Government consumption and growth.
Evans, Paul
I. INTRODUCTION
Interest in formulating and testing growth models has surged in
recent years. Following the seminal articles of Romer [1986] and Lucas
[1988], the theoretical growth literature has primarily sought to
endogenize the trend growth rate, which had been treated as an exogenous
parameter in the earlier vintage of growth models formulated by Solow
[1956] and Cass [1965] inter alia. Although the goal of endogenizing
trend growth rates is surely desirable, it is still important to test
whether trend growth rates are indeed better characterized as exogenous
or endogenous.
Many papers have attempted to do so. Unfortunately, virtually all
of them have used ordinary least squares to fit cross-sectional
regressions relating the average growth rate of per capita output over
some period to its initial value and other country characteristics.(1)
My 1996a paper shows that this method produces seriously biased
estimates and unreliable inferences.
This paper makes two contributions. First, using a simple
stochastic growth model that nests both exogenous and endogenous growth,
it shows that the growth rate of output per capita should be mean
stationary if growth is exogenous, and should be difference stationary
if growth is endogenous and any difference-stationary variable affects
investment. Specifically, if the share of output devoted to government
consumption is difference stationary, the growth rate should be mean
stationary or difference stationary depending on whether growth is
exogenous or endogenous. Furthermore, the growth rate should be
negatively related to the share of output devoted to exhaustive
government consumption if, and only if, growth is endogenous.
The second contribution is to test whether growth is exogenous or
endogenous. Data for 92 countries over the period 1960 to 1989 strongly
support the mean stationarity of the growth rate of per capita output
and are consistent with the difference stationarity of the share of
output devoted to government consumption. Moreover, the growth rate is
not significantly related to the government share. These two findings
support the exogeneity of growth. Finally, the relationship is precisely
estimated to be weak if not nonexistent. Hence, even if growth is
endogenous, the degree of endogeneity is likely to be small.(2)
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II
formulates a simple stochastic growth model for demonstrating the basic
theoretical results. Section III investigates whether growth rates are
mean stationary and whether shares of output devoted to government
consumption are difference stationary. Section IV examines whether and
how growth rates and government shares are related to each other.
Finally, section V summarizes the paper and offers a few conclusions.
II. THEORETICAL DISCUSSION
This section lays out a simple and tractable stochastic growth
model that nests both exogenous and endogenous growth. The model is
special in many ways because several restrictive assumptions are made
for the sake of tractability. Nevertheless, results similar to the ones
derived below should hold in a wide class of models.
Consider a closed economy inhabited by a government and a household
that lives in periods t = 0, 1, 2, .... The sole activity of the
government is exhaustively consuming G, which is financed by a
proportional tax on gross output Y at the rate [Tau]. Its budget
constraint is therefore
(1) [G.sub.t] = [[Tau].sub.t] [Y.sub.t].
I assume that government consumption is set so that
(2) [g.sub.t] = - ln[1 - ([G.sub.t] / [Y.sub.t])]
is a driftless difference-stationary process.
The household is endowed with one unit of labor, which it supplies
completely inelastically each period; a positive initial capital stock;
and a technology
(3) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
0 [less than] [Alpha] [less than or equal to] 1, t = 0, 1, 2, ...,
which transforms the one unit of labor and the services of the
[K.sub.t] units of capital on hand at the beginning of period t into
[Y.sub.t] units of gross output during period t. In equation (3),
[Alpha] is a parameter, a is a difference-stationary productivity shock,
and b is a mean-stationary productivity shock. Because the capital
variable K aggregates all reproducible factors including human capital
and all technical knowledge available to the economy and not available
elsewhere, its output elasticity a may conceivably be one; that is, K
may be subject to constant, rather than decreasing, returns to scale.
The stochastic variables g, a, and b are generated by the process
(4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Phi](L) is a 3 x 3 matrix of pth-order polynomials in the
lag operator L for which the lead term is the 3 x 3 identity matrix and
all of the roots of det[[Phi](L)] lie outside the unit circle, p is a
nonnegative integer, [Gamma] and [Delta] are parameters that equal the
unconditional means of [Delta]a and b and w is a serially uncorrelated
error vector with a zero mean and a positive definite covariance matrix.
