Risk, rationality, and religious portfolios.
Iannaccone, Laurence R.
I. INTRODUCTION
This paper builds on two assumptions - the first, self-evident; the
second, more controversial. Together they yield a provocative theory of
religious behavior and organization.
The first assumption is that religion involves a great deal of risk.
Those who engage in religious acts cannot know that their efforts will
have the desired effects. Religious acts thus have the character of
risky investments, exacting resource costs in return for uncertain
rewards. The second assumption is that people choose their religious
behavior rationally, weighing the costs and benefits of religious
behavior and seeking to limit the risk associated with religious
choices.
Churches and other "religious firms" employ a variety of
institutional arrangements that mitigate religious risk. Most
arrangements follow one of two major risk management strategies, which
in turn give rise to two different styles of religion. One centers on
collective production, the other on private production and diversified
consumption. Collective religion is congregationally oriented and tends
to employ exclusivity and costly prohibitions to limit free riding and
maintain high levels of commitment. Private religion is less susceptible
to free-rider problems, but also less capable of generating commitment.
Private religion tends to center on client/practitioner relationships or
fee-for-service transactions, and consumers tend not to form exclusive
attachments to a single religious firm. Outright payments for goods and
services overshadow costly demands for an austere, deviant, or
sacrificial life-style.
A large body of descriptive, historic, and anecdotal evidence confirms these predictions and illustrates their range of application.
The concluding sections of the paper apply the proposed theory to a
series of contrasts: Asian versus Western religion, mainstream
"churches" versus exclusive "sects," New Age versus
standard American religion, and Greco-Roman paganism versus
Judeo-Christian monotheism.
II. RELIGIOUS COMMODITIES AND THE PROBLEM OF RISK
Economic models of religious behavior typically begin by assuming
that individuals allocate their time and money so as to maximize their
utility from religious commodities, R, and all other (secular)
commodities, S. The production of religious commodities depends on
personal inputs of time and money, but may also depend on past
experience (religious human capital), styles of behavior (such as diet,
dress, and sexual practices), and the time and money inputs of others
(such as fellow church members). See Azzi and Ehrenberg [1975], Sullivan
[1985], and Iannaccone [1992] for formal analyses and empirical tests.
With the exception of Durkin and Greeley [1991] and Montgomery
[1992], previous models take belief as given, thereby sidestepping the
issue of risk. But religious commodities do involve risk; sermons and
scriptures do emphasize the need for faith; and people do wrestle with,
and often yield to, doubt.
Insights from secular markets and the economics of uncertainty
explain a broad range of behaviors and institutions that arise in
response to religious risk. In particular, they highlight two different
risk-reducing strategies, one of which centers on exclusivity and
collective production, the other centers on diversification and private
production.
Managing Risk through Collective Action: Religious Congregations
The would-be believer faces a situation not unlike the would-be used
car buyer. Used cars are classic "experience" goods [Nelson
1970], since potential buyers are hard-pressed to determine car quality
in advance of purchase. Sellers thus have an incentive to overstate the
value of their merchandise and to disguise its true nature. Used car
buyers, in turn, are aware of the sellers' incentive to
misrepresent their products and so will attempt to increase their stock
of information and/or reduce their risk in many ways. They may demand
guarantees, seek information from third parties, investigate the
seller's reputation, and so forth. For their part, sellers also
have an incentive to provide, or at least appear to provide, proof that
their claims are true.
