Institutional change and the velocity of money: a century of evidence.
Bordo, Michael D. ; Jonung, Lars ; Siklos, Pierre L. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The study of the long-run behavior of velocity has intrigued many
researchers who have sought to link it to the evolution of financial
systems over time. Indeed, the approach taken by Bordo and Jonung [1987]
(BJ) explains the long-run portion of velocity in five countries by
institutional factors including monetization and financial development,
while the seminal study by Friedman and Schwartz [1982] (FS) argues that
financial sophistication is an important determinant of the long-run
behavior of velocity in the U.S. and the U.K. The aim of this study is
to further explore the connection between long-run velocity movements
across several countries, as well as the relationship between countries
of its principal institutional and economic determinants.
This line of research is important for a number of reasons. It allows
us to demonstrate that the demand for real balances cannot be adequately
expressed by a few aggregates alone and that institutional variables
need be included. If technological changes in the financial system are
found to influence the demand for money, this has implications for the
question of whether the demand for real balances is likely to be stable
over time. This also impinges on the links which are thought to exist
between monetary aggregates and economic activity. Finally, as Boughton
[1992] argues, international comparisons of the demand for money reveal
not only that institutional factors represent an important determinant
of velocity, but that these appear to differ in the short-run across
countries. Given the increasingly global nature of financial markets, it
is of interest to explore whether the common development of long-term
institutional changes among selected countries represents only a postwar
phenomenon.
BJ [1981; 1987] suggest that institutional changes explain much of
the long-run behavior of velocity. Siklos [1993], following upon BJ,
confirms that in order to generate a long-run statistical model of
velocity, a conventional model of velocity (as a function of real income
and the nominal interest rate) needs to be augmented with institutional
change proxies. Many economists now contend that institutional change
represents an important element in explaining the long-run behavior of
velocity or the demand for money (e.g., Laidler [ 1993]).(1)
This study examines the long- and short-run relationship of velocity
for a sample of five industrialized countries using annual data
beginning in 1870. Since the "long run" in economics need not
be the same for all problems, an important issue is the selection of the
sampling frequency of the data (e.g., Perron [1991]). In particular, the
effects of technological or institutional changes in the financial
sector occur slowly, necessitating as long a sample as possible.
Given recent findings by BJ [1990] and Siklos [1993], which
empirically demonstrate that institutional change is common to each
country, it would seem natural to ask whether there are common features
in financial changes across countries. To investigate such a
possibility, we perform a variety of tests to determine if velocity, and
each of its individual determinants are, separately, cointegrated across
countries. We also examine the short-run dynamics and the stability of
any unique cointegrating relationship which is detected using some
recently developed statistical tests. Finally, we attempt to estimate a
joint velocity function by pooling data for all the countries in our
sample.(2) In so doing, we improve on the earlier studies of long-run
common movements in velocity and its conventional and institutional
determinants, presented by BJ [1987, ch. 4] and FS [1982, ch. 7].
In performing time-series tests our objectives are three-fold. First,
we wish to explore whether the common features of financial systems
across countries are as significant as FS [1982, ch. 7] found them to be
for the U.S. and the U.K., based on more sophisticated measures of
correlation. We also expand the selection of countries to include Canada
and Sweden.(3) Second, an analysis of the common features of
institutional change across countries could shed some light on the speed
with which technological changes are transmitted across countries. That
is, do countries at similar stages of development in effect import
payments technologies from other countries? A third objective is to
ascertain whether certain historical features, which would presumably have had an impact on financial development, can be detected in the
data. It is here that structural stability tests serve a useful purpose.
Briefly, the results lend support to the view that there exists a single
cross-country long-run relationship in velocity, but not in income and
interest rates. We also find that only a model which includes
institutional change proxies is both properly specified in the pooled
time-series case and produces long-run elasticities consistent with
theoretical predictions. In general, we argue that the statistical
evidence can only be understood in the context of common historical
developments in the respective countries' financial systems.
Another important conclusion is that studies which suggest that
international linkages between financial developments are essentially a
post-World War II phenomenon are misleading. The common development of
institutional changes in the financial system is not a recent
occurrence, for we find signs of such behavior dating back to at least
the beginning of this century.
After a brief review of the institutionalist hypothesis of the
long-run behavior of velocity (section II), and a description of
econometric issues (section III), empirical evidence confirming the
above conclusions are presented (section Iv). The paper concludes with a
summary in section V.
II. THE INSTITUTIONALIST APPROACH: A REVIEW
Since much has been written about the institutionalist explanation of
the long-run behavior of velocity advanced by BJ [1981] (see also BJ
[1987; 1990], Siklos [1993], Ireland [1991], Laidler [1993], and
Hallman, Porter and Small [1991]), we present only a very brief review
here.