Because g must lie on the interval, [0, [infinity]), the entries in the
first row and column of the covariance matrix are assumed to shrink
toward zero as g approaches zero. In other words, the first entry of w
must be heteroskedastic in order for g to be difference stationary as is
assumed. According to equations (3) and (4), the difference-stationary
component to productivity is Harrod neutral and the stationary component
is Hicks neutral. This assumption is necessary so that the economy can
have a stochastic balanced growth path with growth in output whether
[Alpha] [less than] 1 or [Alpha] = 1.
Given its endowments and knowledge of the process generating g, a,
and b and of their current and past realizations, the household
maximizes the objective function
(5) [E.sub.0] [summation of] [[Beta].sup.t] ln[C.sub.t] where t = 0
to infinity, 0 [less than] [Beta] [less than] 1,
subject to the sequence of budget constraints
(6) [C.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (1 - [[Tau].sub.t])[Y.sub.t], t = 0, 1,
2, ...,
the sequence of accumulation equations
(7) [K.sub.t+1] - [K.sub.t] = [I.sub.t] - [K.sub.t], t = 1, 2, 3,
...,
the sequence of technological constraints (3), and a sequence of
solvency constraints. In equations (5) through (7), [C.sub.t] and
[I.sub.t] are consumption and gross investment during period t and
[Beta] is a parameter. In order to make the model tractable, I have made
three noteworthy simplifying assumptions: the production function is
Cobb-Douglas; momentary utility is logarithmic; and capital depreciates
completely in a single period - see equation (7).
The first-order conditions for the household's problem are
(8) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and
(9) [C.sub.t] + [K.sub.t+1] = (1 - [[Tau].sub.t])[Y.sub.t].
In turn, equations (8) and (9) imply that(3)
(10) [C.sub.t] = (1 - [Alpha][Beta])(1 - [[Tau].sub.t])[Y.sub.t].
and
(11) [K.sub.t+1] = [Alpha][Beta](1 - [[Tau].sub.t])[Y.sub.t].
Finally, equations (10) and (11) imply that the household is always
solvent since the transversality condition
(12) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
is always satisfied.
Equilibrium is characterized by the stochastic process (4) for g,
a, and b; a positive value for [K.sub.0]; and functions that map
[K.sub.t], [g.sub.t], [g.sub.t-1], ..., [g.sub.t-p], [a.sub.t],
[a.sub.t-1], ..., [a.sub.t-p], and [b.sub.t], [b.sub.t-1], ...,
[b.sub.t-p+1] onto [Y.sub.t], [C.sub.t] and [K.sub.t+1] and that satisfy
equations (3), (10), and (11). Note that equations (1), (7) and (9)
imply the equilibrium condition
(13) [C.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] + [G.sub.t] = [Y.sub.t];
that is, the household and government always spend the gross output
of the closed economy.
Updating equation (3) one period, taking logarithms of both members
of the resulting equation, and substituting from equations (11), (1),
and (2) yields
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
or
(14) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [y.sub.t] [equivalent to] ln[Y.sub.t].(4)
I consider the two cases of output elasticity [Alpha] = 1 and
[Alpha] [less than] 1 separately. In the former case, equation (14)
reduces to
(15) [Delta][y.sub.t+1] = ln [Beta] - [g.sub.t] + [b.sub.t+1].
Equations (15) and (4) have five important implications. First, the
economy would have an average growth rate of [Delta] + In [Beta], were
government consumption always zero. Second, the growth rate is higher,
the more productive is the economy and the more patient is the
household. Third, purely transitory shocks to productivity induce
permanent changes in the level of output. Fourth, increasing g induces a
lower growth rate. Fifth, if one abstracts from fluctuations in b, the
growth rate wanders around the interval (-[infinity], [Delta] + In
[[Beta]] a s g wanders around the interval [0, [infinity]). For this
reason, the growth rate is difference stationary.
