Environmental protection in the federalist system: the political economy of NPDES inspections.
Helland, Eric
I. INTRODUCTION
Federal regulatory programs, from occupational safety to protection
of the environment, are implemented jointly by national and state
agencies. More broadly, almost all regulatory programs involve some
delegation to branch offices (meat inspections) or regional districts
(tax collection). Given the pervasiveness of regulatory federalism,
surprisingly little research has been done on the political consequences
of delegating national policy to local actors. In particular, the small
but growing literature on the politics of regulation has almost
completely ignored the role of federalism in implementing regulatory
policy.(1)
Perhaps the most widely accepted model of bureaucratic decision
making, Peltzman's [1976] model of support maximization implies
that delegation can have a profound impact on the implementation of
regulatory policy. Peltzman's model posits that regulators maximize
support while minimizing opposition. In the context of environmental
protection, a rational regulator would calculate the marginal support
from pollution abatement generated by inspecting a given plant and
equate that to the marginal opposition, arising from job loss, generated
by that action. Pashigian [1985] points out that in environmental
legislation local and national interests are unlikely to be identical
because industry, the primary target of pollution control measures, has
an uneven geographic distribution. Thus a local regulator, performing
Peltzman's calculation, is quite likely to reach a very different
decision than a national regulator.
This paper examines the extent to which local regulators are able to
respond to local interests when enforcement of a national policy has
been delegated to them. There are three possibilities. One is that
delegation of enforcement to local government represents a complete
abdication of control by the federal government. At the other extreme is
the possibility the federal government can delegate with no loss of
control because of its ability to enforce its goals through the use of
threats (loss of authority over the program) and incentives (additional
grant money). The third possibility is that both local and national
interests can influence a delegated program. The federal government will
lose some control when it delegates, but the loss will not be total.
The Clean Water Act of 1972 is one of the largest federal regulatory
programs ever delegated to the states. Under the Act, the federal
government took over the previously state level responsibility for
regulating water pollution.(2) Under the Clean Water Act, industrial
polluters are issued permits, which specify types and amounts of
pollutants allowed in effluent discharged during a given time period.
These limits are set by state or regional authorities but must conform
to minimum national standards. Permit writers may consider the desires
of the local community if those desires demand more stringent standards
than the federal minimums, but may not respond to community demands for
lower standards. Local communities with considerable employment in the
industry, for example, might want a lower standard than the federal
mandate. Although a politically-minded regulator does not have the
ability to actually grant a permit with a lower standard, a second
source of discretion is available in the form of selective enforcement.
While permits are difficult enough to issue, they are meaningless
without some method of verifying compliance.(3) The state or regional
Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) conducts regular on-site
inspection of polluters. Although the EPA requests that delegated states
inspect polluters at least once a year, it is not required. In practice,
states have considerable discretion on how and when to inspect
polluters. This should not come as a surprise. There are 7,500 NPDES facilities in the country. Variation in state performance could be due
to location alone?
This study, using data from the EPA's Permit Compliance
Database, which tracks compliance with the Clean Water Act, analyses
plant level inspection, violation and effluent discharge data. The
analysis focuses on the pulp and paper industry, which is the largest
industrial polluter of the nation's waterways and therefore most
affected by the provisions of the Clean Water Act. The results of the
study support the theory that interest groups do have an impact on
state-level regulatory bureaucracies. Agencies make marginal adjustments
in order to satisfy changing interests of both national and local
actors.
II. SPECIFICATION
The three possible outcomes of delegation offer differing predictions
on the sources of agency discretion. To address this question, three
empirical specifications of the determinants of inspections, violations
and effluent discharge are estimated. The importance of inspections has
been noted above. The determinants of the probability a firm is in
violation of its NPDES permit and the average pollution discharge at the
mill are estimated to address the question of whether or not inspections
are important in deterring violations and reducing pollution. It is
possible that a decline in pollution or a compliant mill causes a
decline in the probability of inspection, not political concerns; that
is, the level of pollution and the probability of a violation at the
mill also determine the probability of inspection. If this is the case,
then estimating these three equations independently will yield
inconsistent estimates of the parameters. For this reason the three
equations are estimated via a two-stage instrumental variables approach.
