Consumer search costs and market performance.
Davis, Douglas D. ; Holt, Charles A.
I. INTRODUCTION
One of the seminal developments leading to the information
economics revolution in the 1970s and 19c0s was Diamond's [1971]
theoretical result that, in the absence of publicly posted price
information, the existence of even a small search cost could lead to
monopoly pricing. The intuition is straightforward: No buyer with one
price quote would want to search for a second, unless it is likely that
the buyer would encounter a price reduction that covers the search cost.
Thus each seller has an incentive to price slightly above any common
price, and the noncooperative equilibrium in a single-stage game yields
a monopoly price. This result is viewed as a paradox, since a
"small" search cost produces high prices, but a zero search
cost would produce the usual Bertrand incentives that drive prices to
competitive levels, in the absence of capacity constraints and other
imperfections.(1)
Recent theoretical work has focused on finding a
"resolution" to the paradox. Stahl [1989], for example,
generates a smooth transition between competitive and monopoly outcomes
as the fraction of consumers with zero search costs increases from zero
to one. Interestingly, Stahl finds that increasing the number of sellers
makes pricing more monopolistic, holding the number of informed buyers
constant. Bagwell and Ramey [1992] propose an alternative resolution
that applies to an infinitely repeated market game where sellers who
raise prices can develop a reputation that can affect sales in future
periods. Bagwell and Ramey show that buyers can obtain lower equilibrium
prices by following a "loyalty-boycott" search rule, where
low-pricing sellers are rewarded with repeated purchases, and
high-pricing sellers are punished with switching. The price predictions
vary continuously between monopoly and competitive levels, depending on
the size of the consumer search cost.
The policy relevance of the Diamond paradox depends on whether
there are realistic market environments in which small reductions in the
availability of price information can cause large price increases.(2)
Due to the difficulty of controlling and measuring information flows in
natural markets, the laboratory represents an ideal place to evaluate
the Diamond paradox and proposed resolutions. The only experimental
analysis of these issues is reported by Grether, Schwartz and Wilde
[1988], who observed monopoly pricing in three of four predicted cases.
These results are suggestive, but not definitive, for reasons discussed
below. In particular, as Grether, Schwartz and Wilde [1988, 328]
observe, all four cases involved the same group of subjects "to the
extent possible."
This paper reports an experiment consisting of twelve market
sessions designed to assess the effects of public price information. The
markets are conducted as normal posted-offer markets, except that buyers
must pay a small cost each time they approach a different seller. In
baseline "posted-offer" treatments, all prices are publicly
displayed to buyers, while in "search" treatments, prices are
not publicly displayed. In brief, we find that prices approach
competitive levels under the posted-offer treatment, and prices are
significantly higher under the search treatment. Nevertheless, the
Diamond prediction of monopoly pricing under search is not observed,
although increases in search costs do raise prices. These results
indicate that economists should take a more careful look at attempts to
resolve the Diamond paradox by introducing other factors that may impede monopoly pricing in markets with consumer search.
The paper is organized as follows. Our two primary treatments are
outlined in section II, and results are presented in section III. The
failure to observe the Diamond monopoly price prediction motivated additional research on the effects of reputations and search costs,
which is presented in section IV. The final section contains a
conclusion.
II. EXPERIMENT DESIGN AND PROCEDURES
The first six sessions to be discussed involve the posted-offer and
search treatments mentioned above. Each session consisted of two
sequences of twenty market periods, with prices being posted publicly to
buyers in one sequence and not in the other. Sellers could not see one
another's posted prices in either treatment. The treatment order
was alternated in every other session in this "within-group"
design. In all sessions the buyers' shopping cost was set at
fifteen cents per seller approach.
Sessions were conducted as standard posted-offer markets, with the
exceptions of the shopping cost and the privacy of price information in
the search treatment. At the outset of each trading period, buyers and
sellers are provided unit values and costs. Seller earnings accrue as
the difference between the price and the cost of units sold. Buyer
earnings are the difference between the value and the price of units
purchased, less all seller-approach expenses. At the beginning of each
trading period, sellers privately make price (and maximum sales
quantity) decisions, while buyers wait. Once all sellers have completed
their decisions, buyers are randomly drawn one at a time and given the
opportunity to make as many purchases as they want at the posted prices.
The period ends when all buyers have been given an opportunity to shop,
or when all sellers are out of units. Consistent with the bulk of market
experiments, all cost and value information was private and was revealed
to none of the other traders.(3)
The search treatment implements a standard sequential search setup:
in order to see a seller's price, the buyer must specify the seller
and pay the fifteen-cent cost. The buyer may then either purchase at the
posted price by pressing "p" on the keyboard, or shop
elsewhere by pressing "s." In the posted-offer treatment, a
buyer could see all of the sellers' prices at no cost, and the
displays indicated whether a seller was out of stock. The buyer would
still have to pay the fifteen-cent shopping cost to approach a seller.
This cost is like a travel cost in the sense that it is independent of
the number of units purchased. Although the shopping cost is incurred in
each treatment, it becomes a search cost when prices are not public in
the search treatment.(4)
Each session consisted of three buyers (B1-B3) and three sellers
(S1-S3), with values and costs indicated by the trader identifications
for each unit on the market demand and supply curves shown in Figure 1.
The buyers are identical, each with a marginal value of one unit at
ninety-five cents, a second unit at fifty-five cents, and then zero for
all additional units. Similarly, sellers faced identical costs, with a
single unit at a marginal cost of zero, and three additional units with
costs at twenty-five cents.(5) The competitive prediction is [P.sub.c] =
25 cents.
Although the competitive equilibrium is a useful benchmark, it is
not a Nash equilibrium for the market-period "stage-game" in
this design. To see this, observe that half of the units are not sold at
a common competitive price of twenty-five cents. Thus, sellers do not
earn the twenty-five cent profit on the low-cost unit with certainty,
and any seller may increase expected earnings by offering a single unit
for a price slightly less than twenty-five cents. Also, there is no Nash
equilibrium at prices below twenty-five: For any set of prices below
twenty-five cents, only three units are offered, and any seller could
unilaterally increase earnings by selling four units at a price of
fifty-five cents.
