Evolution and spontaneous uniformity: evidence from the evolution of the limited liability company.
Kobayashi, Bruce H. ; Ribstein, Larry E.
I. INTRODUCTION
Among Armen Alchian's many major contributions to economic
analysis is his pioneering application of the principles of biological
evolution and natural selection to economics. In his 1950 article,
"Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory," Alchian used
evolutionary principles to demonstrate that the standard tools of
economics can be directly applied to situations where strong assumptions
about individual behavior cannot be made. As Alchian noted:
The essential point is that individual motivation and foresight,
while sufficient, are not necessary. All that is needed by economists is
their own awareness of the survival conditions and criteria of the
economic system and a group of participants who submit various
combinations and organizations for the system's selection and
adoption.... As a consequence, only the method of use, rather than the
usefulness, of economic tools and concepts is affected by the approach
suggested here; in fact, they are made more powerful if they are not
pretentiously assumed to be necessarily associated with, and dependent
upon, individual foresight and adjustment.
Alchian's approach emphasizing the "decisions and criteria
dictated by the economic system as more important that those made by
individuals in it" is especially relevant to the use of economics
to study the creation of law. This approach does not require that one
question the importance of rational calculation by actors within the
system.(1) Rather, it suggests a more powerful approach to studying the
creation of law - one that deemphasizes the motivation or foresight of
judges or legislators in favor of a broad consideration of the numerous
forces affecting the legal system. Such an evolutionary approach has
been used to illustrate how the incentives of litigants can cause
judge-made law to evolve towards efficiency without the active
participation of judges.(2) Similar "evolutionary" forces can
act upon individual legislators and legislatures to produce efficient
statutory outcomes. Both competition between interest groups,(3) and
competition between jurisdictions can cause statutes to evolve toward
efficiency.(4)
Such evolutionary processes are particularly relevant to the creation
of uniform laws. A large body of centrally produced federal and uniform
state laws have been promulgated as a uniform solution to problems
created by diverse state statutes. But there are defects inherent in
centralized lawmaking by the federal government and uniform lawmaking
bodies.(5) Such uniformity inhibits exit from perverse laws, and thus
eliminates an important mechanism through which the evolutionary forces
can operate.(6) Thus, it is important to consider whether decentralized processes, such as state jurisdictional competition, can better overcome
both incentive and public choice problems and produce efficient
uniformity. Yet little is known about the legal evolution of statutory
law or the extent to which such decentralized evolution can produce
efficient uniformity.(7)
This paper extends the current literature on the decentralized
evolution of law by examining whether the process of unguided state
provision of statutes for closely held firms leads to interstate uniformity in areas where such uniformity can be expected to promote
economic efficiency. Our focus is the recent evolution of the limited
liability company statutes, a form of closely held business which
combines the benefits of limited liability with the tax advantages of
partnership (Ribstein [1992; 1995b], and Ribstein and Keatinge [1992]).
We adopt Alchian's suggestion by deemphasizing the often ambiguous
predictions of theories based on the behavior of individual market or
political actors in favor of an empirical examination of the ultimate
evolution of limited liability company statutes. The evidence presented
in this paper is consistent with the hypothesis that unguided evolution
can achieve uniformity, and that such uniformity occurs when the
benefits of uniformity outweigh the costs of reduced variation and
experimentation.
Our paper suggests an expanded role for unguided jurisdictional
competition and less reliance on centralized uniform lawmaking. Our
results also suggests the applicability of Alchian's approach to
other areas involving the centralized versus decentralized production of
uniformity, including the evolution of technological standards
(Liebowitz and Margolis [1990; 1994]), and the choice between legal
rules and standards (Shavell [1991]).
The organization of the paper is as follows: section II reviews
theories of evolution of the closely held firm through jurisdictional
competition. Section III provides a theory of the costs and benefits of
uniform laws. The theory is used to test whether the recent evolution of
limited liability company statutes is consistent with appropriate
spontaneous uniformity. Section IV concludes.
II. EVOLUTION OF CLOSELY HELD FIRMS
The evolution of closely held firms confirms Alchian's insight
that a study of the "adaptive mechanism" of the market may be
more fruitful than that of "individual motivation and
foresight." As noted in the introduction, jurisdictional
competition can play a potentially large role in the evolution of state
statutory law. However, the existing literature on jurisdictional
competition has focused primarily on state legislators' motives to
maximize estate revenues from chartering public corporations.(8)
Commentators have noted that the law can achieve uniformity by
firms' moving to favored states, particularly Delaware, and by
other states' imitating these states to prevent further losses.(9)
They disagree mainly about whether this process is a "race to the
bottom" in which the states attract incorporation business by
exploiting principal-agent problems resulting from the separation of
ownership and control,(10) or a "race to the top" that is
disciplined by efficient capital markets.(11)
With respect to closely held firms, by contrast, legislators seem to
lack a motive to compete for chartering revenues. Because foreign
incorporation is marginally costlier for close corporations than for
public corporations, so that few close corporations will choose to
incorporate outside the state in which they do business, states with
inefficient statutes do not face the threat of loss of incorporation
business. Thus, it has been suggested by Ayres [1992] that state
legislators will not compete to supply close corporation statutes. It
may be that, whatever legislators' motives, lawyers can drive
jurisdictional competition.(12) Even so, lawyers in individual states
probably lack the knowledge or foresight to know when to adopt uniform
rules. Indeed, the rule must first be widely adopted before it becomes
uniform.
The previous discussion suggests little reason to expect promulgation of close corporation statutes, much less the evolution of efficient
close corporation statutes. Applying Alchian, however, suggests that
regardless of the incentives, motivation, or foresight of individual
legislators or other lawmakers efficient rules can evolve if the system
fosters survival of such rules. As noted in the introduction, adoption
of the evolutionary approach does not imply the rejection of rational
calculation by individuals within the legal system - indeed Demsetz
[1996] rejects the notion that rational behavior and evolution are
alternative or substitute explanations of behavior. Rather, it suggests
that the survival of efficient rules is fostered by rational behavior of
economic actors where the end result is shaped by forces beyond the
control or foresight of individual lawmakers or legislatures.(13)
One way in which the system can encourage the survival of efficient
rules is if participants in the system - in this case, parties to
closely held firms - rationally pursue alternative methods of earning
profits. According to the contractual theory of the firm pioneered by
Coase [1937; 1960] and by Alchian and Demsetz [1972], firms'
choices of contractual arrangements, including their selection of
particular business forms and legal default rules, reflect choices
influenced by positive transactions and information costs.(14)
Contractual terms can be defined by standard statutory forms provided by
state or federal law, or in custom agreements. The transaction cost
literature predicts that closely held firms will demand uniform or
standard statutory forms when the benefits of using customized
agreements are small relative to the additional transactions costs that
would be incurred in using such agreements.(15) Statutory forms such as
the close corporation compete with non-statutory business forms, which,
in turn, compete across jurisdictions through the use of contractual
choice of law clauses.(16) Transaction cost considerations also
determine when firms will demand uniform statutory provisions and when
provisions will vary from state to state.(17) Following Alchian's
theory, efficient rules will be selected as a result of this process of
"jurisdictional" natural selection if the system widely adopts
rules that are appropriate for a large number of firms. Ultimately, the
extent to which such forces do or do not operate in this or any area
remains largely an empirical question.
