Geographically localized knowledge: spillovers or markets?
Zucker, Lynne G. ; Darby, Michael R. ; Armstrong, Jeff 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Knowledge spillovers - positive externalities of scientific
discoveries on the productivity of firms which neither made the
discovery themselves nor licensed its use from the holder of
intellectual property rights - play a central role in the literature as
causes of both economic growth and geographic agglomeration.(1) Zvi
Griliches [1992] has surveyed the importance of R&D spillovers as a
major source of endogenous growth in recent "New Growth
Theory" models and the difficult empirical search for their
existence. While the search for spillovers has been difficult, there has
been considerable success in finding their fingerprints by demonstrating
statistically significant effects on a firm's productivity of being
near great universities and other sources of scientific discovery -
geographically localized knowledge spillovers. (See particularly, Adam
B. Jaffe [1989], Jaffe, Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson [1993], and Edwin Mansfield [1995].)(2) Providing further evidence of
the empirical relevance of geographically localized knowledge spillovers
in the case of biotechnology, Lynne G. Zucker, Michael R. Darby, and
Marilynn B. Brewer [1997] have recently demonstrated that
"intellectual human capital," measured operationally by where
and when "star" scientists at the leading edge of basic
bioscience are active, is a principal determinant of both the location
and timing of the entry of new biotechnology enterprises in the United
States.(3)
Operationalizing Sherwin Rosen's [1981] superstar concept,
Zucker, Derby, and Brewer [1997] relate geographically localized
knowledge spillovers in the formative years of the biotech industry to a
relatively small number of outstanding scientists (207 of whom ever
worked in the U.S.) who combined brilliant scientific productivity with
specific knowledge of the new techniques which formed the basis of
industrial formation and transformation (see Data Appendix). In this
paper, we further explore the technology by which apparent
geographically localized knowledge spillovers operate. Case studies and
interviews point to the fact that the star scientists are not simply
located in the same geographic area with biotech firms, but in fact are
frequently deeply involved in their operations as principals, employees,
or consultants. We find empirically that what might appear using
standard methodology and data sets as geographically localized external
economies for enterprises located near university stars turn out to
exist only for that much smaller set of enterprises which are linked to
particular star professors by contract or ownership - that is, by market
exchange, This same subset of firms with explicit ties to star
scientists also appear to account for a disproportionately larger share
of industry growth, measured here as number of products in development,
number of products on the market, and employment growth between 1989 and
1994. Indeed, it seems to us that the source of geographically localized
effects on firm performance is the same as the reason that much of the
fruits of the biotechnological revolution was much more appropriable by
the star scientists than by the universities which (typically) employed
them.(4) These star scientists generally retain their university
affiliations while involved in commercial applications within easy
commuting distance of home or university, thus creating localized
effects of university research.
Here we examine the effects of one scientific breakthrough on a
relatively small number of industries which experience a technological
transformation as a result. If, as we will argue in section V may well
be the case, other instances of geographically localized knowledge
spillovers are in fact also instances of appropriation and market
exchange by discoveting scientists, then both interpretation of prior
studies and their strong policy implications need to be reexamined.
Before drawing these conclusions, we must turn to the concrete analysis
which suggested them.
We open the "black box" of the actual working relationships
between university star scientists making the discoveries and the firms
utilizing them commercially, because we believe that relying on the
typically assumed, but unmeasured, pre-publication spillover of new
discoveries made in university labs has led to flawed inferences about
the processes of technology transfer. We examine the actual transfer by
developing a novel empirical indicator (Zucker, Derby, and Armstrong
[1994]; Zucker and Darby [1996]; Liebeskind, Oliver, Zucker, and Brewer
[1996]; Zucker, Brewer, Oliver, and Liebeskind [1993]): articles written
jointly between university star scientists and firm scientists
("linked") or articles written by university star scientists
who become employed full-time by a firm ("affiliated"), with
the number of such articles indicating the intensity of the bench level
scientific collaboration. The validity of this indicator for the
existence of contractual or ownership relationships with firms has been
confirmed through extensive interviews conducted with university
scientists and administrators, and with firm scientists, CEOs, and
corporate board members (for U.S. examples, see Zucker and Darby [1995];
Zucker, Brewer, Oliver, and Liebeskind [1993]).
Our complex, relational data base - to be described in more detail
below and in the Data Appendix - provides the basis for linking specific
scientists to specific firms, and allows us to construct high validity,
high specificity measures without becoming focused on a single
innovation case study.(5) By concentrating on genetic sequences and
firm-specific products and employment in biotechnology, we are able to
combine basic-science data with data from firms in multiple industries
from pharmaceuticals to instrumentation, agriculture, food processing,
and brewing. This variety of industries is illustrated by such biotech
products currently on the market or in development as a hepatitis B
vaccine, drugs to combat anemia in kidney dialysis patients, a
diagnostic test for testicular cancer, nematodes for control of navel
orange worm, modified vegetable oils for improved nutrition and
industrial lubrication, improved fermentation processes, and reversible
color-change ultraviolet-sensitive ink.(6)
Key to this multi-industry technological revolution was the 1973
discovery by Stanford professor Stanley Cohen and University of
California-San Francisco professor Herbert Boyer of the basic technique
for recombinant DNA (rDNA).(7) Today biotechnology refers principally to
the application of genetic engineering based upon taking a gene from one
organism and implanting it in another (rDNA) and production of the
outcome of this process.(8) While the production part of biotechnology
can be done by many firms, the selection of promising lines and the gene
transfer itself require very special skills and talents which were quite
rare at least until very recently. Following Harold Demsetz [1988], we
argue that mastery of this specialized body of knowledge played a
central role in delineating the boundaries of biotechnology firms.
Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1997] showed the key role of leading-edge
science in the entry of biotech firms and we show here that role
continued in determining the success and failure of these enterprises.
For the empirical work in this paper, California is not only a
technically tractable site, given data collection constraints for such a
highly detailed relational data base, but indeed nearly an ideal site
for the study because of the early entry into both the science and
industry of biotechnology, as well as the number of distinct locales
where bioscience or both the science and industry have developed.
Further, the state's firms exhibit the geographic agglomeration
associated with spillovers. Therefore, California is a suitable while
still manageable subject for a study that develops techniques for
identifying spillovers more precisely by identifying linkages between
biotech firms and star scientists affiliated with universities.(9)
Further, as we will discuss in more detail below, the pattern of our
results for California at the aggregate level matches the pattern of
results found for spillovers in Jaffe's nationwide study [1989].
Section II discusses and presents summary data on California
biotechnology firms and their underlying scientific base and relates our
methodology and measurements to the literature. Estimation methods are
outlined in section III. Section IV presents empirical results on the
determinants for California biotech firms of employment growth and
numbers of products in development and on the market. Section V analyzes
the implications of these results for the concept of geographically
localized knowledge spillovers. A Data Appendix concludes the paper.
II. BIOTECHNOLOGY SCIENCE AND INDUSTRY IN CALIFORNIA
California plays a leading role in both the basic science and its
commercialization and, if it were a separate country, would tie with
Japan in both science and industry for second to the rest of the United
States. California boasts 30% of the U.S. universities with
biotech-relevant departments receiving the highest ratings in the 1982
National Academy of Sciences reputational survey.(10) California firms
such as Amgen, Chiron, and Genentech are world leaders in biotechnology.
These firms, along with other California firms, are among early entrants
into commercial biotechnology, providing a sufficiently long track
record for meaningful analysis of their patterns of performance and
growth. To develop our California data base, we build on our U.S. work
in which we linked existing publicly available data sets together with
published information in ways that have not been done before, allowing
us to construct the links between the basic science (using data bases
created by and for scientists) and industry (using data bases created by
and for firms).
Describing California New Biotechnology Enterprises
For the empirical work in this paper, the existing large
scientist-article-citation-university-institute-enterprise-economy data
base presented in Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1994; 1997] was extended
for California in five principal ways:(11) (a) a telephone census of
California biotech firms verified existing 1989 and added 1994
employment data, (b) data on the numbers of products in development and
on the market in 1991 was collected for these firms from Bioscan, (c) a
second telephone survey of California star scientists was used to
illuminate patterns of linkage between firms and stars not affiliated
with firms, (d) patterns of coauthorship by stars not affiliated with
firms were derived from the existing data base to uncover implicit
linkages to firms, and (e) patenting activity by California stars
reported in Entrez was examined to uncover differences according to the
nature of the stars' ties, if any, to local firms.(12) The extended
data base was used to examine the determinants of success for California
biotech firms with special emphasis on understanding geographically
localized knowledge spillovers.
