Primary and secondary reform.
Conlon, John R. ; Pecorino, Paul
I. INTRODUCTION
The export-led growth performance of the East Asian newly
industrialized countries has increased interest in liberalization among
developing countries in general. Such reforms are felt to benefit the
economy, not only because they reduce the usual economic distortions,
but also because they tend to drive agents out of rent seeking and into
productive activities. However, the presence of lobbyists working for
vested interests, such as import competing industries, makes these
distortions difficult to remove.(1) Developed countries, of course, face
similar problems. In analyzing the political and economic consequences
of a reform, it is essential to consider the full range of rent-related
activities in which individuals may engage. Our model focuses on two
activities, rent seeking and lobbying, and examines the feedback effects
resulting from reforms which target one or the other of these
activities.(2) In particular, when people are driven out of rent seeking
by a reform, their most natural alternative may be some other
rent-related activity such as lobbying.
We refer to reforms which target lobbying as primary reforms, while
reforms which target rent-seeking activities are called secondary
reforms. Primary reforms target the decision making process. An example
is an institutional reform which lowers (all else equal), the marginal
product of lobbying. Secondary reform focuses on the side effects resulting from the policy which has been put in place by lobbying. An
example is the replacement of quotas by their tariff equivalent
(tariffication) in an attempt to reduce rent seeking associated with the
trade regime.
In our model, import competing firms may lobby for protection which
takes the form of a combination of tariffs and quotas. Raising the
domestic price of the imported good increases the returns to sector
specific capital located in the protected industry. To the extent that
binding quotas are utilized, rents will accrue to those who acquire the
import licenses. Rent seeking consists of resources (time) spent
attempting to acquire the import licenses.(3)
An important feature of the model is that, for the individuals
involved, rent seeking and lobbying are highly substitutable activities.
The presumption is that the skills required for these activities are
more closely related to one another than they are to productive
activities. This type of substitution between rent related activities is
suggested by Rodrik [1994, p. 86, footnote 6]: "To the extent that
rent-seeking behavior dissipates some of the rents of trade protection,
the efficiency gains of reform may be larger than those measured here.
However, the rent-seeking literature generally exaggerates these gains.
If individuals can waste resources competing for the rents generated by,
say, quotas, they can also waste resources lobbying the government for
the reimposition of quotas that have been taken away."(4)
Our assumption about the nature of rent seeking and lobbying
activities has important implications for understanding the response to
reform. In particular, this response depends on the extent to which
reform is directed at rent seeking (secondary reform) or lobbying
(primary reform). Feedback effects arise both because of labor market linkages, and because rents are created as a side effect of lobbying for
trade protection. As we show below, the feedback effects from primary
reforms often tend to reinforce the original reform, while the feedback
effects associated with secondary reforms tend to retard the reform
process. Near autarky, however, a primary reform can actually raise
rents by increasing the volume of trade. Thus, in this situation, any
primary reform should presumably be accompanied by secondary reform.
Though the model presented here is extremely simple, and is a rather
specific example of reform of the trade regime, the insights gained may
apply to rent seeking and lobbying more generally. Our model is relevant
whenever a related set of rent seeking and lobbying activities involve
similar skills. For example, Anne Krueger's [1990] discussion of
the U.S. Sugar Program emphasizes the role of sector specific human
capital in the perpetuation of that program in the face of exogenous "shocks" to policy. Her focus on the role of specific human
capital supports the basic story of our model. This example is discussed
in the conclusion.