III. EVIDENCE FROM THE EVOLUTION OF LIMITED LIABILITY COMPANY
STATUTES
In this section, we describe a positive theory of desirable and
undesirable uniformity. This theory is based on the tradeoff between, on
the one hand, uniformity's benefits of reducing information costs,
facilitating exchange and improving the allocation of resources, and, on
the other, diversity's benefits of increasing flexibility and
promoting experimentation and innovation. We then attempt to explain the
observed pattern of uniformity found in existing limited liability
company statutes using this theory.
After identifying circumstances in which uniformity of statutory
provisions relating to business associations would, and would not, be
desirable, we review data on limited liability company statutes which
show that, even without a uniform proposal from the National Conference
of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws, the states have generated
greater uniformity in exactly the circumstances transactions cost
economics predicts uniform limited liability company provisions would be
most desirable. Our examination suggests the pattern of evolution is
consistent with appropriate uniformity, and inconsistent with
non-efficiency rationales for uniformity, such as herd behavior.
The Benefits of Uniformity
Economic analyses examining the benefits of uniformity have stressed
the information and other costs created by diversity. In particular,
information costs are generated when parties face a large number of
statutory variations among jurisdictions. But these information costs
vary among different types of provisions. This forms the basic insight
for our test for appropriate uniformity. Uniformity is relatively
important for provisions affecting third-party creditors who engage in
small, non-recurring transactions with many firms, where the
creditors' marginal cost of learning an applicable provision likely
exceeds their marginal benefit. Under these circumstances, parties will
choose not to obtain the information and will instead apply a discount
to reflect uncertainty. Firms have an incentive to avoid this penalty by
adopting uniform provisions that reduce transaction costs and
uncertainty.(18) By contrast, uniformity is less important regarding
provisions that affect the members themselves. The members of closely
held firms typically make relatively large investments in few firms and
therefore have relatively large marginal benefit and small marginal cost
in being informed about each provision. As a result, firms have less of
an incentive to adopt uniform provisions of this type.(19)
Owners also may have a tax incentive to adopt uniform provisions. The
tax rules for characterizing firms as partnerships require that the firm
lack at least two of the "corporate" characteristics of
limited liability - centralized management, continuity of life, and free
transferability of interest.(20) In order to ensure against adverse tax
consequences of surprise characterization of a firm as a corporation,
the parties may insist that the firms adhere to a standard form that has
been explicitly sanctioned by the Internal Revenue Service. Since almost
all limited liability companies have limited liability, tax
considerations suggest that limited liability company statutes will tend
to ensure that limited liability companies lack at least two of the
other corporate characteristics. For example, the vast majority of the
statutes provide for a default rule of decentralized management.(21)
The Benefits of Diversity
A second consideration in determining whether uniformity is desirable
with respect to a type of statutory provision is whether there are
significant benefits from diversity. For some types of provisions it is
important only that there is a clear rule, and not precisely what the
rule is. For others, there may be a significant question as to what rule
is appropriate for particular firms or for firms generally. Indeed,
Romano [1992] suggests that close corporation arrangements generally are
more idiosyncratic than public corporations, and therefore less amenable to standard statutory forms. Firms may want to be able to select the
latter type of provision from a menu of alternatives. Perhaps more
important in the context of closely held firms, there may be a need for
experimentation among jurisdictions to arrive at the appropriate default
rule.
Many of the provisions listed above as involving high benefits of
uniformity also involve relatively low benefits of diversity. These
rules are designed to provide minimal protection from trade creditors
above those provided by bankruptcy or state insolvency law. While there
may be some debate about whether such provisions are necessary (Ribstein
[1988]), there is little room for variation in the substance of the
provisions themselves, and consequently relatively little benefit from
state-by-state evolution. For example, the rules provide small trade
creditors with a simple fall-back rule that prevents the most egregious cases of debtor misconduct. Because this is only baseline protection,
the precise contours of the rule are unimportant. By contrast, many of
the provisions listed as involving low benefits of uniformity also
involve relatively high benefits of diversity. These include provisions
regarding such matters as management form and allocation of voting and
financial rights. In fact, these provisions have undergone substantial
evolution in the short history of limited liability company statutes.