The Nash equilibrium involves mixing over the range from
twenty-five to fifty-five. The observation that competitive and Nash
predictions differ here is useful, since it is well documented that in
posted-offer type markets prices tend to be drawn away from the
competitive outcome when the predictions differ.(6) Nevertheless, as a
behavioral matter, the absence of a pure strategy Nash equilibrium at
[P.sub.c] should be of little consequence, since the bulk of the pricing
density in the mixed equilibrium distribution clusters about
twenty-five. The median of the pricing distribution, for example, is
25.73 cents (see Appendix A). This median is far below the
joint-profit-maximizing ("monopoly") price of [P.sub.m] = 55
cents.(7)
This market design does not exactly implement any specific search
model in the literature. In particular, the design violates the standard
assumption that sellers produce at constant marginal cost and that
buyers have a constant and uniform reservation value. The high-value and
low-cost steps were added to give the competitive and monopoly
predictions a realistic chance of being observed, since stable outcomes
in which one side of the market earns nothing are rarely observed. The
design is anchored on a minimum earnings of twenty-five cents per trader
per period at each of these outcomes. For this reason, the cost step for
the first unit is twenty-five cents below [P.sub.c] = 25. Similarly, the
placement of each buyer's first unit value at forty cents above the
monopoly price, [P.sub.m] = 55, guarantees each buyer a minimum earning
of twenty-five cents at the monopoly outcome, after subtracting out the
fifteen-cent shopping cost.
Nevertheless, our design retains the features necessary to generate
starkly different equilibrium predictions across price-information
conditions. In contrast to the prediction that publicly observed prices
will cluster about the competitive prediction, the Nash equilibrium for
the static search game is for all sellers to offer their units at
[P.sub.m] = 55. To verify that this is a Nash equilibrium, assume that
buyers randomly approach the sellers in light of a common expectation
that all sellers will post a price of fifty-five cents. Since sellers
are approached randomly, each may sell between zero and four units. It
is straightforward, if somewhat tedious, to show that under these
conditions expected profits are about 78.5 cents. (See Appendix B for
details.) To demonstrate that this is a Nash equilibrium, first note
that price deviations are not observed ex ante by buyers in the search
treatment. Therefore, no unilateral reduction from fifty-five cents can
be profitable, since the price decrease will neither divert purchases
from other sellers nor allow for an increase in aggregate sales.
Unilateral price increases are also unprofitable: Given that buyers
expect sellers to post a price of fifty-five cents, any deviation more
than fifteen cents above fifty-five will induce a buyer to shop
elsewhere. Thus, the maximum possible deviation is a price of seventy
cents, in which case expected earnings are about 65.2 cents (see
Appendix B). As shown in Appendix C, this equilibrium is unique in the
set of equilibria where all sellers have positive expected sales.(8)
Two additional features of our design bear comment. First (and
unlike Diamond's original formulation of the problem), our
implementation is based on an explicitly static analysis. Any failure to
observe monopoly prices may be attributable to omitted dynamic
considerations, such as learning, or the possibility that buyers are
able to keep prices low by exploiting the repeated nature of the market
game to punish high-pricing sellers. Second, we wish to emphasize the
differences between our implementation and that reported by Grether,
Schwartz, and Wilde [1988]. In their search ("monopoly")
treatment, buyers were shown the complete list of prices actually posted
in each period, without seller identifications. A buyer could avoid a
search cost by making a purchase (if profitable) from one seller
randomly selected by the experimenter. Alternatively, the buyer could
pay a cost (ten cents) to obtain a sample of two or more randomly
selected prices, so that a purchase could be made at the lower price. We
decided not to reveal any prices to buyers unless they paid a search
cost in a sequential search setup. We were motivated in part by
Stahl's [1989, 7001 argument against "the dubious assumption
that consumers can 'see' deviations by firms before they
actually search."(9)
Subjects were University of Virginia students who were recruited
from economics classes. Buyer and seller roles were determined by random
draws. Then subjects were seated at visually isolated personal
computers. Instructions were presented on the displays as an
experimenter read them aloud.(10) After the initial twenty period
treatment, supplemental instructions were read for the final
twenty-period sequence. The final period was not announced for either
sequence.(11) Subjects were paid $6.00 for showing up, in addition to
earnings from trading. Earnings averaged $24.10 per subject and ranged
from $12.50 to $35.25. Payments were made in private immediately after
the session. Two of the six sessions were conducted with subjects who
had previously participated in a laboratory posted-offer market session
(but of a different design), while participants in the remaining four
sessions had no previous experience in an economics experiment.
The configuration of treatments by session is summarized by the
three-part identifiers in the first column of Table I. Each identifier
consists of a two-letter prefix ("SP" or "PS") to
indicate whether the search or posted-offer sequence came first,
followed by a number indicating the order in sequence, and an
"x" if the session used experienced participants. Thus, for
example session PS3x in Table I refers to the third session in the
posted-offer/search sequence, with experienced participants.