Velocity is traditionally viewed as an analogue of the demand for
real money balances. Consequently, it is treated as a function of income
(or permanent income) and an interest rate. The latter variable serves
as a proxy for the opportunity cost of holding money.(4) BJ suggest
that, in addition to its traditional determinants, velocity is a
function of institutional changes in the financial system. These
institutional developments proceed in roughly two phases. First, most
economies experience a monetization phase. During this period money is
used more intensively to settle transactions. At the same time, the
speed with which the banking system spreads throughout the economy
produces rapid growth in the use of currency and deposits. A second
stage is characterized by growing financial sophistication during which
the number of substitutes for bank notes and deposits grows. The
combination of these two factors produces a U-shaped long-run pattern in
velocity for the countries considered in this paper. As shown in Figure
1, velocity demonstrates a falling trend that ends during the interwar
period and a rising trend starting for most countries in our sample in
the mid-1940s. The downward trend in velocity before World War II is
attributed to the process of monetization, and the upward trend since to
two developments:(5) increasing financial sophistication and improved
economic stability.(6)
The striking similarity in the behavior of velocity across
industrialized countries suggests the possibility of common financial
developments in different countries despite differences in fiscal and
monetary policies, in their inflationary experiences, and industrial
development. Alternatively, the shared economic features might be due to
similar experiences in income or interest rate patterns. For example,
existing economic and historical evidence suggests that while there are
several common features in macroeconomic aggregates such as GNP and
consumption across countries (e.g., Backus and Kehoe [1992]), none of
the studies, to our knowledge, has applied tests of cointegration either
to determine whether financial change is common across countries or to
attempt to isolate the sources of common movements if they exist.(7)
Many authors have applied tests of cointegration to determine whether
the traditional determinants of the demand for money, namely income and
interest rates, are cointegrated with some measure of the money stock.
Miller [1991] and Hafer and Jansen [1991] represent only a partial list
of recent contributions in this area. Existing empirical evidence for
U.S. data suggests that a broad monetary aggregate (usually M2), income
and nominal interest rates are cointegrated over a variety of samples,
at least for U.S. data.
By contrast, empirical evidence is decidedly mixed for models which
use an M1 definition of money. Baba, Hendry, and Starr [1992] augment
their long-run M1 model to incorporate yield spreads and risk features
of interest rate behavior. Miller [1991] finds that M1 is an unreliable
variable for understanding short-run money demand behavior. Hafer and
Jansen [1991] prefer M2 over M1 for U.S. annual data since 1915, in the
sense of finding cointegration among the variables in a conventional
money demand relation. Because the M2 definition incorporates the
influence over time of financial innovations, this may explain a
potential source of money demand instability in M1-based models (see
also Baba, Hendry, and Starr [1992]).
Recent theoretical work has also attempted to model the role of
technological changes in the financial sector. Ireland [1994]
incorporates two of the features which are central in the empirical work
to follow, namely monetization and growing financial sophistication, in
a general equilibrium model which is capable of reproducing empirical
facts about the long-run behavior of velocity.
III. ECONOMETRIC SPECIFICATION
Specifications Tested
Cointegration describes the relationship between two or more time
series which appear to share a common trend as a statistical description
of the long run in economics. A large literature has refined and
improved the original single-equation testing procedure presented in
Engle and Granger [1987] (EG). Tests for cointegration have also become
popular as one way, albeit not the only one, of conducting inference on
time series which are non-stationary and drift over time.
The fundamental approach of this paper may be described as follows.
Let velocity, [v.sub.t], be determined by its traditional determinants,
denoted by the vector [Phi], and its institutional proxies, denoted by
the vector [Omega]. The institutionalist hypothesis may then be written
(1) [v.sub.it] = [[Beta].sub.0][prime] + [[Beta].sub.1][prime]
[[Phi].sub.it] + [[Beta].sub.2][prime] [[Omega].sub.it] +
[[Epsilon].sub.t].
The vector [Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [y.sup.p] is real
per capita permanent income, and R is a proxy for the opportunity cost
of holding money. The vector of institutional proxies
[Omega]=[[(NBFA/FA).sub.t], [(C/M).sub.t], [lnal.sub.t]], where NBFA/FA
is the ratio of total non-bank financial assets to total financial
assets, (C/M) is the currency-money ratio, and lnal is the share of the
labor force in nonagricultural pursuits. The index i identifies a
particular country and t is time.
The theoretical rationale for the vector [Phi] is well known (see
Goldfeld and Sichel [1990] for a survey). The motivation behind the
vector [Omega] can be stated briefly as follows (see also BJ [1987]).
Since NBFA/FA proxies financial development, its increase would be
expected to reduce the demand for money by increasing the number of
close substitutes and thereby raising velocity. The C/M series mirrors
the spread of commercial banking since, as the banking habit spreads,
the use of deposits increases relative to the use of currency (i.e., C/M
falls). This increases the desired holdings of real balances and reduces
velocity. Thus, changes in velocity are positively related to changes in
C/M. The steady rise in the proponion of the labor force in
non-agricultural pursuits reflects the "spread of the monetary
economy" (BJ [1987, 34]) and growing urbanization. Other things
being equal, BJ predict that, as this series rises over time, velocity
falls.(8)
Previous research (BJ [1981; 1987; 1990] and Siklos [1993]) has
concentrated on estimates of equation (1) for individual countries. The
present application pools data for up to five countries and estimates a
"North Atlantic Velocity Function" to determine whether a
common velocity function can be identified. If so, institutional change
may be a common feature for at least the countries considered in our
sample. In addition, because previous studies have suggested that the
[Omega] vector, in particular, significantly explains velocity in each
of the countries considered, this would suggest that if a velocity
function is common to all countries, it may be due to common features in
[Omega] or [Phi], or both. Thus, one objective of the present empirical
analysis is to examine whether the following linear combinations are
also stationary, that is, whether they are cointegrated.