In contrast to most provisions, tax-motivated provisions involve a
conflict between the benefits-of-diversity and the
benefits-of-uniformity criteria. There is significant room for evolution
and variation in the rules regarding management, transferability and
dissolution. Indeed, the tax rules do not provide a strong reason for
uniform statutes. Because, as noted above, firms must possess three of
four "corporate" features to fail to qualify for partnership
tax treatment, many firms may not want to adopt particular tax-compliant
features. Moreover, the tax rules themselves provide enough guidance
that there may be little need for business associations statutes to
mimic these rules. On the other hand, lawyers may prefer uniform rules
that ensure tax compliance because they risk potential malpractice liability without incurring the benefits of diversity.(22) Lawyers are a
highly coordinated interest group who can further their interests in
state legislatures. Accordingly, tax-induced uniformity is less likely
to be explained by efficiency considerations than by lawyer-client
agency costs.(23)
The Evidence on Limited Liability Company Evolution
This section shows evidence that spontaneous beneficial uniformity
through the evolution of limited liability company statutes actually
occurs, as predicted by Alchian's theory. Figure 1 shows the total
number of states adopting limited liability company statutes and the
total number of limited liability company statutes passed over time. In
the fifteen year period between 1977 and the end of 1991, only eight
states had passed limited liability company statutes. Since a tax ruling
opened the floodgates on limited liability companies, forty-seven states
and the District of Columbia had passed limited liability company
statutes by the end of 1994. These adoptions are listed chronologically in Table I.(24)
Table II lists sixty-nine provisions found in the forty-eight limited
liability company statutes, and whether each provision primarily affects
the members, primarily affects third parties, or primarily affects the
firm's tax liability. The table also lists the number of adoptions
of the form contained in the original Wyoming statute, and the number of
adoptions of the leading form.(25) Examining Table II, we see that large
numbers of states have adopted similar forms of many types of
provisions.(26) This evidence strongly refutes theories that suggest
close corporation statutes will not be produced by state legislatures,
and is consistent with the hypothesis that the states, without the help
of a uniform lawmaking body, have recognized and attempted to reduce the
costs of diversity by adopting uniform default rules that reduce the
transactions and information costs of operating close corporations.(27)
However, uniformity also could be consistent with inefficient behavior,
a possibility discussed below. Further, many provisions do not have a
widely adopted form.(28)
TABLE I
Adoption of Limited Liability Company Statutes
Year Order State Enactment Date
1977 1. Wyoming June 30, 1977
1978 None
1979 None
1980 None
1981 None
1982 2. Florida April 21, 1982
1983 None
1984 None
1985 None
1986 None
1987 None
1988 None
1989 None
1990 3. Colorado April 18, 1990
4. Kansas May 11, 1990
1991 5. Nevada January 1, 1991
6. Virginia March 21, 1991
7. Texas June 16, 1991
8. Utah July 1, 1991
1992 9. West Virginia March 27, 1992
10. Iowa April 27, 1992
11. Minnesota April 29, 1992
12. Oklahoma May 1, 1992
13. Maryland May 26, 1992
14. Arizona June 2, 1992
15. Louisiana July 7, 1992
16 Rhode Island July 21, 1992
17. Delaware July 22, 1992
18. Illinois September 11, 1992
1993 1R. Wyoming (revised) March 5, 1993
19. South Dakota March 13, 1993
20. Montana March 18, 1993
3R. Colorado (revised) March 22, 1993
21. Idaho March 26, 1993
4R. Kansas (revised) April 5, 1993
22. New Mexico April 7, 1993
23. Arkansas April 12, 1993
24. North Dakota April 12, 1993
25. Michigan April 14, 1993
26. North Carolina April 23, 1993
10R. Iowa (revised) April 26, 1993
27. Indiana May 13, 1993
11R. Minnesota (revised) May 13, 1993
7R. Texas (revised) May 19, 1993
28. Alabama May 20, 1993
13R. Maryland (revised) May 27, 1993
29. Nebraska June 2, 1993
15R Louisiana (revised) June 9, 1993
12R. Oklahoma (revised) June 11, 1993
2R. Florida (revised) June 14, 1993
30. Connecticut June 23, 1993
31. New Hampshire June 23, 1993
32. Oregon June 24, 1993
33. Georgia July 1, 1993
34. Missouri July 2, 1993
5R. Nevada (revised) July 9, 1993
16R. Rhode Island (revised) July 22, 1993
35. New Jersey July 30, 1993
36. Wisconsin December 13, 1993
1994 37. Mississippi March 15, 1994
38. Kentucky March 19, 1994
39. Ohio April 1, 1994
40 Washington April 1, 1994
6R. Virginia (revised) April 5, 1994
41. Tennessee April 14, 1994
3R. Colorado (revised) April 19, 1994
14R. Arizona (revised) April 19, 1994
42. Maine April 20, 1994
43. District of Columbia May 18, 1994
31R. Connecticut (revised) June 7, 1994
44. Alaska June 8, 1994
45. South Carolina June 16, 1994
46. New York July 4, 1994
47. California September 6, 1994
48. Pennsylvania December 7, 1994
1995(*) 22R New Mexico (revised) April 5, 199
32R Oregon (revised) May 5, 1995
* Through May 5, 1995
In order to examine whether spontaneous uniformity has led to
appropriate uniformity, we test to see if the amount of uniformity that
has developed for the types of provisions identified above correlates
with the desirability of uniformity. As noted above, we divide limited
liability company provisions into three mutually exclusive categories:
those which affect primarily the members; those which affect third
parties; and those which are primarily tax motivated. We identify the
"uniform" provision for each category of provisions as the one
that has the most adoptions.(29) Our theory predicts that if spontaneous
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED]
uniformity promotes uniformity in situations where it is most desirable,
provisions affecting members will be less uniform than provisions in the
third-party or tax categories.
Table III lists the average number of adoptions and the share of the
leading form, by category. We hypothesize that the average number of
adoptions of the leading form will be smaller for provisions affecting
members than for provisions affecting either third parties or the
limited liability company's tax status. The data on existing
limited liability company statutes are consistent with our hypothesis.
The leading form in provisions affecting members are adopted, on average
by 23.1 of the forty-eight jurisdictions that have adopted limited
liability company statutes as of the end of 1994. That is, the leading
form in provisions that affect members on average has a "market
share" of less than one half. By contrast, the leading form in
provisions affecting third parties or affecting the limited liability
company's tax liability is adopted, on average, by thirty of the
forty-eight jurisdictions (a share of 62.5 percent).
Table IV lists the difference between the average number of adoptions
of the leading form along with a t-statistic testing the null hypothesis that the difference of the means is zero. The null hypothesis that there
is no difference between the average number of adoptions of the leading
form of the third-party and member categories is rejected at standard
significance levels. The difference between the average number of
adoptions of the leading form of tax and member provisions is also
positive and statistically significant at the .10 level. Finally, the
difference between the average number of adoptions of the leading form
for third-party and tax provisions is negative, but not statistically
different from zero at standard significance levels.(30)
We also examined the development of uniformity over time as new
statutes were passed. If spontaneous uniformity has moved the states
towards appropriate uniformity, [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED] then
the theory discussed above predicts that uniformity (measured by the
average share of the leading form) will rise for provisions in the
third-party category, but that there will be no such movement towards
uniformity for provisions in the member category.
The clearest test of evolution of statutory law concerns tax
provisions. Lawyers' pressure for tax-compliant provisions is
likely to cause at least initial uniformity. Without evolution, this
uniformity is likely to persist. By contrast, our theory suggests that
profit-seeking firms will seek alternatives to tax-motivated provisions,
thereby eroding the market shares of initially popular provisions.
However, because uniformity regarding this type of provision is more
efficient than for other types of member provisions, our theory suggests
that tax provisions ultimately may be more uniform than other member
provisions.
