Principles of professional advancement.
Alchian, Armen A.
You've finished your Ph.D. ordeal, and luckily you're now
in your first year as a real member of the faculty. The expected relief
from the burden of completing the dissertation is quickly replaced by
the burden of publishing. But then you realize it's the same
pressure again. You've already extracted what little there might
have been in the dissertation. What can you do next, something really on
your own?
You may not know now, but in a few decades, predictably, you'll
have more than you can complete. Unfortunately, by then you'll have
less desire to publish. The capital value of another publication will
have become pretty small. So you'll find yourself passing ideas to,
and encouraging, the younger members of the department, wondering if
they'll be so fortunate as you were in early publishing a article
that really helped your career.
These reflections by an older, retired, out-of-date person - one who
has succeeded far above the "expected value" of entrants to
the profession - are a sort of confession of "How I did it."
Or more honestly, maybe, "How it was done to me!" Perhaps it
will inspire hope in new entrants, particularly with respect to
publications.
I emphasize that the opening part of this essay is not entirely a
conjectural story. It's mine, with a couple of minor exceptions.
I'll confine my major comments to three papers I wrote some time
ago, and with which I remain pleased today (for reasons I'll
explain). I hope the comments will be of some interest to economists,
especially in those moments when everything seems a bit confused, though
not hopeless. I won't resist the temptation to reminisce and
pontificate, the privilege of the emeriti.
BACKGROUND
Although I was officially awarded the Ph.D. in 1944, while in the
United States Air Force, I actually had finished my doctoral work by
1942, just before entry into the military. My dissertation was on the
presumed effects of a general cut in wage rates across the economy. Like
most dissertations, it should have been addressed to my supervisors with
the label, "For Your Eyes Only," and then forgotten - as mine
properly has been. It had nothing to do with my subsequent work,
happily. But the USAF engagement meant that between the dissertation and
the first academic job there were several years in the military, with
time to wonder what the point was in being what is called an
"economist."
Fortunately, I had a major sub-discipline as required in the 1930s:
statistics. I had learned a few things about inference, probability,
random walks, and stochastic, evolutionary processes. I learned them
from a few extraordinary teachers, among them Allen Wallis, Edward Shaw
and Holbrook Working. And during military service I got to use what I
had learned. At the USAF Training Command from 1942 to 1945, I did
statistical evaluation of the validity of entry-level test scores of Air
Force cadets, for their training as pilots, navigators or bombardiers.
Principle of Professional Advancement No. 1
Upon return to civilian life in 1946 in my new teaching job at UCLA,
I again started to read the journals in economics with my superb
graduate students (the majority of them relatively mature ex-military
men in their mid-twenties). In that way I began to relearn economics.
For economists, Principle of Professional Advancement No. 1 is,
"Have super students!" The value of good students is evidenced
by publications. All three of the articles I will discuss below were
developed during classroom exposition and discussion with my students.
"Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory" [1950]. In my
early years of teaching, a pair of confrontational articles by a
Professor Richard Lester and a Professor Fritz Machlup, published in the
leading journal, the American Economic Review, were dutifully studied
with disappointment and distress. Current readers will be astonished to
know that the debate was about whether business people
"really" used marginal productivity and profit-maximization
analysis in making decisions! Lester said "no;" Machlup said
"yes." Of course, both were right and both were wrong, but
their reasoning and defenses were easily demolished by each other.
If that was the quality of analysis passing for economics, I should
have stayed in the military I thought. So, one day in class I explained
what I had read. Then a bit testily, I complained about the quality of
the articles, all in the privacy of the classroom. I then explained what
I thought the two economists should have said. They should have said,
"Read Darwin! It's not what you think you are doing or how you
rationalize your choice of that action. It's whether the action has
survival value. And if outside analysts can identify the reasons the
chosen action had survival value, and in what direction changes in the
environment (constraints) affect survival conditions, economists
don't have to worry about how people discover by thought or luck
what are the new best conditions. Competitive trial and error will
evolve toward the fittest - whom economists characterize as profit
maximizers."
Word of my comments passed to my colleague, Professor Stephen Enke,
as sensible and practical an economist as you would ever want to know.