Letting [Alpha] [less than] 1, differencing equation (14), and
rearranging the resulting equation yields
(16) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Equations (16) and (4) have five important implications, which
differ markedly from those of the previous paragraph. First, the trend
growth rate is [Gamma] since the terms in the right-hand side of
equation (16) have zero means. Second, the trend growth rate depends on
neither the level of productivity nor the subjective discount rate.
Third, purely transitory shocks to productivity induce only transitory
changes in the level of output. Fourth, increasing g induces a lower
output level but does not affect the average growth rate. Fifth, the
growth rate is mean stationary.
These results should hold in a much wider class of models than
those considered here. The reason is plain to see. Without diminishing
returns, no force leads households to stop accumulating (decumulating)
reproducible factors following shocks to government consumption or to
restore the initial level of reproducible factors following transitory
shocks to productivity. By contrast, with diminishing returns, the
return to reproducible factors falls (rises), inducing consumption to
rise (fall) and reproducible factors to decumulate (accumulate). Given
that this result should hold quite generally, one should be able to test
whether growth is exogenous simply by testing whether growth rates are
mean stationary and whether government consumption affects the growth
rate permanently. Sections III and IV formulate and implement such
tests.
The result that the growth rate should be difference stationary if
growth is endogenous should generalize to cases in which other variables
affecting investment are difference stationary. Specifically, equation
(8) suggests that permanent shifts in [Tau] permanently affect the
growth rate of per capita consumption and hence the growth rate of per
capita output. Whether the shift occurs because government consumption
changes or because transfer payments, government regulation, or the
security of property rights changes should be immaterial.
III. TESTING ORDERS OF INTEGRATION
According to section II, [Delta][Y.sub.nt], the growth rate of per
capita output in some country n, should be difference stationary if
growth in that country is endogenous and if any variable affecting
investment is difference stationary. In particular, if the growth is
endogenous and [g.sub.nt], the share of output devoted to government
consumption for country n, is difference stationary, [Delta][y.sub.nt]
should also be difference stationary. By contrast, [Delta][y.sub.nt]
should be mean stationary if growth is exogenous.
Because the theory of the previous section suggests that g and
[Delta]y are heteroskedastic, I employ the method of Phillips and Perron [1988] in order to test whether they are mean stationary. Figure 1 plots
the test statistics obtained for 92 countries over the period
1960-1989.(5) The data come from the Penn World Tables of Summers and
Heston [1991] as updated in 1993. I selected a window length of six
years. The results for moderately shorter and longer window lengths are
qualitatively similar. According to the figure, the null hypothesis that
g is difference stationary can be rejected for only three of the 92
countries at the .05 significance level. Because three is less than .05
x 92, it is sensible to posit that g is difference stationary for all 92
countries. By contrast, the null hypothesis that [Delta]y is difference
stationary can be rejected for all but seven of the 92 countries.
Because Phillips-Perron tests on 30 annual observations have little
power to reject the null of difference stationarity even against
alternatives far from the null, this finding constitutes strong evidence
that [Delta]y is mean stationary for all 92 countries.
IV. A BIVARIATE TEST OF EXOGENOUS VS. ENDOGENOUS GROWTH
The theory of section II suggests that
(17) [Delta][y.sub.nt] = [[Mu].sub.n] +
[[Theta].sub.n][g.sub.n,t-1] + [e.sub.nt],
n = 1, 2, ..., N, t = 1, 2, ..., T.
where the [Mu]s and [Theta]s are parameters, the es are error
terms, N is the number of countries under consideration, and T is the
sample size for each country.(6) The parameter [[Theta].sub.n] is zero
or negative depending on whether growth is exogenous or endogenous in
country n. Under the null hypothesis that ([[Theta].sub.n] = 0), the
error term [e.sub.nt] has a zero mean and finite variance. Under the
alternative hypothesis that ([[Theta].sub.n] [less than] 0), it also has
a zero mean and finite variance so long as [g.sub.nt] is the only
difference-stationary variable that affects investment in country n. If
instead other such variables exist and growth is endogenous, then
[e.sub.nt] must be a driftless difference stationary process. Variables
that affect investment and that might conceivably be difference
stationary include the ratio of real transfer payments to output, the
degree of market power in product and factor markets, the extent to
which the government regulates business, and the security of property
rights.