The analysis is further complicated by the fact that the data on
violations do not represent a random sample. The fundamental problem is
that there is no verification of compliance without an inspection. Mills
listed as "in compliance" may actually be "in
violation" because they were fortunate enough to not have been
detected.(5) This problem is compounded by the fact that mills can
report a violation on their quarterly noncompliance reports even if
there is no inspection.
In the case of violations, an assumption that mill operators are
rational can reduce the partial observability problem. A rational owner
or manager will not voluntarily report a violation unless one actually
exists. Thus only one subcase suffers from partial observability: the
uninspected firms who do not report a violation. A log-likelihood
function that corrects for this partial observability is given by,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Phi] denotes the normal cdf, [y.sub.1i] denotes the violation
variable, [x.sub.1] are the independent variables in the violation
equation, [[Beta].sub.1] are the coefficients for the violation
equation, [y.sub.2i] denotes the inspection variable, [x.sub.2] denotes
the inspection equation variables, and [[Beta].sub.2] denotes the
coefficients for the inspection equation. The problem is less (or more)
acute for effluent discharges because the data set contains no
information on which effluent observations have been verified and which
have not. For this reason it is impossible to estimate a sample
selection model of effluent discharge and the OLS results are reported.
The three equations are estimated as
[Y.sub.it] = f ([[Beta].sub.i1] [x.sub.i1], [[Beta].sub.i2]
[x.sub.i2], [[Gamma].sub.i] [z.sub.i] + [[Epsilon].sub.i]
where [Y.sub.it] is one of the three dependent variables: i =
inspection, violation, or effluent discharge; [x.sub.i1] are the federal
variables; [x.sub.i2] are the local variables; [z.sub.i] are the
inspection, violation or effluent equation control variables; and
[[Beta].sub.i1], [[Beta].sub.i2], [[Gamma].sub.i] are coefficients on
the respective model components.
A. State and Local Political Variables
A key variable relating to the cost of environmental protection is
the economic stability of the mill. The EPA [1993] argues that the
probability of a mill closing is captured by the difference between the
plant's shutdown point and the current price of its product. While
the actual shutdown point is not available, the EPA has produced an
econometric model for the industry which can be used to estimate just
how far the plant's cost can be raised before it exits the
industry. As the distance between price and the shutdown point grows,
the probability of an inspection should rise because the plant is less
likely to close if a violation is detected. A decrease in the distance
between the shutdown point and the market price should increase the
probability of a violation and the level of effluent discharge for
similar reasons.
The impact of environmental groups, whose importance to local
policymakers is well documented, is measured by the percentage of the
state's residents who are members of the Sierra Club. The
percentage of environmentalists is predicted to have a positive effect
because the size of the environmental constituency determines the
importance of their support or opposition to the regulator. For similar
reasons it is expected that the probability of a violation and the level
of effluent discharge will decrease as the size of environmental groups
increases.
Because a relatively affluent community is more likely to react to
undetected violations the per capita income for the average household in
the mill's county is also included. The more affluent the county,
the greater is the probability of an inspection, the lower the
probability of a violation and the lower the level of effluent
discharge. The unemployment rate in the county in which the mill is
located is included because an increase in the unemployment increases
the implicit price of environmental protection (in terms of jobs). This
increase causes the probability of an inspection to fall, the
probability of a violation to rise and the level of effluent discharge
to increase. In addition, the percentage of the county labor force
employed at the plant is included to capture the importance of the plant
to the local economy. The larger the level of employment, the greater
the impact if the plant closes. For this reason, the probability of
inspection should decline, the probability of a violation increase, and
the level of effluent discharged increase as the employment at the plant
increases. An interaction term between local employment and the
unemployment rate is also included to capture the opportunity cost of
job loss in the county. If the unemployment rate is high, it will be
more difficult for the local labor market to absorb a large number of
unemployed mill workers. Thus, it is expected that as unemployment and
the size of the mill's employment increase, inspections will become
even less likely.
The variable Governor is designed to capture the governor's
preference for environmental protection and is equal to one if the
state's governor is a member of the Democratic party.