He remarked that the comments would make a publishable article. I
scoffed that it was all too obvious and trivial, and appropriate only
for a class lecture, not as a publishable article. He nevertheless urged
me to write it at least for future classroom handouts.
I did. He read it, and liked it enough to demand that I send it to a
journal. I didn't know of one minor enough to warrant a chance for
publication. He persevered, saying I should not send it to the AER,
where the original two had been published. Instead, he brazenly
suggested and insisted that I send it to the Journal of Political
Economy.
To my genuine surprise, a very encouraging letter was quickly (by
current standards) received from a Professor Milton Friedman, of whom I
had heard. The paper would be published if a few suggested
extrapolations and minor modifications were made. The article quickly
appeared. It was my first article.(1) I proudly fondled the issue and
sent reprints to close friends, expecting they might respond by saying
"Thanks, I'll read it sometime soon." I could not at that
time believe that evolutionary competitive principles were so forgotten
or ignored.
Principle of Professional Advancement No. 2
I have since begun to realize that I was exceptionally fortunate to
have had a father who thrust my nose into Darwin's Origins when I
was in high school. Then, in college, I had a course in biology which
was all Darwin and evolution. Finally, at the graduate level, I was
fortunate to have worked with Professor Wallis, who introduced me to R.
A. Fisher's Statistical Methods for Biological Research, and to
have studied with Professor Working, whose chief interest was random
walks in wheat futures prices. With that training, evolutionary
interpretations were virtually genetic. So Principle No. 2 is: "To
advance your career, you have to be smart enough to have had the right
teachers."
Principle of Professional Advancement No. 3
That's also how, by great foresight and research, you can be at
the right place at the right time. The article on evolution and
economics happened to appear at a time of reviving interest in and a
more rigorous formulation of the evolutionary processes. That the
approach helps relieve economists from squirming and hedging in futile
attempts to assess what business people were "really doing"
was probably a reason why the article was so well received and why it
has remained a relatively well-cited paper. Principle of Professional
Advancement No. 3 is "Plan to be at the place where your training
happens to be useful - at the right time.
I'm still astonished at the success of the article on evolution
and economics. As I look back - the privilege granted to those who
survive for a long time - I see that the idea had an enormous effect.
But not because of the article I wrote. It was because of the idea
itself, taken from Darwin. I just happened to be the person who brought
the news to economics, as a middleman brings goods from manufacturers to
consumers. If I hadn't done it, many others would have.
I would regard the article as having contributed to a major revision
in the science if there had followed a strong interest and research in
the genetics of economic behavior. For example, whileeconomists treat
the "individual" as the unit of analysis, a more general and
(I conjecture) more powerful analysis of economic behavior can be
founded on "genes" as the unit of analysis or, more exactly,
as the competing units. Certainly the convex preference map is a convex
survival map, mapping points of equal survival probability. Is it not
true that all forms of life have indifference survival curves that are
convex, etc.? Using a biological approach - economics is a life science!
- economists would look at competition beyond the benevolent type.
Jack Hirshleifer's recent work is an example of this thrust into
ignored economic behavior. Someplace in my 1950 article on evolution (or
perhaps elsewhere), I argued that biology and economics ultimately would
merge. My colleague Professor Hirshleifer now appears to be manipulating
a takeover of the one by the other.
"Costs and Outputs" [1959]. My ability to apply Principle
of Professional Advancement No. 3 - being at the right place at the
right time - was illustrated by my decision to join UCLA, close to where
the AND Corporation would later be created. RAND would (at the
instigation of Allen Wallis) invite me to be their first resident
consulting economist. I happened to join the UCLA faculty in 1946; it
happened that RAND was set up in Santa Monica in 1945. Allen happened to
know General "Hap" Arnold well. So it was all happenstance -
like the birdies I make in golf.
RAND was not sure what an economist would do. I certainly didn't
know either. But I learned a lot about "big real world
problems' - too big to comprehend, usually. Since it wasn't
clear at first what an economist could do that was pertinent, the task
was to snoop around, look at the problems being analyzed (defense
problems, usually) and try to see how economics could help.