Suppose that each e has the representation
(18) [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [Lambda] is a time-specific fixed effect, the [Psi]s are
parameters, [Epsilon] is an error term that is uncorrelated across
countries,(7) and m is a finite nonnegative integer large enough that
[Epsilon] is essentially uncorrelated with all leads and lags of
[Delta]g. Substituting equation (18) into equation (17) yields
(19) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Under the null hypothesis
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
equation (19) can be rewritten in the form
(20) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
n = 1, 2, ..., N, t = 1,2, ... T,
with [Theta] = 0 and [u.sub.nt] = [[Epsilon].sub.nt]
Furthermore, the error term u has a zero mean and a finite
variance. The appendix shows that applying ordinary least squares to
equation (20) yields an estimator [[micro]meter] which converges in
probability to zero as T approaches infinity. Moreover, using the method
of Newey and West [1987] produces a t-ratio that converges in
distribution to standard normal. By contrast, under the alternative
hypothesis
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
the t-ratio of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] diverges to
-[infinity] as T approaches infinity.(8) As a result, the null
hypothesis that all of the countries 1, 2, ..., N grow exogenously can
be easily tested against the alternative hypothesis that at least one of
them grows endogenously.(9)
Using ordinary least squares, I fitted equation (20) to the data
described in the previous section for values of m ranging from zero to
five years. I then used the method of Newey and West with a window
length of ten years to calculate standard errors, t-ratios, and marginal
significance levels. Table I reports the estimates, standard errors,
t-ratios, and marginal significance levels obtained. All of the
estimates are statistically insignificant at the .05 level on a
one-tailed test. For this reason, the hypothesis that all of the
countries grow exogenously cannot be rejected. Furthermore, the
estimates are small in magnitude and precisely estimated. Therefore,
even if some countries do grow endogenously, the degree of endogeneity
is likely to be small.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
Using a simple stochastic growth model that nests exogenous and
endogenous growth, I show that the growth rate of output per capita
should be mean stationary if growth is exogenous. If instead growth is
endogenous and any variable that affects investment is difference
stationary, the growth rate should be difference stationary. The paper
presents strong evidence that the growth rate is in fact mean
stationary. Evidence is also found that is consistent with the
difference stationarity [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] of the share
of output devoted to government consumption, a variable affecting
investment. These two pieces of evidence support the hypothesis that
growth is exogenous for the 92 countries considered here.
The model formulated in this paper also indicates that permanent
increases in the government's share of output appreciably and
permanently reduce the growth rate of output per capita if growth is
endogenous but only lower its level if growth is exogenous. No evidence
is found that the government's share permanently affects the growth
rate. The hypothesis that growth is exogenous is therefore further
supported. Moreover, even if growth is endogenous, my estimates indicate
that the degree of endogeneity is likely to be small.
APPENDIX
Without essential loss of generality, I suppose that
(A.1) [Delta][y.sub.nt] = [Theta][g.sub.n,t-1] + [e.sub.nt]
and
(A.2) [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [g.sub.n0] = 0 and [[e.sub.nt], [v.sub.nt]] is an error
vector that is independently and identically distributed across
economies and over time with a zero mean vector, a covariance matrix
[[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted]],
and finite fourth moments. Under the null hypothesis [H.sub.0], [Theta]
= 0. For this reason, the estimator [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
obtained by applying ordinary least squares to equation (A.1) for a
sample consisting of data for countries 1, 2, ..., N and periods 1, 2
..., T takes the form
(A.3) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Suppose that T approaches infinity. One then has
(A.4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Furthermore, Hamilton [1994, Chapter 19, Section 3] has shown that
conditional on [G.sub.nT] = {[g.sub.n0], [g.sub.n1], ...,
[g.sub.n,T-1]},
(A.5) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Hence, conditional on [G.sub.T] [equivalent to] {[G.sub.1T],
[G.sub.2T], ..., [G.sub.NT]},
(A.6) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Combining equations (A.4) and (A.6) then produces
(A.7) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
with
(A.8) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Equation (A.7) implies that for any natural number N, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] converges in probability to zero as T approaches
infinity. Without loss of generality, I set the window length for the
Newey-West standard error of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] to zero.