The recent adoption history of limited liability company provisions
is consistent with these predictions. Figure 2 shows the average share
of the leading provision by category over the last three years when most
limited liability company statutes have been passed. During this time,
the difference between the average share of the leading form for the
third party and member categories has increased.(31) The average share
of the leading form for provisions in the member category remained
relatively constant, rising from 46.8 percent to 48.2 percent during the
period February 1992 to May 1995, while the average share of the leading
form for provisions in the third-party category increased from
approximately 58 to 62.3 percent during the same time period. The
leading form share of the tax provisions fluctuated during this time
period, showing initial uniformity, a period of diversity when the
initial uniform law was being replaced, and finally, a return to the
initial level of uniformity of 62.5 percent.
Non-efficiency Explanation for Spontaneous Uniformity
We have shown that the states have tended to move toward uniformity
in situations in which our theory suggests uniformity may be desirable.
This leaves the question whether the uniform provisions that have
emerged are efficient.(32) As suggested above concerning tax-compliant
provisions, uniformity may result from political pressure by a dominant
interest group - i.e., lawyers. Thus, is it is possible that uniformity
may reflect wealth-decreasing rather than wealth-increasing forces.(33)
Spontaneous uniformity may be undesirable for the additional reason
that state [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE V OMITTED] legislators are engaging
in "herd" behavior by ignoring their private information and
simply adopting prior statutes.(34) If so, the states probably are not
evolving toward a more efficient rule because legislators are
disregarding the information generated by the experience of other
states. The policy implication of either explanation would be that the
uniformity promoted by the National Conference of Commissioners on
Uniform State Laws, despite its defects, may be superior to spontaneous
uniformity that is generated by inefficient early statutes and a simple
game of follow-the-leader.
Once again, our data supports Alchian's intuition that overall
market processes can produce desirable evolution even when
individuals' motivations or foresight are suspect. Our evidence
that the states are achieving uniformity in situations where our theory
predicts it is efficient to do so suggests that legislators are sorting
provisions according to the desirability of uniformity measured by
independent criteria, and therefore are using private information rather
than blindly following the leader.
Other data can be used to test more directly test the herding
hypothesis. One implication of the herding hypothesis is that early
statutory forms would have disproportionate influence.(35) That is, the
herding hypothesis predicts that the first provisions adopted are likely
to be the uniform provisions. Table V suggests this is not the case.
Overall, the form initially adopted in the Wyoming statute is the
uniform statute in only twenty-four of the sixty-nine provisions. Even
more striking, for provisions affecting third parties, the initially
adopted form is the uniform form in only 26.5 percent (nine of
thirty-four) of the cases. The percentage is much higher for provisions
affecting members (just over 45 percent).
Figure 3 illustrates the declining importance of the initial form
over time by graphing the average share of the initial and leading (or
uniform) form for each type of provision.(36) The path of the average
share of initial provisions falls over time for all three types of
provisions, while the average share of the uniform provisions
consistently rises over time. As our theory predicts, this rise is less
pronounced for the provisions that primarily affect members. In the
third-party situation, spontaneous uniformity is not evidence of
inefficient herding because in this situation the substance of the rule,
and therefore legislators' private information about the
"right" rule, matters least.
IV. CONCLUSION
The evidence from the recent evolution of the limited liability
company shows that passage of state statutes has achieved significant
uniformity in those situations predicted as appropriate by the
transaction cost model of the firm. Further, the evidence suggests that
early statutes do not have a disproportionate effect on subsequent
statutes, suggesting that observed uniformity is not the result of
inefficient herd behavior These effects occur despite commentators'
doubts about motives of individual legislators to produce efficient
statutes, consistent with Alchian's intuition about the role of
market processes. This strongly suggests that states can achieve
desirable spontaneous uniformity without the "help" of uniform
lawmaking bodies such as the National Conference of Commissioners on
Uniform State Laws or the federal legislature.(37)
1. For a critique of Alchian's attack on the importance of
rational calculation, see Demsetz [1996]. Although Alchian questioned
the importance of rational calculation, he noted that adoption of the
evolutionary approach "does not imply that individual foresight and
action do not affect the nature of the existing state of affairs."
2. Much of the economic literature on the evolution of the common law
was a direct response to the difficulties involved in defining
non-arbitrary preferences of judges. See Rubin [1977], Priest [1977],
Landes and Posner [1979], and Cooter and Kornhauser [1980]. For models
of judicial behavior, see Posner [1993a; 1993b], Miceli and Cosgel
[1994], and Kobayashi and Lott [1993]. The evolutionary approach was
also suggested by Oliver Wendell Holmes as a way to examine the progress
of the common law. See Elliot [1984]. For an analysis of the choice
between judge-made and statutory law, see Rubin [1982].
3. For example, Becker [1976; 1983] suggests that competition in
political markets will cause political institutions that lower the cost
of producing wealth transfers to survive over time, and that political
policies that raise efficiency will be more likely to be adopted than
policies that lower efficiency. Lott [1996] suggests, however, that
political institutions that have the lowest cost of producing any given
level of wealth transfers may not increase wealth, as such institutions
can increase total amount and total costs of generating wealth
transfers. See also Peltzman [1976].
4. See Hirshleifer [1976] for a discussion of within and between
regime political competition as complements. The issue of jurisdictional
competition is discussed in more detail below. For analyses of
spontaneous evolution of laws, see Benson [1989] and Bernstein [1992].
5. Ribstein and Kobayashi [1995; 1996], Ribstein [1993b], Baysinger
and Butler [1984], and Schwartz and Scott [1995] provide recent analyses
of uniform lawmaking bodies. Ribstein and Kobayashi [1996] produce
evidence that states have been adept at sorting proposals by the uniform
lawmaking body, the National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform
State Laws (National Conference) and determining when uniformity is
likely to increase economic efficiency. Nevertheless, the National
Conference's promotional efforts still might cause some uniform
provisions to be adopted when uniformity does not promote economic
efficiency. Moreover, as Ribstein and Kobayashi [1995] and Schwartz and
Scott [1995] found, whether or not even in cases where uniformity could
potentially increases economic efficiency, the uniform lawmaking process
may tend to produce poorly written laws. For discussions of the problems
with federal law, see Macey [1990], Easterbrook and Fischel [1983], and
Carlton and Fischel [1983].
6. The classic paper on the benefits of diversity is Tiebout [1956].
See also Easterbrook [1983] and Levmore [1987].
7. For discussions of the incentives of individual legislators see,
e.g., Lott [1987], Lott and Reed [1989], Lott and Davis [1992], Kalt and
Zupan [1984], Niskanen [1975], Maloney, McCormick and Tollison [1984],
and Stigler [1971].