II. THE MODEL
We wish to consider a well developed market for lobbying services,
and a competitive rent-seeking activity. There are many identical import
competing industries demanding lobbying services, so that each
individual industry takes the wage of lobbyists as given.(5) The labor
market for lobbyists/rent seekers is segmented in the short run from the
market for productive labor services. We will focus on lobbying and rent
seeking in one representative import competing industry. We do not
explain within our model the reasons why political economic equilibrium results in import protection bias, but as in most of the literature we
take this as given.(6)
Firms are defined by ownership of sector specific capital, and all
firms have access to an identical constant returns to scale production
technology. Labor in the productive sector is perfectly mobile among
firms, and is hired at a market determined wage. As in Grossman and
Helpman [1994; 1995a,b] we assume that wages of productive labor are set
in a Ricardian sector in which a numeraire good is produced, and freely
traded at world prices. As long as there is sufficient labor in the
economy to ensure positive production in this sector, it will serve to
fixed wages of productive workers in the rest of the economy. This
assumption allows us to put aside general equilibrium considerations to
focus on the lobbying/rent seeking sector of the economy.(7)
Lobbying
We assume that each industry is able to overcome the free-rider
problem and lobbies cooperatively for the tariff which is optimal from
the perspective of sector specific capital located in the industry.(8)
As in Lovely and Nelson [1994], lobbying is conducted through a
Political Action Committee (PAC) run by political entrepreneurs earning
zero economic profit. The PAC lobbies to maximize the return to sector
specific capital net of lobbying costs.(9) Firms are perfectly
competitive in the output market. This set of assumptions may reflect a
situation where firms are allowed to form industry associations for
lobbying, but are prohibited from colluding in the output market by
antitrust law. In addition, once the domestic price is determined by the
lobbying process, competition from the rest of the world will force the
industry to act as a price taker, even if it were otherwise able to
collude in the output market.(10)
The industry has a variable cost function c(Q), where C[prime](Q)
[greater than] 0 and C[double prime](Q) [greater than] 0.(11) Under
constant returns to scale, the fixed supply of the sector-specific
factor implies increasing marginal costs (C[double prime](Q) [greater
than] 0). Domestic demand for the import good is D(P) where D[prime](P)
[less than] 0. The domestic price of the import good P exceeds the world
price by an amount T which is determined in the lobbying process:(12)
(1) P = [P.sup.w] + T.
The domestic price which emerges from the lobbying process should be
thought of as a target price which is obtained by a combination of
tariffs and quotas. The price wedge T is given by
(2) T = At([L.sub.t]),
where A is a shift parameter which will be used to analyze the
effects of primary reform, [L.sub.t] is labor hired for lobbying,
t[prime]([L.sub.t]) [greater than] 0, and t[double prime]([L.sub.t])
[less than] 0.(13) Given the domestic price P determined through the
lobbying process, industry output is determined by
(3) C[prime](Q) = P,
which reflects the setting of marginal cost equal to price. Lobbyists
may be hired by the industry PAC at the competitive wage [w.sub.L]. The
total return to sector specific capital [Pi] is revenue net of variable
production costs C(Q) and lobbying costs [w.sub.L][L.sub.t].(14) The
PAC's problem is to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where equations (1), (2) and (3) imply the following functional
dependencies: P = P([L.sub.t]) and Q = Q([L.sub.t]). The first order
condition is
d[Pi]/d[L.sub.t] = dP/d[L.sub.t] Q - [w.sub.L]
+ (P - C[prime](Q)) dQ/d[L.sub.t] = 0.
From equations (1) and (2), dP/d[L.sub.t] = At[prime]([L.sub.t]). Use
this plus equation (3) to rewrite the first order condition as
(4) d[Pi]/d[L.sub.t] = At[prime]([L.sub.t])Q - [w.sub.L] = 0.
We can solve equation (3) to obtain Q = S(P), and since C[double
prime](Q) [greater than] 0, we know that S[prime](P) [greater than] 0.
Substitute Q = S(P) into equation (4) and rearrange to get
(4a) At[prime]([L.sub.t])S(P) = [w.sub.L].
Note from equation (4a) that the marginal product of lobbying depends
in part on the level of output s(P) produced by the industry.
In discussing the comparative statics of the model in section III, we
will refer to the following claim:
Claim 1:
The marginal product of lobbying, At[prime]([L.sub.t])S(P) increases
more than proportionally with A, when [L.sub.t] is held constant.
If A rises, P = [P.sup.w] + At([L.sub.t]) rises, so S(P) rises (since
S[prime](P) [greater than] 0). Thus, At[prime]([L.sub.t])S(P) rises more
than proportionally with A when [L.sub.t] is held constant.
For a firm taking [w.sub.L] as given, the second order conditions for
an interior maximum require that the marginal product of lobbying,
At[prime]([L.sub.t])S(P), be decreasing in [L.sub.t]. In general, there
is no guarantee that this will be so. The condition that t[double
prime]([L.sub.t] [less than] 0 suggests decreasing returns to lobbying.
However, greater lobbying raises P and leads to higher output S(P). From
the left-hand side of equation (4a), higher output raises the return to
lobbying. Thus, unless t[prime]([L.sub.t]) falls sufficiently quickly,
it is possible for the marginal product of lobbying to increase in
[L.sub.t].