TABLE I
Mean Deviations of Transactions Prices from the Competitive
Prediction for the Final 5 Periods: Search and Posted-Offer Treatments
Search Sequence Posted-Offer Sequen
Session P-[P.sub.e] P-[P.sub.e]
SP1 5 1
SP2 22 1
SP3x 25 1
AVG. for SP1-3 18 1
PSI 15 6
PS2 3 1
PS3x 14 8
AVG. for PS1-3 11 5
III. RESULTS
Mean transactions price paths are shown on the right side of Figure
1. Results for the search/posted-offer treatment sequence are shown
above the posted-offer/search results.(12) The bold line in each panel
represents the mean price path averaged across the three sessions for
each treatment sequence. Mean transactions prices for the individual
sessions are indicated by the light lines. In each panel, the thin solid
line represents a session with experienced subjects. Several conclusions
are immediately apparent from Figure 1. First, prices exhibit a much
more pronounced tendency to converge to the competitive level in the
posted-offer treatment than in the search treatment. In fact, prices are
higher in the search sequence of each session than in the corresponding
posted-offer sequence. Table I shows mean deviations from the
competitive price for the last five periods each session.(13) Mean price
deviations in the search sequence of each session (second column) are
larger than the mean price deviations for the corresponding posted-offer
sequence (third column). This outcome allows rejection of the null
hypothesis of no treatment (public price-posting) effect at a 98 percent
confidence level, using the nonparametric randomization test.(14) This
observation supports our first conclusions:
CONCLUSION 1. Search matters: nonpublic postings raise prices.
This conclusion is not particularly surprising, and was previously
observed by Grether, Schwartz and Wilde [1988]. The relationship of
transactions prices to the monopoly prediction, [P.sub.m] in the search
treatment is perhaps more interesting. When search precedes posted offer
(the left side of the upper panel), the bold overall price path is
roughly two-thirds of the distance from the competitive to the monopoly
price. In contrast, overall average transactions prices are only about
one-third of that distance in the search treatment when it follows
posted offer (the right side of the lower panel). Moreover, even
"near monopoly" prices are the exception rather than the rule.
In more than half of the six sessions summarized in column 2 of Table I,
mean prices are as least as close to the competitive level as to the
monopoly outcome. This forms our second primary conclusion:
CONCLUSION 2. The Diamond-paradox monopoly price is not consistently
observed in this environment.
The variability of performance within treatments suggests that
differences in participant behavior may be important.(15) Even in a
single session there is often a lot of price dispersion, which may
impede an upward price-adjustment process. It may be straightforward for
sellers to appreciate the logic of raising price above some common
level, as long as the price increase is less than the shopping cost. But
when the prices of other sellers are unobserved (and are in fact very
dispersed), sellers may find it very risky to raise price, since the
sellers know little about buyers' price expectations. Buyers, on
the other hand, may be able to force prices down by
"punishing" sellers. As suggested by Bagwell and Ramey, buyers
may either refuse to purchase if a posted price is unacceptably high, or
may purchase but shop elsewhere in other periods.
There is at least anecdotal evidence that buyers employed
punishment behavior of this sort. Consider for example, the sequence of
contracts for the search sequence of session PS3x in Figure 2. Data for
the twenty trading periods are separated by vertical lines. Within
periods, price postings for sellers S1, S2 and S3 are represented, in
respective order, by crosses (+). Contracts for single units are denoted
by small dots ([multiplied by]); multiple units sold at the same price
show as an overlap of dots to the right of the price postings. Thus, for
example, period 1 of session PS3x is illustrated between the left-most
pair of vertical bars in Figure 2. In this period, sellers S1 and S2
posted prices five cents below [P.sub.m], and S3 posted a price twenty
cents above [P.sub.m]. Sellers S1 and S2 subsequently sold two units
each, while S3 sold a single unit.
Seller S2 continued to post prices well above [P.sub.m] in periods
2 to 5 and posted prices at [P.sub.m] in periods 7 and 10. Although this
seller occasionally made sales at high prices (e.g., in periods 2, 3 and
7), the buyers became wary of these high postings and failed to approach
this seller in periods 10 through 17, this despite successive price
decreases in periods 11, 14 and 17 (where price was lowered to the cost
of the low-cost unit). Although punishment was not immediate in this
session, seller S2 clearly paid for high price postings in early
periods.
Instances of punishment were also observed in the other sessions,
albeit less dramatic. It is difficult to develop a reasonable statistic for switching away in response to high prices, since, given shopping
costs, a high price in a given period is a subjective assessment on the
part of the buyer. In Figure 2, for example, one buyer (B1) consistently
purchased units from S1, despite the fact that this seller posted the
highest price in periods 11 to 20.
One crude means of assessing the tendency for buyers to punish
sellers posting high prices is to calculate the propensity of buyers to
switch away from sellers after observing prices in various ranges.
Figure 3 summarizes this information for the search sequences of our
initial six sessions. In the figure, each bar reflects the percentage of
the time that buyers in a particular session observed prices in the
indicated price range and then switched. Thus, each cluster of six bars
summarizes behavior over a given price range, for all six sessions. The
solid line connects dots representing average behavior in each cluster.
From the within-period behavior summarized in the left panel of the
figure, it is seen that buyers tend to pay the fifteen-cent approach fee
more than once in a period only if prices are very high, particularly
above the fifty-five-cent monopoly level. But, as indicated by the right
panel of the figure, except at the very highest prices, buyers exhibit
much more willingness to shift among sellers between periods. Behavior
is highly variable across sessions. Moreover, the high propensity of
buyers to switch sellers across periods even in the lowest price range
suggests that some of the switching is due to price-searching rather
than intended punishments. Nevertheless, even though the effect is
clearly not dominant, the generally positive slope of the lines
summarizing average switching propensities in each panel suggests that
reputations may play some role in determining pricing, since buyers
exhibit at least some tendency to go elsewhere as prices increase.
The effects of reputation may be more systematically evaluated by
examining behavior in additional laboratory sessions where reputations
are controlled. A primary goal of the research described in the next
section is to isolate the effects of sellers' reputations.
IV. SEARCH COSTS AND REPUTATIONS
Although the absence of price information tends to raise prices in
an environment where shopping is costly, prices are not raised to
monopoly levels as implied by the Diamond paradox. This raises the
question of whether there is a reasonable baseline condition in which
the absence of public price information clearly generates monopoly
prices. To evaluate this question we tried two new treatments, with
three sessions each. In both cases, we attempted to control for
reputations by disguising seller identities. The second treatment
differs from the first in that shopping costs are doubled. These
sessions are summarized by the identifiers listed in the first and third
columns of Table II. These identifiers roughly follow the labeling
convention in Table I: the two-letter "SN" prefix indicates
that price information was not publicly displayed (e.g.,
"search"), and that sellers' reputations were disguised ("no reputations"). This prefix is followed by an
"L" (search cost = 15 cents) or "H" (search cost =
30 cents), a number in sequence, and an "x" if experienced
participants were used.
