Could stable money have averted the great contraction?
Bordo, Michael D. ; Choudhri, Ehsan U. ; Schwartz, Anna J. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Although over fifty years have elapsed since the onset of the Great
Contraction, controversy still swirls about the factors responsible for
its depth and long duration. A basic issue is the hypothesis due to
Friedman and Schwartz [1963] that the Great Contraction would have been
attenuated had the Federal Reserve not allowed the money stock to
decline. Although the validity of the hypothesis has been a subject of
much debate, there is little empirical evidence directly addressing it.
A direct test of the Friedman and Schwartz hypothesis requires
simulating the behavior of output under a counterfactual policy of
stable money. That approach was adopted by Warburton [1966], Friedman
[1960], and Modigliani [1969], none of whom constructed a model of the
economy on the basis of which to conduct his test. Recently, McCallum
[1990] has used simulations from a macro model to show that his base
rule (with feedback) would have avoided the severe decline in nominal
income that occurred between 1929 and 1933.(1) The extent to which his
rule would have improved the behavior of nominal income depends on the
value of the feedback coefficient. McCallum's simulations, however,
do not address the issue considered here of how a stable-money rule
would have performed.
In this paper we present simulations that focus on the stable-money
counterfactual. Our model is based on McCallum's, but we use a more
general framework than his that (a) estimates separate relations for
output and the price level, and (b) places no prior restrictions on the
feedback from output and the price level to money. Our stable-money
counterfactual does not change the long-term rate of money growth (from
that actually experienced) and thus involves only short-run changes in
the behavior of the money supply. We assume that dynamics embedded in
the output and price relation are not especially sensitive to this type
of policy change.
We simulate two variants of Milton Friedman's [1960] constant
money growth rule. The first, a strong form of the rule, assumes that
the Fed could quickly offset changes in the money multiplier by changes
in high-powered money and thus keep the money stock on the constant
growth rate path in each quarter. The second, a weaker form of the rule,
assumes that the money multiplier is observed with a one-quarter lag and
the Fed can only set the expected rate of growth of money (conditional
on last-period information) equal to the constant rate.
Our basic simulation is derived from a model estimated for the
1921.1-1941.4 interwar period. The results of this simulation buttress the views of Friedman and Schwartz. Had a constant money growth rule
(with an annual rate equal to the average 1921-41 rate of 2.95 percent)
been followed throughout the interwar period the Great Contraction would
have been avoided. Real output would have declined from 1929.3 to
1933.1, but the order of magnitude of the cumulative change (-11.1 to
-21.6 percent) and the annual rate of change (-3.3 to -6.6 percent),
when the actual cumulative change was -36.2 percent and the annual rate
of change was -12.1 percent, would have been comparable to other
recessions in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.
In the basic simulation we assume that the output and price relations
remained stable over the entire interwar period. The extraordinary
economic conditions of the Great Contraction could have arguably shifted
the output and price relations. Thus, we also present an alternative
simulation that uses estimates of these relations based on the 1920s
data. This simulation shows that a constant money growth rule (with an
annual rate equal to the 1921-29 average of 3.29 percent) would have
prevented even a mild recession during the Great Contraction period.
Section II contains a brief survey of the continuing debate over the
cause and propagation mechanism of the Great Contraction and its
implications for the stable-money hypothesis. Section III presents an
overview of the behavior of the variables considered in our model.
Section IV describes our methodology for performing counterfactual
simulations for the interwar years 1921 to 1941. Section V provides
basic simulations of the paths of output and the price level under
different variants of the constant money growth rule. Section VI
explores the sensitivity of our results to alternative specifications.
Section VII contains a brief conclusion.
II. THE CONTROVERSY OVER THE GREAT CONTRACTION
Since the publication of A Monetary History in 1963, a voluminous
literature has appeared, some of it critical and some supportive of
Friedman and Schwartz's contention that monetary
forces--specifically the failure of the Federal Reserve to engage in
expansionary open market operations to offset a series of banking panics
beginning in October 1930--turned a not-unusual cyclical downturn in the
United States into the greatest depression of all time. Various survey
articles in recent years have dealt with many of the issues--notably
Bordo [1989], Calomiris [1993], Eichengreen [1992a], Temin [1993], and
Romer [1993]--so our discussion will be brief.