With increasing returns, the amount of lobbying will increase until
either an area of decreasing returns is reached, or a corner solution is
reached in which T becomes prohibitive and all imports cease (a corner
solution with zero lobbying is also possible). Given our concerns, the
corner solutions are uninteresting, and we will not consider them
further. Thus, in all our diagrams it is assumed that the marginal
product of lobbying (shown as the [w.sub.L] curve) is decreasing in
[L.sub.t]. This would follow from some combination of fixed factors in
production with the associated decreasing returns in mobile factors, and
decreasing returns to the tariff lobbying function t([L.sub.t]).
Rent Seeking
In the process of lobbying to increase the return to sector specific
capital, the industry creates rents which it does not capture. These
rents accrue to those who obtain import licenses. As an alternative to
the lobbying activity, individuals may expend time in an effort to
obtain valuable import licenses. The total amount of rents R available
to rent seekers is
(5) R = [Theta][R.sub.E](A, [L.sub.t]),
where [Theta] is a shift parameter used to analyze secondary reform
and
(5a) [R.sub.E](A, [L.sub.t]) = At([L.sub.t])[D([P.sup.w] +
At([L.sub.t])) - S([P.sup.w] + At([L.sub.t]))].
That is, total rents R are proportional to the price wedge T =
At([L.sub.t]) times imports (D(P) - S(P)). Note that this is the tariff
revenue equivalent, and is denoted [R.sub.E](A, [L.sub.t]). The
parameter [Theta] reflects the extent to which quota rents are absorbed
by the tariff. When [Theta] = 1, tariffs are zero, and when [Theta] = 0,
all quota rents are absorbed by the tariff (i.e., the tariff is set so
that the quota just binds). For the purpose of the comparative static
exercises in section III, we would like to make two claims about the
expression in equation (5a).
Claim 2:
If [R.sub.E](A, [L.sub.t]) is increasing (decreasing) in [L.sub.t]
with A held constant, then it is increasing (decreasing) in A with
[L.sub.t] held constant.
This follows because A and t([L.sub.t]) enter symmetrically in
equation (5a), and t[prime]([L.sub.t]) [greater than] 0.
Claim 3:
When A increases ([L.sub.t] held constant), [R.sub.E](A, [L.sub.t])
either increases less than proportionally with A, or it decreases.
When A rises with [L.sub.t] held constant, P = [P.sup.w] +
At([L.sub.t]) rises, so the volume of imports, D(P) - S(P), falls. Thus,
when A rises, [R.sub.E] rises less than proportionally, or else it
falls.
We next assume that all rents are dissipated, and individuals earn
rents based on their time spent rent-seeking relative to the total time
expenditure of all rent seekers. Thus, the wage in rent seeking
[w.sub.R] is
(6) [w.sub.R] = R/[L.sub.r] = [Theta][R.sub.E](A,
[L.sub.t])/[L.sub.r],
where R is total rents, and [L.sub.r] is the number of rent seekers.
Equilibrium
There is perfect substitutability of labor between rent seeking and
lobbying so there are essentially no distinctions between individuals
engaged in either of these two activities. What is crucial for the
following is that skills be more highly substitutable between rent
seeking and lobbying than they are between either of these two
activities and production. With perfect mobility between rent seeking
and lobbying, we have
(7) [w.sub.R] = [w.sub.L] = [w.sup.8],
where [w.sup.*] denotes the equilibrium wage.
Lobbyists' skills are acquired and this creates a wedge between
their marginal product in rent seeking/lobbying and their marginal
product in productive activities. These skills may reflect the
establishment of contacts, and the costs of learning the rules of the
game. In the short run, the number of lobbyists/rent seekers is fixed at
L reflecting the existence of sector specific human capital and the
resulting labor market segmentation. Labor market clearing implies
(8) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Over time, there is turnover in the labor market, and L is free to
adjust. In the long run there is an infinitely elastic supply of labor
to the rent-seeking/lobbying sector at the wage [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], which reflects both the competitive wage determined in the
Ricardian sector and the wage premium necessary to compensate
individuals for the accumulation of sector specific skills. We do not
explicitly analyze the transition to the long run, but it is reasonable
to assume that the speed of the movement into and out of the rent
seeking/lobbying sector will depend positively on the gap between the
current wage [w.sup.*], and the long-run equilibrium wage [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] as reflected by
(9) [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where g(0) = 0 and g[prime] [greater than] 0.(15) Reforms which cause
a large fall in [w.sup.*] will lead to a sharp outflow of labor from the
rent seeking/lobbying sector via equation (9). One setting in which an
equation such as (9) could apply would be an overlapping generations
model, though other specifications are possible. The particular choice
of microfoundations for equation (9) will not have a major effect on the
conclusions of our model.