Traditionally, Democratic governors have been more pro-environment than
their Republican counterparts. Therefore, Governor is expected to be
positively related to probability of inspection. The majority party in
the state Senate and House are included (1 = Democrat). Again, it is
expected that Democratic majorities will be relatively more
pro-environment.
B. Federal Political Variables
The congressional oversight variables are the median League of
Conservation Voters (LCV) scores for the House Energy and Commerce
Committee, House Oversight, and the Senate Environment and Public Works Committee, Senate Oversight, respectively. The more pro-environment the
committee (higher LCV scores), the greater is the probability of
inspection, the lower the probability of a violation and the lower the
level of effluent discharge. These two variables proxy the ideological
location of two of committee members.(6) Because national politicians
may intervene differently in their home states, i.e. lobby for more
stringent regulation for their home state or district, the LCV score for
district or state's member on the House Energy and Commerce
Committee and the Environment and Public Works Committee are also
included. The predicted effects on the independent variables are similar
to those of the committee's median member. In addition, because
some states do not have a representative on the respective committees,
two dummy variables controlling for membership are included. These dummy
variables equal one if the state or district has a member on the
respective committee.
The national unemployment rate is also included. It is expected that
when the unemployment rate rises, the probability of an inspection fall,
the probability of a violation and effluent discharges rise. As the
opportunity cost of pollution abatement rises, the federal government,
if it controls local policy, will reduce abatement efforts.
C. Inspection Control Variables
To control for seasonal effects the quarter of the year is
included.(7) Because the national government still retains control over
several state enforcement efforts, a dummy variable is used to
differentiate between states in which the federal government, at least
legally, is in charge of inspections. The real dollar amount the state
spends on water quality divided by the number of manufacturers in the
state is also included.(8) The state's water pollution control
budget is not available on an annual basis and the 1988 budget is used
for 1989 while the 1991 level is used for 1990-1993.(9)
The EPA suggests that local authorities inspect plants at least once
a year. Therefore the number of quarters since the plant has been
inspected in the last year is included and is expected to have a
positive impact on the probability of inspection. The EPA also suggests
that plants found to be in significant noncompliance, i.e. far in excess
of their permit, be inspected again within one year, therefore the
number of significant violations in the last year is included.(10)
Finally, the EPA requires plants to supply monthly reports to local
regulators. If plants fail to report a violation, which is then
detected, this should trigger future inspections because it is a visible
sign that a firm is not complying with EPA directives. A series of
variables, equal to one if the plant failed to file a report one to four
quarters ago, are included. Given the EPA's guideline we would
expect these variables to have a positive impact on the probability of
inspection. To control for industry specific effects, such as the
difficulty in inspecting certain types of mills, the SIC code of the
mill is used to construct a series of four variables: pulp mills, paper
mills, paperboard mills, paperboard containers and boxes and converted
paper products.
In addition, two structural parameters are included in all three
specifications: (1) if there is a predicted violation at the mill in the
current quarter and (2) the predicted effluent emission. If a violation
is expected at the mill and/or the predicted effluent level rises,
inspections should become more likely.(11) Two different versions of the
full model are estimated. The first version contains only an intercept
term. The second version substitutes the EPA region of the country in
which the mill is located to control for any regional fixed effects.
Finally, all inspections are not equally stringent; an inspection that
involves only a check of paperwork is not as stringent as an inspection
that involves sampling. For this reason the full model is also estimated
using only inspections which involve sampling as the dependent variable.
D. Violation and Effluent Discharge Control Variables
The state-local and federal political variables are also included in
the violation and effluent equations. Because local regulators, in
conjunction with the national EPA, write the permits that govern
pollution discharges, it is possible that political forces will also
impact violation rates and discharge rates. The control variables for
violations and effluent discharge follow Magat-Viscusi [1990]. Because
both violations and effluent discharges may have a seasonal component,
variables for the first through the third quarters are included. To
capture economies of scale in pollution abatement the daily output, in
tons, of the mill is included. Given the nature of the permitting
process, larger plants need not be in violation more often than smaller
plants. However, the EPA has explicitly included the disproportionate impact of pollution abatement regulations on small plants as a factor in
its cost-benefit studies. This suggests that the EPA believes there are
some economies of scale in pollution control. Plant size should be a key
component in the amount of effluent discharged from the mill because the
greater the output of the mill the more water used in the production
process.