In the 1970s and 1980s debate focused on Peter Temin's [1976]
contention that monetary forces could not have been the primary cause of
the contraction because short-term interest rates fell rather than rose,
as would be consistent with a left-ward shift in the LM curve. For his
alternative causal mechanism he posited a collapse of autonomous
expenditures.
The consensus of the subsequent literature was that, although
monetary forces were paramount, nonmonetary shocks should not be
discounted. Thus, according to Hamilton [1987] and Field [1984], tight
monetary policy initiated by the Fed in 1928 to counter the stock market
boom and to stem a gold outflow to France, following her return to gold
at an undervalued parity, initiated the contraction. The stock market
crash of October 1929 then aggravated the downturn in the year following
the crash by both increasing uncertainty and wealth-loss effects that
led to a reduction in expenditures on consumer durables, as in Romer
[1990] and Mishkin [1978]. Romer [1993] agreed that banking panics in
1930, 1931, and 1933 turned a severe recession into depression. Though
consensus prevails on the primacy of monetary forces, debate still
persists over the issues of the exogeneity of the money supply, as in
Schwartz [1981], Bordo [1989], and Calomiris [1993], and of the
propagation mechanism.
In the past decade, the focus of the literature has shifted to the
mechanism by which monetary collapse was transmitted to the real
economy. What is in contention is whether declining output responded to
a bank-panic-induced (by a fall in the deposit-currency and
deposit-reserve ratios) decline in money supply in the face of sticky
wages and prices, or whether the bank failures themselves reduced output
via the nonmonetary channel of the disruption of the process of
financial intermediation, as suggested by Bernanke [1983].
This debate hinges on the issue of whether or not deflation was
anticipated. If not, as Hamilton [1987; 1992] argued, based on evidence
from commodity futures markets, and as Evans and Wachtel [1993] found
for 1930-32, based on nominal interest rates, then debt deflation (by
reducing the net worth of firms and banks) was the propagation
mechanism, as in Fisher [1933], and Bernanke and Gertler [1989] and
[1990]. If it was largely anticipated, as Nelson [1992] argued, based on
an examination of the business press, and as Cecchettti [1992] found,
based on time-series models of prices, then the mechanism worked through
a rise in the ex ante real interest rate.
Another unsettled issue concerns the causal and propagation roles of
international factors--whether the U.S. depression spread to the rest of
the world or vice versa, as in Kindleberger [1973] and Temin [1993],
with the consensus favoring the U.S. depression as the primary cause
with reflex influences on the United States from declining output
abroad, as Eichengreen [1992a] concluded. In addition, both Eichengreen
[1992b] and Temin [1989] have argued that adherence to the gold standard
rule of convertibility was crucial both in the international
transmission of shocks and in preventing the monetary authorities of
adherents from following reflationary policies.
Our approach in this paper is compatible with much of the recent
literature. We develop a methodology to ascertain the effect of the
Friedman and Schwartz hypothesis of stable money on output and the price
level. Such a framework is compatible with propagation mechanisms based
on sticky wages and prices and on mechanisms stressing both
unanticipated and anticipated deflation. It is also compatible with
studies that identify the relative importance of different shocks, such
as those of Cecchetti and Karras [1994] for the United States, and of
Betts, Bordo and Redish [1995] for the United States and Canada.
According to these studies, which identify the banking panics as supply
shocks, output declines up to the middle of 1931 are generally accounted
for by demand shocks and subsequent output declines mostly by supply
shocks. Regardless of the source and importance of supply shocks, these
results are not inconsistent with the Friedman and Schwartz hypothesis,
since a stable money policy could have diminished the effect of all
types of shocks to the economy.