The uncertainty surrounding most religious goods far surpasses that
which surrounds used cars. Indeed, religion qualifies as the ultimate
"credence good" [Darby and Karni 1973] since no amount of
experience suffices fully to evaluate most religious claims. Hence we
can predict the emergence of institutions and arrangements designed to
increase information (or at least the appearance of information) and
reduce fraud.(1)
Examples are not hard to find. Testimonials are commonplace in
religion and, predictably, are more common in those variants that place
greater emphasis on material blessings. Testimonies are more likely to
be believed when they come from a trusted source, such as a personal
acquaintance or a respected figure. They are especially credible when
testifiers have relatively little to gain (or better yet much to lose)
from having their claims heard and believed. This helps to explain why
the character of religious activity is so often collective and structure
of religious organizations is so often congregational. Fellow members
are more trustworthy than strangers. They also have less incentive to
overstate the benefits of the religion than do members of the clergy,
whose livelihood depends on a steady stream of "sales." The
clergy, in turn, are more persuasive when they do not benefit materially
from their followers' faith (or have large sunk costs invested in
their reputation). This may help to explain why clergy receive low
salaries relative to their level of training. Citizens fully expect the
managers of successful secular corporations to earn large salaries,
bonuses, and stock options; and they rarely boycott a firm simply
because its chief officers have grown rich from product sales. Yet the
same citizens have little but scorn for religious leaders who parlay
successful ministries into personal fortunes.
Several distinctive features of religious institutions are thus
explained in terms of their ability to reduce the risk of consumer
fraud. These include: a minimal professional staff whose financial
compensation is low and independent of customer contributions/payments;
heavy reliance on part-time and volunteer workers (and thus reliance on
payments of time and service rather than money); a congregational
structure, which limits the need for full-time professionals and
provides a source of credible product endorsements; and collective
activities, which provide continuous assurance through the enthusiasm,
devotion, conviction, and testimony of fellow members.
Free-rider problems. There is, however, a downside to congregational
structure and collective activities: free-rider problems. These problems
lead to an organizational response that I have labeled "sacrifice
and stigma."(2)
To understand the temptation to free ride, consider the situation
confronting the typical member of a Protestant church. The pleasure and
assurance that he (or she) derives from Sunday services depends not just
on his own inputs but also the inputs of others - how many others
attend, how warmly they greet him, how well they sing, how
enthusiastically they read and pray, how deep their expressed
commitment, and so forth. This leads immediately to two related
problems. The first is that members with low levels of participation
(and perhaps also low levels of faith) are tempted to free ride off
those with higher levels, since given the choice they are better off in
groups whose average level of participation is greater than their own.
The second is that even in a homogeneous group, opportunistic behavior
leads to an inefficient equilibrium with suboptimal participation, since
individuals maximize personal welfare by ignoring the external benefits
of their participation.
Costly demands offer a solution to free-rider problems. These costs
are not the standard costs associated with the production or purchase of
secular commodities. Rather, they are apparently gratuitous costs -
sacrifice and stigma - foreign to most secular contexts: burnt
offerings, which destroy valued resources; distinctive dress and
grooming that invite ridicule or scorn; dietary and sexual prohibitions
that limit opportunities for pleasure; restrictions on the use of modern
medicine or technology. Sacrifice and stigma discourage free-riding by
prohibiting or penalizing activities (such as interaction with
nonmembers) that otherwise compete for members' resources. In
heterogeneous populations, sacrifice and stigma tends to screen out the
less committed members. And even in homogeneous populations, it induces
a substitution effect that can raise average levels of group
participation and group utility.
Deviant norms thus mitigate the externality problems faced by
religious groups. Distinctive diet, dress, grooming, and social customs
constrain and often stigmatize members, making participation in
alternative activities more costly. Potential members are forced to
choose: participate fully or not at all. The seductive middle-ground of
free-riding and low participation is eliminated. Paradoxically, those
who remain find their welfare increased. It follows that perfectly
rational people can be drawn to decidedly unconventional groups. It also
follows that any collectively oriented religion will benefit from some
level of sacrifice and stigma, although the optimal level declines as
the average member's income and education rise.
We have thus traced the consequences of religious risk down a lengthy
path: from collective activities and congregational structures, to
free-rider problems, to sacrifice and stigma.
Managing Risk through Diversification: Religious Portfolios
There is, however, an alternative response to risk - portfolio
diversification. To apply this insight to religious behavior, note that
most people have access to a variety of different religions or different
classes of religious acts within a single religious tradition.(3) It
follows that rational religious investors have reason to avoid
specializing in a single religion or class of religious acts, preferring
instead to diversify their investments over a number of them.(4) In
fact, since risk is most effectively reduced by investing in assets that
vary independently or even negatively, rational investors may hedge
their bets in one religion with other bets in very different religions.