(2) [v.sub.it] + [[Delta].sub.0][prime] [v.sub.jt] =
[[Epsilon].sub.v],
(3) [[Phi].sub.it] + [[Delta].sub.1][prime] [[Phi].sub.jt] =
[[Epsilon].sub.[Phi]],
(4) [[Omega].sub.it] + [[Delta].sub.2][prime] [[Omega].sub.jt] =
[[Epsilon].sub.[Omega]], i [not equal to] j,
where v is a vector to indicate that a cointegrating relationship for
velocity exists between a time series for countries i and j, where j can
represent values for one or several countries and the residuals
[Epsilon] are stationary. For example, suppose we have a sample
consisting of data from two countries. The finding that a relationship
with cointegrating vector [1 -1] is stationary would imply that velocity
in country i is cointegrated with velocity in country j, thereby
establishing a long-run statistical relationship between velocity in the
two countries. The same arguments can be extended to the case where
three or more countries are considered and to the relationship between
the variables in equations (2) to (4).
Next, suppose that [[Phi].sub.i] and [[Phi].sub.j] are not
cointegrated, while one is able to reject the absence of cointegration
between [[Omega].sub.i] and [[Omega].sub.j], and that
[[Beta].sub.1][prime] = 0 in equation (1). In that case the explanation
for the common movement in [v.sub.i] and [v.sub.j] would be explained by
common movements in elements of [[Omega].sub.i] and [[Omega].sub.j].
Since the latter vector proxies financial development, this implies that
financial development is common in one or more of the countries
sampled.(9) Alternatively, of course, it may be that the cointegrating
relationship in velocity is explained by common trends in income and
interest rates (e.g., as in when [[Beta].sub.2][prime] = 0 in equation
(1)). Clearly, some combination of the two extremes is also possible,
although we intend to empirically demonstrate that, at least in the long
run, one can easily reject the hypothesis that [[Beta].sub.2][prime] = 0
in terms of equation (1), and that this is due to the properties of
equation (4). It is the omission of the vector [Omega] in much of the
previous work in this area that we wish to draw attention to. The
approach outlined in equations (2) to (4) also begs the question whether
any long-run relationship is stable and whether we can identify the
transmission of institutional factors from one country to another.
Gregory and Hansen [1996] develop tests of the stability of
cointegrating relationships. They find a break in a conventional U.S.
money demand function during the early 1940s, but the evidence against
stability is not strong.
Testing for Unit Roots and Cointegration
There exists a large literature examining whether economic time
series are stationary around a deterministic trend, or are the sum of a
permanent component best described as a random walk (perhaps with a
drift) and a transitory component. We assume, based on existing
empirical evidence, that each of the series in equation (1) possesses a
unit root. This contention is based on results of several available unit
root tests. Test results using the present data set have been presented
in Siklos [1993].(10) Testing for unit roots is often viewed as a first
step in determining whether two or more series are cointegrated.(11)
The approach used here to study common features in time series is
based on the work of Johansen [1991], and Hansen and Johansen [1992].
Since several expositions of the technique are now available in the
literature (e.g., Johansen [1991], Johansen and Juselius [1990], Hafer
and Jansen [1991]), we refer readers to these sources for the details
about the so-called Johansen procedure for tests of cointegration.
Johansen's procedure also enables the investigator to perform a
variety of tests of various restrictions imposed on a model.
Nevertheless, there are a number of issues which need to be
considered when applying Johansen's procedure. First, is the
selection of the lag length in the VAR. Lag lengths in this study were
selected on the basis of Akaike's Information Criterion (AIC),
primarily because it tends to select relatively long lags thereby
reducing the chances of certain types of specification errors.
Two test statistics can be used to evaluate the number of
cointegrating relationships, namely the trace test and the maximal eigenvalue test. For long samples, such as the one considered here, the
two tests generally yield the same conclusions. Results based only on
the trace test are reported below while other test results are available
upon request.(12)
The Stability of Cointegrating Relationships
While wars or the Great Depression may not have influenced the
long-run common pattern in velocity across the countries considered, it
is nevertheless possible that these events may have interrupted the
relationship which exists between the time series. BJ [1987, ch. 4]
separately examined periods of falling and rising velocity and found few
differences across countries in the latter period which largely
coincides with the post-World War II era. They did not, however, rely on
a statistical test to determine whether their chosen break-point is
appropriate.(13) FS [1982, ch. 7] adjust their estimates of the
relationship between secular movements in velocity between the U.S. and
the U.K. by including dummy variables for wars and the Depression.
Similarly, they document the fact that while velocity movements in the
U.S. and the U.K. "reflect a unified financial system" (FS
[1982, 337]), some differences exist during the pre-1914 period. This is
apparent from Figure 1 since it suggests that velocity levels were
falling in all of the countries considered, except the U.K. which
exhibited only a slight overall decline in the period 1870-1914.