What we economists did first was detect how economics was being
ignored, in particular how costs and interest rates were ignored in
making military-strategy decisions. Another "complicated,
surprising" proposition was that for assigning nuclear material to
the Air Force versus the Navy, it was not deemed necessary to know
whether it was more important for the Navy or the Air Force to have more
fissile material. But of course, that would be very desirable to know.
With the idea of indifference curves between nuclear material and labor
(as inputs), marginal rates of substitution between the two in the Navy
and also in the Air Force would indicate directions in which to revise
the allocations. That "revelation" gave the economics group
some extra clout.
I cite these as two examples of how the simplest concepts and
propositions in economics have mega-ton power. In that vein, I like to
brag that I did the first "event study" in corporate finance,
back in the 1950s and 1960s. The year before the H-bomb was successfully
created, we in the economics division at RAND were curious as to what
the essential metal was - lithium, beryllium, thorium, or some other.
The engineers and physicists wouldn't tell us economists, quite
properly, given the security restrictions. So I told them I would find
out. I read the U.S. Department of Commerce Year Book to see which firms
made which of the possible ingredients. For the last six months of the
year prior to the successful test of the bomb, I traced the stock prices
of those firms. I used no inside information. Lo and behold! One
firm's stock prices rose, as best I can recall, from about $2 or $3
per share in August to about $13 per share in December. It was the
Lithium Corp. of America. In January, I wrote and circulated within RAND
a memorandum titled "The Stock Market Speaks." Two days later
I was told to withdraw it. The bomb was tested successfully in February,
and thereafter the stock price stabilized.
In the economics division I was working with Stephen Enke, under the
strong support and leadership of Charles Hitch.(2) One thing we
discovered was that engineers didn't quite understand why
"cost" had something to do with a choice of armaments. To help
them learn how and why costs and things like interest rates weren't
just financial shenanigans, we collected cost data on production and
operations of airplanes. I quickly noticed that the production engineers
kept saying marginal costs decreased and continued to decease, lower and
lower. To the contrary, as every economist knew, marginal costs begin to
rise at some stage. And our textbook diagrams and cost theory proved it.
So what mistake were the engineers making? After too long a time,
with embarrassment, I discovered that "output" meant something
entirely different to production engineers than it appeared to mean to
economists. Output to engineers was measured in units of accumulated
total output, not in rate of output. Simple, but spectacularly
different. Yet, not a single economics textbook, advanced or elementary,
mentioned that. In fact most of the time the texts left unclear what was
meant by "amount of output." The engineers were explicitly
clear - it was the accumulated number of units produced, with nothing
whatever about the rate of production of that aggregated volume of
output. Economists, judging by the relations posited to exist with
"output," had if anything the "rate of output" in
mind, unconscious of the importance of the difference between rate and
volume of produced output.
Which group was correct? It was a draw. The engineers were right in
that marginal costs of volume decreased with volume; economists still
could be allowed to presume marginal costs of increased speed of output
were rising. But the economists were obviously right more generally in
emphasizing costs in the choice of alternative weaponry. And in
measuring cost it was capital value, the present value of a stream of
future activities, that was pertinent, not just the initial year's
flow of "cost."
The important points were, first, that investment decisions for
output involved contemplated total amount, or volume, as well as the
rate. Second, the cost had to be in terms of capital values - the
present value of the contemplated outlay in the future. By confining
one's thoughts to rates of output the capital value measure was
hidden, resulting in overly narrow attention on variable, fixed and
marginal costs of changes in the rate of output. I thought that was
important. At least it matched the procedure being initiated in the
Kennedy administration's five-year military costing conception.
I was allowed to summarize the situation in some memoranda on
learning and "progress curves," as the engineers dubbed the
cost-output relations.(3) A summary of implications was written, called
"Costs and Outputs," which was accepted for publication in the
American Economic Review. But then I was asked instead to include it in
a collection of papers being prepared by Moses Abramovitz and others in
honor of their Stanford colleague - and my old teacher - Professor
Bernard Haley. I declined the invitation to publish "Costs and
Outputs" in the AER in favor of the Haley festschrift. I regret
that it did not get into the AER where more people would have seen it.