8. For a review of non-corporate jurisdictional competition, see
Ribstein [1993a]. Easterbrook [1983] applies the jurisdictional
competition model to the state action doctrine in antitrust. For
broad-based discussions of the economics of federalism, see Kitch
[1981], Rose-Ackerman [1980; 1981], Cover [1981], and Shapiro [1972].
9. See Romano [1985], noting the literature's emphasis on
"survivorship," and that as "a corollary of the
process's efficient (optimal) outcome, uniform statutes are
predicted." Proponents of this view include Easterbrook and Fischel
[1983] and Manne [1967]. Some commentators, including Posner and Scott
[1980], Easterbrook [1983], and Baysinger and Butler [1985], suggest
that diverse public corporation statutes exist to allow different types
of firms to select the set of legal rules most appropriate for their
particular circumstances. Romano [1985] argues that empirical evidence
is inconsistent with these corporate diversity theories, and suggests
that partial diversity exists because firms shop for particular types of
statutory provisions when they are planning to engage in certain types
of transactions. Uniformity clearly has emerged in Canadian corporate
law. See Daniels [1991] (arguing that the uniformity resulted from
jurisdictional competition) and Macintosh [1993] (arguing that the
uniformity resulted from the provinces' lack of incentive to
compete to supply corporate law).
10. The original "race to the bottom" hypothesis was stated
in Cary [1974]. See also Nader, Green and Seligman [1976]. For a more
recent treatment, see Bebchuk [1992]. These articles stress the agency
costs created by the separation of ownership and control suggested by
Berle and Means [1932]. For general discussions of agency theory and the
theory of the firm, see Fama and Jensen [1983a; 1983b], and Jensen and
Meckling [1976].
11. For discussion of the race to the top, see Winter [1977]. For
empirical evidence favoring the race to the top hypothesis, see Carney [1993], Romano [1985], and Dodd and Leftwich [1980]. For studies of the
role of jurisdictional competition in the transition from special
chartering to general incorporation, see Shughart and Tollison [1985],
and Butler [1985].
12. Romano [1985] and Macey and Miller [1987] note the importance of
the demand by lawyer and other professional interest groups in
supplementing revenue maximization by the legislature as an incentive
for legal change. Further, Ribstein [1993a; 1994] notes the role of
contractual choice of law clauses and the incentives of lawyer interest
groups in supplying Delaware corporate law. In any event, legislators
face such weak incentives to innovate, and taxpayers are such a poorly
coordinated group, that maximization of franchise tax revenues is
unlikely to be a strong motive for corporate statutes. For a general
theoretical discussion of the weak incentives faced by legislators, see
Rose-Ackerman, [1980; 1981]. For an application to promulgation of
public corporation statutes, see Ribstein [1995b].
13. Indeed, our research on the uniform lawmaking process under the
National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws suggests that
attempts by centralized decision makers to shape the ultimate result
(i.e. deciding which rules should become uniform) often results in
perverse outcomes. See Ribstein and Kobayashi [1996]. Our results
suggest that this centralized process results in a large number of
uniform law proposals where uniformity is not efficient. Further, these
attempts at achieving uniformity are largely unsuccessful, as we find
that inefficient uniform proposals are not widely adopted. That is, our
results suggest that the decentralized decisions by state legislatures
to not adopt these uniform law proposals defeat the inefficient planned
actions of the centralized body. For a critique of the National
Conference's Uniform Limited Liability Company Act, see Ribstein
and Kobayashi [1995].
14. For a clear statement of this proposition, see Easterbrook and
Fischel [1992]. While a large literature has examined a firm's
contractual choice of control structure using the transactions cost
framework, little attention has been paid to the firm's choice of
organizational form. It is often assumed that the choice of form merely
reflects tax considerations. We take a broader view in this paper by
treating the choice of form as reflecting transactions and information
costs in addition to tax considerations. See Ribstein [1988; 1992;
1995b].
15. See Ribstein [1994].
16. See Butler [1985] and Ribstein [1995b; 1995c] for an analysis of
competition between statutory and non-statutory forms. See Ribstein
[1993a; 1994] for a discussion of jurisdictional competition and choice
of law clauses.
17. The distinction between issues on which diverse provisions are,
and are not, efficient provides a basis for our empirical test of
appropriate uniformity.
18. Provisions where uniformity is likely to be important include,
for example, simple default terms that minimize the debtor-creditor
agency costs inherent in limited liability. Specific examples of
provisions in this category include: (1) requirements regarding the
contents and execution of the filed document (certificate or articles);
(2) limitations on purposes for which the firm may be formed; (3) place
and form of filing the basic disclosure document; (4) mechanisms for
enforcing obligations (e.g., rules on registered agents and service of
process); (5) form of members' capital contributions (i.e.,
investments that are subordinated to creditor claims); (6) enforcement
of capital contribution obligations; (7) definition of and penalties for
wrongful distributions to owners by financially distressed firms; (8)
members' personal liability for debts of the firm; (9) rules
governing "foreign" firms (i.e., those organized under the law
of another jurisdiction); (10) rules ensuring accuracy of the disclosure
document; (11) regulation of misleading names (i.e., names that might
confuse creditors concerning the nature or identity of the firm); (12)
limitation on members' or manager's powers to bind the firm;
(13) rules for determining what property is owned by the firm; and (14)
transfer of firm property. See Table II for a comprehensive list.
19. Examples of these provisions include: (1) formalities and other
rules governing the "operating agreement" or similar document
that spells out the agreement between the parties but is not intended as
notice to third parties; (2) whether the statutory default provides for
centralized or decentralized management; (3) the method of allocating
profits and distributions; (4) the method of allocating voting rights;
(5) matters on which members have a right to vote; (6) rules for
meetings of members and managers; (7) rules regarding assignment of
interests; (8) fiduciary duties of managers and remedies for breach; (9)
dissolution and liquidation of the firm; (10) maintenance and inspection
of records.
20. See Treas. Reg. Sec. 301.7701-2(a).
21. See Table II, and Ribstein [1995b]. For discussions of how state
legislators tend to design their limited liability company and
partnership statutes around federal tax regulations, see Ribstein [1988;
1992; 1994].
22. For a discussion of lawyers' role in resisting flexibility
that might trigger malpractice liability, see Ribstein [1994].
23. See Macey and Miller [1987] and Ribstein [1995b]. Tax-based
provisions represent a special case for lawyers' collective
preference for clear, uniform rules. More generally, successful lawyer
interest groups may not prefer simple rules. Increased complexity may
increase the demand for lawyers' services in the absence of
external sources of guidance (White [1992]). On the other hand, lawyers
also have incentives to produce efficient statutes in order to help
their states compete for a larger share of the market for state law. See
Ribstein [1994; 1995b].
