Computers, productivity, and input substitution.
Stiroh, Kevin J.
I. INTRODUCTION
The last two decades has been a puzzling time for many productivity
analysts. While computer prices fell at extraordinary rates and firms
invested hundreds of billions of dollars in new computer equipment,
aggregate productivity growth remained sluggish. This "computer
productivity paradox" has generated a large literature that
examines the economic impact of the computer revolution.(1)
This paper offers a simple solution to the computer productivity
paradox by making careful distinction between computers as an output
from one sector and an input to other sectors. Data for 35 manufacturing
and service sectors for 1947-1991 show that sectoral differences are
crucial in understanding the impact of computers. Aggregate analysis is
inappropriate since it obscures basic distinctions between a shifting
production function in the computer-producing sector (multi-factor
productivity growth) and movements along production functions in the
computer-using sectors (substitution and capital accumulation). Once
these differences are isolated, the growth impact of computers is
readily observable.
The computer-producing sector experienced fundamental technological
progress and now produces cheaper, better computers. The sectoral data
show this as rapid Multi-Factor Productivity (MFP) growth for 1973-1991.
Although aggregate MFP growth remains below historic averages, the
computer-producing sector has clearly done its part - MFP growth in this
sector is many times the economy average and has contributed over
one-third of aggregate MFP growth for 19811991. The sectoral detail
shows that the slowdown in aggregate productivity would have been much
more severe were it not for such large MFP gains in the
computer-producing sector.
For the other sectors of the economy, computers affect growth in a
more traditional, although less glamorous, way. When the price of real
computing power fell so dramatically in the 1970s and 1980s, firms
responded by substituting away from relatively expensive labor and
non-computer capital and investing heavily in cheap computers. For these
sectors, the computer revolution affects output growth not by raising
MFP, but by inducing firms to accumulate computers at extraordinary
rates. Real computer services, for example, grew in excess of 20% per
year in 14 out of 35 sectors for 1973-1991.
Although virtually all sectors are rapidly accumulating computer
equipment, computers remain small in levels. In 1991, for example,
computer investment was only 10% of private fixed investment so the
growth contribution of computers remains small relative to sectoral
aggregates of labor and non-computer capital. The rapid rates of
accumulation, however, are clearly making computers a more important
source of growth across sectors.
With this heavy investment also came the wide-spread expectation that
computers would fundamentally alter the way firms operate and lead to
higher MFP. The reality has been very different as the most
computer-intensive sectors show steep declines in MFP growth after 1973.
With three-quarters of all computers concentrated in three service
sectors (Trade, FIRE, and Other Services), however, this finding must be
interpreted with caution. As Griliches [1994] notes, output in these
sectors is largely "unmeasurable" and thus MFP growth will be
understated.
Nonetheless, it is quite reasonable that even computer-using sectors
where output is easier to measure show no MFP gains. Computer investment
creates a capital input that enters the production function like any
other purchased input. Since constant-quality deflators embody
productivity improvements in investment, the direct impact is seen
through the rapid capital accumulation. Only if the adoption of
computers leads to production externalities or spillovers would computer
investment also increase MFP growth. The data, however, show no evidence
of this.
II. COMPUTERS AND GROWTH
The national statistics most clearly show the computer revolution in
the investment data. Over the last three decades, real computer
investment increased from $0.1 billion in 1958 to $51 billion in 1991
and the price of computer investment fell 20% per year.(2) The
literature on the computer productivity paradox questions why such a
large increase in the quality and quantity of computers has not been
manifest in the aggregate statistics, particularly productivity.
Possible explanations for this puzzle include measurement errors, the
small relative size of computers, realloaction of output, long learning
lags, and market frictions.
It is not clear, however, that improved computers should dramatically
improve aggregate MFP or even MFP in a typical sector. The fundamental
technological change, e.g., more memory or Millions of Instructions Per
Second (MIPS) per dollar of inputs, occurred in the computer-producing
sector. Even if this sectoral MFP growth is measured correctly, the
increase in aggregate MFP growth may be relatively small due to the
small size of the sector. After all, gross output in the
computer-producing sector was only 5% of aggregate value-added in 1991.
Computer-using sectors, on the other hand, take advantage of the
technology-induced price declines and substitute towards the relatively
cheap computer. In a strict sense, this input substitution induces firms
to move along a given production isoquant but does not shift the
production function or increase MFP.(3) The substitution towards
computers increases the growth contribution of capital for both the
computer-using sectors and in the aggregate. Since the constant-quality
deflators embody the improvements in computers in new investment, growth
is attributed to capital accumulation and not to MFP gains.
One could argue that computer investment would increase MFP growth in
the computer-using sectors, but these explanations typically lie outside
of the traditional neoclassical framework of Solow [1957] or Jorgenson
[1990]. For example, a production spillover from computer investment in
one sector could allow faster growth in another sector. Alternatively,
if investment prices do not fully reflect quality improvements, then
real investment and capital input will be under-measured. In both eases,
computer investment increases measured MFP, but each example requires a
specific departure from the neoclassical model. The importance of these
non-traditional effects is an empirical question that is examined in
Section III.