A third set of factors is the plant's history of past
inspection. Inspections are expected to have a deterrent effect on
future violation by raising the probability of detection. To capture
this effect, four variables were created, numbering one if the plant was
inspected one to four quarters ago. These variables are expected to have
a negative effect on the probability of a violation and reduce effluent
discharges. Another factor contributing to noncompliance and effluent
discharge is the mill's history of past violations. There are two
possible impacts of past violations. One possibility is that, because
violations can only be corrected with the installation of new abatement
technology which takes time, past violations will increase the
probability of current period violations and increase effluent
discharges. Alternatively, it may be that violations have a deterrent
effect. Once the mill's employees or regulators discover the
violation, efforts are made to correct it, reducing the probability of
future violations and future effluent discharges. To capture these
effects, a series of variables was created, numbering one if the plant
was in violation one to four quarters ago.
The product type that the mill produces may also contribute to the
probability of a violation and the level of effluent discharge. This
effect is again captured by the SIC code(s) of the mill. The EPA alleges
that pulp, paper and paper board mills utilize more water and have a
production process that is subject to more spill overs, the usual cause
of a violation.(12) The predicted probability of an inspection is
included in both equations. An increase in the probability of an
inspection this quarter is expected to decrease the probability of
violation and the level of pollution discharged at the mill.(13)
E. The Data Base
The data used in this study is derived from the EPA's Permit
Compliance System database. The study focuses on the pulp and paper
industry because: (1) it is a large industry in terms of pollution
discharge, (GAO [1987]) and can be an issue in local politics, and (2)
there are many sites so the inspection issue is important. There are 232
plants in the sample covering 30 states. The time period considered for
this study is from 1989 to 1993. The analysis is conducted by quarter
because the same mill is only rarely inspected more than once a quarter.
Table I compares the sample to the population of mills in the United
States. The sample has good coverage, with 80% of the regulated industry
included in the data set.
The sample characteristics can be found in Table II. The inspection
rate is similar to previous studies, at about 34%. This is slightly
higher than what one would expect if local authorities followed the
EPA's one inspection per year guide. The non-compliance rates in
this sample are actually lower than in either Magat-Viscusi [1990], the
EPA [1986] or the more general GAO [1987] study. Magat and Viscusi found
a 25% violation rate, the EPA found 16% noncompliance, while the GAO
found 21% noncompliance. This study finds a noncompliance rate of 11%
for the full sample, closer to the EPA estimates than either
Magat-Viscusi or the GAO.(14)
III. RESULTS
The results for the inspection equations are presented in Table III.
The results for the violation and effluent equations are presented in
Table IV.
TABLE I
Number of Plants in the Population and Sample by State
State Population Sample
Alaska 2 0
Alabama 16 13
Arkansas 8 7
California 2 1
Connecticut 2 0
Florida 6 6
Georgia 10 10
Idaho 1 0
Iowa 2 1
Illinois 3 3
Indiana 4 4
Kentucky 3 1
Louisiana 13 9
Maryland 1 0
Massachusetts 16 11
Maine 8 8
Michigan 15 15
Minnesota 5 3
Mississippi 7 7
Missouri 3 0
North Carolina 7 7
New Hampshire 11 9
New Jersey 10 4
New York 24 24
Ohio 9 9
Oklahoma 3 1
Oregon 14 9
Pennsylvania 10 3
South Carolina 6 6
Tennessee 4 4
Texas 9 6
Virginia 4 2
Washington 18 16
Wisconsin 22 21
A. State and Local Political Variables
The natural logarithm of the difference between the current market
price of the plant's product and its shutdown point is positive and
significant in all specifications. A one standard deviation change in
the difference produces a 2% change in the probability of an inspection.
The importance of this effect indicates that local inspectors consider
the possibility that a mill will be forced to shut down due to detected
violations.(15)
The size of the environmental movement in the state is significant in
all of the inspection specifications. A one standard deviation change in
the percentage of the state's residents in the Sierra Club produces
a 15% increase in the probability of inspection. An increase [TABULAR
DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] in the size of environmental membership in
the state also causes a statistically significant reduction in the
probability of a violation (a one standard deviation increases in the
environmental membership reduces the probability of a violation by 4.2%)
and reduces the rate of effluent discharge at the mill by a
statistically significant amount in all specifications which do not
contain regional intercepts.