TABLE II
Mean Deviations of Transactions Prices from the Competitive
Prediction for the Final 5 Periods: Search with No Reputations
Search, No Reputations, Search, No Reputations,
c = 15 c = 30
Session P-[P.sub.e] Session P-[P.sub.e]
SNL1 18 SNH1x 26
SNL2 6 SNH2x 31
SNL3x 15 SNH3x 21
AVG. 13 AVG. 26
Controlling for Reputations
The most important difference between the search treatment
described in the previous section and the SNL treatment listed in the
first and second columns of Table II is that seller identities were
disguised so that buyers would be unable to determine which sellers
posted which prices. Higher prices in this treatment than in the
preceding treatments would indicate that reputation effects in fact tend
to lower prices.(16)
To disguise seller identities, the following procedures were used.
At the beginning of the session, sellers were visually isolated from the
buyers and were given a colored marble "identifier." Prior to
each period a monitor drew the marbles in sequence from the urn and
assigned the role of seller S1 to the first marble drawn, seller S2 to
the second marble, and S3 to the third marble. The sellers then took
their seats and posted prices. Further, to prevent sellers from
divulging their identity via very rapid or very slow price postings, the
monitor made the final price confirmation for each seller, once all
sellers had finished posting prices. In this way, the posting sequence
was terminated in a preannounced, anonymity-preserving fashion.
In an effort to give monopoly price outcomes a reasonable chance,
we made two additional procedural changes. First, given the likelihood
of sequencing effects, we did not precede any of the sessions with a
posted-offer sequence.(17) Second, we decided to let sellers see each
other's price postings. While the relevant theory is silent on the
matter of the amount of price information available to sellers, we
decided to give this information to sellers in an effort to facilitate
learning of the recursive "price-plus-shopping-cost" reasoning
that goes into generating a static equilibrium at [P.sub.m] = 55 in the
search treatment. If sellers can see the prices posted by the others,
then the sellers at the low end of the distribution may feel more secure
about price increases that are small relative to the shopping cost. In
all other respects procedures were identical to our initial search
treatments: shopping costs were fifteen cents per approach, each
sequence consisted of twenty periods, and the experience profile
consisted of two sessions with inexperienced participants and a single
experienced session.
As in the preceding section, results are obvious and follow almost
without comment from the mean transactions price data in the second
column of Table II. Also, it is apparent from the left panel of Figure 4
that prices do not approach monopoly levels when reputations are
disguised. In fact, comparing price data in sessions SNL1-3x (second
column of Table II) and SP1-3x (second column of Table I), one can see
that mean prices were actually five cents lower on average in the
no-reputation sessions than in the reputation sessions. Although results
are too mixed to allow us to make a reasonable statistical claim that
prices are actually higher when seller identities are not hidden, the
results provide absolutely no support for the hypothesis that disguising
information tends to raise prices. This motivates our third observation:
CONCLUSION 3. Seller reputations do not lower prices in this context;
prices do not approach the monopoly prediction, even when seller
identities are disguised and sellers can see each others' prices ex
post.
The failure to observe monopoly price outcomes, even when seller
identities are hidden and when sellers can see the prices posted by
others, suggests that sellers fail to understand the recursive
"price-plus-search-cost" reasoning underlying our static
implementation of the Diamond result. In large part this may be due to
initial price dispersion, which makes price increases appear risky.
Nevertheless, search costs provide sellers with some pricing discretion,
much in the manner of switching costs or other entry impediments. To the
extent this is true, the magnitude of the impediment determines the
extent of sellers' price discretion. As a final treatment, we
examine this prediction by increasing search costs.
Search Cost Increases
Our final treatment consists of three sessions conducted as in the
no-reputation treatment, except that search costs were increased to
thirty cents. With minor exceptions, other procedures were exactly as
described in the reputation control sessions.(18)
Results of these "SNH" sessions are summarized in the
right panel of Figure 4 and in the fourth column of Table II. A
comparison of the left and right panels of Figure 4 indicates that
increases in search costs raise transactions prices. In the
high-search-cost sessions, the mean deviation of transactions prices
from [P.sub.e] is twenty-six cents, twice the thirteen-cent deviation
observed in the low-search-cost sessions. Further, the mean transactions
price in each SNH session is higher than the highest price in the SNL
treatment. The uniformity of results allows rejection of the null
hypothesis that increasing search costs does not affect prices at a 95
percent confidence level using the nonparametric randomization test.(19)
This leads to our fourth, and final conclusion.
CONCLUSION 4. Increases in search costs tend to increase prices, at
least when seller identities are disguised.
V. DISCUSSION
This paper has examined the results of twelve market sessions
designed to evaluate the behavioral robustness of the Diamond
prediction. The two primary lessons of this research are (1) that the
absence of public price information raises prices when shopping is
costly, but (2) that the monopoly prices implied by the "Diamond
paradox" are not generally observed. Efforts to find a baseline
treatment with monopoly price outcomes yielded two additional
conclusions: (3) controlling for seller identities is not sufficient to
generate monopoly prices, and (4) increases in the search costs will
raise prices.
In an important sense, the results of our initial sessions are
consistent with the intuition motivating Bagwell and Ramey's
efforts to resolve the Diamond paradox. The implied thrust of their work
is that the "Diamond Paradox" is too extreme, and that in
richer contexts non-monopoly prices will be observed. But equally
important, results of our latter sessions are also inconsistent with the
reasoning underlying Bagwell and Ramey's theoretical modifications.
We observe non-monopoly prices, even when reputations cannot form.