Several responses are available to address these issues. One is to
test for structural breaks at particular known dates. However, unless we
catalog all of the events which can impinge on the financial
relationship between countries, we cannot be certain that the most
significant structural break has been accounted for. For this reason it
is preferable to rely on tests for which the date of the structural
break is unknown. Therefore, we implement recently developed tests for
stability in cointegrated relationships where the timing of such a break
is unknown.(14) Alternatively, the stability of any cointegrating
relationship can also be explored by estimating the relevant
relationships recursively. In each recursion a new observation is added
and the model is reestimated. Previously used observations are not
discarded. This approach enables us to examine the evolution of any
postulated relationship over time and is thus not subject to the
criticism of ad hoc sample selection.(15) We can also explore the
stability of long-run relationships by generating rolling estimates
where a fixed proportion of the sample is analyzed in a sequential
fashion. This procedure has the advantage of giving each additional
observation in the rolling regressions equal weight as opposed to the
declining weights inherent in the recursive approach. Either approach
seems preferable to estimation over selected subsamples though such
testing was also conducted (results not shown).(16)
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED]
IV. DATA AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Data
The annual data used in this study are updated from BJ [1987]. The
sample begins in 1870 and ends in 1986. Given the difficulty of updating
some of the institutional change proxies (particularly the NBFA/FA
series) the data could not be readily extended beyond 1986. Five
countries are considered in the empirical results reported below. They
are the U.S., U.K., Canada, Sweden, and Norway.
Testing for Cointegration. Table I presents tests of cointegration
based on the Johansen methodology for equations (2) to (4) separately
for the whole sample. Panel (A) of the table tests for cointegration
using data for the four countries in which the series are available for
the full sample. Panel (B) of Table I adds Norway to the list of
countries considered but omits the years 1921-1922 and 1940-1945 because
data for Norway were non-existent. For velocity, the results are the
same in both cases. We find that one cannot reject the null that a
unique cointegrating relationship exists between velocity for Canada,
the U.S., the U.K., and Sweden. To the extent that velocity reflects
income, interest rate and institutional changes, the results reflect the
statistical confirmation that velocity levels in these countries are
attracted to each other in a statistical sense. These results would also
be the analogue of the Backus and Kehoe [1992] findings of striking
similarities in international business cycles.(17)
The remaining cointegration test results in Table I seek to determine
whether, separately, other determinants of velocity are cointegrated.
Our findings may be summarized as follows. One cannot reject the null of
a single cointegrating vector between [y.sup.p] for the four countries
in our data set. The results differ, however, when the truncated sample
is considered (panel B). There we find that at least three cointegrating
vectors exist for permanent income. Thus, if we control for the war
years, there is evidence of possibly one common stochastic trend in
income but not of a unique equilibrium relationship for all the
countries considered. This means that any one country's income is
representative of income-level movements of all the countries considered
here. In general, however, since the number of cointegrating vectors for
all series except velocity and lnal, rises when Norway is added, this
would suggest that Norway belongs in the long-run analysis considered.
There is also no evidence of a single cointegrating vector in
interest rates for either case considered. Instead, one cannot reject
the null of two or three cointegrating vectors (i.e., two common trends)
between interest rates depending on whether Norway and the war years are
excluded. Given the findings of different numbers of cointegrating
vectors in Table I, it may be of interest to test whether data from some
countries can be excluded altogether from the long-run relationships
considered so far. This is accomplished by testing the significance of
the long-run coefficients in the cointegrating relationships, as well as
testing the hypothesis of weak exogeneity in the error correction
representation of the estimated models (see below). Results (not shown)
indicate that one cannot exclude any country's velocity in Table I
(panel A or B) from the cointegrating vector. Thus, (log) velocity
levels in all five countries are related to each other in the
long-run.(18) This result was confirmed not only by testing whether an
individual country's velocity can be excluded but also via tests to
determine whether separate cointegrating relationships could be found
over the whole sample for Canada and the U.S., the U.S. and the U.K., or
the U.K. and Sweden.(19)
Turning to real per capita income, we found that a unique
cointegrating relationship among income levels could be identified by
excluding Canada while, for the long-term interest rate, both Canada and
Sweden can be omitted from a long-run relationship. Further tests
indicate that separate long-run relationships between the U.S., the U.K.
and Sweden appear to exist for the interest rate. Therefore, the
findings for permanent income and the interest rate imply that permanent
income may be a relatively more important determinant of the long-run
behavior of velocity, as Siklos [1993] suggested. BJ [1981; 1987]
suggest that interest rates might be a relatively more important
variable in explaining the long-run behavior of velocity than permanent
income. The cointegration test results for the institutional proxies, at
least in panel A of Table I, suggest that a single cointegrating vector
is found for (C/M) as well as the financial sophistication proxy
(NBFA/FA). Thus, there appear to be long-run common features in
institutional change. For the labor force variable, there does not
appear to be a single common stochastic trend as the null of four
cointegrating vectors is rejected by the trace test. When Norway is
included, one cannot reject the null of two vectors. Exclusion tests
performed on the currency-money ratio proxy for institutional change
reveal that one cannot exclude any of the countries, thus giving rise to
a single cointegrating vector with the four countries considered. For
the NBFA/FA proxy for financial development one can omit Canada so that
a unique cointegrating relation with the U.S., U.K., and Sweden
adequately describes the long run for this series.