One objection to our approach is that as long as the United States
was committed to gold convertibility, it was beyond the Fed's power
to undertake expansion of domestic credit to maintain stable money
through the Great Contraction, as Eichengreen [1992b] argues.
For several reasons we do not believe this raises serious problems.
First, given that the United States had the largest monetary gold stock
in the world and that at its lowest point in 1932 the Federal Reserve
gold reserve ratio was 56 percent, the threat of the United States being
forced off the gold standard could not have been a binding constraint.
Second, we do not accept the view that Eichengreen [1992b] has
revived, namely, that the Fed could not undertake an expansionary policy
because of a shortage of "free gold"-gold not earmarked either
as backing for Federal Reserve notes and deposits or as replacement for
backing by ineligible assets. Had free gold been a genuine problem, why
did not the Federal Reserve importune the Congress to alter the
eligibility requirement before such legislation was enacted in February
1932? According to Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 406], free gold was
"largely an ex post justification for policies followed, not an ex
ante reason for them."(2)
Third, had the gold constraint been a real deterrent to pursuing
expansionary monetary policy in the Great Contraction, the United States
could have suspended convertibility, as Britain and other countries did.
Once they did so, their economies rebounded, as described in Eichengreen
and Sachs [1985] and Eichengreen [1992b].
A second objection to our approach, advanced by Calomiris [1993]
among others, is that the Fed lacked the requisite understanding to
maintain stable money. In favor of this view, Wicker [1965] and Brunner
and Meltzer [1968] have argued that the Fed accepted the flawed
Burgess-Riefler-Strong doctrine that focused on levels of member bank
borrowing and short-term nominal interest rates as policy indicators. On
this view the Fed conducted expansionary open market operations in the
1924 and 1927 recessions because neither member bank indebtedness nor
nominal interest rates had declined. By contrast, in 1930 member bank
borrowing and nominal interest rates fell. Hence the Fed believed no
action was warranted, according to Wheelock [1992], and Bordo [1989].
Against this objection, we cite two facts: the connection between
stable money and the real economy was well known at the time, as noted
by Laidler [1993], even by isolated Federal Reserve officials; and other
central banks had on earlier occasions acted successfully as lenders of
last resort.
III. OUTPUT, PRICES, AND MONEY IN THE INTERWAR YEARS
Before discussing our model, we briefly review the behavior of real
output, the price level, and the money supply during the interwar
period. For data definitions and sources, see Appendix A.
Figure 1a shows quarterly time series of the log of real GNP (y) for
the period 1921.1-1941.4. Output grew from 1921.1 to the cyclical peak
in 1929.3 at an annual rate of 6.4 percent. The period was marked by two
mild recessions: 1923.2 to 1924.3 and 1926.3 to 1927.4. Output then
declined from 1929.3 to the cyclical trough in 1933.1 by 36.2 percent
(at an annual rate of -12.1 percent), the sharpest and most prolonged
decline in U.S. history. Rapid recovery then followed until the outbreak
of World War II, with output growing at an annual rate of 8.6 percent.
Recovery was marred by a brief, sharp recession from 1937.2 to
1938.2.(3)
Figure 1b presents the quarterly data for the log of the implicit GNP
deflator (p) for the interwar period. Following a sharp post-World War I
deflation, the price level was mildly deflationary until the summer of
1929 when it began a rapid plunge for the next three and a half years.
It declined by 26.8 percent, or an annual rate of -8.5 percent. The
deflation of 1929-1933 was the most severe in U.S. history. Fisher
[1933] and Bernanke [1983] regard unanticipated deflation as an
aggravating condition in the Great Contraction because of its
deleterious effects on the balance sheets of households and firms. From
the cyclical trough in 1933.1 until World War II prices advanced at an
annual rate of 3.5 percent except for a deflationary episode from 1937.3
to 1939.2.