What then causes below-monopoly prices? We conjecture that, as a
behavioral matter, the Diamond result breaks down because sellers
neither immediately appreciate nor do they readily learn the recursive
"price-plus-shopping-cost" reasoning necessary to generate the
monopoly outcome. In the standard posted-offer environment sellers may
simply face too much price dispersion to know when a price increase is
not likely to cause buyers to shop elsewhere. But search costs do give
the seller some market power, in that they make it difficult for buyers
to leave a seller. Thus, the higher the search cost, the more market
power sellers possess.
Our future research in this area will proceed in two directions.
The first involves examining just where and how the Diamond prediction
breaks down. It is possible that there are some contexts in which
sellers are likely to raise price to monopoly levels in a series of
small increments. One possible approach is to evaluate the differences
between our treatments and the Grether, Schwartz and Wilde design (where
monopoly prices were observed). The most obvious alterations are
adjustments that facilitate the learning process. For example, we might
consider a treatment where sellers are informed of the monopoly price,
and where both buyers and sellers know the distribution of prices each
period. Other possible alterations include increasing the number of
buyers, decreasing the capacity of buyers, and perhaps prohibiting
seller stock-outs in a period.(20) The second direction for future
research involves evaluation of predictions in the switching cost
literature. Costs incurred when a buyer changes sellers may generate
price outcomes consistent with those observed here, even when postings
are public.(21)
APPENDIX A
Equilibrium Mixing Distributions for the Posted-Offer Treatment
The mixed-strategy equilibrium is calculated by identifying the
pricing distributions that any two of the sellers must follow in order
to make the third seller indifferent between all prices in the range of
randomization. These calculations will assume risk neutrality and a
continuous price distribution. It is apparent from Figure 1 that the
only profitable unit at a price of twenty-five cents is the
seller's zero-cost unit. The equilibrium strategies to be
constructed will generate prices on the interval [25, 55], with only one
unit offered at twenty-five cents and with all four units offered at
higher prices. (The restriction to one unit offered at a price of
twenty-five cents is made to avoid a continued reference to sellers
pricing slightly below twenty-five cents.) A unit priced at twenty-five
cents will, therefore, always sell since at most three units will be
offered at that price, and demand is six in this range. The earnings of
a (zero-cost) unit priced at twenty-five will be twenty-five cents, and
this provides the "security earnings" level. The expected
profit for any other price in the mixing range must also be twenty-five
cents. Defining F(p) as the probability that a seller prices below p,
and F(25) as the probability mass point at the competitive price, any
seller will mix if other sellers price so that
(A1) 25 = [F(25).sup.2](4p - 75) + 2F(25)[F(p) - F(25)]p
+ 2F(25)[1- F(p)](4p - 75)
+ 2[1- F(p)][F(p) - F(25)](2p - 25)
+ [[1- F(p)].sup.2](4p - 75).
Each of the additive terms in equation (A1) is the probability of a
particular outcome, weighted by the outcome's payoff. The leftmost term on the right side, for example, is the probability that both of the
other sellers price at twenty-five cents in order to sell their single,
low-cost units with certainty. In this case, a seller posting a higher
price p will sell four units, at a sales cost of seventy-five cents
(twenty-five cents for each of the three high-cost units). Similarly,
the second term on the right corresponds to the two possible ways that
one of the other sellers sells a unit at twenty five cents, and the
other seller sells four units at price between twenty-five and p, which
leaves one unit demanded at the price p.
To calculate the mass point at twenty-five cents, F(25) note that
F(p) = 1 at the limit price p = 55. Thus, (A1) evaluated at p = 55
yields
25 = [F(25).sup.2]145 + 2F(25)[1-F(25)]55.
Solving, F(25) = .212857.
F(p) is most easily solved implicitly. Collecting terms by payoffs,
(A.1) may be rewritten as
(A2) 25 = A(4p - 75) + Bp + C(2p - 25),
where A = [F(25).sup.2] + 2F(25)[1 - F(p)] + [[1 F(p)].sup.2]; B =
2F(25)[F(p) - F(25)]; and C = 2[1 F(p)][F(p) - F(25)]. Since p affects
A, B, and C only through F(p), equation (A2) can be solved for p as a
function of F(p).
(A3) p = (25 + 25C + 75A) / (4A + B + 2C)
which is the inverse of the probability distribution function. From
equation (A3) it can be seen that in this mixing equilibrium most prices
will be very close to the competitive price. For example, to find the
median, set F(p) = .5 (and F(25) = .216609) in A, B and C, in equation
(A3), which yields p = 25.73 cents, just above the twenty-five-cent
competitive price.
APPENDIX B
The Existence of a Nash Equilibrium at [P.sub.m] = 55 under the
Search Treatment
In the candidate equilibrium, all sellers offer four units at
fifty-five. Thus, twelve units are offered in aggregate, and six are
demanded. Given the excess supply, it is necessary to calculate earnings
in expectation. First, consider expected earnings at a common price of
fifty-five cents. For specificity, consider sales for seller S1. At
fifty-five cents, each buyer is willing to purchase two units from any
seller, and each seller has a maximum capacity of four units. Thus, S1
may sell four units (and earn 145 = 4 X 55 - 3 X 25); two units (and
earn 85 = 2 X 55 - 25); or zero units (and earn zero). Without loss of
generality, assume B1 shops first, B2 second and B3 third. The possible
selection sequences for buyers B1 and B2 are summarized in the upper
part of Figure 5: buyer B1 may approach S1, S2 or S3, and for each
selection by B1, buyer B2 may also approach S1, S2 or S3. Choices for
buyer B3 in the case that all sellers post the same price are listed in
the middle part of the figure. As indicated in the figure, B3's
choices are similar to those for B1 and B2, except in the event that B1
and B2 approach the same seller, in which case that seller is out of
stock and unavailable.