Given the small size of the computer-producing sector and this input
substitution story, there may not be a computer productivity paradox.
The computer-producing sector experiences technological growth but is
small and might not significantly impact aggregate MFP growth. The
computer-using sectors substitute towards relatively cheap computers and
the growth contribution of capital increases. The remainder of this
section provides empirical estimates of these effects.
Data
The fundamental analysis of this paper is growth accounting at the
sectoral level. To accomplish this, the widely circulated dataset of
Jorgenson, Gollop and Fraumeni [1987] was updated through 1991. This
dataset includes a complete set of input-output accounts and Gross
Output production functions for 35 roughly 2-digit SIC sectors that
comprise the private, domestic U.S. economy. See Jorgenson et al. [1987]
for definitions and data sources.
Since the data come from many sources that are at different levels of
aggregation, data constraints in large part determine the level of
disaggregation. For example, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)
estimates Gross Output for 183 detailed industries, the Bureau of
Economic Analysis (BEA) estimates investment flows for 51 assets for 61
industries and BEA estimates Gross Product Originating (Value-Added) for
88 industries and aggregates. While a more detailed disaggregation would
be desirable, particularly for the service sectors, data constraints
make this impractical.
BEA includes computer investment in its asset class called
"Office, Computing and Accounting Machinery (OCAM)." OCAM is
composed primarily of computer equipment and serves as the measure of
computer investment and capital throughout the paper. Each computer
component of OCAM, e.g., personal computers, mainframes, displays, and
printers, is separately deflated with a constant-quality price index to
account for the large quality improvements.
To show the relative magnitude of each of the 35 sectors, Table I
breaks down 1991 private, business Value-Added into the 35 component
sectors.(4) The table also shows each sector's share of aggregate
Value-Added, non-OCAM capital income, OCAM capital income and labor
income.
Aggregate Results
The data is first aggregated across sectors and, under the
assumptions of constant returns to scale and perfect competition,
aggregate output growth can be decomposed as:
(1) [Delta]Q = [[Alpha].sub.1] *[Delta][K.sub.1] + [[Alpha].sub.2] *
[Delta][K.sub.2]
+(1 - [[Alpha].sub.1] - [[Alpha].sub.2]) * [Delta]L + [v.sub.T]
where a [Delta] before a variable represents a rate of change, Q is
aggregate real output, [K.sub.1] is the flow of non-OCAM capital
services, [K.sub.2] is the flow of OCAM capital services, L is labor
input, [[Alpha].sub.1] is the share of non-OCAM capital income in
nominal output, [[Alpha].sub.2] is the share of OCAM capital in nominal
output, and [v.sub.T] is the growth rate of multi-factor productivity
(MFP) or the Solow residual. Time subscripts have been suppressed.(5)
Table II breaks down aggregate output growth into the contribution of
capital (both non-OCAM and OCAM), the contribution of labor and the
growth rate of MFP. The results are familiar - labor and capital make
roughly equal contributions to growth, the contribution of labor has
increased since 1973, and both output and MFP growth have slowed since
1973.
OCAM capital contributes 0.15 percentage points to aggregate growth
for 1973-1991 due to the large average growth rate ([Delta][K.sub.2] =
20.44%) [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] but small weight
([[Alpha].sub.2] = 0.74%). Despite averaging only 2.4% of all capital
services, this exceptional growth rate allowed OCAM capital to
contribute 16% of capital's entire contribution to aggregate
growth. Given their small relative size, computers are making an
impressive contribution to aggregate economic growth.(6)
TABLE II
Sources of Aggregate Growth
1947-1973 1973-1991 1947-1991
Value-Added 3.754 2.195 3.116
Contribution of Capital 1.133 0.959 1.061
Non-OCAM 1.107 0.807 0.984
OCAM 0.026 0.152 0.077
Contribution of Labor 1.050 1.138 1.086
Productivity 1.571 0.098 0.969
Contribution of an input is the average share-weighted growth rate.
Since all input series are quality-adjusted, the rapid accumulation
of more productive computers increases the contribution of capital but
does not directly impact MFP growth. MFP growth reflects only those
factors, e.g., disembodied technical change, reduced inefficiency,
returns to scale, or new production techniques, that are not embodied in
the quality-adjusted capital and labor series. Thus, it is entirely
consistent that the computer revolution is characterized by rapid
capital accumulation but slow MFP growth at the aggregate level.
Sectoral Framework
The aggregate analyses done by Oliner and Sichel [1994] and above
show that computers are a small source of growth in an absolute sense
but a large source of growth relative to their size. More importantly,
the growth contribution of computers is definitely increasing even at
the aggregate level.
Aggregate growth accounting, however, misses important details in the
relationship between computers and growth. Since computers have a
different impact across sectors, one needs to analyze the sources of
growth at a sectoral level. This type of sectoral approach has three
distinct advantages over the aggregate analyses of Oliner and Sichel
[1994] and above.