The logged household Per Capita Income (PCI) of the surrounding
community is significant and positive in all of the inspection
specifications without regional intercepts. A one standard deviation
increase in the natural log of PCI increases the probability of an
inspection by 8.2%. The importance of PCI suggests that higher income
communities value environmental protection more and are more likely to
complain when inspections are not conducted. In addition, an increase in
PCI reduces effluent discharges by a statistically significant but small
amount; a one standard deviation increase in PCI reduces discharges by
half a percent.
The level of employment at the mill is negative and significant in
all inspection specifications. The marginal effect indicates that a one
standard deviation change in the value of the natural log of mill
employment reduces the probability of an inspection by 2.7%. This is
consistent with the hypothesis that the local agencies charged with
enforcement maximize political support by considering the economic
interest of the surrounding communities. In particular, the sign and
significance of the coefficient suggest that local EPA's are
concerned with the possible employment effects of detected violations.
Further confirmation of this hypothesis can be found in the effect of
the interaction term between the level of employment at the mill and the
unemployment rate in the county in which the mill is located. The
interaction term is negative and significant in all specifications
indicating that as the unemployment rate rises, larger employers are
inspected less frequently. The marginal effect indicates that a one
standard deviation change in the interaction term reduces the
probability of an inspection by 3.4%. The interaction term is also
statistically significant and the marginal effect indicates that a one
standard deviation increase in the interaction term increases the
probability of a violation by 6.8%.
B. Federal Political Variables
Local representation on the national oversight committees has an
important impact on the implementation of pollution control laws. The
LCV score of the district's representative on the House oversight
committee has a significant and positive effect. Merely having a member
on the House Energy and Commerce Committee reduces the probability of
inspection; in the 6% of the observations that have a member on the
oversight committee, 14 total mills, the inspection rate is 30% lower;
the largest effect of any of the independent variables. When the
member's ideology is included, the effect of membership on the
oversight committee is still negative. Evaluated at the mean LCV score
of local representatives, an LCV score of 34, the presence of a
representative still reduces the probability of inspection by 13%. For
the most pro-environment representatives, those with an LCV score of
100, the probability of an inspection in a given quarter increases by
34%, a 100% increase. The results are similar for the level of effluent
discharged at the mill. Mills located in committee member's
districts pollute more; however, the more liberal the member the lower
the pollution levels. The results are similar for the Senate oversight
committee. The magnitude of the marginal effects is, however, smaller. A
Senator with committee membership reduces the probability of an
inspection by only 7% and when the mean LCV score for those states with
a committee member is included the marginal effect drops to only -3.9%.
The effect on effluent discharges is similar to those of the House.
In all specification without regional intercepts the median member of
the House Energy and Commerce Committee is significant and positive. A
one standard deviation increase in the median LCV score (the oversight
committee becomes more liberal) raises the average probability of
inspection by five points; a 15% change in the average inspection rate.
The effect of a change in the Environment and Public Works Committees
median member's LCV score is also statistically significant and
positive. A one standard deviation increase in the median LCV score
increases the probability of inspection by 3.5%.
The results from estimating the models using sampling inspections are
substantively similar. The coefficient estimates and standard errors are
reported in column 5 of Table III.(16) In the specification containing
regional intercepts, several of the local variables are no longer
significant. However, employment effects and the effects of local
representation on the oversight committees remain significant.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED]
C. Control Variables
The control variables used in this study are quite similar to other
studies of enforcement and are not discussed at length (see
Magat-Viscusi [1990]). There are, however, a few interesting features in
the control variables' results. First, the effect an increase in
the pollution abatement budget is not significant. This is surprising
because the level of spending is likely determined by the same political
factors that determine inspections. However, even when political
variables are omitted from the model spending levels, though always
positive, do not have a statistically significant impact on the
probability of an inspection. An alternative explanation for this lack
of significance is the biennial nature of the budget variable, which
adds noise to the data.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED]
Also interesting is the effect of the structural parameters. An
increase in the predicted effluent discharge at the mill increases the
probability of an inspection. Violations are deterred by an increased
probability of an inspection in the contemporaneous quarter and from
inspections three and four quarters before. While neither an increased
probability of inspection nor past inspections appear to reduce
pollution levels, violations three and four quarters ago reduce
pollution levels in the current period. One way to interpret these
findings is that violations that involve excess pollution discharge are
difficult to correct and take nine months to a year before pollution
levels at the mill begin to fall.