But I don't regret having had that opportunity to express
appreciation for the help Professor Haley gave me while I was a student
at Stanford.
The paper - henceforth a festschrift book chapter - has been
reprinted several times (e.g., Breit and Hochman [1971]). Still, the
paper seems to have had no effect on anything. After all, who bothers to
read festschrifts? No texts, so far as I could discover, were changed in
any way to avoid the confusions in the meanings and measures of output
and of the pertinent measure of cost. I was disappointed. Why were the
implications ignored?
A possible answer soon dawned. If capital value concepts of cost and
aggregate output were on the supply side, should something not appear on
the demand side to make the analysis compatible? Demand was
conventionally viewed as a rate of demand, not as an aggregated total
volume. Until modified, the demand and supply analysis would continue to
limp along on one foot.
But an article appearing recently in Economic Inquiry asked and
answered the question why firms persist in intentional mispricing, that
is, in keeping prices too low when demand increases transiently.(4) Why
are shortages and rationing deliberately chosen over a more profitable,
higher, market-clearing price? And which customers are favored? The
basis of the answer, when stripped of all surrounding detail, is, I
believe, that demand and price must be viewed not simply
one-dimensionally as the current rate, but as the anticipated aggregated
volume. More precisely, price is not just the current dollar price for a
unit now, but is the anticipated capital value of all future business
from the customer. For example, which is a greater demand: (a) a rate of
1000 a day lasting one week, or (b) a rate of 100 a day lasting a year?
The rate over time is certainly an important dimension of the demand
vector. More attention is paid to that vector of "demand
price" than to the current flow price. This is especially important
for items like CD disks, computers, computer programs, and drugs where
marginal costs of extra units of volume are very small compared to the
total cost of development.
If I were a young assistant professor today, there's no doubt as
to what puzzles and issues I'd tackle. There is much more work to
be done in tying the volume-demand effect to the stochastic nature of
demand. Applications of such models to a wide range of pricing problems
will be very fruitful, I believe; Art De Vany is doing such work with
theatrical exhibitions and pricing. The "zero" marginal cost of extra units of things like software, drugs, and patented ideas
likewise poses interesting pricing and contractual problems.(5)
"Information Costs, Pricing and Resource Unemployment"
[1969]. Perhaps mistakenly, I like to regard this paper as my best. It
posed the simple question, why is there unemployment? In attempting to
answer the question, the article owes its genesis to a casual comment by
George Stigler one day during a round of golf.(6) That particular day, I
inquired of George, "Economists don't have an explanation of
unemployment. Why does it occur?" Stigler, a man who could
recognize a serious question even when trying to extricate himself from
a bunker, responded "Did you ever think of the reasons for, and
costs of, search?"
That showed I knew how to apply Principle No. 2: have the right
teachers. As with the article on evolution and economics, the paper
sparked by George's comment was at first intended as an exposition
just for my own information and understanding. It ultimately appeared in
Economic Inquiry (then the Western Economic Journal) while Professor
Harold Somers was editor.(7)
I stated above that I think this paper my best. It tackles a clearly
important problem, one on which I had seen much nonsense - and still do.
It was an attempt to put in plain English what economists know about
things like search, and to dispose of explanations based on
"monopoly," "price rigidities," "unions,"
and so forth. Because the exposition was simple but the ideas themselves
powerful, the paper has had wide readership.
Principles of Professional Advancement Nos. 4 and 5
Two more Principles of Professional Advancement remain. Principle No.
4 is: make frequent use of coauthors. They keep you on the
"straight and narrow." If you can survive as friends after a
joint paper, you are doubly lucky. It has been a boon to me to have
co-authors like Robert Crawford, Harold Demsetz, Reuben Kessel, Benjamin
Klein, Roland McKean, William Meckling, and Susan Woodward. (I hope I
have not forgotten any.) Oh, I also have a William Allen as co-author of
a text book [1972] that was forty years ahead of its time, in which he
claims I wrote all the odd words while he wrote the even ones.