First, one can directly examine the fundamental technological change
in the computer-producing sector. Since technology is the driving force
behind the computer revolution, it is important to measure and quantify
this. Second, one can isolate computer-using sectors and pinpoint where
the accumulation of computers is concentrated and where computers are
having the largest growth impact. Third, one can compare the
accumulation of computer capital to MFP growth in each sector and search
for production spillovers from computers. It is impossible to identify
any of these effects with aggregate data.
The sectoral analog to equation (1) is based on a Gross Output
production function that can be written as(7)
(2) [Delta][Y.sub.n] = [[Alpha].sub.K, 1, n] *[Delta][K.sub.1, n] +
[[Alpha].sub.K, 2, n] *[Delta][K.sub.2, n]
+ [[Alpha].sub.L, n] *[L.sub.n] + [[Alpha].sub.E, n]
*[Delta][E.sub.n] + [[Alpha].sub.M, n] *[Delta][M.sub.n]
*[Delta][M.sub.n] + [v.sub.T, n],
[[Alpha].sub.K, 1, n] + [[Alpha].sub.K, 2, n] + [[Alpha].sub.L, n] +
[[Alpha].sub.E, n] + [[Alpha].sub.M, n] = 1
n = 1...35
where [Y.sub.n] is Gross Output, [E.sub.n] is energy intermediate
inputs, [M.sub.n] is material intermediate inputs, [Alpha] is the
nominal share of the subscripted variable in Gross Output and [v.sub.T,
n] is the MFP growth rate, all for sector n. Table III shows the 1991
nominal shares of each input in Gross Output and Value-Added for each of
the 35 sectors. As a comparison, median and weighted average input
shares are also reported.(8)
Equation (2) is used to measure the sources of growth for each of the
35 sectors and Table IV presents sectoral growth accounts for three time
periods - 1947-1973, 1973-1991, and 1947-1991. The sectors of particular
interest are the computer-producing sector (identified by *) and the
computer-using sectors (identified by **).
Baily and Gordon [1988] also take a sectoral approach and present a
detailed analysis of Average Labor Productivity (ALP) at the sectoral
level from 1948 to 1987. Several important differences, however,
distinguish this paper from Baily and Gordon.
The most important distinction is the focus on MFP rather than on
ALP. The complete input-output analysis allows the growth contribution
of computer capital services, [[Alpha].sub.K, 2, n] *[Delta][K.sub.2,
n], to be isolated from the contribution of other inputs and MFP growth.
Moreover, by explicitly estimating capital service prices from
quality-adjusted deflators, the capital indices incorporate quality
change and substitution between heterogeneous types of capital.
Baily and Gordon [1988] cite the lack of data on capital input by
industry and estimate the following relationship
(3) [Delta]ALP = [Delta]Q - [Delta]L
where [Delta]ALP is the growth rate of average labor productivity,
[Delta]Q is the growth rate in output, and [Delta]L is the growth rate
of labor input.
Since ALP increases with the accumulation of all inputs as well as
MFP growth, it is impossible to isolate and quantify the separate
influences of the accumulation of computer capital, other purchased
inputs, technology or spillovers from equation (3). Economic theory
predicts that the rapid price decline in computing power will induce
firms to substitute towards computers and away from other inputs, so
this is an important limitation in the ALP framework.
A related difference is the use of a Gross Output production function
that includes all productive inputs - capital, labor and intermediate
goods - as opposed to the value-added approach in Baily and Gordon
[1988]. Basu and Fernald [1995] show that value-added data can lead to
misspecification and biased estimates of MFP since Gross Output is the
fundamental model of production. Firms in fact use capital, labor,
energy and material inputs to produce goods and services, while
Value-Added simply measures each firm's contribution to GDP.(9)
A final difference is simply the later time period. Baily and Gordon
[1988] present data by sector and estimate the share of the computer
capital stock through 1987. Computer technology has changed dramatically
since 1987 as constant-quality prices continued to fall, quality
improved and personal computers became the dominant form of computer
investment.
The Computer-Producing Sector
The production of computers takes place in the Census industry
"computer and office equipment" (SIC #357) and is included in
the broader "Non-Electrical Machinery" sector (SIC #35). After
computers were introduced into the national accounts in 1958, the
composition of this sector changed dramatically [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE
III OMITTED] [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED] with the share of
computers rising from near zero in 1958 to 33% in 1991. Other forms of
more traditional industrial equipment, e.g., "construction and
related machinery" and "metalworking machinery," declined
in share reflecting the changing structure of the U.S. economy away from
manufacturing and towards services.
The growth accounts for the computer-producing sector (Non-Electrical
Machinery), identified by * in Table IV on page 183, show rapid
acceleration in MFP growth from 0.21% a year for 1947-1973 to 1.42% a
year for 1973-1991. More than half of the 2.63% annual growth in gross
output was due to increased MFP growth for 1973-1991.