It is then given by
(A.9) [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Because [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] converges in probability to 0, [e.sub.nt] converges
in probability to [e.sub.nt]. Consequently, conditional on [G.sub.T],
(A.10) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
as T approaches infinity. The standard normal distribution,
however, does not depend on [G.sub.T]. For this
reason, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] must converge
unconditionally in distribution to standard normal as T approaches
infinity for any given natural number N.
Under [H.sub.1], one must allow for the possibility that the
[Theta]s are not identical. In that case, equation (A.1) should be
replaced by
(A.11) [Delta][y.sub.nt] = [[Theta].sub.n][g.sub.n,t-1] +
[e.sub.nt],
and equation (A.3) takes the form
(A.12) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
with
(A.13) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Under [H.sub.1], the quantity [N.sup.-1] [summation of]
[M.sub.n][[Theta].sub.n] where n = 1 to N converges in probability to a
negative quantity, which I denote [Theta], since the Ms are positive and
at least some of the [Theta]s are negative. As a result, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] behaves like [N.sup.1/2] T [Theta] asymptotically;
that is, it diverges to - [infinity]. Hence, [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] diverges under [H.sub.1]. This result holds whether e is mean
stationary or difference stationary. Finally, note that the convergence
under [H.sub.0] and the divergence under [H.sub.1] is faster, the larger
N is.
1. A far from exhaustive list is Kormendi and Meguire [1985];
Baumol [1986]; De Long [1988]; Barro [1991]; De Long and Summers [1991];
Barro and Sala-i-Martin [1992]; Mankiw, Romer, and Weil [1992]; King and
Levine [1993]; De Gregorio [1993]; Easterly [1993]; Easterly, Kremer,
Pritchett, and Summers [1993]; Alesina and Rodrik [1994]; and Persson
and Tabellini [1994].
2. After writing this paper, I learned of papers by Jones [1995]
and Kocherlakota and Yi [1995] that estimate models similar to mine.
Because these papers consider much smaller samples of countries than I
consider here and do not pool their data, their tests are likely to be
much less powerful than mine. Furthermore, they appear not to account
properly in their estimation for the possibility of a common trend in
the data. My 1996b paper is also related to this paper.
3. Equations (8) and (9) become identities if equations (10) and
(11) are substituted into them.
4. The model can be easily extended to permit government
consumption to generate productive services as in Barro [1990]. If
equation (3) is replaced by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
equation (1) implies that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
with [Alpha] [equivalent to] [[Alpha].sub.1] / (1 -
[[Alpha].sub.2]) and [Zeta] [equivalent to] [[Alpha].sub.2] / (1 -
[[Alpha].sub.2]). The parameter
[Alpha] is less than or equal to one depending on whether
[[Alpha].sub.1] + [[Alpha].sub.2] is less than or equal to one.
Manipulations similar to those in the text then lead to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Empirical analysis of this equation using the procedure of section
IV yields small and statistically insignificant estimates of [Xi].
Therefore, the data analyzed here are consistent with the assumption of
the text that government consumption is not productive.
5. I included all countries in the 98-country sample of Mankiw,
Romer, and Weil for which the requisite data are available over the
entire period 1960-1989 plus Taiwan. These countries are Algeria,
Angola, Argentina, Australia, Austria, Bangladesh, Belgium, Benin,
Bolivia, Botswana, Brazil, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Canada,
Central African Republic, Chad, Chile, Colombia, Congo, Costa Rica,
Denmark, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Finland,
France, Germany, Ghana, Greece, Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras, Hong Kong,
India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Ivory Coast, Jamaica, Japan,
Jordan, Kenya, Korea, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Malaysia, Mauritania,
Mauritius, Mexico, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar, Netherlands, New
Zealand, Niger, Nigeria, Norway, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea,
Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Portugal, Rwanda, Senegal, Singapore,
Somalia, South Africa, Spain, Sri Lanka, Sweden, Switzerland, Syria,
Taiwan, Thailand, Togo, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda,
United Kingdom, United States, Venezuela, Zaire, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.