In the May 1994 telephone census, we obtained usable data on 1989 and
1994 employment levels for 110 California biotechnology using firms.(13)
As expected from Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1997], 109 of these (99.1%)
were located in those four of the state's eight functional economic
areas (regions) as defined by the Bureau of Economic Analysis where star
scientists also worked. Over 40% of the firms are in the San Francisco
Bay region and another third in the San Diego region.(14)
Entry dates for our 110 firms were spread unevenly over time with 35%
entering in either 1980 or 1981 compared to 13, 26, and 26% in
1976-1979, 1983-1985, and 19861989, respectively. This pattern is
similar to that for all U.S. entries into biotechnology: A large number
of the firms got their start around the time of the Genentech initial
public offering in October 1980, a date considered a financial watershed
in biotechnology commercialization (John Elkington [1985, 5960]). We
distinguish between new biotechnology firms founded specifically to
exploit the new bioscience technologies (entrants) and preexisting firms
(including subsidiaries and other subunits) which adopt these
technologies (incumbents). Firm age is measured from date of founding
for entrants and date of entry into biotech for incumbents. (Table A. 1
lists variable definitions.) Biotech firms in principle also include
organizations for which insufficient data exist to establish whether
entrant or incumbent and, as in our sample, problematic organizations
such as a joint venture between an entrant and an incumbent. In our
110-firm sample, there are 87 entrants and 22 incumbents, which is only
slightly higher a ratio of entrants than the national average.
Since many biotech firms are working on pharmaceuticals which
typically require about ten years of development and testing prior to
FDA approval, revenues and especially profits are generally nonexistent early in those firm's development and cannot provide a reliable
indicator of success. Market value of the enterprise would do better,
but considerably less than half of the firms are publicly traded. As a
result, for performance measures we focus on employment growth from 1989
to 1994 and the numbers of products in development and products on the
market in 1991 as measures of enterprise success. At this early stage it
is impossible to accurately separate all the winners from the losers in
the competitive race, but these indicators seem to do so better than any
alternatives.
Interestingly, success is heavily concentrated, particularly in those
firms with connections to star scientists by 1989 described in the next
sub-section: Firms with star ties had an average increase in employment
of 366 workers from 1989 to 1994, compared to only 82 workers for firms
without such ties. Firms with tied stars also account for an average of
10.7 products in development and 8.8 on the market compared to 1.2 and
3.5, respectively, for those without ties to star scientists. These
star-firm ties, we shall see in section IV, are typically established
before the firm, the star, or both achieve success.
California Star Scientists and Their Ties to Enterprises
As indicated by the organizational location given on their
publications, 55 star scientists worked in California firms and
universities during 1976-1989. Of these, ten gave a California firm at
least once as their location during this period; we term these stars
"affiliated" with the firm given.(15) It might appear that the
other "unaffiliated" stars are pure academic scientists,
devoid of commercial concerns and ties, but that conclusion in a number
of cases would be misleading. Our telephone survey of California star
scientists found that academic stars may simultaneously be linked to
specific firms in a number of different ways: exclusive direct
employment (often as CEO or other principal), full or part ownership,
exclusive and nonexclusive consulting contracts (effectively part-time
employment), and chairmanship of or membership on scientific advisory
boards. These ties generally establish ownership rights and the
star's compensation for the fruits of the collaboration. Given the
distinguished achievement of these scientists, most chose to retain
their university positions; even when employed full-time by a firm, many
retain adjunct professorships. University stars thus tend to be a
locally fixed input for commercial applications.
While most academics at major U.S. research universities are aware of
colleagues who have become millionaires or billionaires as a result of
starting a firm while retaining an university appointment, the picture
of explicit contractual linkage to enterprises is at sharp variance with
the picture familiar to economists of how geographically localized
spillovers work. The standard economic notion is that by being near the
universities where cutting-edge research is being done, employees of
local enterprises will hear of important discoveries first and thus be
able to utilize them before others are aware of their existence, much
less their value. In this paradigm, the information in the discovery is
a public good freely available to those who incur the costs of seeking
it out in the groves of academe. It is further assumed that scientific
discoveries have only fleeting value unless formal
intellectual-property-rights mechanisms effectively prevent use of the
information by unlicensed parties; i.e., absent patents, trade secrets,
or actual secrecy, the value of a discovery erodes quickly as the
information diffuses.
Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1997] have a different view: Scientific
discoveries vary in the degree to which others can be excluded from
making use of them. Inherent in the discovery itself is its degree of
natural excludability: if the techniques for replication are not widely
known prior to the discovery, then any scientist wishing to build on the
new knowledge must first acquire hands-on experience.(16) If he or she
cannot gain access to a research team or laboratory setting with that
know-how, then working in that area may be very difficult if not
impossible. They (and we) argue that a scientific discovery -
especially, an "invention of a method of inventing" (Griliches
[1957]) - can give rise to localized industrial effects where the
information is sufficiently costly to transfer due either to its
complexity or tacitness (see Richard R. Nelson [1959], Kenneth J. Arrow
[1962; 1974], Nelson and Sidney G. Winter [1982], and Nathan Rosenberg
[1982]) and the information is embodied in particular individuals tied
to particular locales.
The breakthrough discoveries involved in modern biotechnology have
fundamentally changed how bioresearch is done. Once a new life form has
been created and its use identified and sufficiently demonstrated, then
those specific inventions are alienable from their creator through
intellectual property mechanisms. However, the new techniques used in
their creation have exhibited both high natural excludability and
immense commercial value. Therefore, it is not surprising that Zucker,
Darby, and Brewer [1997] found that where and when stars were actively
publishing were important determinants of where and when enterprises
built to use their special knowledge would be formed.
Ultimately, when the knowledge of how to practice a discovery has
diffused widely and the information is part of routine science, the
intellectual human capital associated with that knowledge will earn only
the normal returns to the cost of acquiring it in graduate school.(17)
In the early period when new industries are being built and old
industries transformed as a result of a major scientific breakthrough,
however, the intellectual human capital embodied in the relatively few
individuals who possess it will have extraordinary value, particularly
so for the early "superstars" (Rosen [1981]) who combine the
requisite tacit knowledge of the commercially (or academically) valuable
technique with the genius and vision to apply those techniques in the
most promising areas of research.(18) Indeed these stars can be the key
determinant of the geographic agglomeration of the new industries
(Zucker, Darby, Brewer [1997]). As we will show below, firms with most
access to this intellectual human capital are most likely to be the
winners in the new and transformed industries.
Since star scientists in biotechnology could simultaneously provide
immense value to both great research universities and biotech firms,
many chose to do both. Scientists in academe and firms agree in
interviews that an effective way to identify those scientists wearing
two hats is to examine the coauthorship pattern of stars unaffiliated
with firms. A star is locally "linked" to a biotech firm if
the star publishes an article with one or more scientists in the firm
while he or she is located at a university in the same region as the
firm. We hypothesize that such locally linked stars are the main channel
by which university star scientists have influenced the success of
biotech firms.(19)
They do so in two primary ways. First, linked star scientists provide
access to and information about discoveries with potential commercial
value made in their own and other university-based labs, transmitting
complex, tacit knowledge by bench-level collaboration. Zucker, Darby,
Brewer, and Yusheng Peng [1996] have shown that organizational
boundaries serve as informational envelopes within which valuable
information characterized by natural excludability is much more likely
to be diffused than to those outside the organization. So, by being in
both the university and the firm, the linked star is able to convey
knowledge of processes and techniques which is not otherwise available
to the firm.
Second, the linked university stars are able to maintain both
university and firm relationships because of the very high quality of
their input. Central to understanding how these dual affiliations work
is the case study finding that bioscientists act as individual actors,
as opposed to acting as agents of their primary ties, whether to the
university or the firm (Zucker, Brewer, Oliver, and Liebeskind [1993]).
These bioscientists can exercise their expertise independently primarily
because they are recognized as having excellent "scientific
taste" in the selection of research problems and using exceptional
care and expertise in executing that research.(20) By exercising their
"scientific taste" these linked stars judge the likely payoff
of different lines of bioscience research and advise the firm concerning
their relative merit. As noted above, we expect that the scientific
advisory boards play a similar role, and plan to investigate them in
later research. Linked stars, while they generally have a significant
financial interest in the firm, also often have the advantage of being
part of a broad external "network for evaluation," providing
the basis for high quality input in product development decisions
(Zucker [1991]).(21)
As described in the Data Appendix, we examined every article through
1989 reporting a gene-sequence discovery written by a star located in a
California university or firm. We classified for each star whether he or
she was affiliated with a firm on that article or, if not, whether any
scientists from a firm in the local region were coauthors on the
article. Accordingly, for each article the star was classified as
affiliated with or unaffiliated with a specific firm. Unaffiliated stars
were further subdivided into those who were locally linked to a specific
firm or untied to any firm.(22)
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED]
For the empirical work reported in section IV below, we use counts of
these classified articles, but first consider a simpler breakdown of the
55 individual California stars as affiliated (if ever affiliated with a
California firm), linked (if ever linked to a California firm but never
affiliated), and untied (otherwise) as reported in Table I.