For example, one might go to confession on Sunday, consult a medium on
Monday, and engage in transcendental meditation on Wednesday. Hence:
PROPOSITION 1. In order to reduce the risk associated with religious
commodities, consumers will seek to hold diversified portfolios of
competing religious assets.
How do we square this prediction with reality? After all, the typical
church-goer is firmly wedded to a single religious tradition, a single
denomination, and a single congregation. This tendency to specialize can
not be dismissed merely by noting that most religions do not allow
diversification. If the demand for diversification is as great as the
preceding argument suggests, then why does competition not force
churches to accommodate it? How do churches demand, and get, the sort of
brand loyalty that secular producers only dream of?
The answers lie in the contrasting production technologies employed
by different types of religion. These technologies may be either
"collective" or "private," and only the latter lend
themselves to diversification.
Most Western religions rely on collective, congregational production.
In describing the risk-reducing advantages of the collective production
approach, I have emphasized that these religions must limit free riding.
Many do so through costly demands that effectively isolate members from
competing groups. The demands can be sustained, despite competition from
other religions, because the costs of exclusivity are for many people
more than balanced by the gains from collective action. But exclusivity
and diversification do not mix; a church can not isolate its members
while at the same time permit them to participate in competing groups.
Hence, congregationally oriented religions can (and generally do) limit
their members' involvement in competing religions. These
limitations are most extensive in highly sectarian groups such as the
Mormons, Jehovah's Witnesses, Adventists, Krishnas, Moonies, and
fundamentalist Christian denominations.
But not every religion is congregationally oriented. Some deal in
private commodities that can be transferred directly from an individual
producer to an individual consumer without recourse to a mediating
group. Most "New Age" products fall into this category -
books, tapes, and seminar lectures; crystals and pyramids; and
techniques for meditation. Production and distribution of these products
are not hampered by free-rider problems, and thus the costly strategies
described in the previous section are neither necessary nor profitable.
Indeed, a private commodity producer who demands exclusivity or stigma
will suffer a competitive disadvantage relative to other private
producers. Firms dealing in private commodities must therefore sell
their products "with no strings attached." It follows that
their customers will patronize other firms so as to diversify their
portfolio of religious assets. In short,
PROPOSITION 2a. Wherever religious firms exist to provide private
commodities, competitive forces and risk aversion will lead consumers to
patronize multiple firms, thereby diversifying their religious
portfolios.
PROPOSITION 2b. Wherever religious firms exist to facilitated the
production of collective goods, the firm and its patrons will demand
exclusivity to mitigate the free-rider problems.
Proposition 2b does not assert that a collective setting alters
people's desire for a diversified portfolio, only their opportunity
to indulge that desire. In the absence of institutional constraints,
people will yield to the temptation to free ride and to diversify, and
this in turn will undermine the institution. Hence, only those firms
that maintain sufficient exclusivity (by means of strictness,
monitoring, and the like) can remain viable. The members' impulse
to diversify will be accommodated only in a limited sense and only
within the individual firm. It follows that these firms will be under
pressure to take a department store approach to religion - comprehensive
belief systems, cradle to grave services, extensive and varied social
networks, and so forth. In contrast, religious firms that produce
private commodities will be under no pressure to provide a full range of
products. The forces of competition will in fact drive them to
specialize, much as secular firms tend to specialize. Over time, private
commodity firms will come to resemble highly specialized boutiques.
If propositions 1 and 2 are correct, then the degree to which a
religious firm provides its customer-members collective versus private
goods should correlate with its tendency to make exclusive versus
nonexclusive demands. The comprehensiveness of firm's product line
should also correlate. Moreover, the content of the religions and their
financial strategies should also follow different patterns. Private
religion will usually deal in specific goods and services, items that
can be produced by one set of individuals and sold to another.