For the more recent period of 1981-1991, the results are even more
striking. While output growth remained constant at 2.63% per year, the
average growth rate of MFP jumped to 2.69% and all inputs except capital
actually shrunk.(10) During the 1980s, virtually all output growth in
the computer-producing sector was due to technological progress. When
the recession year of 1991 is excluded, the average rate of MFP growth
rises to 3.05%.
It may be hard to cleanly interpret these results due to the broad
definition of the sector. The computer-producing sector is an aggregate
that includes the production of many types of machinery from several
industries and the "computer and office equipment" industry
accounted for at most one-third of production in the sector. While
labor, energy and material may be shrinking for the entire sector, for
example, it seems unlikely that inputs to the "computer and office
equipment" industry are declining. Rather, the composition of the
sector is changing from production of heavy equipment that is material
and labor intensive to the production of computers that is OCAM-capital
intensive and experiencing rapid technological progress.
To form a rough estimate for the growth of MFP in just the
"computer and office equipment" industry (SIC #357), one can
turn to the dual price problem. For 1973-1991, output in the
"computer and office equipment" industry experienced an annual
price decline of 6.4% and averaged a 20% nominal share of the sector.
Interpreting the 6.4% price decline entirely as MFP growth, assuming no
other technology advances and applying the one-fifth weight gives a
back-of-the-envelope estimate of MFP at 1.26% a year for the sector.
This is consistent with the estimated rate of MFP growth of 1.42% per
year for the Non-Electrical Machinery sector.
For the period for 1981-1991, the average price decline is 12.0% and
the share is about 25% which implies a rate of MFP growth of 3.0%.
Again, this is close to the estimates from the growth accounts. This
suggests that the annual growth of MFP in the "computer and office
equipment" industry is a remarkable 6% to 12% for the past 20
years.
While the computer-producing sector experienced such strong MFP
growth, the aggregate economy was in the midst of the much-publicized
productivity slowdown. Aggregate MFP growth across the 35 sectors, for
example, fell from 1.57% per year for 1947-1973 to 0.10% for 1973-1991.
There was a modest MFP revival in the 1980s, especially in
manufacturing, but the aggregate MFP growth of 0.43% per year for
1981-1991 remained far below the 2.69% in the computer-producing sector.
A sectoral decomposition shows that, when one accounts for the
relative size, 0.16 percentage points of the aggregate MFP growth for
1981-1991 is due to MFP growth in the computer-producing sector.(11)
Although MFP growth was extraordinary in this sector, the small size of
the sector keeps this contribution small in an absolute sense. When
compared to the other sectors, however, the computer-producing sector is
clearly making a substantial contribution to aggregate MFP growth as
more than one-third of aggregate MFP growth in the 1980s was from the
computer-producing sector alone.(12)
The Computer-Using Sectors
To examine the impact of OCAM as a capital input, sectors are labeled
"computer-using" if the nominal value of OCAM capital services
exceeds 4.0% of total capital services in 1991.13 Eight sectors meet
this classification - Printing and Publishing, Stone, Clay and Glass,
Non-Electrical Machinery, Electrical Machinery, Instruments, Trade, FIRE
and Other Services - and are identified by ** in Table IV.(14)
These computer-using sectors account for 88% of all OCAM capital
services and just three sectors - Trade, FIRE and Other Services -
account for nearly 77% of all OCAM services. While the computer
revolution may appear to be everywhere, computers are actually highly
concentrated in only a few sectors. These computer-using sectors account
for 63% of total value-added in the private economy and are the sectors
where one would expect to find computers, but it is interesting to note
that computers play a very small role in the production of more than
one-third of private GDP.
The first step is to compare the growth contribution of OCAM for
1947-1973 to 19731991. All eight computer-using sectors show large
increases in the growth contribution of OCAM capital. While this
reflects the selection criteria, all sectors show that OCAM capital
became a much more important source of growth. The contribution is not
always large in an absolute sense, but computers are clearly increasing
as a source of growth.
Table IV also shows substantial substitution between inputs in these
computer-using sectors. As the contribution of OCAM increased in the
1970s and 1980s, the growth rate of output fell for all eight sectors
and the contribution of other inputs generally declined. Only Printing
and Publishing and Instruments showed an increase in the contribution of
more than one input besides OCAM capital. If computers are growing
rapidly while the growth of output and other inputs is slowing, the
sectors must be rapidly substituting towards computers.
The substitution towards OCAM capital was not limited to only the
eight computer-using sectors. Out of 35 sectors, only two - Apparel and
Coal Mining - showed decreases in the growth contribution of OCAM
capital. The Petroleum and Gas, Paper, Primary Metals, Fabricated Metals, Motor Vehicles, Miscellaneous Manufacturing, Transportation,
Communication and Gas Utilities sectors all showed large increases in
the growth contribution of OCAM capital and declines from non-OCAM
capital. This contribution is sometimes small, but these sectors clearly
substituted towards the relatively cheap OCAM capital.