As discussed above, while natural excludability leads to the
embodiment of certain knowledge and techniques in individuals, there is
also a role for formal intellectual property rights. When the knowledge
is implemented to create alienable, potentially commercially valuable
discoveries, patents offer an important mechanism for appropriating
returns. Thus, the patenting of discoveries by stars is an indication of
expected commercial value of their discoveries. The data presented in
the upper panel of Table I show that those stars affiliated with firms
are very different in their patenting activity compared to unaffiliated
university stars: half have patented discoveries versus only 15.6% of
the university stars. Among the university stars, a quarter of those
linked to specific firms in the same region have patented discoveries
compared to 13.5% of those not tied to such firms. Although the numbers
are small, the standard [[Chi].sup.2](2) test rejects the hypothesis of
independence.
Comments on earlier versions of this paper suggest that it is
commonly thought - especially among academics - that the very best
scientists are unlikely to be involved with firms or to patent their
discoveries. This presumption may rest on the idea that scientific norms
of openness and disinteredness in fact contribute to the advance of
science and are most likely to be observed by the best scientists.(23)
Commercialization of high science is presumed to be done by lesser
scientists, perhaps in the role of bridge-builders between science and
technology (Lieberman [1978]). However, as seen in the lower part of
Table I, patented scientists are generally more widely cited than
unpatented scientists and affiliated scientists are more cited than
linked scientists who in turn are more cited than untied scientists. To
take the extreme cases, affiliated scientists with patents are cited 6.5
times as frequently as untied scientists without patents. Citation
frequency is the standard indicator of scientific eminence in
quantitative work.(24) It appears that work done either in or in
collaboration with finns is quite productive in terms of influence on
future research. Zucker and Darby [1996] report for the U.S. as a whole
that this apparent positive effect of commercial ties on scientific
productivity of the stars partially reflects the fact that stars with
commercial ties publish at a higher rate (before, during, and after
those ties) than those who do not ever have them. The largest part of
the explanation, however, comes from a much higher average rate of
citation to articles written by stars with or as employees of firms than
before or afterwards. When we put these results together with the strong
positive effects of stars on firm productivity, as we report here, the
relationship between scientists and firms appears to be truly symbiotic contributing to the success of both science and commercial ends.
Relation to Other Empirical Work
In describing the general features of our data base, we have raised
questions concerning prior models and related empirical measures of
innovative inputs, the knowledge generation process, and outputs of that
process. Innovative inputs have generally been treated as measured by
the resources invested in them, most often R&D expenditures. The
underlying assumption that equal investment in R&D produces equal
innovative returns is easily falsifiable and recently patents have been
seen as a better measure of inputs than output of the innovative
process.(25) We know that most scientists have very low productivity,
with most of the scientific output typically produced by the top 1% or
2% of all scientists working in a specific area (Harriet Zuckerman [1967], Crane [1972], Paul D. Allison, J. Scott Long, and Tad K. Krauze
[1982]). Thus, we are concerned with identifying and locating the most
productive, star scientists (all of whom were located in universities
initially), their explicit linkages to firms, and actual measures of
their productivity in the firm linkage. The latter is measured here by
the number of articles reporting genetic-sequence discoveries that are
published either with the firm listed explicitly as the star's
affiliation or which include finn scientists as coauthors.
As an alternative to patents as a measure of innovative output, we
separately measure three different aspects of the economic impact of
inventive activity: the number of products in development (generally
close to the inventive activity), the number of products on the market
(indicating successful development), and net growth in employment
(indicating successful development and marketing of products). Each can
be seen as a successive step in moving from the initial invention to the
impact on economic performance of the firm. Although we use only
cross-sectional data in the work reported here, we are proposing in
future work to exploit available information to develop time series on
the first two measures for 1987-1994, as well as less complete data on
employment changes at the firm level over the same period.
III. ESTIMATION METHODS
Because of the nature of the processes which we will be estimating,
we use two approaches to estimation: (a) poisson regressions are used
for products in development and on the market and (b) a modified Type II
Tobit procedure following Takeshi Amemiya [1985] is used for change in
employment. The procedures used are outlined here and explained more
fully in Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994].
Products in development and on the market are count variables (0, 1,
2, ...) with a considerable number of 0 observations and other values
tailing off in frequency as they increase numerically. Accordingly, the
regressions were estimated in the poisson form appropriate for count
variables with numerous zeroes using LIMDEP (William Greene [1992,
539549]), with the Wooldridge regression-based correction for the
variance-covariance matrix estimates.(26) The poisson regressions
estimate the logarithm of the expected number of firm births; so the
signs and significance of coefficients have the usual interpretation.
It would seem that employment growth is appropriately estimated by
OLS, but we again run into a problem of too many zeroes - although in
this case only one eighth of the observations (see Table A.3). We
suspect that these reports of no change in employment are most often due
to response-bias in which firms for which there has been little change
report no change rather than bother to look up the exact figures. An
observationally equivalent interpretation (which is closer to most of
the econometric literature) is that there are fixed costs of change so
it will be undertaken only where the gains to doing so are significant.
In this case a modified Type II Tobit following James Heckman [1976]
two-stage procedure is appropriate. The first stage is an ordered probit which predicts whether the firm reports decreased, unchanged, or
increased employment. The second stage (a) estimates the size of a
change using only the observations reporting changes, (b) corrects for
sample-selection bias by including as a regressor the Inverse Mills
Ratio (IMR) computed in the first stage, and (c) calculates a consistent
and unbiased estimate of the variance-covariance matrix due to the work
of Keunkwan Ryu [1993] and Woon Gyu Choi [1993]. Inclusion of the IMR
results in unbiased estimates of the coefficients of other explanatory
variables; a significant coefficient on the IMR confirms the presence of
selection bias.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
In this section we report results on three different measures of
biotech-using firm performance: the number of products the firm has in
development as of 1991, the number of products it has on the market at
that time, and the net change in its employment over the five years
following 1989. None of these measures are by any means perfect
substitutes for changes in value of the enterprise as measures of
success. However, many biotechnology firms are small start-up ventures
which are not yet publicly traded and other firms are subunits of much
larger enterprises not primarily involved in biotechnology. Thus, the
sample size would be unacceptably reduced from the 76 firms for which we
have data if we restricted ourselves to those for which enterprise value
was also available.(27) Nonetheless, these three indicators are
interesting in and of themselves from organizational, economic, and
policy perspectives and are likely to reflect spillover effects if they
exist.
As indicated above, in these estimates we use a set of variables
built by counting the number of articles reporting genetic sequence
discoveries and written by each star located in California universities
or firms, according to whether for each article the star was affiliated
with, locally linked to (by being in the same region as their coauthors
affiliated with the firm), or not tied to each of the 110 firms in the
data set. Using an article count to "weight" the stars'
publications was important because there was considerable variation in
the authorship and coauthorship histories (though the star tie,
unweighted by articles, produces qualitatively the same results). The
count also served to capture the strength and/or productivity of the
relationship between the star scientists and enterprises.
In using these variables to explain biotech firm performance, obvious
concerns about the direction of cause-and-effect had to be addressed.
For example, firms could have established ties to star scientists as a
signalling device or because firms which became successful ex post
absorbed scientists as part of their expansion. These concerns were not
supported in the data because tied stars typically were either with the
firm when or very soon after it was founded, or became part of the
firm's production and innovation process shortly after the star had
first published (Zucker and Darby [1996]).(28) In the first case, with a
ten-plus year product cycle the timing argues that these scientists were
the cause - not the result - of the success of the firm. In the second
case, the scientists are too young to be any sort of signalling device,
and again it is more plausible that they are working with the firm
because they are productive, not famous. We also constructed an
analogous set of measures by which individual stars were counted as
affiliated, linked, or untied without regard to article weighting. The
model results using these variables, while qualitatively similar to the
weighted model results, performed less well in terms of goodness of
fit.(29) If star recruitment was a signalling effect motivated by the
desire to list individual stars on the company roster, then the weighted
model results should not have been superior to the unweighted results.