Collective religion will deal in collective action and collective
services - commodities that blur the line between producer and consumer
and that do not lend themselves to buying and selling. The distinction
between private and collective goods thus helps explain why some
religions organize around client/practitioner or buyer/seller
relationships whereas others organize as collectives in which all
members are, to varying degrees, coworkers and co-consumers. Table I
summarizes these and other predictions of the theory.
III. EXAMPLES AND APPLICATIONS
Although the predictions in Table I are straightforward, statistical
tests must await new data. Existing surveys largely [TABULAR DATA FOR
TABLE I OMITTED] ignore the issues of collective versus private
religion, sacrifice and stigma, religious risk, and fee-for-service
religion. They especially ignore diversification, assuming instead that
religious affiliation is exclusive and unitary. Respondents are asked to
state "their religion," and all subsequent questions about
religious practice are assumed to refer back to that religion. The
resulting data radically underestimate levels of involvement in
non-conventional religion and provide no insight into
diversification.(5)
Fortunately, there exists a large body of qualitative evidence
relevant to the theory and its range of application.
Example 1: Western Religions versus Asian Religions
At its most general level, the theory of collective versus private
production suggests a fundamental distinction between Western and Asian
religions.
Western religions - Christianity, Judaism, and Islam - emphasize
collective action. Congregations form the basic unit of religious
production, and congregational events (such as weekly worship services)
underpin the standard cycle of religious activity. Responsibility for
religious production is, to varying degrees, shared by everyone. As the
theory predicts, exclusivity and membership are fundamental to each of
these religions. There is an "in" group and an "out"
group, and the distinction between the two is of great, even eternal,
consequence. Defining and guarding the membership boundary is a central
concern, and transitions across the membership boundary - conversion and
apostasy - are major events. Members are expected to remain loyal to
their particular "brand" of religion, and loyalty is, in fact,
the norm [Roof and McKinney 1987, 162-181]. Those who attempt to
"diversify" their religious practices through participation in
different groups are condemned as backsliders or even excommunicated as
heretics. Indeed, in these religions, renouncing all other faiths is as
important as affirming the group's faith. The archetypal example
appears in the ten commandments: "I am the Lord your God ... You
shall have no other gods before me ... for I the Lord your God am a
jealous God" [Deuteronomy 5:6-9]. In like manner, Muslims are
expected to reaffirm at every private or congregational prayer,
"There is no God but Allah, and Muhammad was his last messenger on
Earth."
Western religions often employ sacrifice and stigma, restricting the
diet, dress, or social and sexual behavior of their members. Religious
goods and services are not usually sold for money; rather they are
freely offered to all members (although contributions are expected in
return). The scope of services is very broad, comprehending virtually
every aspect of this life and the next.
The most popular forms of Asian religions are quite different.
Collective, congregational production takes a back seat to private
practice. Household rituals, individualistic exchanges with the gods (as
when one makes a money offering in order to effect a specific outcome),
the purchase of charms and other religious artifacts, and
client/practitioner exchange relationships are pervasive. Brand loyalty
is weak, and diversification is common. It is not unusual to patronize
more than one priest, more than one temple, or even more than one
religion. According to Maraca [1975, 7-8] dual religious membership is
"observable everywhere in rural and traditional Japan":
A household keeps a family Buddhist altar where Buddha and the
family's ancestral spirits are enshrined, a family Shinto altar for
charms distributed by local shrine and the Ie Grand Shrine; in addition,
charms issued by prayer temples are posted on the walls and pillars of
the house.
In this context, "membership" is at best a matter of
secondary concern and at worst a meaningless construct. According to
McFarland [1967, 20], most Japanese religious institutions "do not
require or even provide for the kind of profession of faith or
commitment to membership that is the sine qua non of meaningful
religious statistics in the West. Thus, even if one turns to the people
themselves$and asks them to identify themselves religiously, he will
find that many of them cannot do so with any certainty." Indeed,
the official statistics cited by Morioka [1975, 4] show that the
combined number of Japanese Shintoists, Buddhists, Christians, and sect
members sums to nearly twice the national population!