Table V decomposes the growth contribution of OCAM into the nominal
share and the growth rate for 1947-1973 and 1973-1991. The results
suggests that rapid accumulation of computers is perhaps the defining
characteristic of the computer revolution. With 14 sectors showing
growth rates of OCAM in excess 20% for 1973-1991, computers are
definitely making an impact. Since the largest sectors accumulated OCAM
capital most quickly, the aggregate growth rate of OCAM capital was a
very rapid 20.44% per year for 1973-1991.
As a caveat, these growth accounting results may understate the
impact of computers for several reasons. The computer-producing sector
sells computer equipment to other sectors in two ways. Computers are an
investment good, which is directly accounted for in the OCAM capital
services, but computers are also an intermediate good that is included
in [M.sub.n]. In 1991, 43% of gross output from the computer-producing
sector was sold as investment goods and 47% was sold as intermediate
goods, e.g., computers installed in airplanes or embedded in factory
machines.(15) This channel is not explored here, but preliminary
evidence suggests that intermediate purchases of computers are
important.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE V OMITTED]
A second reason is that OCAM only includes computers in the literal
sense, e.g., mainframe processors, displays, printers, storage devices,
and personal computers. Other high-tech goods such as communications,
scientific or photocopy equipment embody much the same technology as
traditional computers, but are not examined here. According to BEA
[1993], investment in computer equipment is only 37.7% of 1991 real
investment in "information processing and related equipment."
This suggests that the analysis understates the impact of the advances
in information technology.
III. SECTORAL MFP AND COMPUTERS
This section examines the relationship between OCAM investment and
MFP growth. Casual inspection shows the perhaps surprising result of a
negative relationship between OCAM and MFP growth. For most
computer-using sectors, the average growth rate of MFP fell while OCAM
capital grew. The large literature on the computer productivity paradox
is motivated by previous findings of this type, e.g., Baily and Gordon
[1988] and Berndt and Morrison [1995, 1991].
According to the input substitution story sketched and documented in
Section II, however, the direct impact of the computer revolution for
most sectors is faster accumulation, substitution, and an increased
growth contribution from computers. New products that are only possible
with cheap computer power, e.g., complex derivatives in the finance
sector, are directly attributable to the services from computers. This
increases the contribution of capital services but not MFP growth in the
computer-using sector.
There is no a priori reason to expect faster MFP growth in the
computer-using sectors if firms are simply substituting one input for
another or getting new output from new capital. MFP growth increases
only if more output can be produced from the same inputs, i.e., a shift
in the production function. For example, a positive production spillover
from computer investment would lead to faster MFP growth in the
computer-using sectors. Previous evidence for this, however, is mixed.
Bresnahan [1986] finds evidence of positive down-stream spillovers
for computer-users, Griliches and Siegel [1992] show a positive
correlation between MFP growth and computer investment for 4-digit
manufacturing industries, Lichtenberg [1993] finds excess returns to
computer capital and labor using firm data, Brynjolfsson and Hitt [1994]
find excess returns to computer investment, Bartelsman, Caballero and
Lyons [1994] find a long-run relationship between industry productivity
and suppliers that could represent "technological linkages,"
and Bresnahan and Trajtenberg [1995] provide a theoretical model where
innovation leads to downstream spillovers. This evidence suggests that
computers may have a non-traditional impact on growth.
It is not obvious, however, that these effects are really production
spillovers. The Bresnahan [1986, 742] study, for example, deals with
"improved products whose prices do not fully reflect their enhanced
downstream value." This is not MFP in the conventional sense, i.e.,
more output from the same inputs. Rather, this is a problem of
mismeasurement where downstream users receive a windfall gain due to
incorrect pricing. As Griliches [1991, 13] states, these "are not
real knowledge spillovers. They are just consequences of conventional
measurement problems." The same criticism applies to Bartelsman et
al. [1994, 1083] who hypothesize that the linkage could reflect
"unpriced specialization/quality."
On the other hand, some evidence suggests that computers have no
impact on productivity. Baily and Gordon [1988] show that
computer-intensive industries have experienced weak ALP growth. In a
series of papers by Berndt and Morrison [1995, 1991] and Berndt,
Morrison and Rosenblum [1992], the authors find evidence of
over-investment in high-tech equipment, i.e., marginal costs of
high-tech equipment exceed marginal benefits, and a negative correlation between hightech capital intensity and both MFP and ALP for 2-digit
manufacturing industries.