Since [w.sub.L] = [w.sub.R], equilibrium in the short run requires
that
(10) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
This follows from equations (4a), (6) and (7), and assumes that some
labor is allocated to both lobbying and rent seeking.
To understand how [L.sub.t] is determined in the short run, consider
Figures 1a-b. In both diagrams, the marginal product of lobbying,
[w.sub.L], is decreasing in [L.sub.t] (as discussed earlier). However,
the wage in rent seeking, [w.sub.R] (given by the left-hand side of
equation (10)), may be either increasing or decreasing in [L.sub.t].
This is due in part to the relationship between rents R =
[Theta][R.sub.E] and the price wedge T. Total rents available are
proportional to the price wedge times imports. Lobbying increases the
price wedge, but it reduces imports, so this product may either rise or
fall. Thus, the tariff revenue equivalent curve, [R.sub.E](A,
[L.sub.t]), generally has both upward and downward sloping portions in
[L.sub.t].
If there is a positive relationship between T and R, the wage in rent
seeking will be increasing in [L.sub.t] for two reasons. As [L.sub.t]
rises, there are more rents, but there are also fewer rent seekers
(recall, [L.sub.r] = L - [L.sub.t]). This case is described by Figure
1a, where [w.sub.R] is upward sloping in [L.sub.t]. If rents are
decreasing in T, wages in rent seeking may either increase or decrease
in [L.sub.t]. As [L.sub.t] increases, there are fewer rents to be
sought, but also fewer rent seekers. Thus, either Figure 1a or 1b may
apply. In Figure 1b, rents are falling sufficiently fast with an
increase in [L.sub.t] (and therefore T) to ensure a fall in the wage to
rent seekers even though the number of rent seekers is also declining in
[L.sub.t]. Figure 1b is likely to apply near autarky, where the rents
would tend to decline sharply with T.
If wages in rent seeking are falling more quickly than the marginal
product of lobbying where the curves intersect, there will be an
unstable equilibrium. While this type of instability constitutes one of
the logically possible cases of the model, given our concerns this case
is uninteresting, and we will not discuss it further. To avoid an
unstable equilibrium, the slope of the [w.sub.R] curve must be greater
than the slope of the [w.sub.L] curve where they intersect (so that if,
e.g., [L.sub.t] [greater than] [L.sup.*], then [w.sub.R] [greater than]
[w.sub.L], and [L.sub.t] falls).
III. PRIMARY AND SECONDARY REFORM
We model a primary reform as a reduction in the parameter A. This
reform reduces both the marginal product of lobbying and the level of
the price wedge T, all else held constant. A secondary reform consists
of a reduction in the parameter [Theta] (partial tariffication of the
quotas) which, all else constant, reduces available rents in the
economy.(16) We consider each reform in turn, and each is considered to
affect lobbying or rent seeking uniformly across our industries (in
accordance with our representative industry analysis). We do not
consider broad based reforms under which A and 0 are reduced
simultaneously. Clearly such reforms would obviate some of the negative
feedback effects discussed below.
Welfare Effects of Reform
There are two distortions present in the model, the price wedge T
which leads to inefficient production in the import competing sector,
and the existence of the rent seeking/lobbying activity. The short-run
and long-run success of a reform depends on its ability to reduce these
two distortions. When the price wedge is reduced, mobile productive
labor will flow out of the protected sector, and into the Ricardian
sector where world prices prevail. As a result, the value of output
measured at world prices will rise. A reform which reduces the wage in
the rent seeking/lobbying sector will be successful, over time, in
moving individuals into the productive sector of the economy.(17) All
labor freed from the rent-seeking/lobbying sector is absorbed by the
Ricardian sector, and each unit of labor reallocated in this fashion
raises the value of output measured at world prices by an amount equal
to the wage in the productive sector. In a model with general
equilibrium wage effects, the welfare analysis might be complicated by
second best considerations. In particular, a reduction of one distortion
can be welfare reducing if it worsens a second distortion as in Bhagwati
[1971; 1980].
In addition to the welfare effects discussed above, to the extent
that a reform quickly moves individuals out of rent seeking/lobbying and
into the productive sector, the constituency for maintaining reform will
grow, and the constituency which seeks to overturn reform will shrink.
Such movements are crucial to the continued survival of a reform.