Along with the phenomena of private production, nonexclusivity, and
diversified plural membership, there is less emphasis on the sort of
behavioral restrictions that I have labeled "sacrifice and
stigma." The blessings of religion are often purchased outright.
Obtaining them in return for self-mortification is far less common.(6)
Example 2: The New Age Movement
Within the United States and Europe, the "New Age" movement
and its many precursors epitomize what I have called private religion -
specialized sellers, no congregational structure, client/practitioner
relationships, fee for service transactions, no brand loyalty, and
acknowledged diversification. At New Age fairs, for example, dozens of
exhibitors will set up stalls, side by side, and hawk their wares to
consumers who literally shop around for products - astrology,
numerology, psychic readings, hand-analysis, channeling, runes, tarot,
past-life regression, crystals, metaphysical tapes and books, aura
photographs, massage, chiropractic treatment, and natural foods. See
Jorgensen [1992, 90-100] for details.
Although the fairs are but one facet of New Age religion, similar
features characterize the entire movement. Wilson [1987, 41-42] observes
that "therapeutic movements are vulnerable because their hold on
the clientele is itself so narrow. The basic client-practitioner
relationship of all such movements makes difficult the creation of a
solid core of support." Johnson [1987, 255] states that "such
organizations have difficulty building a stable pool of devoted members
because the bulk of them are essentially fee-paying clients ... There is
a wide-open market in the area of commercialized therapeutic services,
and brand loyalty is weak." And according to McGuire [1987, 125]
the typical "seeker" goes about "permanently searching
for particles of truth from a wide variety of sources ... drawling] upon
several different groups, either simultaneously or serially. ... [T]here
is thus no way to handle 'heresy' and therefore no clear
boundaries between members and nonmembers."
Example 3: The Spectrum of Protestant Denominations
Protestant Christianity is on the whole collectively oriented. But
the degree of commitment to congregational organization and collective
action varies systematically across different Protestant denominations.
This gives rise to a church-sect spectrum, with the so-called
"liberal" or "mainline" denominations at one end and
the "sectarian" denominations at the other. The Episcopal,
Congregational, Presbyterian, and Methodist denominations are among the
most liberal groups; the Southern Baptist, Pentecostal, Fundamentalist,
Adventist, and Jehovah's Witness denominations are among the most
sectarian.
Intra-Protestant comparisons thus provide a small-scale test of the
theory of collective versus private production. Table II summarizes
empirical results from previous studies of Protestant groups [Iannaccone
1992; 1994]. The observed differences are large, significant, and easily
replicated. Compared to members of other Protestant denominations, sect
members are poorer and less educated, contribute more money and attend
more services, hold stronger and more exclusive beliefs, belong to
smaller congregations, are more likely to choose their closest friends
from within their congregation, and are less involved in activities and
organizations outside of their congregation. The spectrum of Protestant
denominations thus provides statistical evidence that the attributes of
religious organizations and the behavior of their members cluster as
predicted.
Other studies extend these findings to the realm of religious
portfolios, proving that members of sect-like denominations are much
less likely to "diversify" than are their more mainline
counterparts. For example, Stark and Bainbridge's [1985, 381-386]
survey of about 1,500 university students found that "Born
Again" Christians were far less likely that other Christians to
approve of astrology, psychic practices, or Eastern meditation. Donahue
[1991] finds that Southern Baptist church members are much less likely
to hold New Age beliefs than are members of more liberal Protestant
denominations. And Tamney et al. [1991] find that experimentation with
New Age religious activities is more common among members of church-like
denominations than sect-like denominations.