6. Let [[Beta].sub.n], [[Gamma].sub.n], [a.sub.nt], and [b.sub.nt]
be the analogues of [Beta], [Gamma], [a.sub.t], and [b.sub.t] for
country n. If growth is endogenous, equation (15) implies that
[[Mu].sub.n] [equivalent to] ln [[Beta].sub.n], [[Theta].sub.n]
[equivalent to] -1, and [e.sub.nt] [equivalent to] [b.sub.nt]. If growth
is exogenous, equation (16) implies that [[Mu].sub.n] = [[Gamma].sub.n],
[[Theta].sub.n] = 0, and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
7. Ideally, the error term [Epsilon] should be allowed to be
correlated across countries. In practice, doing so would create
insurmountable problems. The inclusion of the time-specific fixed effect
[Lambda] in equation (18) may be sufficient, however, to account for
most cross-country correlation. Moreover, the estimates obtained below
are consistent even if [Epsilon] is correlated across countries and the
standard errors and t-ratios obtained may not be seriously biased.
8. Divergence occurs whether [Epsilon] is mean stationary or
difference stationary. This result is fortunate since
difference-stationary variables other than the share of output devoted
to government consumption are likely to affect investment.
9. Note that the formulation (20) permits complete cross-country
heterogeneity in the [Mu]s and [Psi]s under [H.sub.0] and in the [Mu]s,
[Phi]s, and [Theta]s under [H.sub.1].
REFERENCES
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. "Distributive Politics and
Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1994, 465-90.
Barro, Robert J. "Government Spending in a Simple Model of
Endogenous Growth." Journal of Political Economy, October 1990,
S103-25.
-----, "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1991, 407-43.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin.
"Convergence." Journal of Political Economy, April 1992,
223-51.
Baumol, William J. "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and
Welfare: What the Long-Run Data Show." American Economic Review,
December 1986, 1072-85.
Cass, David M. "Optimum Growth in an Aggregate Model of
Capital Accumulation." Review of Economic Studies, July 1965,
233-40.
De Gregorio, Jose. "Inflation, Taxation, and Long-Run
Growth." Journal of Monetary Economics, June 1993, 271-98.
De Long, Bradford. "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and
Welfare. Comment." American Economic Review, December 1988,
1138-54.
De Long, Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers. "Equipment
Investment and Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
May 1991,407-44.
Easterly, William. "How Much Do Distortions Affect
Growth?" Journal of Monetary Economics, November 1993, 187-212.
Easterly, William, Michael Kremer, Lant Pritchett, and Lawrence H.
Summers. "Good Policy or Good Luck? Country Growth Performance and
Temporary Shocks." Journal of Monetary Economics, December 1993,
459-83.
Evans, Paul. "Using Cross-Country Variances to Evaluate Growth
Theories." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, June 1996a,
1027-49.
-----. "Growth and the Neutrality of Money." Empirical
Economics, September 1996b, 187-202.
Hamilton, James D. Time Series Analysis. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press, 1994.
Jones, Charles. "Time Series Tests of Endogenous Growth
Models." Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1995, 495-526.
King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. "Finance and Growth:
Schumpeter Might Be Right." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August
1993, 717-38.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R., and Kei-Mu Yi. "Is There Endogenous
Long Run Growth? Evidence from the U.S. and U.K." Manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, August 1995.
Kormendi, Roger, and Philip Meguire. "Macroeconomic Determinants of Growth: Cross-Country Evidence." Journal of
Monetary Economics, September 1985, 141-63.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "On the Mechanics of Economic
Development." Journal of Monetary Economics, July 1988, 3-42.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weft. "A
Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, May 1992,407-38.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. "A Simple Positive
Semi-definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent
Covariance Matrix." Econometrica, May 1987, 703-08.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. "Is Inequality
Harmful?" American Economic Review, June 1994, 600-21.
Phillips, Peter C. B., and Pierre Perron. "Testing for a Unit
Root in Time Series Regressions." Biometrika, June 1988, 335-46.
Romer, Paul M. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth."
Journal of Political Economy, October 1986, 1002-37.
Solow, Robert M. "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1956, 65-94.
Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston. "The Penn World Table (Mark
5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1991, 327-68.