IV. CONCLUSION
My central objective in this paper is to characterize the source of
discretion found in local bureaucratic agencies and to ascertain the
consequences of delegation by national policymakers. The three models
which were estimated are characterized as the state/local, federal, and
full specifications. The theory predicts that local regulators will
alter the stringency with which pollution control regulations were
enforced in order to maximize the level of political support from
external actors. The federal-specification predicts that local
regulators respond only to external signals from a national coalition.
By contrast, the state/local-specification predicts that local
regulators respond only to local interests.
The results suggest that state agencies are responsive to local and
national interests groups and that delegation allows different political
forces to have an impact in different states. One remaining question is
why, given the loss of policy control, does the national government
choose to delegate? One possible motivation is suggested by the impact
of having local members on the oversight committees. By delegating, the
members of oversight committees, who have been charged with
"watching the watchers," are able to pass a sizable portion of
the costs of enforcement on to state governments. The GAO estimates that
by delegating, the federal government passed $154 million on to the
states in 1995 alone. Furthermore, the results indicate that members of
the oversight committees, particularly in the House, are quite
successful in protecting the interest of their constituents, at least to
the extent that these interests are captured by LCV scores. The
cost-control tradeoff is typical of all regulation; however, the impact
of committee membership shows that this loss of control is by no means
complete. There are alternative explanations for delegation that cannot
be ruled out by the results. One possibility is that oversight
committees delegate when local authorities are going to do what Congress
wants in any case. An alternative possibility is that Congress delegates
in those areas where the marginal opposition to enforcement is
particularly high.
The author is grateful to William Olbrich, Jr., and his staff.
Without their assistance this paper would not have been possible. The
author would also like to acknowledge helpful comments from Art Denzau,
Marilyn Flowers, James Hamilton, John Lott, Bill Lowry, Gary Miller,
Mary Olson, Gary Santoni, Brian Staihr, Mike Sykuta, Mark Zupan, the
anonymous referees, and seminar participants from Ball State University
and Washington University. All errors are my own responsibility.
1. A notable exception is the work of Scholz [1986].
2. Enforcement of the Act was initially a federal responsibility,
with inspections conducted either jointly with the EPA or by independent
contractors hired by the EPA. The current program, delegating oversight
authority to some states, was developed in 1984.
3. Becker's [1968] analysis of crime indicates that as the
probability of an inspection increases, the frequency of violations
would decrease. This decrease is caused by the increase in the expected
cost to the violator from engaging in criminal activity. In the context
of industrial dischargers, Becker's model suggests that as the
probability of an inspection increases, the firm's costs increase
because it must undertake costly pollution abatement or risk an
increased probability of detection.
4. The role of fines in NPDES inspections is more ambiguous. Unlike
OSHA inspections, a reliable record of fines assessed does not exist.
Resources for the Future conducted a survey of states to ascertain the
average penalty per violation and found the average state penalty per
Notice of Violation (NOV) was 393 dollars between 1978 and 1983. Fifteen
percent of the inspections resulted in an NOV. The small dollar amount
of state fines has led Russell et al. [1986] to conclude that fines do
not represent a serious deterrent for polluters. Such a conclusion may
be premature. First the EPA and delegated states recently gained the
right to fine without legal action on the part of the Justice
Department. In addition, Notices of Violation are often used in court
cases when individuals bring legal action against polluters for damages.
The EPA recently fined Louisiana-Pacific and Simon Paper Company 5.8
million dollars as a settlement to a law suit. The plant's history
of non-compliance was considered key evidence in the San Francisco
Chronicle [1991]. While the dollar value of a given penalty may be low,
a sequence of violations, kept on file by the EPA or state agencies, can
cost a company far more than a one time penalty. Typically, mills in
repeated violation are pressured into installing new and more costly
abatement technology. Such investments would not be necessary without
some legal record of a mill's compliance.