TABLE II
Mean Values for Members of Different Protestant Denominations(*)
LIBERAL MODERATE SECT-LIKE SECTS
HOUSEHOLD INCOME: 10,140 9,435 8,399 6,944
(dollars per year)
RESPONDENT EDUCATION: 14.5 13.9 12.3 12.5
(years)
SUNDAY ATTENDANCE: 33.8 38.4 44.2 49.1
(services/year)
CHURCH CONTRIBUTIONS: 244 288 369 497
(dollars/year)
CHURCH FRIENDS: 1.32 1.51 1.80 3.15
(number out of 5 closest)
NON-CHURCH MEETINGS: 48.6 41.1 30.6 29.0
(number/year)
NON-CHURCH MEMBERSHIPS: 3.59 3.07 2.13 1.72
(total number)
EXCLUSIVE BELIEFS: 2.06 2.70 3.79 4.15
(3-item, belief scale)
NUMBER OF RESPONDENTS: 963 882 194 248
Notes:
Source: Iannaccone's [1992] analysis of data from the Northern
California Church Member Study, 1963.
Denominational groups: LIBERAL = members of Congregational,
Methodist, Episcopalian, and Disciples of Christ churches. MODERATE
= Presbyterians, American Lutherans, and American Baptists.
SECT-LIKE = Missouri Lutherans and Southern Baptists. SECTS =
members of Assemblies of God, Church of God, Church of Christ,
Nazarene, Seventh Day Adventist, Gospel Lighthouse, Foursquare
Gospel churches.
* For all variables, the mean difference between members of sects
and the liberal denominations is significant at the 1% level.
Example 4: Paganism versus Early Christianity and Judaism
A final example, drawn from classical history, suggests that the
theory of private versus collective religion may be as applicable to
ancient times as it is to modern societies.
The Roman Empire was filled with competing religions: civic worship
of the old Greco-Roman gods, such as Zeus, Apollo, Artemis, Dionysus,
and the like; Caesar worship; mystery religions of Isis, Mithras,
Adonis, and others; magic and astrology; and numerous schools of
philosophy. All these existed, side by side, in an atmosphere of mutual
toleration. Adherence to one did not preclude involvement in another.
Citizens could, and many did, participate in multiple cults -
sacrificing to several gods, worshipping the emperor, and undertaking a
variety of different rites and initiations. Pagan worship exemplified
the portfolio approach to religion.
Christianity and Judaism were utterly different, and it was this
difference that occasioned their persecution in an empire that otherwise
tolerated virtually any and all religions. Unlike the pagan cults,
Christianity and Judaism demanded not only acceptance of new rites and
new beliefs, but also renunciation of old ways. As Robbins [1988, 65;
see also Nock 1964] notes, they "were characterized by exclusivity
whereby the convert was cut off from his past lifestyle and identity and
from other religious groups. One was thus converted to the intolerant
faiths of Judaism and Christianity while one merely adhered to the cults
of Isis, Orpheus, or Mithra." Pagans might use Mithraism or consult
the Delphic Oracle, but Christians and Jews belonged to their faiths.(7)
Consistent with this paper's theory of exclusive religion,
Christianity and Judaism placed far more rigorous demands on the moral
behavior and life-style of their members and offered a far broader range
of benefits in return. Moreover, Christianity and Judaism were
collective, congregationally oriented religions. According to Dodds
[1965, 136-138], a "Christian congregation was from the first a
community in a much fuller sense than any corresponding group of Isiac
or Mithraist devotees. Its members were bound together not only by
common rites but by a common way of life and ... by their common
danger.... The Church provided the essentials of social security: it
cared for widows and orphans, the old, the unemployed, and the disabled;
it provided a burial fund for the poor and a nursing service in time of
plague... Christians were in more than formal sense 'members one of
another'." The contrasts between paganism and Christianity
thus fit the pattern of Table I in every detail.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
This paper has interpreted many aspects of religious institutions as
attempts to limit religious risk. In particular, it has identified two
major risk management strategies that give rise to two different styles
of religion. One centers on collective production, the other on private
production and diversified consumption. Collective religion is
congregationally oriented and thus susceptible to free-rider problems.
