paul A. "The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical
Perspective on Modern Productivity Paradox." American Economic
Association Papers and Proceedings, May 1990, 355-361.
De Long, J. Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers. "Macroeconomic
Policy and Long-Run Growth," in Policies for Long-Run Economic
Growth: A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, 1992, 93-128.
Denison, Edward F. Trends in American Economic Growth: 1929-1982,
Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1982.
Dickey, David A., and S. G. Pantula. "Determining the Order of
Differencing in Autoregressive Processes." Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, October 1987, 455-461.
Dotsey, Michael, and Peter Ireland. "The Welfare Cost of
Inflation in General Equilibrium." Journal of Monetary Economics,
February 1996, 29-48.
Fischer, Stanley. "Symposium on the Slowdown in Productivity
Growth." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1988, 3-7.
Granger, Clive W. J., and Paul Newbold. "Spurious Regressions
in Econometrics." Journal of Econometrics, July 1974, 111-20.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Mehmet Yorukoglu. "1974."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 46, 1997,
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Griliches, Zvi. "Productivity Puzzles and R&D: Another
Nonexplanation." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1988, 9-21.
-----. "Productivity, R&D and the Data Constraint."
American Economic Review, March 1994, 1-23.
Hall, A. D. "Testing for a Unit Root in Times Series with
Pretest Data based Model Selection." Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, October 1994, 461-70.
Hulten, Charles R., James W. Robertson, and Frank C. Wykoff.
"Energy, Obsolescence, and the Productivity Slowdown," NBER Working Paper no. 2404, October 1987.
Jones, Charles I. "R&D-based Models of Economic
Growth." Journal of Political Economy, August 1995, 759-784.
Jones, Larry E., Rodolfo Manuelli, and Peter Rossi. "Optimal
Taxation in Models of Endogenous Growth." Journal of Political
Economy, June 1993, 485-517.
Jorgenson, Dale W. "Productivity and Post-War U.S. Economic
Growth." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1988, 23-42.
Kaldor, Nicholas. "Capital Accumulation and Economic
Growth," in The Theory of Capital, edited by F. A. Lutz and D. C.
Haque. London: MacMillan, 1961, 177-222.
King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, James H. Stock, and Mark W.
Watson. "Stochastic Trends and Economic Fluctuations."
American Economic Review, September 1991, 819-840.
King, Robert G., and Sergio Rebelo. "Public Policy and
Economic Growth: Developing Neoclassical Implications." Journal of
Political Economy, October 1990, S126-50.
-----. "Transitional Dynamics and Economic Growth in the
Neoclassical Model." American Economic Review, September 1993,
908-31.
Kwiatkowski, Denis, Peter C. B. Phillips, Peter Schmidt, and
Yongcheol Shin. "Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity
against the Alternative of a Unit Root: How Sure Are We that Economic
Time Series Have a Unit Root?" Journal of Econometrics,
October-December 1992, 159-178.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "On the Mechanics of Economic
Development." Journal of Monetary Economics, July 1988, 3-42.
Maddison, Angus. Phases of Capitalist Development, Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1982.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Matthew D. Shapiro. "Trends, Random
Walks, and Tests of the Permanent Income Hypothesis." Journal of
Monetary Economics, September 1985, 165-74.
Nelson, Charles R., and Charles I. Plosser. "Trends and Random
Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and
Implications." Journal of Monetary Economics, September 1982,
139-62.
Ng, Serena, and Pierre Perron. "Unit Root Tests in
Autoregressive-Moving Average Models with Data Dependent Methods for the
Truncation Lag." Journal of the American Statistical Association,
March 1995, 268-81.
Nordhaus, William D. "Economic Policy in the face of Declining
Productivity Growth." European Economic Review, May/June 1982,
131-57.
Perron, Pierre. "The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock and the
Unit Root Hypothesis." Econometrica, November 1989, 1361-401.
-----. "The HUMP-Shaped Behavior of Macroeconomic
Fluctuations." Empirical Economics, 18, special issue entitled New
Developments in Time Series Econometrics, 1993, 151-71.
-----. "Trend, Unit Root and Structural Change in
Macroeconomic Time Series," in Cointegration for the Applied
Economist, edited by B. B. Rao. Basington: MacMillan Press, 1994,
113-46.
-----. "Further Evidence on Breaking Trend Function in
Macroeconomic Variables." Journal of Econometrics, October 1997,
355-85.
Phillips, Peter C. B. "Understanding Spurious Regressions in
Econometrics." Journal of Econometrics, December 1986, 311-40.
Plosser, Charles I. "The Search for Growth," in Policies
for Long-Run Economic Growth: A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1992, 57-86.
Raj, Baldev. "International Evidence on Persistence in Output
in the Presence of an Episodic Change." Journal of Applied
Econometrics, July-September 1992, 281-93.
Raj, Baldev, and Daniel J. Slottje. "The Trend Behavior of
Alternative Inequality Measures in the United States from 1947-1990 and
the Structural Break." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,
October 1994, 479-87.
Rebelo, Sergio. "Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run
Growth." Journal of Political Economy, June 1991, 500-21.
Romer, Paul. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth."
Journal of Political Economy, October 1986, 1,002-37.
-----. "Crazy Explanations for the Productivity
Slowdown." NBER Macroeconomic Annual 1987, 163-201.
-----. "Endogenous Technological Change." Journal of
Political Economy, October 1990, S71-102.
Shapiro, Matthew. "Are Cyclical Fluctuations in Productivity
Due More to Supply Shocks or Demand Shocks?" American Economic
Review, May 1987, 118-24.
Shigehara, Kumiharu. "Causes of Declining Growth in
Industrialized Countries," in Policies for Long-Run Economic
Growth: A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, 1992, 15-39.
Stokey, Nancy L., and Sergio Rebelo. "Growth Effects of
Flat-Rate Taxes." Journal of Political Economy, June 1995, 519-50.
Williamson, Jeffrey G. "Productivity and American Leadership:
A Review Article." Journal of Economic Literature, March 1991,
51-68.
Young, Alwyn. "Growth without Scale Effects." Journal of
Political Economy, February 1998, 41-63.
Zivot, Eric, and Donald W. K Andrews. "Further Evidence on the
Great Crash, the Oil-Price Shock, and the Unit-Root Hypothesis."
Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, July 1992, 251-70.