Products in Development
The number of products the firm has in development as of 1991 is
taken from the firm's listing in Bioscan (see Data Appendix).
Generally, these products are in various stages of clinical trials or
field testing, although in some cases the listed products may be at
earlier stages of development or have received F.D.A. market approval
but not yet be marketed. Among the three indicators examined, this
measure appears to be most closely related to success in application of
the new biotechnologies and least affected either by use of other
technologies or by differences in business strategy (e.g., in-house
production and/or marketing vs. joint agreements with established
pharmaceutical firms).
We first examine the results of a poisson regression in the spirit of
Jaffe [1989]. Model a in Table II explains products in development by
the number of gene-sequence-discovery articles written by stars from
within a local university who were not affiliated with any firm
("unaffiliated articles"), by whether or not the firm is a
entrant (as opposed to a biotech subunit of a pre-existing firm), by the
firm's age, and by whether or not the firm utilizes the rDNA
technology. Model b broadens model a by also including the number of
gene-sequence-discovery articles written by stars affiliated with the
firm ("affiliated articles"). Consider first model a: As
expected, the firm's age and its use of the rDNA technology both
contribute significantly and positively to the number of products in
development. Interestingly, the new dedicated biotech firms are
significantly more likely to be developing new products than incumbent
firms. Finally, we see that the stars concept which was used by Zucker,
Darby, and Brewer [1997] to identify the scientists around which
entrants and incumbents would be built also appears to work here to
uncover important, positive, significant geographically localized
spillover effects of local universities on the success of nearby
enterprise R&D efforts in the manner of Jaffe [1989]. These results
all persist in model b, although the addition to the poisson regression
of the significantly positive number of affiliated articles for the firm
generally reduces both the magnitude and t-statistics for the other
explanatory variables.
Models c and d are identical to models a and b, respectively, except
that the number of articles written by university stars is broken down
into those written in collaboration with scientists from the firm
("linked articles") and the remaining ("untied
articles"). The explanatory power of the regressions are
substantially and significantly improved by relaxing the implicit
constraint that research done in the university has the same effect on
enterprise R&D productivity whether or not it is done in
collaboration with the enterprise's scientists. In fact, the
coefficient on articles written by local university stars not in
collaboration with the firm loses its significance and nearly vanishes
in magnitude. What had appeared to be an undifferentiated geographically
localized knowledge spillover seems to have resulted from a
specification error: If we [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] did not
have the data set required to identify which university stars were
linked to which enterprises, then this study would have confirmed the
previous findings. Instead we find that no such indiscriminate
spillovers are apparent for biotechnology products in development.
It is interesting that when linked articles is admitted to the
regression separately, the coefficients of both affiliated articles and
Dummy-use rDNA are cut sharply in magnitude, and only the latter retains
its significance. We believe that the insignificance of affiliated
articles in this regression should not be taken to mean that having
stars affiliated with an enterprise is irrelevant for developing new
products. For example, enterprises with affiliated stars are most likely
to attract university stars to collaborate with them.(30) The
enterprises with links to university stars are able to most effectively
acquire and use the results of ongoing university research; linked stars
become the conduits for the information and for evaluation of different
lines of research related to potential product development. Furthermore,
we will see that affiliated articles have a significant, positive effect
when products on the market is substituted as the dependent variable.
Products on the Market
The number of products each biotech firm has on the market as of 1991
also is taken from the firm's listing in Bioscan. Although some of
these products result from the application of the new biotechnologies,
by and large, given the typical decade-long FDA approval process for
human therapeutics, the products on the market include a higher
proportion than those in development of reagents and instruments used in
applying the technology [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] rather than
the result of the new biotechnologies themselves.
For products on the market (and also employment growth) there is no
evidence of geographically localized knowledge spillovers, so models a
and b are not reported in either case in Table III to conserve
space.(31) The differences between products on the market and products
in development rationalize most of the differences between the results
reported in Tables II and the first two columns of Table III. In Table
III, the coefficients on Dummy-entrant and Dummy-use rDNA are both
negative and significant which we believe reflects the fact that firms
which are engaged primarily in applying the new technologies are likely
to have fewer products than their suppliers. Nonetheless, firm age
(measured from the date of entry into biotech), affiliated articles (in
model d) and especially linked articles have a positive effect on the
number of products on the market. As to the latter effects, the positive
coefficients reflect the fact that the most successful firms using the
new biotechnologies are the ones most likely to have products which
reached the market.
A more surprising result is the very small but statistically
significant coefficients found for publications by local university star
scientists not linked to the firm (untied articles). We do not think
that this represents any sort of negative spillover from the unlinked
university stars but may reflect the fact that areas with many stars
have many firms competing for local resources so that we detect a slight
congestion effect in these coefficients. This would be consistent with
the result found in Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1997] that the number of
stars in a region has a positive but diminishing effect on firm births.
Changes in Employment
The first-stage ordered probit estimates (useful primarily as a basis
for correction for selectivity bias) are not reported here but is
available in Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994]. In sum, those
estimates indicate that an enterprise is more likely to increase
employment and less likely to decrease employment if it uses rDNA
technology to produce human therapeutics and if it is younger. We will
see below, however, that firm age is (insignificantly) positive in
determining the size of the firm's employment increase. What we
have identified in the first-stage estimates appears to be a sorting
phenomenon in which as the enterprise matures, it either begins to grow
more rapidly or else to shrink according to whether or not its strategy
is proving successful. This increasing probability of decline or failure
is in contrast to the findings for U.S. manufacturing plants generally
reported by Timothy Dunne, Mark J. Roberts, and Larry Samuelson [1989],
perhaps because it is so difficult to tell whether or not a young
biotech enterprise is or is not achieving success.
The last two columns of Table III report selectivity-corrected
second-stage OLS estimates for change in the number of employees
analogous to those reported for products in Tables II and III. Following
Ryu [1993], the variance-covariance matrix has been corrected for the
non-spherical error structure inherent in the two-stage estimation of
the Type II Tobit procedure as noted in section III.(32) The linked
stars are seen to have a significant positive effect as with the other
performance variables. The untied university stars do not enter
significantly nor (in model d) do the affiliated stars as was the case
for products in development. Of the other variables, the only
significant effects are a positive coefficient on the use of the rDNA
technology and another on the Inverse Mills ratio which signifies the
importance of the selectivity bias correction.
Summary of Empirical Results
For all three measures of firm performance, the collaborative
research evidenced by publications written by university stars and
employees of particular firms has a significant positive effect on the
firm's performance whenever these linked articles are in the
regression. Publications by stars affiliated with a firm have a positive
impact on performance whenever they are significant, but their effect is
not robust. While affiliated stars then do not have a robust direct
effect on firm performance, it should be noted that firms with
affiliated stars are more likely to have linked stars and that this
significant correlation between the linked- and affiliated-articles
variables makes it difficult to separately identify their effects.
Local university stars in general, as well as those specifically not
linked to the firm, display inconsistent impacts - inconsistent both
across models and performance measures and with the predictions of the
geographically localized knowledge spillover literature. For the
variable most directly related to innovative activity, the number of
products in development, there appears to be a significant classic
geographically localized knowledge spillover effect from the number of
local university stars. However, this disappears when university stars
are broken down into those which have direct links to the specific firm
and all others. For the other performance variables, local university
stars not linked to the enterprise are estimated to have, if anything, a
negative effect, although where statistically significant this effect is
tiny in magnitude. Such negative effects - if they are taken seriously -
are consistent with congestion effects to the extent they are associated
with more local firms, but not with geographically localized knowledge
spillovers.
An interesting issue of interpretation arises with respect to the
differential performance of entrants and incumbents. The entrants appear
to have significantly more products in development and less on the
market and insignificantly less employment growth in comparison to
incumbents. We related the differences in significant coefficients to
the comparative emphases on therapeutics by entrants and reagents and
instruments among incumbents. However, in a case study of a large
pharmaceutical firm (Zucker and Darby [1995]), two other plausible
explanations were suggested by (the not disinterested) scientists at
that incumbent: Pharmaceutical firms are more experienced and hence
better at choosing winning research projects which get to market and
less inclined to keep pursuing projects which look like dead ends
because they are one of the few things going on at the firm. The
incentive system and policy at this incumbent, at least, also
discourages announcements of products in development until they are
proven in humans (late Phase II of clinicals) while many entrants have
to tout their nascent projects to the financial markets to obtain
initial or additional financing. Clearly it would be premature to
attempt a definitive performance comparison between entrants and
incumbents on the basis of these results.