Exclusivity and costly prohibitions are employed by such religions to
limit free riding and maintain high levels of commitment. Western
religions, particularly their more sectarian forms, exemplify this
pattern. Private religion is less susceptible to free-rider problems,
but is also less capable of generating commitment. It may attract many
"customers" but few real "members." New Age
religions in America and Shinto and Buddhism in Japan exemplify this
style of religion. The practice of these religions tends to center on
client/practitioner relationships or fee-for-service transactions, and
consumers tend not to form exclusive attachments to a single religion or
religious firm. Payments for goods and services tend to overshadow
costly demands for an austere, deviant, or sacrificial life-style.
The analysis is by no means complete. The argument builds on earlier,
formal models of religious participation, but is itself intuitive. The
concept of religious risk needs to be specified more precisely and its
implications derived formally. As things stand, I can not explain why
market forces do not always drive religions toward one style of
production, private or collective. (One should, however, note that
collective religions such as evangelical Protestantism and Islamic
fundamentalism have tended over time to gain market share at the expense
of less demanding alternatives.)
The theory of religious portfolios and of collective versus private
religion is rich in testable predictions. Existing surveys do not
address these implications, but the implications do accord with much of
what is known about religious movements within the United States, across
the globe, and throughout history. That in itself is a very promising
start.
1. I am indebted to Hull and Bold [1989] for drawing my attention to
this fact. Although they do not discuss congregational structure and
collective activity, their basic insights regarding risk and fraud
provide much of the motivation for the following two paragraphs.
2. See Iannaccone [1992] for a formal model of religious groups in
which sacrifice and stigma works to reduce free-riding and raise
utility.
3. The type and range of available options will, of course, differ
from one time and place to another. Contemporary America and ancient
Rome are examples of societies offering an exceptionally wide range of
choices. Societies dominated by a single, state-supported religion
(e.g., medieval Europe and contemporary Iran) do much to limit religious
choice. Still, we tend to underestimate the extent to which even the
medieval Catholic monopoly struggled with competition from paganism,
witchcraft and schism [Stark and Bainbridge 1985, 111-122].
4. One may recoil at a comparison of religious acts and stock market
acquisitions, but it should be noted that investment metaphors are
common to most religions. Pascal's "wager" is an
investment-oriented appeal to faith, as is Matthew 6:19-20.
5. For example, projections from a recent telephone poll of over
113,000 American households [Kosmin 1991] imply that only 20,000
Americans identify their religion as "New Age." Nevertheless,
subscriptions to the New Age Journal number more than 140,000.
Evidently, the overwhelming majority of New Age patrons describe
themselves as members of some other religious tradition or no religion
at all.
6. The distinction that I have attempted to draw between Western and
Asian religion is, of course, highly generalized. Within the religious
traditions of virtually every Asian country, one does find some
collective, congregationally oriented groups. Hindu communes and
Buddhist monasteries come readily to mind. Some of Japan's new
religions, such as Shokagakkai, also fall into this category as do
America's best-known imported "cults" - Hare Krishna and
the Unification Church. As the theory predicts, all these groups
emphasize membership, demand exclusivity, maintain high levels of
participation, enforce strict codes of behavior and provide a
comprehensive range of services.
7. Some pagans attempted to add Christianity and Judaism to their
religious portfolios. For example, Dodds [1965, 107] reports that
"the Emperor Alexander Severus, kept in his private chapel statues
of Abraham, Orpheus, Christ and Apollonius of Tyana" and that the
Gnostic Carpocrates preached a "comprehensive cult" that
"worshipped images of Homer, Pythagoras, Plato, Aristotle, Christ
and St Paul." Christians' steadfast refusal to practice any
element of civic religion was thus grounded in the realistic fear that
"even the most formal concession to pagan cult would lead in the
end to Christianity being swallowed up and digested in the all-embracing
maw of Graeco-Roman paganism" [Dodds 1965, 113].
REFERENCES
Azzi, Corry, and Ronald G. Ehrenberg. "Household Allocation of
Time and Church Attendance." Journal of Political Economy, February
1975, 27-56.
Darby, Michael R., and Edi Karni. "Free Competition and the
Optimal Amount of Fraud." Journal of Law, and Economics, April
1973, 67-88.