I'm not going to comment on how the jointly-authored articles
were initiated and co-authored. The co-authors would have to co-author
any current recollections. But a common theme has been the structure and
role of types of property rights. All the persons mentioned have
remained good friends to this day, except that Kessel and McKean, most
sadly, died far too early. I want to seize this rare opportunity to pay
tribute to Reuben Kessel, whom I met at RAND, and with whom I worked
most intensively. He was a natural born economist, and he was "homo
economicus." My error rate in economics diminished rapidly after a
few years of friendship with him, and my horizon of understandable
events widened.
Finally, and in that vein, be sure you have helpful, smart
colleagues, ones who are willing to spend hours trying to demolish your
argument while trying to help you reach a better understanding, or in
suggesting ideas for you. I followed that advice. Not only has fortune
favored me with excellent graduate students and co-authors, but also
with other colleagues who are superb economists. Of course, although
it's not publicized, colleagues who aren't co-authors with you
often contribute more to your career than co-authors. Being smart enough
to have cooperative colleagues like that is not just luck. I was deeply
involved in recruiting for the department. So in closing, I commend
Principle No. 5: have superb and cooperative colleagues.
1. I had published a small, minor comment in the Journal of the
American Statistics Association on someone else's paper.
2. As a Rhodes scholar, Charles Hitch had been a friend of John
Williams, the chief of the division at RAND in which the mathematicians
were located, and where I was placed for lack of knowing what an
economist could do. Williams invited Hitch to Santa Monica for a month
on the beach, which fortunately helped to persuade Hitch to be the head
of an economics division. In addition to myself and Hitch, the economics
division included my UCLA colleague Roland McKean, who co-authored a
book with Hitch [1960] based on some of the work being done at RAND.
3. That work also led to my writing an article on the reliability of
progress curves in airframe production [1963].
4. Haddock and McChesney [1994]. In essence, Haddock and McChesney
argue that once demand is viewed more broadly, in more dimensions of
"size," the implied market-clearing competitive pricing
concept in altered. What appears to be irrational, inefficient pricing
is seen to be economically efficient.
5. The biological-genetic work mentioned above is also of great
interest, although this area is too technical for many people trained as
economists.
6. George was an avid golfer. He lived next to Flossmoor Country
Club, where I was lucky enough to play with him a couple of times. I
also visited George at his summer home on Lake Muskoka in Canada, where
we boated across the lake to alternate golf courses. And we played a few
holes at Princeton (where I first met George at a conference), with
Milton Friedman as our caddy.
It is unclear whether golf and economics are complements or
substitutes. Bob Crawford and I used to talk a lot about economics as we
were developing our ideas about opportunistic behavior (Klein, Crawford
& Alchian [1978]), but bad golf was sometimes the resuit.
7. Somers, retired from the UCLA economics department and my current
office-mate, is also the man who brought Ronald Coase from England to
Buffalo.
REFERENCES
Alchian, Armen A. "Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic
Theory." Journal of Political Economy, June 1950, 211-21.
-----. "Costs and Outputs," in The Allocation of Economic
Resources, edited by M. Abramovitz et al. Palo Alto: Stanford University
Press, 1959, 23-40.
-----. "The Reliability of Progress Curves in Airframe
Production." Econometrica, October 1963, 679-93.
-----. "Information Costs, Pricing and Resource Unemployment.
Western Economic Journal, June 1969, 109-28.
Alchian, Armen, and William R. Allen. University Economics: Elements
of Inquiry, 3d ed. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth Publishing Co., 1972.
Breit, William, and Harold M. Hochman. Readings in Microeconomics,
2nd ed. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1971.
Haddock, David D., and Fred S. McChesney. "Why Do Firms Contrive Shortages? The Economics of Intentional Mispricing." Economic
Inquiry, October 1994, 562-81.
Hitch, Charles J., and Roland N. McKean. The Economics of Defense in
the Nuclear Age. New York: Atheneum, 1960.
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian.
"Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive
Contracting Process." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1978,
297-326.
ARMEN A. ALCHIAN, Professor Emeritus, Department of Economics, UCLA.