Figure 1c displays the behavior of the log of the M2 money supply
(m).(4) Following a sharp policy-induced contraction after World War I,
the money supply increased from 1922.2 until 1928.2 at an annual rate of
5.7 percent. The subsequent failure to grow in 1928-29 reflected
contractionary Federal Reserve policy in reaction to the stock market
boom and a gold flow to France after it returned to the gold standard at
a parity that undervalued the franc as in Hamilton [1987] and Field
[1984]. Money supply declined for the first year of the Great
Contraction by 2.2 percent, a decline not much different from that
experienced in earlier severe recessions (Friedman and Schwartz
[1963]),(5) but, beginning in October 1930, with the onset of a series
of banking panics, it began a plunge whereby m 1n M2) fell by 12.4
percent at an annual rate. The fall in m did not end until the Banking
Holiday of March 1933.
Beginning in March 1933, the money supply expanded rapidly at an
annual rate of 7.8 percent until World War II, with the exception of a
sharp contraction in 193738. According to Friedman and Schwartz, the
Federal Reserve's decision to double reserve requirements in an
attempt to soak up what it regarded as excess liquidity in the banking
system was responsible for the monetary contraction.
Friedman and Schwartz link the severe decline of the money supply
from 1930 to 1933 to a series of banking panics which ultimately caused
one-third of the nation's banks to fail. The banking panics reduced
the money supply by their effects on the money supply multiplier (see
Figure 2a). The bank failures, attributed to the absence of Federal
Reserve lender-of-last-resort action, undermined the public's
confidence, leading to a massive decline in the deposit-currency ratio.
The banks in turn reduced their loans, resulting in a sharp fall in the
deposit-reserve ratio (see Figure 2b).
Friedman and Schwartz emphasize the bank failures as the force which
led to a collapse of the money supply; for Bernanke [1983] they were
also important for their nonmonetary role of impairing the financial
intermediation process and hence reducing the level and growth rate of
real output.(6) As a standardized measure of the importance of bank
failures, we use the log of the ratio of deposits in suspended banks to
total deposits (s) (see Figure 2c).(7) This ratio, s, was quite high in
the 1920s, reflecting deep-seated structural problems in the U.S.
banking system--the weakness of unit banks in primarily agricultural
areas of the country. The dramatic increase in s from 1930 to 1933
largely reflects the banking panics. Following the Bank Holiday of March
1933 and the advent of FDIC in 1934, s declined to a much lower
level.(8) That the rise in s in 1930-33 was accompanied by a fall in the
money supply multiplier underscores the importance of bank failures in
the money supply process.
IV. METHODOLOGY
In this section we describe the methodology we use to simulate
counterfactual historical situations for the interwar period. We
estimate a small quarterly model of the interwar U.S. economy. To keep
our framework simple, our basic model includes only three variables:
output, y, the price level, p and money, m. However, we also consider
two variations of the basic model. In one variation, we introduce the
rate of interest (r) as an additional variable while in the other we add
the variable s to capture the role of bank failures. We assume that
money affects output in the short run. The short-run non-neutrality of
money is assumed to result from sticky prices or wages.(9)
We assume that y, p, m, r, and s are all stationary in first
differences.(10) Also, we assume initially that the first four of these
variables are cointegrated via a money demand relation of the following
form:
(1) [m.sub.t]-[p.sub.t]=[[alpha].sub.0]+[[alpha].sub.1][y.sub.t]+
[[alpha].sub.2][r.sub.t]+[v.sub.t]
where [v.sub.t] is a stationary component.(11) In view of (1), we
include [v.sub.t-1] as an error correction term in the equations that
model the behavior of output and the price level as follows:
(2) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
(3) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [a.sub.ij](L) are lag polynomials of order k, [z.sub.t]=
[r.sub.r] or [s.sub.t], and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] are mutually uncorrelated white-noise
disturbances representing demand and supply shocks respectively.(12) The
determination of the money supply is modeled as
(4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is a white-noise money supply
shock (uncorrelated with-both [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]). Equation (4) allows for-potential
effects of y, p and z on m-through high-powered money (via the
Fed's reaction function) as well as the money multiplier.
In our basic model, we suppress the role of both the interest rate r
and bank failures s by letting [[alpha].sub.2] = 0 in (1), and
[[alpha].sub.14](L) = 0, i = 1,2,3, in equations (2) through (4).