The Transmission of Institutional Change
The results in the previous section suggest that the dynamic
relationship among many of [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] the
series considered can be modeled via a vector autoregression augmented
by error correction terms. Vector error correction models (VECM) are
useful as a further test of the cointegration hypothesis, as a device to
determine the size of the error or deviation in an equilibrium
relationship, and to determine which variable in a system is weakly
exogenous relative to other variables in the model. To illustrate, the
results of the estimation of VECMs for velocity are provided in Table
II. The error correction terms, z, are statistically significant and of
the correct sign in all of the regressions except in the U.S. equation,
where the error correction term is statistically insignificant. Hence,
these results suggest that U.S. velocity is weakly exogenous of velocity
in the other countries. Together with the results considered in Table I,
there is confirmation of a unique cointegrating relation in velocity
among the four countries considered. The size of the error correction
terms is small, suggesting that adjustment to equilibrium is slow, in
the order of approximately 7% to 8% per year in the U.K. and Swedish
cases for example. Such an outcome is not surprising since institutional
change is believed to take place slowly and has long-lasting effects on
the demand for money, as discussed in BJ [1987, ch. 3]. Further insights
may be gained from Figure 2 which plots estimates based on a rolling
regression with a fixed sample size of 40 years, along with the standard
error bands, of the error correction terms for the U.K. and Sweden
equations in Table II.(20) The top panel of Figure 2 reveals that the
size of the error correction coefficients becomes larger for the U.K.
following 1967 (the year of the sterling devaluation), indicative of
relatively faster adjustment toward equilibrium in the post-Bretton
Woods period.(21) This is interpreted as a reflection of the relatively
greater impact of U.S. variables in the postwar period, that is, an
indication of growing international financial integration since 1946.
For Sweden, the impact of U.S. velocity is strongest during the
1925-1945 period but becomes more stable thereafter.(22) These results
provide support for FSs and BJs earlier evidence of the existence of a
unified financial system among the industrialized countries, as well as
the dominant influence of U.S. velocity on velocity in the other
countries. Figure 2 also suggests the possibility, because the size of
the coefficients are rather different between the pre- and postwar
samples, that a structural stability problem might exist.
A North Atlantic Velocity Function?
We performed additional cointegration tests to determine whether the
long-run behavior of velocity is explained by conventional or
institutional variables, or both, in a panel data set. This is
accomplished by stacking the data on the conventional and institutional
variables for all five countries.(23) Panel A in Table III tests whether
permanent income and an interest rate jointly explain the long-run
behavior of velocity (i.e., model 1 with [[Beta].sub.2][prime] = 0).
Panel B of Table III adds the institutional determinants to test whether
these can also explain long-run velocity. Table III also provides
estimates of the long-run elasticities (i.e., the cointegrating vector)
of each of the determinants with respect to velocity.
Panel A suggests that we are unable to reject the null of a single
cointegrating vector between velocity, permanent income and an interest
rate.(24) However, whereas the income elasticity is found not to be
significantly different from one at the 10% level of significance, the
interest elasticity is of the wrong sign and a test of the null of a
zero interest elasticity is rejected.(25) On this basis, the
conventional velocity model appears to be misspecified. When the
institutional determinants of velocity are included along with the
traditional determinants, the results in panel B lead to the conclusion
that one cannot reject the null of four cointegrating vectors at the 10%
level. Restrictions need to be imposed, therefore, in order to identify
a cointegrating vector. It seems reasonable, based on the results of
panel A, as well as the results for the individual series considered
above, to impose unitary elasticity and a zero elasticity on the lnal
variable.(26) The resulting vector is one for which the signs of all the
coefficients conform with the theoretical predictions of both the
conventional and institutionalist hypotheses of velocity, and thus this
appears to be a well-specified model of velocity. Since the mean
interest rate over all five countries is .054, this implies a North
Atlantic interest elasticity of 0.22 which is well within the range
found by FS [1982, Table 6.11] for the U.S. and the U.K., and Hafer and
Jansen [1991] for the U.S.
The Stability of the Cointegrating Relationships
To establish the robustness of the results of the previous section to
sample selection, we evaluated the cointegration test statistics first
for the 1870-1913 sample and then by increasing the sample five years
forward until the full sample was reached. In the case of the
conventional model of velocity (equation (1) with [[Beta].sub.2][prime]
= 0) the null cannot be rejected for any post-World War II sample for
Canada; for the U.S. and Sweden there is a tendency for [TABULAR DATA
FOR TABLE III OMITTED] the same null not to be rejected for samples
ending after 1958 (and beginning in 1873); for the U.K. there is
considerable variation, with the inability to reject the null
concentrated in pre-World War II samples as well as the full sample
(1872-1985). By contrast, when the institutionalist model is considered,
it is generally not possible to find cases where the null of no
cointegration cannot be rejected, the only exception being the U.S. for
the full sample (1873-1986). Similar results were obtained when the
cointegration tests were generated via rolling regressions.