To examine the relationship between computers and MFP, the following
cross-sectional regressions were estimated
(5) [Delta]MF[P.sub.n] = [Alpha] + [[Beta].sub.1][Delta][K.sub.2, n]
+ [[Epsilon].sub.n]
(6) [Delta]MF[P.sub.n] = [Alpha] + [[Beta].sub.1][Delta]([K.sub.2,
n]/[K.sub.n]) + [[Epsilon].sub.n]
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE VI OMITTED] where [Delta] represent the
average growth rate of each variable for either 1947-1991 or 1973 -
1991. MF[P.sub.n] is multi-factor productivity, [K.sub.2, n] is the flow
of OCAM services and [K.sub.n] is flow of total capital services, all
for sector n.(16)
The results in Table VI support the growth accounting results, Baily
and Gordon [1988] and Berndt and Morrison [1995] as the data show little
relationship between OCAM growth and MFP growth. This is true if OCAM
growth is measured as the quantity of OCAM capital services, the share
of OCAM capital in total capital services, if the recession year of 1991
is excluded, or if the service sectors are excluded.
A concern regarding results of this type is that computer investment
is highly concentrated in the sectors where output is particularly hard
to measure. Griliches [1994, 11] argues that the "computer
paradox" may be due to the difficulty in measuring output in the
computer-intensive service sectors. Since MFP growth is precisely the
difference between measured output growth and measured input
contributions, any unmeasured output directly biases MFP growth
downward. With 77% of all OCAM services concentrated in three service
sectors where output is notoriously hard to measure (Trade, FIRE, and
Other Services), mismeasurement of service output probably contributes
to the weak findings.(17) Berndt and Morrison [1995, 1991], however,
find similar results for only manufacturing industries and these results
are qualitatively similar when the service sectors are excluded.
Potential errors in measuring output do not, however, change the main
conclusion of large substitution towards computers. As the relative
price of computing power falls, firms are purchasing more computers and
relatively less of other inputs. Since primary input growth is measured
independently of output growth, input substitution and changes in the
growth contribution of the inputs is not subject to the same downward
biases as the measurement of MFP growth. Even if output and MFP are
poorly measured, sectors are clearly substituting towards relatively
cheap computer capital and rapidly accumulating computers.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
This paper explores the relationship between computers and economic
growth at both the aggregate and sectoral level. The data show that the
rapid technological advances in the production of computers have
translated into higher multi-factor productivity for the
computer-producing sector, substantially contributed to aggregate
multi-factor productivity growth, and led to a large substitution
towards computers as an input for computer-using sectors.
The analysis focuses on private, business investment in OCAM and the
direct growth impact from investment and accumulation of computer
capital. A more broadly defined measure of computer technology could
include spending on inputs that are complements to computers such as
software, computers as intermediate inputs, or the purchase of other
high-tech equipment that embodies much the same technology as computers.
By narrowing the focus to just computer investment and capital, the
results highlight the substitution towards computers as an input but
likely underestimate the true impact of the computer revolution on
economic growth.
Nonetheless, these results show that computers have made a clear and
increasing contribution to economic growth. The contribution of computer
capital to aggregate output growth increased from 0.03 percentage points
per year for 1947-1973 to 0.19 percentage points for 1981-1991.
Similarly, the contribution of the computer-producing sector to
aggregate multi-factor productivity growth increased from 0.01
percentage points to 0.16 percentage points for the same periods.
Perhaps more importantly, many sectors are taking advantage of the lower
price of computer services and substituting towards computers as a
production input.
As a final point, the massive price declines and related computer
investment have continued since 1991. According to BEA [1995], the price
of new computer equipment fell 16% a year from 1991 to 1994 and real
computer investment increased 30% a year. Businesses are still investing
heavily in computer equipment and taking advantage of the relative price
decline. As firms continue to substitute towards cheap computers,
computers will become an increasingly important source of U.S. economic
growth.
APPENDIX
A production function shows how a given technology transforms a flow
of inputs into a flow of outputs. To estimate a production function, one
needs an estimate of the flow of real productive services from capital
and not a measure of the existing capital stock. This conceptual
distinction goes back at least as far as Solow [1957] and has been
empirically implemented in many growth accounting studies such as
Jorgenson [1990], BEA [1992], and Oliner and Sichel [1994]. This section
outlines the methodology used to estimate the flow of capital services.
The real capital stock, [A.sub.n, i, t] for each sector n for each
asset i at time t is calculated with BEA constant dollar investment data
via the "perpetual inventory method" as
(A 1) [A.sub.n, i, t] = (1 - [[Delta].sub.i])*[A.sub.n, i, t - 1] +
[I.sub.n, i, t]
where [[Delta].sub.i] is depreciation and [I.sub.n, i, t] is
investment, all in sector n = 1...35 for asset i = 1...51 at time t =
1948...1991. The BEA investment series actually begin in 1929, so the
initial capital stock for each sector for each asset, [A.sub.n, i,
1947], is estimated using a perpetual inventory from 1929 to 1947
assuming the capital stock begins at zero in 1929. [[Delta].sub.i] is
assumed constant across sectors and taken from Hulten and Wykoff [1981].