Friedman and Schwartz [1963] treated bank panics as exogenous shocks to
money supply and did not consider output and the price level as
significant determinants of either high-powered money or the money
multiplier. Their view suggests including bank panic shocks in
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and setting [a.sub.31](L) =
[a.sub.32](L) = 0 in (4).
Before discussing the estimation of our basic model, it is
interesting to compare it with McCallum's [19901 model and to note
the points of difference. First, McCallum estimates a relation for
nominal income growth (i.e., [delta][y.sub.t] + [delta][p.sub.t] in our
notation), which depends on its own lagged values and lagged money
growth. This relation can be thought of as a special case of our
equations (1) and (2), which could be derived by placing restrictions on
appropriate lag polynomials in (1) and (2). Second, McCallum models
money growth differently from the way we do. He assumes that the growth
of the money base is exogenous but allows growth in the money multiplier
to depend on a bank failure variable (denoted by s in our model), which
in turn is influenced by deviations of nominal income from its target
path. Thus, there is a feedback from nominal income to money growth in
his model, but this effect is restricted to the above channels and is
not as general as our equation (3).
We estimate our basic model in the form of a vector error correction
model. Letting [x.sub.t] [equivalent to] [[delta][y.sub.t],
[delta][p.sub.t], delta[m.sub.t] and [eta] [equivalent to] [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], write equations (2) through (4) as [Ax.sub.t] =
[[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][v.sub.t-1] + [A.sup.-1] to obtain
(5) [x.sub.t]=[[gamma].sub.0]+[[gamma].sub.1][v.sub.t-1]+C(L)
[x.sub.t-1]+[e.sub.t]
where [y.sub.i] = [A.sub.-1][[beta].sub.i], i=0, 1, C(L) =
[A.sup.-1]B(L) and [e.sub.t] [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is a
vector of reduced-form shocks. The reduced-form shocks are related to
structural shocks by
(6) [e.sub.t] = [D[eta].sub.t]
where D(= [A.sup.1][delta]) [equivalent to] [[D.sub.ij]], i, j =
1,2,3.
To perform counterfactual simulations of output, y, and prices, p,
based on (5), we define the constant money growth policy as the Fed
targeting a rate of growth of the money stock equal to [theta], based on
all available information. Under this policy
(7) E([m.sub.t] | [I.sub.t])=[m.sub.t-1]+[theta]
where [I.sub.t], is the Fed's information set in period t. The
degree of monetary control under a constant money growth policy clearly
depends on the information available to the Fed. We consider several
possibilities. At a minimum, we assume that the Fed observes all
variables with a one-period lag (i.e., [I.sub.t], contains values of all
variables up to t-1). Using this weak informational assumption, the
constant money growth rule (7) implies that the [delta]m equation of
model (5) will change to
(8) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
We replace the [delta]m equation in (5) by (8) to simulate the
behavior of output and the price level under this policy. This
simulation does not require identification of structural shocks, and
would be consistent with any view about the contemporaneous relationship
between m, y, and p.
A stronger assumption about the Fed's monetary control is that
it knows contemporaneous money supply shocks (i.e., [I.sub.t] includes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] in addition to information on all
variables up to-t-1). In this case the constant money growth policy
would eliminate [Mathematical Expression Omitted] shocks. Using (6), the
constant money growth rule under the stronger informational assumption
implies that
(9) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Moreover, with money supply
shocks eliminated, [delta]y and [delta]p equations in (5) will be
subject only to shocks [Mathematical Expression Omitted] respectively.
Note that the simulation based on (9) requires the identification of
only [Mathematical Expression Omitted] shocks as [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]* can be estimated as a residual in a projection of
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] w = y,p,m,.