Quantity outcomes for S1, and the associated probabilities, are
summarized below B3's choices, in the middle of the figure. For
example, the 1/18 probability listed on the left side of the row is the
probability that B1 chooses S1, times the probability that B2 chooses S1
(thus exhausting S1's supply), times the probability that B3
chooses S2 instead of S3: 1/3 X 1/3 X 1/2 = 1/18. The "4"
listed below the "1/18" in the figure represents the sales
quantity for S1, in this case four units. Seller S1's profit for
this case (not shown) is 155: 220 from selling four units at fifty-five
cents less seventy-five for three high-cost units at twenty-five cents
each. Weighting S1's profit for each outcome by its probability, it
is straightforward but tedious to show that expected earnings for S1 are
78.519 cents.
Now consider the profitably of deviations from fifty-five cents. As
argued in the text, no unilateral price reduction can increase expected
earnings: since all sellers offer four units, at any price of fifty-five
cents or less a reduction will only reduce revenue per unit, leaving the
probability of sales constant. Thus expected earnings must fall with any
unilateral price decrease.
Expected earnings also fall with any unilateral price increase.
Although price increases raise revenues per unit, they also affect the
sales probabilities in a way that reduces expected earnings, since at
any price over fifty-five cents a buyer will purchase only one rather
than two units from a seller. This latter effect is attenuated somewhat,
however, since it is possible to sell units to all three buyers. The net
effect depends on the size of the deviation.
Consider the maximum possible positive deviation, a fifteen-cent
increase to a price of seventy cents. (Recall that any deviation larger
than the search cost will motivate buyers to search elsewhere.) Again
for specificity suppose seller S1 deviates, with S2 and S3 each posting
fifty-five cents. At a price of seventy cents each buyer approaching S1
will purchase a single unit. Thus, S1 may sell three units (and earn 160
= 3 X 70 - 2 X 25); two units (and earn 115 = 2 X 70 - 25); one unit
(and earn 70 = 70 - 0) or zero units (and earn zero). Without loss of
generality, assume B1, B2 and B3 approach the sellers in rank order.
Possible quantity outcomes for S1, along with their associated
probabilities are shown in the bottom portion of Figure 5. Again,
weighting the payoff for each outcome by the associated probability of
occurrence, it is straightforward to show that S1's expected
earnings from a unilateral deviation to a price of 70 are 65.185 cents.
For any deviation smaller than seventy cents, per unit revenues fall
without affecting sales probabilities. Thus expected earnings fall for
any possible positive deviation.
APPENDIX C
The Uniqueness of "Trading" Nash Equilibrium at [P.sub.m] =
55 Under the Search Treatment
This appendix rules out asymmetric equilibria in which all three
sellers have positive expected sales quantities. In all equilibria where
some units trade, buyers expect that sellers will not price so high that
shopping is unprofitable. Thus, in any equilibrium with trade, the
expected price must be at least fifteen cents below the ninety-five-cent
value of each buyer's first unit, or below eighty.
First consider the possibility of multiple symmetric equilibria. No
common price between fifty-six and eighty cents can be an equilibrium,
because each seller would have a unilateral incentive to raise price
slightly. The price increase is not observed, so it does not affect the
probability of sale. Similarly, at any common price below fifty-five
cents, a small unilateral increase will not affect sales probabilities.
Therefore, the only possibility is at fifty-five, which was shown to be
a Nash equilibrium in appendix B.
Now consider asymmetric equilibria. No set of prices all below
fifty-five cents could be an equilibrium, since the low-pricing seller
would have a unilateral incentive to raise price. Similarly, there can
be no asymmetric equilibrium with prices above fifty-five. This type of
argument shows that the only remaining possibilities involve some
combination of fifty-five and eighty cents, the highest price consistent
with trade. If we assume that buyers know the equilibrium price strategies of each seller, then it is straightforward to show that
either of the two sellers posting eighty cents would find a unilateral
deviation to fifty-five cents profitable. Suppose S1 and S2 post eighty,
and S3 posts fifty-five. In an asymmetric equilibrium the buyers know
this and the first two buyers to shop purchase all four of the units
available from S3. This leaves one remaining buyer who is willing to
purchase only a single unit from either S1 or S2, who would each have a
unilateral incentive to lower price to fifty-five cents where at least
two units would be sold. Finally, a "no trade" equilibrium
arises in the case where a single seller posts eighty and the other two
sellers post fifty-five. In this case the buyers purchase six units from
the two low-priced sellers, leaving the high-priced seller with no
sales, independent of his or her price. Even though this is one of the
equilibria we are excluding, note that it involves only trades at the
monopoly price.
These kinds of arguments can also be used to rule out equilibria in
mixed strategies. Since buyers do not observe prices before shopping,
sellers cannot be indifferent over price ranges. Over the price range
between twenty-five and fifty-five cents, for example, increases above
twenty-five will increase revenue per unit without affecting sales
probabilities. Randomization at prices over fifty-five can be ruled out
in a similar way.
APPENDIX D
Results in Terms of Posted Prices
Tables III and IV present posted price information parallel to the
transactions price information presented in the text. As is clear from
the tables, the effect of the search treatment is somewhat weaker when
presented in terms of posted prices. Nevertheless, using the
nonparametric randomization test described in footnote 14, each of the
affirmative conclusions drawn in the text are supported with posted
price data at least at a 90 percent confidence level.
TABLE III
Mean Deviations of Posted Prices from the Competitive Prediction for
the Final 5 Periods: Search and Posted Offer Treatments
Search Sequence Posted-Offer Sequence
Session P-[P.sub.e] P-[P.sub.e]
SP1 8 1
SP2 26 3
SP3x 25 2
AVG. 20 2
PSI 17 19
PS2 3 1
PS3x 14 17
AVG. 15 12
TABLE IV
Mean Deviations of Posted Prices from the Competitive Prediction for
the Final 5 Periods: Search with No Reputations
Search, No Reputations, Search, No Reputations,
c = 15 c = 30
Session P-[P.sub.e] Session P-[P.sub.e]
SNL1 24 SNH1x 26
SNL2 7 SNH2x 32
SNL3x 15 SNH3x 23
AVG. 15 AVG. 27
Conclusion 1, for example, hinges on rejection of the null
hypothesis that prices are no higher in the search sequences than in the
posted-price sequences. Under this null hypothesis, the signing of the
six differences observed in Table III are coincidental. Of the [2.sup.6]
= 64 ways that signs for the six differences could have arisen, six
generate a sum of differences as large or larger than that observed.