For the biotechnology industry, we have provided strong evidence that
apparent geographically localized knowledge spillovers in fact represent
specific market exchange. Informal discussions with many of the linked
scientists indicates that this exchange often takes place through equity
sharing. With even a small degree of non-salvageability among the
transacting parties - as when a firm's product development becomes
uniquely dependent on a particular star scientist - coupled with a high
degree of uncertainty, it is not surprising to observe such
"vertical integration" as described by Benjamin Klein, Robert
Crawford, and Armen Alchian [1978]. While we await other
researchers' results for additional industries and technologies, we
hypothesize that apparent local spillovers generally may confound strong
effects from university scientists directly involved with local firms
and weak or nonexistent effects from all other university scientists.
V. CONCLUSIONS
Paul M. Romer [1990] shows that knowledge spillovers have substantial
macroeconomic implications for growth and international trade. These
implications result because investments in R&D produce an output
(characterized by Romer as a set of instructions) which is both
nonrivalrous and at least partially excludable.(33) Our empirical
results suggest that what have been termed geographically localized
knowledge spillovers do not seem to fit this definition of spillovers,
at least in the case of biotechnology. In particular, because
discoveries in this area are characterized by natural excludability and
embodied in human capital and because transmitting the discovery to
others requires the active participation of those with the knowledge,
the technology cannot be characterized as a nonrivalrous set of
instructions.(34) Thus to the extent that our results generalize to
other cases of apparent geographically localized knowledge spillovers,
the inefficiencies derived in Romer's analysis are not present.
The standard notion of geographically localized knowledge spillovers
is based on the idea that university scientists are pursuing
disinterested basic research, the results of which can be most quickly
put to commercial use by those enterprises located nearby who can most
readily learn novel results from social ties between employees and
university scientists or by attending informal seminars at the
university.
Our picture of how the process in fact has worked in biotechnology is
quite different. We find that all the parties involved (government and
other funding agencies, universities, professors, and enterprises) are
or can be connected by contractual and/or ownership ties in competitive
markets. The most productive scientists generally are either employees
of or collaborators with the enterprises. The government grants patent
rights to universities (with a proviso for minimum royalty rates for
discovering scientists) and rights of exploitation to scientists who
embody any intellectual human capital resulting from their work. As a
result, the prices paid by government funding agencies are reduced both
directly due to any expected patent royalties to universities and
indirectly because competitive university salaries are lower, other
things equal, in areas where faculty expect the possibility of receiving
substantial outside income or wealth as a result of skills developed
doing research at the university. Since these discoveries are
characterized by natural excludability, the discovering scientists do
not give away to enterprises the fruits of their intellectual human
capital but instead enter into contractual arrangements with existing
firms or start their own firm in order to extract the supranormal
returns available to those fortunate and talented enough to acquire that
capital. The scientists work with or create firms within commuting
distance of home or university - where they nearly always retain
affiliation - thus creating localized effects of university research. In
this way, we see that what appeared to others as a case of knowledge
spillovers with resulting inefficiencies is in fact a standard case of
market exchange of rivalrous and excludable goods. We believe that this
geographically localized impact, like extraordinary returns to
intellectual human capital itself, is a transitory phenomenon during the
important initial period of industry development resulting from a major,
commercially valuable scientific breakthrough characterized by natural
excludability.
The quantitative estimates of the effects of the collaborations
between academic stars and firm scientists are interesting in
themselves, providing direct evidence of a large, significant impact of
academic research on local industrial development. For an otherwise
average firm, the full models d in Tables II and III imply that just two
such collaborative articles translate into one more product in
development, one more product on the market, and 344 more employees.(35)
Since the product relations are nonlinear, we should note that five such
collaborative articles imply 4.7 more products in development, 3.5 more
products on the market, and 861 more employees.
The empirical results in this paper are restricted to evidence on
geographically localized knowledge spillovers in the California
biotechnology industry. However, we believe that the analytical
technology we are developing and many of our central findings will prove
generalizable to other cases of major scientific breakthroughs which
lead to important commercial applications. As observed by Alvin
Klevorick, Richard Levin, Nelson, and Sydney Winter [1995], economists
have recently explained an industry's R&D intensity "by
two key factors - technological opportunity and the ability to
appropriate returns from new developments." [their emphasis] While
relatively few mature industries are driven by technological opportunity
in the form of basic scientific breakthroughs, the emergence phase of
important industries frequently is so driven. The most important lessons
are to be drawn not for analysis of past breakthroughs which have formed
or transformed industries, but for those yet to come in sciences we can
only guess. Nonetheless, we are pleased that other researchers are
beginning to apply our earlier work to the analysis of technologies such
as semiconductors and high-temperature superconductors. We are
encouraged in our belief that our results will be generalizable to other
technologies by extended discussions with those familiar with those
technologies and by some fragmentary evidence in the literature.
For example, Bruce Kogut, Gordon Walker, Weijian Shan, and Dong-Jae
Kim [1994] find broadly similar patterns of interfirm relationships for
large and small enterprises within and across national boundaries for
semiconductors and biotechnology, although they argue and point to some
corroborating evidence that embodiment of technology in individual
scientists is even more important for semiconductors than for
biotechnology. Levin [1982] notes that [as with products of recombinant
DNA] integrated circuits were initially nearly impossible to patent.
More generally, David Balkin and Luis Gomez-Mejia [1985] report on the
distinctive emphasis on incentive pay and equity participation for
technical employees in (largely non-biotech) high-tech firms, especially
for the "few key individuals in research and development ... viewed
as essential to the company. ..." Success in high-technology,
especially in formative years, we believe comes down to motivated
services of a small number of extraordinary scientists with vision and
mastery of the breakthrough technology.
The results reported here, if they are confirmed for additional
industries and locations, have great significance for the interpretation
of geographically localized knowledge spillovers: First, the welfare
losses normally associated with uncompensated externalities are not
present.(36) Second, the question of why some apparent knowledge
spillovers - as in biotechnology - are geographically localized while
others - as in high-temperature superconductivity - are not appears to
be intimately related to what Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1997] termed
intellectual human capital, in particular whether the discovery in
question is characterized by natural excludability. Third, university
policies which limit professors' ability to contract freely with
and to establish ownership positions in firms may protect norms of
disinterested science at the cost of limiting technology transfer and
local development in scientific areas characterized by natural
excludability.
DATA APPENDIX
A detailed description of the basic data sets developed for the
Project on "Intellectual Capital, Technology Transfer, and the
Organization of Leading-Edge Industries: The Case of Biotechnology"
(Lynne G. Zucker, Marilynn B. Brewer, and Michael R. Darby, Principal
Investigators) is presented in Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1994] and
Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994]. These data will be archived upon
completion of the project in the Data Archives Library at the UCLA Institute for Social Science Research.
Summary definitions of the variables are provided in Table A.1. Table
A.2 provides summary statistics for the variables. Table A.3 provides
summary statistics for key variables broken down by regions and by
whether employment is reported as increased, unchanged, or decreased.
Our basic source for employment growth from 1989 to the winter or
spring of 1994 is a telephone census conducted in May 1994. We attempted
to conduct telephone interviews for all 182 California biotech firms in
the Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1994] data base and obtained 110 useable
observations for employment (1994) as detailed in Zucker, Darby, and
Armstrong [1994, 29-30, 55]. For 78 of these firms, we were able to
count how many products were in development and on the market using 1991
issues of Bioscan (1992 or 1990 issues in a few cases). Two more cases
were lost due to missing data on whether the firm reported using the
recombinant DNA technology (indicated by Dummy-use rDNA = 1). The
missing cases are generally for small firms, marginally in the industry
and are not believed to distort the results reported (see Zucker, Darby,
and Armstrong [1994] for further discussion).
Zucker, Darby, and Brewer [1994] defined star scientists based on the
universe of all articles reporting genetic sequence discoveries up to
1990.(37) Worldwide 327 leading researchers (the "stars") were
identified on the basis of the number of genetic sequence discoveries
and articles reporting them up to 1990 for which they were an author.
These 327 stars were listed as authors on 4,061 distinct articles in
major journals. These articles were hand collected and used to identify
and locate institutional affiliations at the time of publication for
each of our stars and their coauthors who were either other stars or
"collaborators" (6,082 scientists worldwide).