From the acquisition prices of new investment, [P.sub.A, n, i, t],
one can calculate the user-cost of capital, [P.sub.K, n, i, t],
according to a user-cost of capital formula
as
(A2) [P.sub.K, n, i, t] = [P.sub.A, n, i, t - 1] *[r.sub.t] +
[P.sub.A, n, i, t]
*[[Delta].sub.i] - ([P.sub.A, n, i, t - 1] *[r.sub.t] + [P.sub.A,
n, i, t]
where [r.sub.t] is the discount rate.
The user-cost of capital is the rental price of capital. In
equilibrium, the rental price equals the opportunity cost of investment
plus economic depreciation less capital gains. This expression is
adjusted for tax factors - the investment tax credit, capital gains and
capital consumption allowances - using tax parameters as in Jorgenson
and Yun [1989].
At the level of the individual asset, the flow of real capital
services, [K.sub.n, i, t] is assumed proportional to the lagged stock of
assets, [A.sub.n, i, t - 1]. The flow of total capital services,
[K.sub.n, t], is a Divisia quantity index of the 51 heterogeneous assets
as
(A3) ln([K.sub.n, t]) - ln([K.sub.n, t - 1])
[summation of (ln([K.sub.n, i, t])] where i = 1 to 51 - ln([K.sub.n,
i, t - 1]))*[v.sub.n, i, t]
where [v.sub.n, i, t] is equal to the average share of nominal
capital services from asset i in sector n and is calculated as
(A4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
The flow of real capital services in sector n, [K.sub.n, t]
represents the flow of productive services from all capital goods into
production in that sector. [K.sub.n, t] can be decomposed into two
components for the growth accounting - [K.sub.l, n, t] represents
capital services from all assets except OCAM and [K.sub.2, n, t]
represents OCAM capital services.
I would like to thank Barbara Fraumeni, Zvi Griliches, Mun Ho, Lauren
Johnston, Dale Jorgenson, Madhu Khanna, Greg Mankiw, Bob McGuckin,
Thomas Saving, two anonymous referees, seminar participants at Bentley
College, Harvard University, and the 1996 WEA International Conference.
The conclusions represent the views of the author only.
1. For example, Baily and Gordon [1988], Gordon [1990], Berndt and
Morrison [1991], Griliches and Siegel [1992], Brynjolfsson and Hitt
[1994], Sichel [1994], Oliner and Sichel [1994], Berndt and Morrison
[1995], Jorgenson and Stiroh [1995] and Lehr and Lichtenberg [1996]. See
Brynjolfsson [1993] for a review of nearly 20 papers on the topic.
2. Computers first enter the National Income and Product Accounts
(NIPA) in 1958 and hedonic quality adjustments were officially
incorporated in 1986. The purpose of the hedonic approach is to account
for the dramatic quality change and transform investment series into
standardized "constant-quality" units that can be compared
over time. See Sadee [1996] for a recent update of the BEA methodology
and Gordon [1990] for a more general treatment.
3. See Baily and Gordon [1988] and Triplett [1994].
4. Private, business Value-Added is about 80% of GDP. Government and
household sectors account for the rest.
5. See the Appendix for details on defining, estimating and
aggregating capital services.
6. These estimates are consistent with Oliner and Sichel [1994] who
estimate a growth contribution from computing equipment of 0.16
percentage points a year for 1970-1992. They focus on Computer and
Peripheral Equipment, a subaggregate of OCAM, which explains the
slightly different growth contribution.
7. Using an earlier version of this data, Basu and Fernald [1996,
1995] conclude that sectors on average have slightly diminishing returns
to scale. Constant returns to scale, however, seems to be a reasonable
approximation.
8. Data was not available for OCAM investment for Government
Enterprises.
9. Real Gross Output, of course, still relies crucially on official
price deflators for output and inputs that may be problematic in some
sectors.
10. The 1981-1991 growth accounting results are not shown in any
table and are as follows: the annual contribution of non-OCAM capital
fell to 0.17%, the contribution of OCAM capital increased slightly to
0.15% and the contribution of labor, energy and materials were negative,
0.19%, -0.05% and -0.15%, respectively.
11. This applies a "Demur" weight to the sectoral
productivity growth rate. See Jergenson et al. [1987] for details.
12. According to the official numbers in BLS [1996], MFP growth for
the private business economy increased from 0.1% per year for 1973 -
1981 to 0.7% per year for 1982-1991. This increase was primarily due to
faster MFP growth in the manufacturing sectors and is consistent with
the 35-sector data.
13. This criteria was subjectively chosen to isolate sectors that are
the most computer-intensive. There is a clear distinction in factor
payments between the computer-using sectors and the other sectors.
14. Other Services includes computer-related services (SIC #737) such
as software sales, programming services, data processing, rentals and
repairs. Even in 1991, computer-related services are small, accounting
for only about 5% of total gross output in the Other Services sector.
15. Consumption and government purchases are relatively small at 3%
and 6%, respectively.
16. Agriculture, Non-Metallic Mining and Government Enterprises were
excluded from the regression since computer capital was zero for early
years. This left a cross-section of 32 sectors.