This occurs with probability of 6/64 = .091. Similarly, conclusion 3
rests on the conclusion that prices in the SNH sessions are higher than
in the SNL sessions. Given that we are talking about six independent
deviations rather than six treatment effects, a different version of the
randomization test must be applied. In this case, sum deviations for the
three SNH sessions and for the three SNL sessions. Then difference the
sums. Under the null hypothesis, the association of the observed
deviations with particular treatments is coincidental, so the difference
of the sums should cancel out. But of the [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] = 20 possible ways that the observed deviations could have
occurred, only two generate a total as large as that observed. This
occurs with probability 2/20 = .10.
(1.) Much subsequent theoretical research focused on the sensitivity
of this paradox to alterations in the information-transmission
technology. The resulting models identify conditions under which
monopoly, competitive and heterogeneous prices are predicted, depending
on how information is disseminated. See, e.g., Butters [1977], Salop and
Stiglitz [1977], and Wilde and Schwartz [1979]. (2.) Both intuition and
the Diamond result would suggest that if goods are sold on a
posted-price basis, then public information about those prices should
improve performance. But it should not be assumed that the effect of
public information is independent of other institutional aspects of the
market. For example, Hong and Plott [1982] show that market performance
is impaired, not improved, by the transition from unstructured bilateral
negotiation (with no public price information) to posted prices (with
public price information). In contrast, the Diamond paradox pertains to
a comparison between costly and public price information, within a
common institutional framework in which prices are posted on a
take-it-or-leave-it basis. (3.) There is some argument to be made for
providing traders with complete cost and value information when
evaluating game-theoretic predictions, e.g., Davis and Holt [1994]. We
did not provide such information here, for two reasons. First, we wished
to evaluate search predictions in a market-like environment, where full
cost and value information is typically not available. Second, as is
clear from a review of ultimatum game experiments, summarized in Davis
and Holt [1993, chapter 5], rivalistic behavior is typical in full
information environments when earnings deviate significantly from an
equal division of the available surplus. We wanted to keep such
rivalistic behavior from preventing the monopoly or competitive outcomes
predicted by Diamond-paradox arguments. (4.) Thus we compare performance
across price-information conditions, holding seller-approach costs
constant. This differs from the usual theoretical discussion, which
focuses on the effects of injecting costly search into an environment
where prices are not public. We chose not to evaluate performance in a
nosearch cost/private-information baseline environment largely for
procedural reasons: it takes each buyer several minutes to elicit costless price quotes from sellers each period. Not only would this
treatment make it difficult to examine a pair of treatments in a
two-hour session, but any observed differences in performance from that
observed in a standard posted-offer market could be attributable to
(uncontrolled) time-costs of shopping. (5.) Marginal cost and marginal
value parameters are presented to participants via our posted-offer
software. In trading, participants are not required to adhere to these
constraints (that is, trades at a loss are permissible). However, prior
to posting units at prices below costs, or making a purchase at an
above-value price, the participant must acknowledge a warning that they
are about to lose moneY In fact, there were very few trades at a loss,
and those that did occur were confined to the initial periods. Finally,
costs and valuations were all increased by $6.00. This has no effect on
the equilibria and is omitted from the text for expositional ease. (6.)
See, for example, chapter 4 of Davis and Holt [1993]. (7.) Verification
that the joint-profit-maximizing price is fifty-five: At a common price
of fifty-five cents, each seller can sell one low-cost and one high-cost
unit, for earnings of eighty-five cents (= 2 X 55 - 25). At any common
price below fifty-five, earnings are lower, since per unit revenues
fall, and aggregate sales quantity cannot increase. At any price above
fifty-five, sellers can expect to sell only one unit, and the highest
price that will induce buyers to pay the approach fee is eighty cents.
Thus, maximum earnings at any common price above fifty-five cents are
eighty cents. (8.) There are also an infinite number of
"no-trade" equilibria in which sellers price above eighty
cents and buyers do not shop. These are weak Nash equilibria since a
unilateral price reduction will not increase sellers' profits above
zero. Most theoretical models avoid such equilibria by assuming that at
least some buyers costlessly have access to some prices. It is typical,
for example, to let buyers make their first approach free. We did not
implement an assumption of this type here, as it is both rather
artificial and is invoked to avoid a problem that is not behaviorally
very important. With one exception (a high-search-cost session,
described below), buyers always approached sellers. (9.) There are
numerous other differences between our search treatment and that
reported by Grether, Schwartz and Wilde. In addition to using the same
participants for all sessions (as mentioned in the introduction) and
posting the price distribution to buyers, these authors used thicker
markets (five to eight sellers and twenty-five buyers); buyers each had
a constant marginal valuation for a single unit; sellers had U-shaped
cost curves (induced via a fixed cost and a capacity constraint); and
sellers could not stock-out in a period. Rather, sellers were obligated
to satisfy all realized demand even if they had to incur the fixed
production costs again to start a new production run in the same period.
(10.) Instructions for the baseline posted-offer treatment are printed
in Appendix A4.2 of Davis and Holt [1993]. The additional instructions
that were read aloud to participants to create the search treatment are
available from the authors, on request. (11.) In retrospect, we might
have announced the final period since we are evaluating a static
prediction. Uncertainty about the final period would at least implicitly
induce discounting and therefore might prompt price increases via the
use of trigger strategies. The generally low prices in the posted-offer
treatment suggest that tacit collusion was not a problem. (12.) All of
the following analysis is presented in terms of transactions, rather
than posted prices. Each of the conclusions drawn in the text is
supported using posted prices, although at a slightly weaker level of
confidence (but at least 90 percent). Relevant posted price information
is presented in Appendix D. The slightly weaker effects of the search
treatment on posted prices strengthens our overall conclusion that the
absence of public price information does not quickly draw prices from
the competitive to the monopoly prediction.