We also considered a number of other tests of the stability of the
cointegrating relationships given in Tables I and III. Test statistics
which complement the results of Table I, panel A, were also
generated.(27) The null of a single cointegrating vector cannot be
rejected beginning with the 1870-1983 sample only, so that the
cointegrating rank is not, strictly speaking, constant. This points to a
possible source of instability in equation (2). However, it should also
be noted that the cointegrating rank is stable if a 15% significance
level is chosen throughout all subsamples. The evidence against the
stability of equation (2) is, therefore, not overwhelming. We also
examined whether our findings for equation (1) reported in Table III
would be affected by how the countries in the sample were grouped
together. Thus, we compared estimates of equation (1), with and without
the institutional variables, and found the results in Table III to be
generally robust only when the institutionalist variables are added to
the model. In other words, for the conventional velocity model, one
cannot reject the null of no cointegration for any subsample (as in
Table III, panel A). Hence, the pooled cointegration test results are
specific to the full sample only, but the same was not found to be true
for the institutionalist model where the null of zero cointegrating
vectors is easily rejected. The results are the same, at the 12.5% level
of significance, as those shown in panel B of Table III when all
countries are considered in a panel. Again, while it is possible that
the "North Atlantic" velocity function is unstable, the
statistical evidence against stability is not particularly strong.
Finally, the results of implementing the Gregory-Hansen [1996] test
reveal that there is no apparent instability in the cointegrating
relationships considered. Thus, the equilibrium relationship describing
velocity, permanent income, and the interest rate across countries
(i.e., as in equations (2) and (3)) does not appear to be subject to a
regime shift.
V. CONCLUSIONS
This paper utilizes cointegration and error correction modeling to
investigate the role of institutional factors in explaining the long-run
behavior of the income velocity of money in five industrialized
countries. Relying on recent work which suggests that institutional
factors are important determinants of velocity's behavior in
individual western industrialized countries, we asked in this paper
whether these factors can explain the common U-shaped pattern of
velocity for over a century of data for these countries. Notwithstanding
the difficulties in measuring and assessing financial development and
innovations (Boughton [1992]), the evidence presented in this paper
suggests that institutional change is a good candidate to explain the
striking similarities in the long-run behavior of velocity.(28) The
importance of institutional factors is also reinforced by the finding
that it is comparatively hard to detect instability in the long-run
velocity model augmented with financial change proxies.(29)
The implications of our findings are important for at least three
reasons. First, studies of the long-run behavior of velocity are
inadequate if they exclude the impact of technological changes affecting
the financial sector. Second, our empirical results clearly demonstrate
that financial change is transmitted across countries. Third, the common
features detected in institutional factors in velocity are not simply a
post-1945 phenomenon; instead they emerged early this century if not
earlier.
ABBREVIATIONS
BJ: Bordo and Jonung FS: Friedman and Schwartz EG: Engle and Granger
Bernhard Eschweiler provided able research assistance on earlier
drafts. Siklos thanks Wilfrid Laurier University for financial
assistance in the form of a short-term research grant, a Course
Remission Grant, the Academic Development Fund, and the Social Sciences
and Humanities Research Council of Canada (grant 410-93-1409). Katarina
Juselius, Neil Quigley, and two anonymous referees provided useful
comments on earlier drafts. Previous version of this paper were
presented at the Application of Quantitative Methods to Canadian
Economic History Conference (Vancouver, October 1992) and the
Cliometrics Conference (Anaheim, January 1993). Results not presented in
the main body of this paper are contained in an appendix included in the
working paper version available from Pierre Siklos. This paper is a
revised version of NBER Working Paper No. 4379.
1. An exception is Rasche [1987] who does not find institutional
change to be important. However, his testing procedure is univariate in
nature, not multivariate as is the ease in the present paper.
2. BJ [1987, 48] pool their data to show that the influence of
institutional change variables on velocity is similar in all the
countries examined, suggesting that common forces underlying the
institutionalist proxies explain the common behavior of velocity. But
their study confounds short-run and long-run influences since they could
not rely on recent advances in time-series analysis.
3. Norway is included in subsample estimation but could not be
included in full sample estimates because of gaps in the data.
4. Specifications which examine the determinants of real balances
have been preferred in part because of the finding that velocity behaves
like a random walk. Nevertheless, given the difficulties surrounding
tests of the random walk hypothesis (see Campbell and Perron [1991]),
and the presence of statistical breaks in the random walk behavior of
velocity (e.g., Perron [1989]), the empirical evidence suggests, on
balance, that the random walk hypothesis is not a substitute for a
complete model of velocity's behavior.
5. There have been some interruptions in the rising trend, such as
during the 1980s in the U.S. when velocity in M1 levels began to level
off and even decline. Since these unexpected changes have, in hindsight,
been ascribed to the slow pace of regulatory reform in the face of
financial innovations, there is still greater reason to consider the
possibility of a relationship between velocity and institutional change.
6. Whether the postwar period produced more stable variation in
economic aggregates such as GNP or unemployment, particularly in the
U.S., has been the subject of a debate which remains unsettled.
7. We would have liked to expand the data set to consider other
countries, as in Backus and Kehoe [1992], who kindly made their data
available to us. We are unable to do so for three reasons. First, the
power of the tests which are applied below falls with the number of
variables in the model. Second, we are unable to produce estimates of
institutional change for countries other than the five considered in
this paper. Third, the countries examined are, for historical and
economic reasons, relatively good candidates for common institutional
and economic development. Thus, for example, the gold standard as well
as trading relationships linked the U.S., the U.K., and Canadian
economies, and the same is true of the links between Sweden and Norway,
on the one hand, and the U.K., Sweden, and Norway on the other, by
virtue of exchange rate regimes and geographical proximity.
8. Omitted from equation (1) is BJs measure of economic stability, a
six-year moving standard deviation of the annual percent change in real
per capita income. Using a moving standard deviation measure of
volatility is problematical in econometric estimation.