Secondary Reform
Consider first a reform targeting the rent-seeking activity as
reflected by a reduction in [Theta]. This reform represents a partial
conversion of quotas to their tariff equivalent.(18) As seen in Figures
2a-b, the [w.sub.R] curve shifts down, [w.sub.*] falls and [L.sub.t]
rises regardless of whether [w.sub.R] is upward or downward sloping.
Since [L.sub.t] rises, a negative side effect of tariffication is
movement into lobbying so that the price wedge T grows. The reform will
result in an eventual exit from the rent-seeking/lobbying sector, but in
the short run the reform will worsen the existing production distortion.
The fall in [w.sub.*] and the rise in [L.sub.t] are most dramatic
when, as may be the case near autarky, [w.sub.R] is downward sloping
(implying that the revenue equivalent of the tariff falls when T rises).
Wages to rent seekers fall as [Theta] falls, and this is reinforced when
[L.sub.t] rises and the economy moves further down the tariff revenue
equivalent curve. Thus, large decreases in [w.sub.*] are achieved at the
cost of moving the economy close to autarky.
When [w.sub.R] is upward sloping, the feedback effect tends to
increase total rents, and so dampen the effect on [w.sub.*] (though it
also results in a correspondingly smaller increase in [L.sub.t] and
therefore in the price wedge T). The movement out of rent seeking into
lobbying increases the revenue equivalent of the tariff, and so
partially offsets the reform's initial reduction in rents. The
rents created by this feedback effect then tend to result in a sluggish
exit from the rent-seeking/lobbying sector. In the long run, however, T
will fall to its initial level as [w.sub.*] returns to its long-run
equilibrium value w, and rents will be reduced in proportion to the
reduction in [Theta].
The difficulty with tariffication is that, in the short run, while
rent seeking is reduced, pressures appear elsewhere in the system in the
form of increased lobbying. The production distortion will be worsened,
and if rents are increasing in the amount of lobbying, exit from the
rent seeking/lobbying sector may be quite sluggish. As discussed below,
there are some cases in which negative feedback effects are associated
with reductions in A (the shift parameter from the lobbying function),
but negative feedback from the reduction of [Theta] is guaranteed.
Primary Reform
Consider next a reform which targets the lobbying activity as
reflected by a reduction of the parameter A. The responses to such a
reform are summarized in Figures 3a-c. In each case, the [w.sub.L] curve
shifts down as the marginal product of lobbying is lower for all values
of [L.sub.t]. If rents are increasing in T, then the reduction in A will
also cause the [w.sub.R] curve to shift down as in Figure 3a. This is
because, as A falls, T falls, so total rents fall, and the wage in rent
seeking is lower at the initial value of [L.sub.t]. This seems to give
an ambiguous effect of a reduction in A on [L.sub.t]. However, by Claim
1, the [w.sub.L] curve shifts down more than proportionally with the
reduction in A, while by Claim 3, the [w.sub.R] curve shifts down less
than proportionally with the reduction in A. Thus, the [w.sub.L] curve
shifts down more than the [w.sub.R] curve, so [L.sub.t] must fall, as
shown in the figure.
The reduction in rent availability is a positive side effect of
primary reform in this case. The reduction in rents puts strong downward
pressure on [w.sub.*], which will promote exit from the
rent-seeking/lobbying sector. In the long run, [w.sub.*] will rise back
up to [Mathematical Expression Omitted], resulting in a further decrease
in lobbying (and so, distortions and rents) relative to the short run.
The long-run decrease in lobbying is determined by the horizontal shift
in the [w.sub.L] curve.
Next, consider when the tariff revenue equivalent curve is decreasing
in [L.sub.t], and so, by Claim 2, decreasing in A as well ([L.sub.t]
held constant). Since the tariff revenue equivalent is decreasing in A,
a reduction in A shifts the [w.sub.R] curve up. The [w.sub.R] curve may
now be either upward or downward sloping. If the [w.sub.R] curve is
upward sloping, the effect of a decrease in A is reflected by Figure 3b.
Since the [w.sub.L] curve shifts down and the [w.sub.R] curve shifts up,
the effect on [w.sub.*] is ambiguous, but there is a sharper drop in
[L.sub.t] than in Figure 3a (and therefore a greater reduction in the
distortion represented by T). The rent expansion effect due to increased
trade prevents a sharp drop in the wage, and results, at best, in a
sluggish exit from the rent-seeking/lobbying sector.
If we are very near autarky, so that [w.sub.R] slopes downward, then
a decrease in A necessarily increases rents ([L.sub.t] held constant).