"Affiliated articles" counts the number of articles by
stars where the firm is given as the affiliation. The summed number of
articles written by stars listing universities located in the region
("unaffiliated articles") is the same for each firm in a given
region. This total is disaggregated into two firm-specific variables:
"Linked articles" counts the number of articles by a
university star coauthoring with a scientist affiliated with the firm
(either a collaborator or another star scientist); "untied
articles" counts the number of articles by university stars that
were not linked to the firm. For each firm, the sum of its linked and
untied articles equals its unaffiliated articles count.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE A.1 OMITTED]
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE A.2 OMITTED]
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE A.3 OMITTED]
ABBREVIATION
IMR: Inverse Mills Ratio
This research has been supported by grants from the National Science
Foundation (SES 9012925), the University of California Systemwide
Biotechnology Research and Education Program, and the University of
California's Pacific Rim Research Program. We acknowledge very
useful comments on earlier versions from Woon Gyu Choi, Harold Demsetz,
Erwin Diewert, Mark Grady, Zvi Griliches, Rebecca Henderson, Joshua
Lerner, Marvin B. Lieberman, Richard R. Nelson, Maximo Torero, J. Fred
Weston and participants in seminars at M.I.T., the 1995 National Bureau
of Economic Research (NBER) Summer Institute on Productivity, and UCLA.
The authors thank Woon Gyu Choi who provided program code used to
estimate a modified two-stage Heckman procedure, Keunkwan Ryu who
provided helpful advice on its implementation, and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge
for his good counsel on implementing his procedure for correcting the
poisson variance-covariance matrix estimates in LIMDEP. We are indebted
to a remarkably talented team of postdoctoral fellows Zhong Deng, Julia
Liebeskind, and Yusheng Peng and research assistants Paul J. Alapat,
Lynda J. Kim, Kerry Knight, Edmundo Murrugara, Amalya Oliver, Alan Paul,
Erika Rick, and Maximo Torero. This paper is a part of the NBER's
research program in Productivity. Any opinions expressed are those of
the authors and not those of UCLA or the NBER.
1. On the former see, for example, Paul M. Romer [1986; 1990], Gene
M. Grossman and Elhanan Helpman [1991], David T. Coe and Helpman [1995],
Coe, Helpman, and Alexander W. Hoffmaister [1997], and Jonathan Eaton
and Samuel Kortum [1994; 1995].
2. Nancy S. Dorfman [1988], Bryan D. Jones and Arnold Vedlitz [1988],
Raymond W. Smilor, George Kozmetsky, and David V. Gibson [1988], Neil
Bania, Randall Eberts, and Michael Fogarty [1993], and James D. Adams
and Jaffe [1994] also indicate geographic localization of knowledge
spillovers. There are, of course, other important sources of geographic
agglomeration (see, for example, Keith Head, John Ries, and Deborah
Swenson [1994]).
3. These firms include both new biotechnology firms formed to exploit
the new technologies and divisions, subsidiaries, or other units of
incumbent finns which adopt the new biotechnology.
4. Philippe Aghion and Jean Tirole [1994] have begun a complementary
research program examining the effects of necessarily incomplete
contracts upon the organization of R&D activities where inventing
employees may opportunistically appropriate successful discoveries. We
note that Stanford and the University of California earned very
substantial amounts of money from the Cohen-Boyer patent on the founding
discovery of biotechnology, but at least one of the discoverers has
realized an order of magnitude higher return on the equity positions
obtained with his knowledge of how to actually apply their discovery.
5. See Griliches [1992, S31-S33] on the pitfalls along the path of
narrowly focussed research.
6. See Tables A.4 and A.5 in Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994] for
more examples.
7. Cohen, Chang, Boyer, and Helling [1973].
8. The other basic technology is cell fusion (also termed monoclonal
antibodies, MABs, or hybridomas) in which lymphocytes are fused with
myeloma cells to create rapidly proliferating antibody-producing cells.
Robert D. Sindelar [1992; 1993] provides a useful introduction to these
applications in the pharmaceutical industry. Sindelar [1992, 3-4] notes
in reference to pharmaceuticals that modern biotechnological techniques
can be divided "into three broad areas. ..." Recombinant DNA
techniques "take identified gene sequences from one organism and
place them functionally into another to permit the production of protein
medicines such as human insulin, alpha interferon, and
colony-stimulating factors. Second, methodologies have been developed
for producing monoclonal antibodies, ultrasensitive immune
system-derived cells designed to recognize specific substances known as
antigens that are uniquely associated with chemicals found in foreign
organisms and/or humans. Developments in this field have led to their
use as diagnostic agents for laboratory and home use in pregnancy tests
and ovulation prediction kits and in the design of site-directed drugs
such as OKT-3 for kidney transplant rejection. Finally, the development
of technologies to study DND-DNA and DNA-RNA interactions has led to the
formation of DNA probes (antisense technology) for a variety of research
purposes with potential uses as diagnostics and therapeutics."
9. In California, a relatively small number of star scientists list
affiliations with a third category of organizations: research institutes
and hospitals. Since these organizations are not generally considered in
studies of geographically localized knowledge spillovers and there are
no significant linkages between their stars and firms, we focus in this
paper exclusively on stars who are located at some time in at least one
California university or firm.
10. The survey is reported in Lyle V. Jones, Gardner Lindzey, and
Porter E. Coggeshall [1982]. The twenty U.S. universities with top-rated
biotech relevant departments included California Institute of
Technology, Stanford, and the University of California campuses at
Berkeley, Los Angeles, San Diego, and San Francisco.
11. This work was funded by a grant to Zucker and Darby for
"Linking California Universities and Scientists to the
Biotechnology Industry" from the University of California
Systemwide Biotechnology Research and Education Program.
12. For Entrez, see U.S. Department of Health and Human Services [1994].
13. Details are described in Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994,
29-30, 55].
14. Most, but not all, of the remainder are located in the Los
Angeles region. The Sacramento (Davis) region is the fourth area with
star scientists.
15. One of these ten stars was affiliated sequentially with two firms
over the period; the other nine stars were each affiliated with only one
firm.
16. Indeed natural excludability has created some problems for making
the "enabling disclosure" that is required for a valid U.S.
patent application. In order to obtain the seventeen-year monopoly
granted by a patent the applicant must make a disclosure that will
enable the public to practice the innovation once the patent expires.
After some litigation and legislation, patents are now obtainable by
biotech inventors who disclose their invention by placing a culture in a
recognized public depositary. (See Rebecca S. Eisenberg [1987] for a
discussion of this history.) Disclosure by deposit eliminates the
inherent difficulty in disclosing the art used to obtain the invention
so that it can be readily replicated.
17. Where natural excludability is entirely absent and the discovery
can be easily incorporated into the human capital of any competent
scientist, the discoverer(s) cannot earn any personal returns - as
opposed to returns to intellectual property such as patents or trade
secrets. In the case of biotechnology, it may be empirically difficult
to separate intellectual human capital from the conceptually distinct
value of cell cultures created and controlled by a scientist who used
his or her nonpublic information to create the cell culture.
18. Clearly the extent to which access to particular localized
individuals shapes the evolution of an industry is positively related to
both the importance of the breakthrough and the degree of natural
excludability. First, there must be the defining technological
opportunity for commercialization but there must also be sufficient
natural excludability to provide appropriability to individuals
personally rather than through mechanisms of intellectual property. Thus
precisely the same factors that drive technical progress for industries
(Nelson and Edward N. Wolff [1992], Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard C.
Levin, Nelson, and Winter [1995]) appear to be crucial at another level
to endowing individuals with the opportunity to exert geographically
localized influence.
19. Coauthorship serves here as a proxy for a variety of more complex
relationships including ownership, employment, consulting, and serving
on a board of directors or scientific advisers. In future research, we
plan to examine some of these other relationships separately using data
from IPO prospectuses for those firms that have gone public (see Lerner
[1995]). This will require expanding the data set to cover the entire
U.S.
20. Dual affiliations of bioscientists are a specific instance of a
very general phenomenon in which individuals with exceptional quality of
performance and productivity compared to others with similar kinds of
skills come to have more than one simultaneous organizational
affiliation (Zucker [1991]). For example, top ranked physicians tend to
have multiple affiliations with hospitals and top producers and
directors are much more likely to have multiple contracts with
independent film companies while others have none (R. R. Faulkner and A.
B. Anderson [1987, Tables 2-4]).
21. For similar internal firm use of external evaluative information,
see Robert Eccles and Dwight Crane [1988, 152-154] on the use of
customer surveys to determine salary increases, bonuses, and promotion
in investment banking.