(13.) We confine our attention to the last five periods of each
treatment sequence as a crude means of controlling for learning. (14.)
The randomization test is an exact probability test, based on the
differences in prices across treatments in each sequence. The test
assumes independence of the treatment pairs and that both the magnitude
and direction of price changes are meaningful. The relevant probability
is calculated as the ratio of the number of ways that a sum of price
differences at least as large as the observed sum could be generated,
divided by the total number of possible outcomes. In the present case,
this probability is very easy to calculate: since the search treatment
raises prices in each session, the observed sum of price differences is
the largest possible out of the [2.sup.6] = 64 possible outcomes. Under
the null hypothesis of no treatment effect, an outcome this extreme
would be observed 1/64 (= .015) of the time. For a more complete
description of the test see Conover [1980]. (15.) The heterogeneity of
outcomes both within and across treatments also indicates that factors
other than the presence of public price information may affect pricing
behavior. Some of these factors are largely procedural. In particular,
an order-of-treatment effect is suggested by the mean price information
in Table I. Average deviations are higher in sequences where the search
sequence occurred first (eighteen cents vs. eleven cents), but the
difference is not significant at conventionally accepted confidence
levels. (Using the randomization test, the null hypothesis of no
order-of-sequence effect can be rejected at only an 80 percent
confidence level.) (16.) Although this treatment may be expected to shed
some light on the importance of seller reputations on pricing outcomes,
it should not be interpreted as a test of the Bagwell-Ramey model. An
exact implementation of the Bagwell-Ramey model would require too many
design alterations to allow comparison of results with our existing
sessions. In particular, buyers and sellers should have full information
about values and costs. Moreover, although indefinite repetition is not
necessary to generate higher prices in the search sessions, either the
final period, or announcement of a termination rule is necessary to give
the theoretical predictions a reasonable chance of being observed. (17.)
Actually, we decided to focus on the effects of reputation in the
initial session after observing almost perfectly competitive prices in
the search sequence of a no-reputation pilot session where the search
sequence followed a posted-offer sequence. The reported sequences were
followed with a variety of pilot treatments, none of which are
particularly relevant to this discussion. (18.) There were two
exceptions. First, our experience profile consisted entirely of
experienced participants. Second, buyer earnings were supplemented with
a private, one-time $5 payment in the middle of each session. We were
prompted to provide this supplement while observing very low buyer
earnings in session SNH1x, which threatened to diminish buyer interest.
(19.) Intuitively, of the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] = 20
possible ways that the average price deviations for the six sessions in
the SNL and SNH treatments could be arranged into groups of three, the
observed outcome generates the largest possible difference between the
sum of the group deviations. Under the null hypothesis of no treatment
effect, this would occur one time out of twenty. (20.) Other differences
across our design and the Grether, Schwartz and Wilde design are
important, but are clearly less likely candidates for motivating price
increases. In particular, in each of the Grether Schwartz and Wilde
sessions, there were either five or eight sellers, compared to the three
sellers used here in each session. Indeed, ex ante a critic might argue
that it is our design that is biased toward monopoly outcomes, and it
may well be the case that increasing the number of sellers in our design
will generate yet more competitive outcomes. Nevertheless, the high
prices observed with a relatively large number of sellers by Grether,
Schwartz and Wilde, combined with the more competitive outcomes we
observe in three-seller markets, suggests that standard pure-structure
effects are dominated by other factors when price information is not
public. (21.) Klemperer [1992] provides a nice summary of issues in the
switching cost literature.
REFERENCES
Bagwell, Kyle, and Gary Ramey. "The Diamond Paradox: A Dynamic
Resolution." Discussion Paper No. 1013, Northwestern University,
1992.
Butters, Gerald. "Equilibrium Distributions, Sales and
Advertising Prices." Review of Economic Studies October 1977,
465-91.
Conover, W. J. Practical Nonparametric Statistics. New York: John
Wiley and Sons, 1980.
Davis, Douglas D., and Charles A. Holt. Experimental Economics.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993.
--. "Market Power and Mergers in Laboratory Experiments with
Posted Prices." RAND Journal of Economics, Autumn 1994, 467-87.
Diamond, Peter A. "A Model of Price Adjustment." Journal of
Economic Theory, June 1971, 158-68.
Grether, David M., Alan Schwartz, and Louis L. Wilde.
"Uncertainty and Shopping Behavior: An Experimental Analysis."
Review of Economic Studies, April 1988, 323 42.
Hong, James T., and Charles R. Plott. "Rate Filing Policies for
Inland Water Transportation: An Experimental Approach." The Bell
Journal of Economics, Spring 1982, 1-19.
Klemperer, Paul. "Competition when Consumers Have Switching
Costs: An Overview." Working paper, Oxford University, 1992.
Salop, Stephen, and Joseph Stiglitz. "Bargains and Ripoffs: A
Model of Monopolistically Competitive Price Dispersion." Review of
Economic Studies October 1977, 493-510.
Stahl, Dale O. "Oligopolistic Pricing with Sequential Consumer
Search." American Economic Review, September 1989, 700-12.
Wilde, Louis, and Alan Schwartz. "Equilibrium Comparison
Shopping." Review of Economic Studies, July 1979, 543-53.
CHARLES A. HOLT, Virginia Commonwealth University and University of
Virginia, respectively. We thank without implicating two anonymous
referees and Kyle Bagwell. This research was supported by grants from
the University of Virginia Bamkard Fund and the National Science
Foundation (grants SBR 9319842 and SBR 9320044). Data reported in this
paper are available at FTP address: fido.econlab.arizona.edu.