24. Ten states passed new limited liability company statutes in 1992,
eighteen states passed new statutes in 1993, and twelve states passed
new statutes in 1994. Only Hawaii, Massachusetts, and Vermont had not
passed limited liability company statutes by the end of 1994. Further,
seventeen states have revised existing statutes since March 1993. For a
discussion of the effect of partnership tax classification rules on the
terms governing limited liability companies, see Ribstein [1995b].
25. A comprehensive cataloging of the various forms for each of the
sixty-nine provisions found in existing limited liability company
statutes and listed in Table II was compiled. For a detailed description
of limited liability company provisions and forms, see Ribstein and
Keatinge [1992]. For example, provision 5, which controls whether or not
execution of articles is required, serves to provide simple default
rules that minimize debtor-creditor agency costs inherent in limited
liability, and is classified as one that primarily affects the limited
liability company's interactions with third parties. For each state
statute, we recorded whether the statute: (1) requires acknowledgment or
verification; or (2) does not require acknowledgment or verification.
The Wyoming statute adopted form (2), which is used in eight of the
forty-eight jurisdictions. Form (1) is the most adopted or uniform form,
adopted by forty jurisdictions.
26. For example, thirteen of the sixty-nine provisions have leading
forms that have been adopted by at least thirty-six of the forty-eight
jurisdictions, and thirty-nine have leading forms adopted by over half
of the states. Note that classification of two statutes as adopting the
same form means that the statute falls within the definition of the
category, and is judged to have the same legal effect. It does not mean
that the language in the statutes are identical. While this approach may
arguably overstate the extent to which states have adopted
"uniform" statutes, (e.g., due to unforeseen differences in
effect or due to differences in statutory interpretation across the
states) there is no reason to believe that any existing classification
errors are systematically related to whether a provision falls into the
third party, member, or tax categories. Instead, a tendency to adhere
closely to uniform language may depend on the characteristics of the
adopting state. In our examination of the uniform state lawmaking
process, we found that states with full-time legislatures were less
likely, ceteris paribus, to adopt uniform law proposals. See Ribstein
and Kobayashi [1996]. However, an examination of the same factors found
no significant correlations between characteristics of a state (e.g.,
size of legislature, volume of bills, population, general state
expenditures) and the rate at which a state adopts the leading form of
third-party or member provisions.
27. The states' spontaneous movement towards uniformity is
similar to a social convention, where similarity can arise because
people recognize the benefits of conforming to a single standard, such
as driving on the same side of the road. See Schelling [1960] and Sugden
[1986].
28. For example, eight provisions have leading forms with fewer than
fifteen adoptions.
29. This is equivalent to the "one-firm" concentration used
in many studies in industrial organization. We also report the
Herfindahl index, which takes into account the distribution of the
provisions. Which index is used does not affect the substantive results
of the paper.
30. In comparing the average number of adoptions of the leading form
of the member category versus the average number of adoptions of either
the third-party or tax categories, the alternative hypothesis is that
the average number of adoptions of the member category is less than the
average number of adoptions of the third-party or tax categories,
suggesting a one-tailed test is appropriate. Our theory does not predict
a clear relationship between the degree of uniformity of the third-party
and tax categories, suggesting that a two-tailed test is appropriate in
this situation. Similar results are obtained if a broader measure of
uniformity is used. For example, results using the Herfindahl index are
consistent with those obtained by looking only at the leading form. The
Herfindahl index for provisions primarily affecting members equals .333.
By contrast, the Herfindahl index for provisions primarily affecting
third parties or the limited liability company's tax liability
equals .485 and .490 respectively.
31. This difference, however, is not statistically significant at
standard levels (the t-statistic with 63 degrees of freedom equals
.459). We find that 58.8 percent of the third party provisions (20/34)
remained equally uniform or became more uniform (as measured by the
share of the leading form) over this time period, compared to 54.8
percent (17/31) of member and 50 percent (2/4) of the tax provisions.
32. As noted above, although there is evidence of spontaneous
uniformity in the corporate area, it is not clear why this uniformity
has developed and, in particular, whether it is efficient. For example,
Carney [1993] identified some circumstances which may account for the
trend toward diffusion of corporate law provisions, including the role
of lawyer and manager interest groups and of the Model Business
Corporation Act. The interest group factor may explain why certain types
of provisions have been adopted, but it does not explain why there is a
move toward uniformity regarding these provisions. The role of the Model
Act suggests that uniformity is not necessarily "spontaneous"
in these situations.
33. More generally, uniformity may in some cases reduce the costs of
rent seeking. See Ribstein and Kobayashi [1996]. The predictions for
efficiency in these cases are ambiguous - lowering the costs of
transfers decreases the costs of achieving a given level of transfers,
suggesting an increase in efficiency. However, decreasing the costs of
transfers may increase the total amount and costs of such transfers, and
can result in a decrease in efficiency. For a general discussion of
these issues, see Lott [1996]. Such problems may be minimized in the
limited liability company context by the fact that uniform third-party
provisions generally define simple default rules where the content of
the rule matters least, and where the wealth-transferring potential
present with other mandatory rules is minimized. See Miller [1992] for a
similar discussion of the efficiency of close corporation statutes. See
Ribstein [1995b] for a more detailed discussion of the efficiency of the
content of limited liability company provisions.
35. The theoretical economic literature on technological standards
has used examples of the persistence of early inefficient standards to
suggest the inefficiency of markets in generating standards in the
presence of network effects. The most common example used in the
economics literature is the continued dominance of the QWERTY keyboard over the supposedly superior Dovrak keyboard. Theoretical papers suggest
that the continued use of QWERTY represents the perpetuation of an
inefficient standard, resulting from its early adoption and the
inability of market forces to overcome the inertia created by
QWERTY-specific human capital. However, Liebowitz and Margolis [1990]
present empirical evidence suggesting that the assumptions of the
theoretical literature about the relative efficiency of QWERTY are
incorrect. See also Liebowitz and Margolis [1994]. While our paper and
the literature on network effect both consider the process through with
uniformity is produced, our analysis does not consider the role network
effects. For an application of the net-work-effects literature to
explain the evolution of state corporate law, see Klausner [1995].