Thus, the [w.sub.R] curve will shift up as in Figure 3c. There is an
increase in [w.sup.*] and a correspondingly sharp decrease in lobbying
effort. The rise in [w.sup.*] implies long run entry into the rent
seeking/lobbying sector. In a highly distorted economy, a move toward
free trade can result in an increase in lobbyist's wages in the
short run, and in rent-seeking activity in the long run, due to the rent
expansion effect. As a result, the welfare benefits of freer trade are
traded off against the costs of greater rent seeking.(19) Note in Figure
3c, that the long-run decrease in the tariff is smaller than the
short-run decrease; the equilibrium wage will fall in the long run as
additional lobbyists/rent seekers are attracted to the sector. To
counteract the rent expansion effect near autarky, primary reform should
probably be accompanied by secondary reform.
Two goals of trade reform are the reduction of the production
distortion resulting from protection and the movement of individuals
over time out of the rent-seeking/lobbying sector into the productive
sector of the economy. Primary reform will reduce the production
distortion and may exhibit either a positive or negative feedback
through its effects on rent availability. However, secondary reform is
guaranteed to produce a negative feedback effect in the short run as it
pushes agents out of rent seeking into the lobbying activity. This will
increase the production distortion and may lead to an increase in rents
which can partially offset the initial reduction due to the reform.
IV. CONCLUSION
The model presented here is clearly incomplete in some important
ways. For example, we do not specify the forces which initially drive
reform and therefore cannot within the model derive the responses which
might cause a reform to collapse.(20) Still, it seems reasonable to
assume that the success of a reform depends critically on its
effectiveness in moving individuals out of unproductive activities and
into productive ones, and possible gains from more efficient patterns of
production. Thus, the success or failure of a reform may depend
critically on the feedback effects analyzed in this paper.
Changes in the lobbying parameter A may reflect either changes in the
party in power, changes in the receptivity to calls for protection
within a given ruling party, or institutional changes affecting the
lobbying process. For example, reductions in A might reflect tighter
ethics rules (or improved ethics) as well as stricter disclosure
requirements for lobbyists. In the case of trade policy in the United
States, parameter A would (among other things) reflect the
administrative protection apparatus related to antidumping actions and
countervailing duties.
Our analysis has nothing to say about how to bring about fundamental
changes in receptivity to lobbying. However, it does suggest that a
focus on institutions may be as important as a focus on the policies
themselves. The analysis is also consistent with a high failure rate for
reforms imposed on governments by external forces (e.g. the IMF) when
the underlying attitudes of the government are unchanged. This type of
policy cycle (reform followed by relapse) is noted by Krueger [1978] and
Bhagwati [1978] in their studies of trade policy in developing
countries.
Though our analysis is conducted within the context of trade policy,
the insights gained from the model generalize. The analysis should apply
to any situation where one can separate out rent seeking from lobbying
with respect to a specific set of policies. Also, "rent
seeking" should be interpreted broadly to include, among other
things, positions in the bureaucracy. Just as quota rents may arise as a
side effect of trade restrictions, positions in the bureaucracy may
arise as side effects of programs created to benefit other groups. As we
discuss below, bureaucrats may also acquire human capital specific to
certain programs and form part of the labor pool available for the
bureaucratic, lobbying and rent seeking activities related to a
particular set of programs.
The history of the U.S. sugar program is very complex, but important
elements of the story do seem to correspond with our model. The program
has, at various times, set a domestic target price for sugar, and also
determined domestic production quotas and foreign import quotas. The
complexity of the program led lobbyists and bureaucrats to acquire a
good deal of specific human capital. Writing about sugar and other
agricultural programs, Krueger [1990, 213] notes, "Those with
understanding of the U.S. Sugar Program could seek employment as
lobbyists for foreign governments, or as representatives of domestic
groups, as Congressional staff assistants, or with the Department of
Agriculture. For any non-specialist to enter the policy dialogue in a
meaningful way would require a considerable investment."
This had important consequences when exogenous factors affected the
program. Country-specific quotas were initially designed to benefit
Cuba, but in 1960, Cuba's quota was cut to zero. Rather than
leading to the end of country specific import quotas, this led to a
political fight which resulted in a division of the Cuban quota among
foreign and domestic producers. According to Krueger [1990, 210],
"had there been no sugar program in 1960, the most likely outcome
is that the United States would have continued buying sugar on world
markets. It is difficult to imagine a sequence of events under which a
changed Cuban Government could have been seized upon as a rationale for
the inauguration of a Sugar Program."