22. The linked and untied distinction for our university stars may
suggest James D. Thompson's [1967] distinction between
boundary-spanning and core personnel. However, this analogy could prove
misleading since nearly all the university stars have extensive contacts
with organizations other than their own university and those stars who
are actively involved in collaborations with firms typically do so for
their own gain and not as part of their role in the university.
23. In the literature, the norms of science are said to dictate open
disclosure to all other scientists, in an "invisible college"
model of the flow of scientific information (Diana Crane [1972]; Robert
M. Merton [1970, 80-111]). However, as noted in Zucker, Darby, Brewer,
and Peng [1996], whenever the discoveries have significant value,
whether as pure science or as a commercial product, behavior has often
systematically excluded potential competitors from access to that
information (James D. Watson [1980]; G. Taubes [1986]). There is
considerable evidence that this has occurred in bioscience, perhaps
because of a divergence between the norms and the reward structure
(Eisenberg [1987, especially 197-205, 214-216, and 229-231]).
24. See, for example, Mark Blaug [1985, vii-ix], David Colander
[1989], H. P. F. Peters and A. F. J. van Raan [1994], and R. Plomp
[1994].
25. See Griliches [1990] for a review of the use of patent statistics
as economic indicators.
26. As discussed in Jerry Hausman, Bronwyn H. Hall, and Griliches
[1984], the poisson process is the most appropriate statistical model
for count data such as ours. In practice, overdispersion (possibly due
to unobserved heterogeneity) frequently occurs. Given the problems with
resort to the negative binomial discussed by A. Colin Cameron and Pravin
K. Trivedi [1990], Jeffrey M. Wooldridge [1991] developed a flexible and
consistent method (his "Procedure 2.1") for correcting the
poisson variance-covariance matrix estimates regardless of the
underlying relationship between the mean and variance. We are indebted
to Wooldridge and Greene for advice in implementing the procedure in
LIMDEP subsequent to Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994].
27. From an organizational sociology perspective, products in
development is the preferred measure because it is conceptually most
closely related to the R&D function of intellectual human capital.
The extent to which scientific entrepreneurs are able to transfer
intellectual human capital value to the firm and the accuracy with which
that capital is priced in the financial markets is the subject of future
research.
28. For scientists who began publishing by the year the firm entered,
the average lag between its entry and the first tied publication by the
star was 3.0 years - small given the time to establish a new laboratory
and given the prevalence of listing affiliation where the work was done
rather than where one is employed at time of publication. For star
scientists who began publishing after the firm was founded, the average
lag from the star's first publication to the first publication
affiliated or linked with the firm was 2.1 years.
29. These results will be made available upon request to any of the
authors at least through 1999.
30. The number of linked articles is positively and significantly
correlated with the number of affiliated articles, and neither of these
variables are significantly correlated with untied articles.
31. These models are reported in Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong [1994]
but without the Wooldridge correction for the standard errors.
32. Recall that these regressions are run only for the subset of
firms for which employment changes were reported. We also tried
percentage changes in employment with no significant differences in the
qualitative results. We believe the level changes are easier to
interpret and conform more closely to a Type II Tobit model and so
report them here.
33. Nonrivalry implies that use by one person or enterprise does not
reduce the amount available for use by others. Excludability, which
refers to the ability of the owner of a good to prevent others from
using it, can derive from technology, law, or both.
34. See Romer's careful discussion [1990, S74-S75] of the key
distinction between his technology and human capital.
35. The antilog of the regressions in Table II and III (first two
columns) give the expected numbers of products in development and on the
market respectively. The numbers quoted in the text are calculated by
substituting the mean values for the other independent variables from
Table A.2 and comparing the antilog for linked articles = 0, 2, and 5.
The regressions in the last two columns of Table III are linear in
linked articles, so a similar procedure is not required to predict the
employment effects.
36. It should not be entirely surprising that where the holders of
the valuable knowledge are few in number, contracts can be negotiated
which eliminate the effects of potential externalities; see Ronald H.
Coase [1960]. Coase [1974] also observed that economists are overly
prone to assume externalities, as in lighthouses, where market contracts
can in fact exist. Steven N.S. Cheung [1987, 456] notes that Coase
objected to the term The Coase Theorem since "what he did was to
specify the conditions under which the traditional theorem of exchange
becomes operative." This paper aims to show that those conditions
may also apply in the case of what has been considered to be
geographically localized spillovers.
37. See also Zucker, Brewer, Oliver, and Liebeskind [1993]. The rDNA
technology devolved from high to routine science in the late 1980s; so
1990 was a good year to end the literature base for identifying
scientists possessing intellectual human capital.
REFERENCES
Adams, James D., and Adam B. Jaffe. "The Span of the Effect of
R&D in the Firm and Industry." Paper presented at the NBER
Summer Institute on Productivity, Cambridge, Mass., July 28, 1994.
Aghion, Philippe, and Jean Tirole. "The Management of
Innovation." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1994,
1185-209.
Allison, Paul D., J. Scott Long, and Tad K. Krauze. "Cumulative
Advantage and Inequality in Science." American Sociological Review,
October 1982, 615-25.
Amemiya, Takeshi. Advanced Econometrics. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1985.
Arrow, Kenneth J. "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of
Resources for Invention," in The Rate and Direction of Inventive
Activity: Economic and Social Factors, edited by Richard R. Nelson,
N.B.E.R. Special Conference Series. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1962, 609-25.
Arrow, Kenneth J. "The Limits of Organization." New York:
W. W. Norton & Company, 1974.
Balkin, David B., and Luis R. Gomez-Mejia. "Compensation
Practices in High-Technology Industries." Personnel Administrator,
June 1985, 111-23.
Bania, Neil, Randall Eberts, and Michael Fogarty. "Universities
and the Startup of New Companies: Can We Generalize from Route 128 and
Silicon Valley." Review of Economics and Statistics, November 1993,
761-66.
Blaug, Mark. Who's Who in Economics: A Biographical Dictionary of Major Economists, 1700-1986, 2nd ed. Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1985.
Cameron, A. Colin, and Pravin K. Trivedi. "Regression-based
Tests for Overdispersion in the Poisson Model." Journal of
Econometrics, December 1990, 347-64.
Cheung, Steven N. S. "Ronald Harry Coase," in The New
Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, edited by John Eatwell, Murray
Milgate, and Peter Newman, vol. 1. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd.,
1987, 455-57.
Choi, Woon Gyu. "The Discount Rate Policy Reaction Function of
the Monetary Authority: An Application of a Sample Selectivity
Model." Paper presented in the Econometrics Workshop, UCLA
Economics Department, November 2, 1993.
Coase, Ronald H. "The Problem of Social Cost." Journal of
Law and Economics, October 1960, 1-44.
-----. "The Lighthouse in Economics." Journal of Law and
Economics, October 1974, 357-76.
Coe, David T., and Elhanan Helpman. "International R&D
Spillovers." European Economic Review, May 1995, 859-87.
Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander W. Hoffmaister.
"North-South R&D Spillovers." Economic Journal, January
1997, 134-49.
Cohen, Stanley, A. Chang, Herbert Boyer, and R. Helling.
"Construction of Biologically Functional Bacterial Plasmids in
vitro." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, November
1973, 3,240-44.
Colander, David. "Research on the Economics Profession."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1989, 137-48.
Crane, Diana. Invisible Colleges: Diffusion of Knowledge in
Scientific Communities. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1972.
Demsetz, Harold. "The Theory of the Firm Revisited."
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, Spring 1988, 141-61.
Dorfman, Nancy S. "Route 128: The Development of a Regional High
Technology Economy," in The Massachusetts Miracle: High Technology
and Economic Revitalization, edited by David Lampe. Cambridge: MIT
Press, 1988, 240-74.
Dunne, Timothy, Mark J. Roberts, and Larry Samuelson. "The
Growth and Failure of U.S. Manufacturing Plants." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, November 1989, 671-98.
Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. "International Parenting and
Technology Diffusion." National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper No. 4931, 1994.
-----. "Trade in Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in the
OECD." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5049,
1995.
Eccles, Robert G., and Dwight B. Crane. Doing Deals: Investment Banks at Work. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1988.
Eisenberg, Rebecca S. "Proprietary Rights and the Norms of
Science in Biotechnology Research." Yale Law Journal, December
1987, 177-231.
EIkington, John. The Gene Factory. New York: Carroll & Graf
Publishers, Inc., 1985.
Faulkner, R. R., and A. B. Anderson. "Short-term Projects and
Emergent Careers: Evidence from Hollywood." American Journal of
Sociology, January 1987, 879-909.
Greene, William H. LIMDEP: User's Manual and Reference Guide,
Version 6.0. Bellport, N.Y.: Econometric Software, Inc., 1992.