9. One of the criticisms of BJ is that the elements of those vectors
are not independent enough of each other in principle. Empirically,
however, the problem does not appear to be a very serious one.
10. Questions have been raised about whether unit root findings may
be biased in the presence of a structural break in the data. An appendix
(available upon request) presents results based on one recently
developed test (see Siklos [1993]) which generally confirms the
existence of a unit root in the series considered here despite the
possibility of a break in the series.
11. But, as in Johansen and Juselius [1990], while such tests are
useful guides to the possibility of finding a cointegrating
relationship, they are not sufficient tests for cointegration.
12. Critical values depend on whether the VAR contains a constant, a
constant vector, and a constant vector restricted to lie in the
cointegration space. These are Tables A1, A2, and A3, respectively, in
Johansen and Juselius [1990]. Osterwald-Lenum [1992] has produced
improved estimates of Johansen's critical values. These are used in
the empirical work which follows.
13. Indeed, the coefficients in their velocity model incorporating
institutional change factors show signs of a structural break in only
one of the five countries considered, namely Canada (BJ [1987, Table
A.2]). This could be a sign either that the importance of institutional
factors permeates the entire sample or that the break points were
inappropriately chosen.
14. An alternative to tests for breaks in certain years or over time
is to select some suitably long subsample. The only sample sufficiently
long to conduct cointegration tests is the Gold Standard period
1870-1914. We also tested for cointegration conditional on the presence
of shocks arising from the two world wars, the Great Depression, and the
two oil price shocks, where these are assumed to be exogenous. Our
conclusions are unaffected.
15. In the context of cointegrated relationships, however, there are
additional considerations to keep in mind. One can constrain the
short-run component of a model and estimate recursively long-run
parameters or one can, as in most studies, fix the long-run and estimate
the short-run recursively. Hansen and Johansen [1992] argue that the
first two are most useful for the analysis of structural breaks in
long-run relationships as they do not rely on the identification of the
individual cointegrating vectors. In this paper, we follow the former
approach although it is to be noted that inference can be different
under the two approaches. Again, see Hansen and Johansen [1992] for the
details.
16. Gregory and Hansen [1996] propose new tests of stability in the
context of cointegrated relationships. Their test posits that the null
is the standard cointegration equation. Thus, for two series [y.sub.1t]
and [y.sub.2t], the standard cointegrating regression is written
[y.sub.1t] = [Mu] + [Theta][y.sub.2t] + [e.sub.t].
One alternative hypothesis is written
[y.sub.1t] = [[Mu].sub.1] + [[Mu].sub.2][[Phi].sub.t[Tau]] +
[[Theta].sub.1] [y.sub.2t] + [[Theta].sub.2] [y.sub.2t]
[[Phi].sub.t[Tau]] + [e.sub.t].
This last equation is augmented with a change in intercept
([[Mu].sub.2]) and a change in the slope. We define a dummy variable [Phi] as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where n is the number of observations and where [Phi] is created for
each possible break point [Tau]. The usual notation is [n [Tau]] where
[Tau] is defined in the interval [.15n, .85n]. Some trimming of the
sample is required because the test statistic is not, strictly speaking,
defined over all of n. The sequence of residuals can then be analyzed in
the same manner as the test for cointegration proposed by EG [1987],
that is, by generating an augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) statistic for
each [Tau].
17. An alternative way of stating the above result is to say that
with four countries a single cointegrating vector implies three common
stochastic trends. Thus, several factors may be driving velocity levels
in the countries considered.
18. As a referee correctly points out, the mere fact that we cannot
exclude any of the countries considered in the long-run relation does
not imply that, had we included other countries not considered here,
these would also be excluded. Indeed, there are good reasons to believe,
based on previous work (e.g., BJ [1987]), that the appropriate vector of
countries one might want to consider should be larger. Footnote 7
describes the data limitations we faced. Our objective here is simply to
confirm that the group of countries considered here can be viewed as a
single entity in a narrow sense.
19. There is a chance, however, that a separate long-run relationship
exists between U.S. and U.K. velocity, but no such separate
cointegrating relationship could be found between either the U.S. and
Canada or the U.K. and Sweden.
20. It is unclear, a priori, how wide the window or fixed portion of
the sample should be. The size of the error correction term would
suggest a minimum of at least 20 years. Windows of 20, 40 and 60 years
were considered.
21. Based on recursive estimates, the error correction coefficient is
rather stable in the post-World War II period for both the U.K. and
Sweden as well as being consistent with faster adjustment to
equilibrium.
22. Essentially, comparable results were obtained from the
recursions.
23. Clearly, by stacking the variables in such a manner we are
assuming that the same specification works well for all five countries.
The evidence in BJ [1987; 1990] and Siklos [1993] suggests that this is
appropriate and that the coefficients in the model for individual
countries are roughly similar. Given the potential loss of degrees of
freedom we did not pursue additional refinements.
24. This result holds even if Norway is excluded as in Table I, panel
A.
25. To give economic meaning to estimates of a cointegrating vector,
coefficients must be normalized. Following previous convention (Siklos
[1993]) estimates were normalized on velocity.
26. Results are similar if lnal is not constrained to zero, but the
evidence in Table I is quite decisive about the lack of statistical
significance of this variable. The various restrictions were imposed on
all possible cointegrating vectors.