Though the program was not renewed in 1974 during a period of high
sugar prices, it was revived in 1981 and country specific import quotas
were reimposed shortly thereafter. The program has proved very difficult
to kill, though it has mutated over time in response to various shocks.
This is likely due in part to the acquired human capital which was
specific to the sugar program. As Krueger [1990, 212-3] puts it,
"... the specialists in a given policy instrument become a vested
interest in the maintenance of SOME policy." (emphasis in the
original)
In understanding the response to a reform, it is necessary to
understand the range of activities to which rent seekers/lobbyists can
apply their skills given a change in the policy climate. To the extent
that their skills may be easily applied to other unproductive
activities, pressures may reappear elsewhere in the system that will
tend to frustrate reform. Whether this happens will, in turn, depend
critically on the nature of the original reform.
ABBREVIATION
PAC: Political Action Committee
1. For an account of the policies followed in developing countries
and attempts to reform those policies, see Krueger [1978] and Bhagwati
and Srinivasan [1975] as well as the other country studies in this NBER project. Also, see Krueger [1993], Bhagwati [1993] and Rodrik [1996]
among others.
2. These are dubbed directly-unproductive profit-seeking activities
by Bhagwati [1982].
3. As modeled, rent seekers take the amount of rents as given. That
is, they do not lobby in an attempt to directly affect the amount of
rents available. The model could be extended to allow them to lobby, but
to the extent they behave atomistically, there is no incentive for them
to do so.
4. The model implicit in Rodrik's quote differs from ours in
that rent creation is considered an end achieved through lobbying
(people lobby to create rents they later seek), while in our model, rent
creation is a by-product of tariff lobbying. The quote is consistent
with our main assumption that DUP activities may be close substitutes
for one another.
5. That the market for lobbying services is competitive is clearly
only an approximation. In some cases (see the discussion in the
conclusion), it may be the case that human capital is specific to
lobbying and rent seeking activities associated with a single industry.
As a result, the labor market may be "thin." We have chosen
the assumption which makes for a simpler labor market interaction, but
the basic flavor of the results should hold in a more complex labor
market setting as well.
6. See the discussion of this issue in Rodrik [1995].
7. Alternatively, one can think of our model as lobbying and rent
seeking within a related set of industries (say in agriculture) which is
small compared to the economy as a whole.
8. In a related setting, Conlon and Pecorino [1998] analyze feedback
effects from reform in a model where the free-rider problem is
specifically taken into account. As with this paper, they identify
negative feedback effects from secondary reforms, but in the presence of
a free-rider problem, these effects may be greatly multiplied.
9. For more on the specific factors model, see Jones [1971].
10. For a homogeneous good under a nonprohibitive tariff, foreign
competition will force a monopolist to behave as a price taker. See
Helpman and Krugman [1989, 29-30]. Though it is supported by both a
quota and a tariff, from the perspective of firms in the protected
industry, the target price in equation (1) is equivalent to a tariff.
11. Since wages of productive labor are determined in the Ricardian
sector, we suppress the dependence of the cost function on wages.
12. Alternatively, the industry could lobby over the size of the
quota. This assumption would have no effect on our results.
13. Our model of lobbying is in the line of Findlay and Wellisz
[1982]. Also see Mayer's [1984] model of tariff determination via
direct voting, and Magee, Brock and Young's [1989] model of
probabilistic elections with campaign contributions. Grossman and
Helpman [1994; 1995a,b] consider models where campaign contributions
purchase influence directly, rather than influencing election outcomes
as in Magee, Brock and Young.
14. In Findlay and Wellisz [1982] and Grossman and Helpman [1994;
1995a,b] political activity (either lobbying or campaign contributions)
is also directed at raising the return to sector specific capital.
15. Of course equation (9) would not be adequate for a full analysis
of exit and entry. A more complete analysis would involve, for example,
expected future wages as well as current wages.
16. We do not consider parallel shifts in the lobbying function. With
a function of the form T = [Gamma] + At([L.sub.t]) a reduction in
[Gamma] would reduce the level of the price wedge and affect available
rents, but (other things constant) leave the marginal effect of lobbying
on the price wedge unaffected. Such reforms are considered in a somewhat
different context by Pecorino [1997].
17. We are ignoring an important larger issue which is the proper
role of lobbying in a democracy. Taking the legitimate role of lobbying
into account, our presumption here is that the economy in question
initially has more than the "socially optimal" level of
lobbying.