5. For an excellent treatment of this problem implicit in all
empirical tests of compliance, see Feinstein [1990].
6. The LCV scores for the various committees represent a difficult
choice for a researcher. Some 35 committees and subcommittees oversee
the Environmental Protection Agency (Lazarus [1991]). A potential
solution is to regress the LCV scores on the number of inspections. The
problem with such a test is that the relatively short time span produces
extreme multicollinearity between the committees and their
subcommittees. For this reason the House Energy and Commerce Commission,
which according to Lazarus had the largest number of EPA testimonies in
the House, and the Senate Environment and Public Works Committee, which
occupies a similar position in the Senate, were selected. The motivation
for this selection is theoretical. The usual method used by committees
to oversee executive agencies is testimony. The number of times EPA
officials where called to testify before Congressional committees can be
found in Lazarus [1991].
7. To avoid perfect collinearity with the constant term or the
regional intercepts quarter four is suppressed.
8. The number of manufacturers is the total number manufacturing
establishments in the state listed in the Dunn and Bradstreet directory.
Although not all of these firms are regulated, the Council of State
Governments argues that this is a good measure by which to compare
state's regulatory mandate.
9. The Council of State Governments, which collects the data, does so
only every two years. In addition, given the differing ways in which
states present their budgets, the Council adjusts the budget numbers
into similar categories making comparisons possible.
10. Ideally I would like to know the magnitude of the violation.
However the EPA's data does not contain information of the amount
by which a mill exceeded its permit.
11. Effluent is measured as the pounds per day of biological oxygen
demand, the amount of oxygen, which the mill's effluent removes
from the stream. It is the conventional measure of pollution.
12. A spillover is untreated water over flowing from the treatment
pond.
13. Because divergent magnitudes in the independent variables can
cause problems for maximum likelihood estimation, the natural log of a
number of the variables is used.
14. The principal reason for these differences may be the period in
which the studies where conducted.
15. The economic impact of the independent variables is evaluated
using the marginal effects from the full model unless otherwise noted.
16. The results for the violation equation and the effluent equation
using the probability of sampling inspections as a structural parameter
are not reported because they are almost identical to the results
reported above.
REFERENCES
Becker, G. "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach."
Journal of Political Economy, March/April, 1968, 169-217.
Feinstein, J. "Detection Controlled Estimation." Journal of
Lava and Economics, April 1990, 233-77.
General Accounting Office. Water Pollution: Application of National
Cleanup Standard to Pulp and Paper Industry, 1987.
Lazarus, R. "The Neglected Question of Congressional Oversight
of EPA: Quis Custodiet Ipsos Custodes (Who shall watch the watchers
themselves)." Law and Contemporary Problems, Autumn 1991,205-48.
Magat, W., and K. Viscusi. "Effectiveness of the EPA's
Regulatory Enforcement: The Case of Industrial Effluent Standards."
Journal of Law and Economics, 33, October 1990, 361-30.
Pashigian, P. "Environmental Regulation: Whose Self-Interests
are Being Protected?" Economic Inquiry, October 1985, 551-84.
Peltzman, S. "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation."
Journal of Law and Economics, August 1976, 211-40.
Russell, C., W. Harrington, and W. Vaughan. Enforcing Pollution
Control Laws. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 1986.
San Francisco Chronicle. "Pulp Mills Pollution Settlement."
10, September 1991, Sec. A, p. 18:1.
Scholz, J., and F. Wei. "Regulatory Enforcement in a Federalist System." American Political Science Review, December 1986,
1,249-70.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency: Water Management Division,
Facilities Performance Branch. Study of the Pulp and Paper Industry in
Region IV, 1986.
-----. Economic Impact and Regulatory Flexibility Analysis of
Proposed Effluent Guidelines NESHAP for the Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard
Industry, 1993.
Helland: Assistant Professor, Ball State University, Muncie, Ind.,
Phone 1-764-285-5378, Fax 1-765-285-8024 E-mail
00eahelland@bsubc.bsu.edu