Although our evidence of evolution of state statutory standards suggests
that there was no "lock-in" of an inefficient early standard,
the rules provided by the first limited liability company statutes
probably were not sufficiently well established to produce network
effects. Network effects in the limited liability company context are
better indicated by the statutes' application of partnership rules
in order to capitalize on the existing network of partnership customs
and precedents. See Ribstein [1995c].
36. The graph uses the form adopted by the Wyoming statute as the
initial form. Similar results are obtained if one compares a set of
early statutes (e.g., those adopted prior to 1992). Using the leading
form from either the first four or first eight statutes as the initial
form results in a similar decline, suggesting the absence of a
disproportionate influence from this group of early statutes.
37. This question is of some topical interest, as the National
Conference recently produced the Uniform Limited Liability Company Act.
For analyses an analysis of this uniform act, see Ribstein and Kobayashi
[1995] and Ribstein [1995a].
REFERENCES
Alchian, Armen A. "Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic
Theory." Journal of Political Economy, June 1950, 211-21.
Alchian, Armen A., and Harold Demsetz. "Production, Information
Costs, and Economic Organization." American Economic Review,
December 1972, 777-95.
Ayres, Ian. "Judging Close Corporations in the Age of
Statutes." Washington University Law Quarterly, Summer 1992,
365-98.
Banerjee, Abhijit. "A Simple Model of Herd Behavior."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1992, 797-817.
Baysinger, Barry D., and Henry N. Butler. "The Role of Corporate
Law in the Theory of the Firm." Journal of Law & Economics,
April 1985, 179-91.
-----. "Revolution versus Evolution in Corporate Law: The
ALI's Project and the Independent Director." George Washington
Law Review, May/August 1984, 557-81.
Bebchuk, Lucian A. "Federalism and the Corporation: The
Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law." Harvard
Law Review, May 1992, 1435-510.
Becker, Gary S. "A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups
for Political Influence." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August
1983, 371-400.
-----. "Comment." Journal of Law & Economics, August
1976, 245-48.
Benson, Bruce L. "The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial
Law." Southern Economic Journal, January 1989, 644-61.
Berle, Adolph A., and Gardner C. Means. The Modern Corporation and
Private Property. New York: Macmillan, 1932.
Bernstein, Lisa. "Opting Out of the Legal System: Extra Legal
Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry." Journal of Legal
Studies, January 1992, 115-57.
Bikhchandani, Sushil, David Hirshleifer, and Ivo Welch. "A
Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational
Cascades." Journal of Political Economy, October 1992, 992-1026.
Butler, Henry N. "Nineteenth-Century Jurisdictional Competition
in the Granting of Corporate Privileges." Journal of Legal Studies,
January 1985, 129-66.
Carlton, Dennis W., and Daniel R. Fischel. "The Regulation of
Insider Trading." Stanford Law Review, May 1983, 857-95.
Carney, William J. "Federalism and Corporate Law: Conditions for
Optimal Development." Mimeo, Emory University, 1993.
Cary, William. "Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections upon
Delaware." Yale Law Journal, March 1974, 663-705.
Coase, Ronald H. "The Nature of the Firm." Economica, 4(2),
1937, 386-405.
-----. "The Problem of Social Cost." Journal of Law &
Economics, October 1960, 1-44.
Cooter, Robert D., and Lewis A. Kornhauser. "Can Litigation Improve the Law with the Help of Judges?" Journal of Legal Studies,
January 1980, 139-64.
Cover, Robert M. "The Uses of Jurisdictional Redundancy:
Interest Ideology and Innovation." William and Mary Law Review,
Summer 1981, 39-682.
Daniels, Ronald J. "Should Provinces Compete: The Case for a
Competitive Corporate Law Market." McGill Law Journal, February
1991, 130-90.
Demsetz, Harold. "Rationality, Evolution, and
Acquisitiveness." Economic Inquiry, this issue, 1996.
Demsetz, Harold, and Kenneth Lehn. "The Structure of Corporate
Ownership: Causes and Consequences." Journal of Political Economy,
December 1985, 1155-77.
Dodd, Peter, and Richard Leftwich. "The Market for Corporate
Charters: Unhealthy Competition versus Federal Regulation." Journal
of Business, July 1980, 259-83.
Easterbrook, Frank H. "Antitrust and the Economics of
Federalism." Journal of Law & Economics, April 1983, 23-50.
Easterbrook, Frank H., and Daniel R. Fischel. The Economic Structure
of Corporate Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1992.
-----. "Voting in Corporate Law." Journal of Law &
Economics, June 1983, 395-428.
Elliot, E. Donald. "Holmes and Evolution: Legal Process as
Artificial Intelligence." Journal of Legal Studies, January 1984,
113-46.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael Jensen. "Agency Problems and
Residual Claims." Journal of Law and Economics, June 1983a, 327-49.
-----. "Separation of Ownership and Control." Journal of
Law & Economics, June 1983b, 301-25
Hirshleifer, Jack. "Comment." Journal of Law and Economics,
August 1976, 241-44.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. "Theory of the
Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure."
Journal of Financial Economics, October 1976, 305-60.
Johnston, Jason. "Notes on the Economic Theory of Legal
Evolution." Mimeo, Vanderbilt University, 1993.
Kalt, Joseph P., and Mark A. Zupan. "Capture and Ideology in the
Economic Theory of Politics." American Economic Review, June 1984,
279-300.
Kitch, Edmund W. "Regulation and the American Common
Market," in Regulation, Federalism and Interstate Commerce, edited
by Dan Tarlock. Cambridge: Oelgeschlager, Gun & Hain, 1981.
Klausner, Michael. "Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of
Contracts." Virginia Law Review, April 1995, 757-852.
Kobayashi, Bruce H., and Lott, John R. Lott, Jr. "Judicial
Reputation and the Efficiency of the Common Law." Mimeo, George
Mason University, 1993.
Landes, William M., and Richard A. Posner. "Adjudication as a
Private Good." Journal of Legal Studies, March 1979, 235-85.
Levmore, Saul. "Variety and Uniformity in the Treatment of the
Good-Faith Purchaser." Journal of Legal Studies, January 1987,
43-63.
Liebowitz, S. J., and Stephen Margolis. "The Fable of the
Keys." Journal of Law & Economics, April 1990, 1-25.
-----. "Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy." Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Spring 1994, 133-50.
Lott, John R., Jr. "Political Cheating." Public Choice,
February 1987, 169-86.
-----. "When Does Political Reform Increase Wealth?" Public
Choice, forthcoming, 1996.
Lott, John R., and Michael Davis. "A Critical Review and an
Extension of the Political Shirking Literature." Public Choice,
December 1992, 461-84.