18. If it is believed that revenue seeking, as in Bhagwati and
Srinivasan [1980], will draw in the same level of resources as
distribution of quota licenses, this reform can be considered some
change in the distribution of quota licenses which makes a smaller
percentage of the total subject to rent seeking. Alternatively, it could
be considered as an earmarking of a certain percentage of revenues for
specific purposes such that they were less subject to revenue seeking.
Dinopoulos [1984] considers the possibility that only some fraction of
revenues are subject to revenue seeking.
19. Krueger [1974, 301] points out that with rent seeking, an import
prohibition may be preferable to a positive quota.
20. See Krueger [1993] for a discussion of both of these issues.
REFERENCES
Baumol, William J. Entrepreneurship. Management, and the Structure of
Payoffs, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1993.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. "The Generalized Theory of Distortions and
Welfare," in Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth: Essays in Honor
of Charles Kindleberger, edited by J. N. Bhagwati, R. W. Jones, R. A.
Mundell and J. Vanek. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1971.
-----. Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Anatomy and
Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes. New York: NBER, 1978.
-----. "Lobbying and Welfare." Journal of Public Economics,
December 1980, 355-63.
-----. "Directly-Unproductive, Profit-Seeking (DUP)
Activities." Journal of Political Economy, October 1982, 988-1002.
-----. India in Transition: Freeing the Economy, Oxford: Clarendon
Press, 1993.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. and T. N. Srinivasan. Foreign Trade Regimes and
Economic Development: India New York: Columbia University Press, 1975.
-----. "Revenue Seeking: A Generalization of the Theory of
Tariffs." Journal of Political Economy, December 1980, 1069-87.
Conlon, John. R. and Paul Pecorino. "Does Free Riding in
Lobbying Activities Make Reform More Difficult?" Manuscript,
University of Mississippi, 1998.
Dinopoulos, Elias. "The Optimal Tariff and Revenue-Seeking: A
Contribution to the Theory of DUP Activities," in Neoclassical
Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities,
edited by D.C. Colander Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger Publishing Company,
1984.
Findlay, Ronald and Stanislaw Wellisz. "Endogenous Tariffs, the
Political Economy of Trade Restrictions, and Welfare," in Import
Competition and Response, edited by J. N. Bhagwati. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1982, 245-58.
Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman. "Protection for
Sale." American Economic Review, September 1994, 833-50.
-----. "Trade Wars and Trade Talks." Journal of Political
Economy, August 1995a, 675-708.
-----. "The Politics of Free Trade Agreements." American
Economic Review, September 1995b, 667-90.
Helpman, Elhanan and Paul Krugman. Trade Policy and Market Structure.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1989.
Jones, Ronald W. "A Three Factor Model in Theory, Trade and
History," in Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth: Essays in Honor
of Charles P Kindleberger, edited by J. N. Bhagwati, R. A. Mundell, R.
W. Jones and J. Vanek. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1971.
Krueger, Anne O. "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking
Society" American Economic Review, June 1974, 291-303.
-----. Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization
Attempts and Consequences. Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1978.
-----. "The Political Economy of Controls: American Sugar,"
in Public Policy and Economic Development, edited by M. Scott and D.
Lal. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990.
-----. Political Economy of Policy Reform in Developing Countries
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. 1993.
Lovely, Mary E. and Douglas R. Nelson. "Illegal Trade and
Endogenous Tariff Formation." Public Finance/Finances Publiques,
1994 supplement, 182-94.
Magee, Stephen P., William A. Brock and Leslie Young. Black Hole
Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1989.
Mayer, Wolfgang "Endogenous Tariff Formation." American
Economic Review, December 1984, 970-85.
Pecorino, Paul. "Exogenous Tariff Changes with an Endogenous
Lobbying Response" Public Choice, July 1997, 91-108.
Rodrik, Dani. "The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World:
Why So Late? Why Now? Will it Last?" in Voting for Reform:
Democracy, Political Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment, edited by
S. Haggard and S. B. Webb. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1994.
-----. "Political Economy of Trade Policy," in Handbook of
International Economics v. 3, edited by G. M. Grossman, and K. Rogoff.
Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1995.
-----. "Understanding Economic Policy Reform" Journal of
Economic Literature, March 1996, 9-41.
Shughart, William F. "Private Antitrust Enforcement,
Compensation, Deterrence, or Extortion." Regulation, Winter 1990,
53-61.