Griliches, Zvi. "Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of
Technological Change." Econometrica, October 1957, 501-22.
-----. "Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A
Survey." Journal of Economic Literature, December 1990, 1,661-707.
-----. "The Search for R&D Spillovers." Scandinavian
Journal of Economics, 1992 Supplement, 29-47.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. Innovation and Growth in the
Global Economy. Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1991.
Hausman, Jerry, Bronwyn H. Hall, and Zvi Griliches. "Econometric
Models for Count Data with an Application to the Patents-R&D
Relationship." Econometrica, July 1984, 909-38.
Head, Keith, John Ries, and Deborah Swenson. "Agglomeration
Benefits and Location Choice: Evidence from Japanese Manufacturing
Investment in the United States." National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 4767, 1994.
Heckman, James. "The Common Structure of Statistical Models of
Truncation, Sample Selection, and Limited Dependent Variables and a
Simple Estimator for Such Models." Annals of Economic and Social
Measurement, Fall 1976, 475-92.
Institute for Scientific Information. Science Citation Index, ISI Compact Disc Editions machine readable data base. Philadelphia:
Institute for Scientific Information, various years through 1993.
Jaffe, Adam B. "Real Effects of Academic Research."
American Economic Review, December 1989, 957-70.
Jaffe, Adam B., Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson.
"Geographic Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by
Patent Citations." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1993,
577-98.
Jones, Bryan D., and Arnold Vedlitz. "Higher Education Policies
and Economic Growth in the American States." Economic Development
Quarterly, February 1988, 78-87.
Jones, Lyle V., Gardner Lindzey, and Porter E. Coggeshall, eds., An
Assessment of Research-Doctorate Programs in the United States:
Biological Sciences. Washington: National Academy Press, 1982.
Klein, Benjamin, Robert Crawford, and Armen Alchian. "Vertical
Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting
Process." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1978, 297-326.
Klevorick, Alvin K., Richard C. Levin, Richard R. Nelson, and Sidney
G. Winter. "On the Sources and Significance of Interindustry
Differences in Technological Opportunities." Research Policy, March
1995, 185-205.
Kogut, Bruce, Gordon Walker, Weijian Shah, and Dong-Jae Kim.
"Platform Technologies and National Industrial Networks," in
Technical Change and the World Economy, edited by John Hagedoorn. Hants,
U.K.: Edward Elgar, 1994, 58-82.
Lerner, Joshua. "Venture Capitalists and the Oversight of
Private Firms." Journal of Finance, March 1995, 301-18.
Levin, Richard C. "The Semiconductor Industry," in
Government and Technological Progress: A Cross-Industry Analysis, edited
by Richard R. Nelson. New York: Pergamon Press, 1982, 9-100.
Lieberman, Marvin B. "A Literature Citation Study of
Science-Technology Coupling in Electronics." Proceedings of the
IEEE, January 1978, 5-13.
Liebeskind, Julia Porter, Amalya Lumerman Oliver, Lynne G. Zucker,
and Marilynn B. Brewer. "Social Networks, Learning, and
Flexibility: Sourcing Scientific Knowledge in New Biotechnology
Firms." Organization Science, July/August 1996, 428-43.
Mansfield, Edwin. "Academic Research Underlying Industrial
Innovations: Sources, Characteristics, and Financing." Review of
Economics and Statistics, February 1995, 55-65.
Merton, Robert K. Science, Technology and Society in
Seventeenth-Century England. New York: Howard Fertig, 1970.
Nelson, Richard R. "The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific
Research." Journal of Political Economy, June 1959, 297-306.
Nelson, Richard R., and Sidney G. Winter. An Evolutionary Theory of
Economic Change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1982.
Nelson, Richard R., and Edward N. Wolff. "Factors behind
Cross-Industry Differences in Technical Progress." New York
University Reports 92-27, June 1992.
Peters, H. P. F., and A. F. J. van Raan. "A Bibliometric Profile
of Top-Scientists: A Case Study in Chemical Engineering."
Scientometrics, 29(1), 1994, 115-136.
Plomp, R. "The Highly Cited Papers of Professors as an Indicator
of a Research Group's Scientific Performance." Scientometrics,
29(3), 1994, 377-393.
Romer, Paul M. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth."
Journal of Political Economy, October 1986, 1,002-37.
-----. "Endogenous Technological Change." Journal of
Political Economy, 1990 Supplement, S71-S102.
Rosen, Sherwin. "The Economics of Superstars." American
Economic Review, December 1981, 845-58.
Rosenberg, Nathan. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982.
Ryu, Keunkwan. "Modified Heckman's Two-Step Estimation and
Specification Test in Sample Selectivity Models." Working Paper,
UCLA Economics Department, 1993.
Sindelar, Robert D. "Overview/Preview of Current and Future
Recombinant DNA-Produced Pharmaceuticals." Drug Topics, April 20,
1992, Supplement, 3-16.
-----. "The Pharmacy of the Future." Drug Topics, May 21,
1993, 66-84.
Smilor, Raymond W., George Kozmetsky, and David V. Gibson. Creating
the Technopolis: Linking Technology, Commercialization, and Economic
Development. Cambridge: Ballinger Publishing Co., 1988.
Taubes, G. Nobel Dreams. Power, Deceit and the Ultimate Experiment.
New York: Random House, 1986.
Thompson, James D. Organizations in Action. New York: McGraw-Hill,
1967.
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, National Center for
Biotechnology Information Entrez: Sequences and Entrez: References,
Release 9.0, machine readable data base. Bethesda, Md.: National Library
of Medicine, National Institutes of Health, February 15, 1994.
Watson, James D. The Double Helix: A Personal Account of the
Discovery of the Structure of DNA, New York: Norton, 1968.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. "On the Application of Robust,
Regression-based Diagnostics to Models of Conditional Means and
Conditional Variances." Journal of Econometrics, January 1991,
5-46.
Zucker, Lynne G. "Markets for Bureaucratic Authority and
Control: Information Quality in Professions and Services." Research
in the Sociology of Organizations, 1991, 157-89.
Zucker, Lynne G., Marilynn B. Brewer, Amalya Oliver, and Julia
Liebeskind. "Basic Science as Intellectual Capital in Firms:
Information Dilemmas in rDNA Biotechnology Research." Working
Paper, UCLA Institute for Social Science Research, 1993.
Zucker, Lynne G., and Michael R. Darby. "Present at the
Revolution: Transformation of Technical Identity for a Large Incumbent
Pharmaceutical Firm after the Biotechnological Breakthrough."
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5243, 1995.
-----. "Star Scientists and Institutional Transformation:
Patterns of Invention and Innovation in the Formation of the
Biotechnology Industry." Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, November 12, 1996, 12,709-16.
Zucker, Lynne G., Michael R. Darby, and Jeff Armstrong.
"Intellectual Capital and the Firm: The Technology of
Geographically Localized Knowledge Spillovers." National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 4946, 1994.
Zucker, Lynne G., Michael R. Darby, and Marilynn B. Brewer.
"Intellectual Capital and the Birth of U.S. Biotechnology
Enterprises." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 4653, 1994.
-----. "Intellectual Human Capital and the Birth of U.S.
Biotechnology Enterprises." American Economic Review, June 1997, in
press.
Zucker, Lynne G., Michael R. Darby, Marilynn B. Brewer, and Yusheng
Peng. "Collaboration Structure and Information Dilemmas in
Biotechnology: Organizational Boundaries as Trust Production," in
Trust in Organizations, edited by Roderick M. Kramer and Tom R. Tyler.
Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage, 1996, 90-113.
Zuckerman, Harriet. "Nobel Laureates in Science: Patterns of
Productivity, Collaboration, and Authorship." American Sociological
Review, June 1967, 391-403.
Zucker: Professor, Department of Sociology and Policy Studies,
University of California, Los Angeles, and Research Associate, NBER,
Phone 1-310-825-9155, Fax 1-310-206-4453 E-mail
zucker@soc.sscnet.ucla.edu
Darby: Warren C. Cordnet Professor of Money and Financial Markets,
Anderson School, and Departments of Economics and Policy Studies,
University of California, Los Angeles, and Research Associate, NBER
Phone 1-310-825-4180, Fax 1-310-454-2748 E-mail
michael.darby@anderson.ucla.edu
Armstrong: Visiting Professor, Faculty of Economics Thammasat
University, Bangkok, Thailand Phone 1-662-221-6111 x6401, Fax
1-662-224-9428 E-mail sparky@econ3.tu.ac.th