17. Griliches [1992] details the difficulties in measuring prices,
output, and productivity growth in the service sectors. To avoid this
problem, one needs to assess each sector individually and generate
alternative output measures which is beyond the scope of this paper.
REFERENCES
Baily, Martin N., and Robert J. Gordon. "The Productivity
Slowdown and Explosion of Computer Power." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 2, 1988, 145.
Bartelsman, Eric J., Ricardo J. Caballero, and Richard K. Lyons.
"Customer- and Supplier-Driven Externalities." The American
Economic Review, 84(4), September 1994, 1,075-84.
Basu, Susanto, and John G. Fernald. "Are Apparent Productive
Spillover a Figment of Specification Error?" Journal of Monetary
Economics, 36, 1995, 165-88.
-----. "Returns to Scale in U.S. Production: Estimates and
Implications." Manuscript, 1996.
Berndt, Ernst R., and Catherine J. Morrison. "Assessing the
Productivity of Information Technology Equipment in U.S. Manufacturing
Industries." NBER Working Paper #3582, 1991.
-----. "High-Tech Capital Formation and Economic Performance in
U.S. Manufacturing Industries." Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 65,
1995, 9-43.
Berndt, Ernst R., Catherine J. Morrison, and Larry S. Rosenblum.
"High-Tech Capital Formation and Labor Composition in U.S.
Manufacturing Industries: An Exploratory Analysis." NBER Working
Paper #4010, 1992.
Bresnahan, Timothy F. "Measuring the Spillovers from Technical
Advance: Mainframe Computers in Financial Services." The American
Economic Review, 76(4), September 1986, 741-55.
Bresnahan, Timothy F., and M. Trajtenberg. "General Purpose
Technologies: Engines of Growth?" Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 65,
1995, 83-108.
Brynjolfsson, Erik. "The Productivity Paradox of Information
Technology: Review and Assessment." Communications of the ACM,
35(12), 1993, 66-77.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Lorin Hitt. "Computers and Economic
Growth: Firm-Level Evidence." Manuscript, 1994.
Bureau of Economic Analysis. National Income and Product Accounts of
the United States. Washington: Department of Commerce, 1992.
-----. "National Income and Product Accounts." Survey of
Current Business, 73(7), July 1993, 7-25.
-----. "National Income and Product Accounts." Survey of
Current Business, 75(7), July 1995, 1-23.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. "Multifactor Productivity Trends,
1994." USDL-95-518, January 17, 1996.
Gordon, Robert J. The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1980.
Griliches, Zvi. "The Search for R&D Spillovers." NBER
Working Paper #3768, 1991.
-----. "Productivity, R&D and the Data Constraint." The
American Economic Review, 84(1), March 1994, 123.
-----. Output Measurement in the Service Sector. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1992.
Griliches, Zvi, and Donald Siegel. "Purchased Services,
Outsourcing, Computers and Productivity in Manufacturing," in
Output Measurement in the Service Sector, edited by Zvi Griliches.
Chicago: University Of Chicago Press, 1992.
Hulten, Charles, and Frank C. Wykoff. "The Estimation of
Economic Depreciation Using Vintage Asset Prices," in The
Measurement of Capital, edited by Dan Usher. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press, 1981.
Jorgenson Dale W. "Productivity and Economic Growth," in
Fifty Years of Economic Measurement, edited by Ernst R. Berndt and Jack
E. Triplett. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1990.
Jorgenson, Dale W., Frank M. Gollop, and Barbara M. Fraumeni.
Productivity and U.S. Economic Growth. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1987
Jorgenson, Dale W., and Kevin Stiroh. "Computers and
Growth." Economics of Innovation and New Technology, Vol. 3, 1995,
295-316.
Jorgenson, Dale W., and Kun-Young Yun. Tax Reform and the Cost of
Capital. New York: Oxford University Press, 1989.
Lehr, William, and Frank R. Lichtenberg. "Computer Use and
Productivity Growth in Federal Government Agencies, 1987 to 1992."
NBER Working Paper #5616, 1996.
Lichtenberg, Frank R. "The Output Contributions of Computer
Equipment and Personnel: A Firm-Level Analysis." NBER Working Paper
#4540, 1993.
Oliner, Stephen D., and Daniel E. Sichel. "Computers and Output
Growth Revisited: How Big is the Puzzle?" Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 2, 1994, 273-318.
Sadee, Nadia. "Computer Prices in the National Accounts: An
Update from the Comprehensive Revision." National Income and Wealth
Division, BEA, 1996.
Sichel, Daniel E. "The Computer Paradox and the Productivity
Slowdown: Is Mismeasurement the Culprit." Brookings Working Paper,
1991.
Solow, Robert M. "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function." Review of Economics and Statistics, No. 39, 1957,
312-20.
Triplett, Jack E. "Comments on Oliner and Sichel [1994]."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1994, 318-24.
Stiroh: Economist, The Conference Board, New York Phone
1-212-339-0481, Fax 1-212-7014 Email stiroh@conference-board.org