27. The interest rate test must be interpreted with some caution
because, according to panel A, Table I, there are two cointegrating
vectors for R. A drawback of the Gregory and Hansen [1996] approach is
that, by relying on the EG [1987] methodology, it implicitly assumes the
existence of a unique cointegrating relationship. We did find a peak in
the ADF statistic for velocity in 1927, but it is not statistically
significant even at the 10% level of significance.
28. BJ [1987] and Silos [1993] have attempted to construct other
determinants of institutional change, including proxies for expected
inflation, with little effect on the empirical results for the
institutionalists hypothesis.
29. Nor is this finding necessarily due to the length of the sample.
Siklos [1993] shows that instabilities are more evident for narrower
rather than the broader monetary aggregates.
REFERENCES
Baba, Yoshi, David F. Hendry, and Ross M. Starr. "The Demand for
MI in the USA: 1960-1988." Review of Economic Studies, January
1992, 25-60.
Backus, David K., and Patrick J. Kehoe. "International Evidence
on the Historical Properties of Business Cycles." American Economic
Review, September 1992, 864-88.
Bordo, Michael D., and Lars Jonung. "The Long-Run Behavior of
the Income Velocity of Money in Five Advanced Countries, 1870-1975: An
Institutional Approach." Economic Inquiry, January 1981, 961-16.
-----. The Long-Run Behavior of the Velocity of Circulation: The
International Evidence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
-----. "The Long-Run Behavior of Velocity: The Institutional
Approach Revisited." Journal of Policy Modeling, September 1990,
165-97.
Boughton, James M. "International Comparison of Money Demand: A
Review Essay." Open Economies Review, October 1992, 323-43.
Campbell, John Y., and Pierre Perron. "Pitfalls and
Opportunities: What Macroeconomists Should Know About Unit Roots."
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1991,
141-200.
Engle, Robert F., and Clive W. J. Granger. "Co-Integration and
Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing."
Econometrica, March 1987, 251-76.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. Monetary Trends in the United
States and the United Kingdom: Their Relation to Income, Prices, and
Interest Rates, 1867-1975. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for
N.B.E.R., 1982.
Goldfeld, Stephen M., and David E. Sichel. "The Demand for
Money," in Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by B. M. Friedman
and F. H. Hahn, North-Holland: Amsterdam, 1990, 299-356.
Gregory, Allan W., and Bruce E. Hansen. "Residuals-based Tests
for Cointegration in Models with Regime Shifts." Journal of
Econometrics, June 1996, 99-126.
Hafer, Rik W., and Dennis Wo Jansen. "The Demand for Money in
the United States: Evidence from Cointegration Tests." Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, May 1991, 155-68.
Hallman, R. Porter, and David Small. "Is the Price Level Tied to
the M2 Monetary Aggregate in the Long-Run?" American Economic
Review, September 1991, 841-58.
Hansen, Henrik, and Soren Johansen. "Recursive Estimation in
Cointegrated VAR-Models." Institute of Economics, University of
Copenhagen, Discussion Paper 92.13, 1992.
Ireland, Peter. "Financial Evolution and the Long-Run Behavior
of Velocity: New Evidence from US Regional Data." Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, Economic Review, November/December 1991, 16-26.
-----. "Economic Growth, Financial Evolution, and the Long-Run
Behavior of Velocity." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
May/July 1994, 815-48.
Johansen, Soren. "Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegrated Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models."
Econometrica, November 1991, 1551-81.
Johansen, Soren, and Katarina Juselius. "Maximum Likelihood
Estimation and Inference on Cointegration - With Applications for the
Demand for Money." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
52(2), 1990, 169-210.
Laidler, David E. W. The Demand for Money: Theories, Evidence and
Problems, 4th ed. New York: Harper Collins, 1993.
Miller, Stephen M. "Monetary Dynamics: An Application of
Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling." Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, May 1991, 139-54.
Osterwald-Lenum, Michael. "A Note with Quantiles of the
Asymptotic Distribution of the Maximum Likelihood Cointegration Rank
Test Statistics." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
August 1992, 461-72.
Perron, Pierre. "The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock, and the
Unit Root Hypothesis." Econometrica, November 1989, 1361-402.
-----. "Test Consistency with Varying Sample Frequency."
Econometric Theory, September 1991, 341-68.
Rasche, Robert H. "Velocity and Money Demand Functions: Do
Stable Relationships Exist?" Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, vol. 2, edited by K. Brunner and A. H. Meltzer.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, Autumn 1987, 9-88.
Siklos, Pierre L. "Income Velocity and Institutional Change:
Some New Time Series Evidence, 18701986." Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, August 1993, 377-92.
Bordo: Professor, Department of Economics, Rutgers University, New
Brunswick, N.J. Phone 1-908-932-8019, Fax 1-908-935-7416 E-mail
bordo@fas_econ.rutgers.edu
Jonung: Professor, Stockholm School of Economics Sweden, Phone
46-8-736-9203, Fax 46-8-31-32-07 E-mail nelt@hhs.se
Siklos: Professor, Department of Economics, Wilfrid Laurier
University, Waterloo, Canada Phone 1-519-884-1970 x2559, Fax
1-519-884-0201 E-mail psiklos@mac.#1.wlu.ca