Dodds, E. R. Pagan and Christian in an Age of Anxiety: Some Aspects
of Religious Experience from Marcus Aurelius to Constantine. London:
Cambridge University Press, 1965.
Donahue, Michael J. "Prevalence of New Age Beliefs in Six
Protestant Denominations." Working paper, Search Institute, 1991.
Durkin, John T., Jr., and Andrew M. Greeley. "A Model of
Religious Choice under Uncertainty: On Responding Rationally to the
Non-Rational." Rationality, and Society, April 1991, 178-196.
Finke, Roger, and Rodney Stark. The Churching of America 1776-1990:
Winners, and Losers in Our Religious Economy. New Brunswick, N.J.:
Rutgers University Press, 1992.
Hull, Brooks B., and Frederick Bold. "Towards an Economic Theory
of the Church." International Journal of Social Economics, 16(7),
1989, 5-15.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. "Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free
Riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives." Journal of
Political Economy, April 1992, 271-91.
-----. "Why Strict Churches Are Strong." American Journal
of Sociology, March 1994, 1180-211.
Johnson, Benton. "A Sociologist of Religion Looks at the Future
of New Religious Movements," in The Future of New Religious
Movements, edited by David G. Bromley, and Phillip E. Hammond. Macon,
Ga.: Mercer University Press, 1987, 251-60.
Jorgensen, Danny L. The Esoteric Scene, Cultic Milieu, and Occult
Tarot. New York: Garland, 1992.
Kosmin, Barry A. "Research Report: The National Survey of
Religious Identification 1989-90." The Graduate School and
University Center of the City University of New York, 1991.
McFarland, H. Neill. The Rush Hour of the Gods: A Study of New
Religious Movements in Japan. New York: Macmillan, 1967.
McGuire, Meredith B. Religion: The Social Context, 2nd ed. Belmont,
Calif.: Wadsworth, 1987.
Montgomery, James. "Pascal's Wager and the Limits of
Rational Choice: A Comment on Durkin and Greeley." Rationality and
Society, January 1992, 117-22.
Morioka, Kiyomi. Religion in Changing Japanese Society. Japan:
University of Tokyo Press, 1975.
Nelson, Phillip J. "Information, and Consumer Behavior."
Journal of Political Economy, March/April 1970, 311-29.
Nock, Arthur Darby. Early Gentile Christianity and Its Hellenistic
Background. New York: Harper and Row, 1964.
Robbins, Thomas. Cults, Converts and Charisma: The Sociology of New
Religious Movements. London: Sage, 1988.
Roof, Wade Clark, and William McKinney. American Mainline Religion:
Its Changing Shape and Future. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press,
1987.
Stark, Rodney, and William Sims Bainbridge. The Future of Religion.
Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985.
Sullivan, Dennis H. "Simultaneous Determination of Church
Contributions and Church Attendance." Economic Inquiry, April 1985,
309-20.
Tamney, Joseph B., Barbara A, Bunch, Paul R. Stieber, and Deborah L.
Zigler-Geis. "The New Age in Middletown: An Exploratory
Study." Working paper, Ball State University, 1991.
Wilson, Bryan R. "Factors in the Failure of the New Religious
Movements," in The Future of New Religious Movements, edited by
David G. Bromley, and Phillip E. Hammond. Macon, Ga.: Mercer University
Press, 1987, 30-45.
LAURENCE R. IANNACCONE, Associate Professor, Department of Economics,
Santa Clara University, Santa Clara, CA. Early drafts of this paper were
presented at the meetings of the Society for the Scientific Study of
Religion, November 1991, the American Economic Association, January 1992
and the Western Economic Association, June 1992. I am indebted to many
colleagues for encouragement and suggestions, particularly Douglas
Allen, Corry Azzi, Gary Becker, Thomas Borcherding, Timur Kuran, John
Lott, John Murray, S. Ramachandran, Rodney Stark, Gordon Winston and two
anonymous reviewers. This research was supported in part by a grant
(#90-0004) from the Lilley Endowment's Louisville Institute for the
Study of Protestantism and American Culture.