Lott, John R., and W. Robert Reed. "Shirking and Sorting in a
Political Market with Finite-Lived Politicians." Public Choice,
April 1989, 75-96.
Macey, Jonathan R. "Federal Deference to Local Regulators and
the Economic Theory of Regulation: Toward a Public Choice Explanation of
Federalism." Virginia Law Review, March 1990, 265-91.
Macey, Jonathan R., and Geoffrey Miller. "Toward an
Interest-Group Theory of Delaware Corporate Law." Texas Law Review,
February 1987, 469-523.
Macintosh, Jeff. "The Role of Interjurisdictional Competition in
Shaping Canadian Corporate Law: A Second Look." University of
Toronto Working Paper WPS-18, 1993.
Maloney, Michael T., Robert E. McCormick, and Robert D. Tollison.
"Economic Regulation, Competitive Governments, and Specialized
Resources. Journal of Law & Economics, October 1984, 329-38.
Manne, Henry G. "Our Two Corporation Systems: Law and
Economics." Virginia Law Review, March 1967, 259-84.
Miceli, Thomas J., and Metin M. Cosgel. "Reputation and Judicial
Decision-Making." Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,
January 1994, 31-51.
Miller, Geoffrey P. "The Economic Efficiency of Close
Corporation Law: A Comment." Washington University Law Quarterly,
Summer 1992, 399-408.
Nader, Ralph, Mark J. Green, and Joel Seligman. Taming the Giant
Corporation. New York: Norton, 1976.
Niskanen, William A. "Bureaucrats and Politicians." Journal
of Law & Economics, December 1975, 617-44.
Peltzman, Sam. "Toward a More General Theory of
Regulation." Journal of Law & Economics, August 1976, 211-40.
Priest, George. "The Common Law Process and the Selection of
Efficient Rules." Journal of Legal Studies, January 1977, 65-82.
Posner, Richard A. The Economic Analysis of Law, 4th. ed. Boston:
Little Brown, 1993a.
-----. "What Do Judges and Justices Maximize: The Same Thing as
Everyone Else Does." Supreme Court Economic Review, December 1993b,
1-42.
Posner, Richard A., and Kenneth E. Scott. Economics of Corporation
Law and Securities Regulation. Boston: Little Brown, 1980.
Ribstein, Larry E. "A Critique of the Uniform Limited Liability
Company Act." Stetson Law Review, Winter 1995a, 311-88,
-----. "Statutory Forms for Closely Held Firms: Theories and
Evidence from LLCs." Washington University Law Quarterly, Summer
1995b, 369-432.
-----. "Linking Statutory Forms." Law and Contemporary
Problems, Spring 1995c, 186-220.
-----. "Delaware, Lawyers, and Contractual Choice of Law."
Journal of Corporation Law, 19, 1994, 999-1025.
-----. "Choosing Law by Contract." Journal of Corporation
Law, Winter 1993a, 245-300.
-----. "The Mandatory Nature of the ALI Code. George Washington
Law Review, April 1993b, 984-1033.
-----. "The Deregulation of Limited Liability and the Death of
Partnership." Washington University Law Quarterly, Summer 1992,
417-75.
-----. "An Applied Theory of Limited Partnership." Emory
Law Journal, Fall 1988, 835-95.
Ribstein, Larry E., and Robert Keatinge. Ribstein & Keatinge on
Limited Liability Companies, New York: Shepards-McGraw Hill, 1992.
Ribstein, Larry E., and Bruce H. Kobayashi. "A Economic Analysis
of Uniform State Laws." Journal of Legal Studies, January 1996,
131-99.
-----. "Uniform Laws, Model Laws and Limited Liability
Companies." University of Colorado Law Review, June 1995, 947-99.
Romano, Roberta. "Law as Product: Some Pieces of the
Incorporation Puzzle." Journal of Law, Economics &
Organization, Fall 1985, 225-83.
-----. "State Competition for Close Corporation Charters: A
Commentary." Washington University Law Quarterly, Summer 1992,
409-16.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. "Risk Taking and Reelection: Does
Federalism Promote Innovation?" Journal of Legal Studies, June
1980, 593-616.
-----. "Does Federalism Matter? Political Choice in a Federal
Republic." Journal of Political Economy, February 1981, 152-65.
Rubin, Paul H. "Is the Common Law Efficient?" Journal of
Legal Studies, January 1977, 51-64.
-----. "Common Law and Statute Law." Journal of Legal
Studies, June 1982, 205-24.
Scharfstein, David S., and Jeremy C. Stein. "Herd Behavior and
Investment." American Economic Review, June 1990, 465-79.
Schelling, Thomas. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1960.
Schwartz, Alan, and Robert E. Scott. "The Political Economy of
Private Legislatures." University of Pennsylvania Law Review,
January 1995, 595-654.
Shapiro, Martin. "Toward a Theory of Stare Decisis."
Journal of Legal Studies, January 1972, 125-34.
Shavell, Steven. "Specific versus General Enforcement of the
Law. "Journal of Political Economy, October 1991, 1088-108.
Shughart, William F., II, and Robert D. Tollison. "Corporate
Chartering: An Exploration in the Economics of Legal Change."
Economic Inquiry, October 1985, 585-99.
Stigler, George S. "The Theory of Economic Regulation."
Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Spring 1971, 3-21.
Sugden, Robert. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare, New
York: Basil Blackwell, 1986.
Tiebout, Charles M. "A Pure Theory of Local Expenditure."
Journal of Political Economy, August 1956, 416-24.
White, Michelle J. "Legal Complexity and Lawyers' Benefit
from Litigation." International Review of Law and Economics,
September 1992, 381-95.
Winter, Ralph. "State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the
Theory of the Corporation." Journal of Legal Studies, June 1977,
251-92.
BRUCE H. KOBAYASHI and LARRY E. RIBSTEIN, Associate Professor and
Foundation Professor of Law, George Mason University. This paper was
prepared for the Western Economic Association's symposium in honor
of Armen Alchian's 80th birthday. Support for this research was
provided by the Law and Economics Center at George Mason University
School of Law. Valuable comments were contributed by Harold Demsetz,
Michael Klausner, John Lott, two anonymous referees, and by participants
in workshops at Tulane University and North Carolina State University,
and at a session of the Western Economic Association Meetings. Omar
Gill, Stevan Jones, Gloria Mulligan, Vicki Paisley, Donnell Rini, and
Becky Schelhorse contributed valuable research. Any remaining errors are
the authors'.