A number of approaches can be used to identify [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], the money supply shock term. One interesting
possibility is suggested by the Friedman-Schwartz view that the behavior
of the money supply was essentially independent of output and prices. If
it is assumed that y and p do not affect m at least contemporaneously,
then [a.sub.31](0) = [a.sub.32](0) = 0, and these exclusion restrictions
imply that [D.sub.31] = [D.sub.31] = 0 while [D.sub.33] = 1. Thus
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], and (since [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] = 0) the counterfactual money supply equation (9) reduces to
(10) [delta][m.sub.t]=[theta]
As (8) and (10) represent polar assumptions about monetary control,
the next section focuses on simulations based on these equations to
present the least and the most favorable cases for stable money.
As extensions of our basic model, we include a fourth variable z
representing either interest rates r or bank failures s. The behavior of
the fourth variable is modeled as
(11) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is assumed to be white noise
and uncorrelated with other shocks. In the case of [z.sub.t] =
[r.sub.t], [Mathematical Expression Omitted] can be viewed as shocks to
asset markets while for [z.sub.t]=[s.sub.t], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] ran be thought of as financial shocks relevant to bank
suspensions and failures. The model represented by (1), (2), (3), (4)
and (11) [with [[alpha].sub.2]=0 in (1) for [z.sub.t]=[s.sub.t]] can be
estimated in the form of (5) with [x.sub.t] and [e.sub.t] redefined as
[[delta][y.sub.t], [delta][p.sub.t], [delta][m.sub.t]] and
[[Mathematical Expression Omitted]]. In this case, however, the
restriction that y and p do not contemporaneously affect m is not
sufficient to identify [Mathematical Expression Omitted] since z could
still exert a contemporaneous effect on m. While identification of
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] is not needed for counterfactual (8),
additional assumptions would be required to justify counterfactual (101.
Our simulations assume that a change in the [delta]m equation does
not alter other equations of the model. We suppose that the short-run
adjustment process is not very sensitive to a change in monetary policy.
The long-run rate of inflation would, however, depend on the long-run
rate of money growth. Thus, in constructing our-counterfactual, we avoid
a change in the long-run money growth rate by setting [theta] equal to
the average value of [delta]m for the period over which our model is
estimated.
Our model does not explicitly constrain money to be neutral in the
long run. One implication of long-run neutrality of money is that
[[eta].sup.m] would not permanently affect y. This restriction poses no
problem for simulations based on (8) as any set of restrictions used to
identify structural shocks would be consistent with this counterfactual.
However, restrictions used to identify [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
for counterfactual (10) would not constrain the long-run effect of this
shock to equal zero.
V. BASIC SIMULATIONS
Before discussing our simulations, we present some evidence on the
relationship between money and other variables in the model in the
interwar period. Table I shows results of Granger causality tests
between certain variables in the-model for 1921.1 to i1941.4.
Regressions in this table include the lagged value of-the error
correction-term, D, and three lagged values of other regressors. Here,
assuming that [[alpha].sub.1] equals one and [[alpha].sub.2] equals
zero, we measure v by (m-p-y).(13)
[TABULAR DATA I OMITTED]
The first three regressions in the table are based on the
three-variable framework of the basic model. In the first regression, we
examine the influence of output and the price level on money. As the
results show, three lagged values of both [delta]y and [delta]p as well
as the lagged value of v, the error correction term, are insignificant
in the regression explaining [delta]m. This evidence on the absence of
Granger causality from output and the price level to money is consistent
wish the view that the money supply in this period was exogenous. The
second and the third regressions in the table examine the links from
money to output and the price level. The lagged values of [delta]m are
significant (at the .011 level) in the [delta]y equation but
insignificant in the [delta]p equation. However, even in the [delta]p
equation,=the lagged value of v is significant (at the .023 level), and
thus money does exert an effect on the price level through the error
correction term. Although we have suppressed the role of the interest
rate in our basic model, we nevertheless explore the influence of this
variable on money, output and the price level in regressions 4, 5 and 6.
As the results show, interest rates do not improve the predictive
content of any of these regressions.
The remaining regressions :in the table explore the interaction of s
with m, p and y. The results based on regressions 7 through 9 show that
lagged As terms are significant in the [delta]m and [delta]p equations
(at .017 and .360 levels, respect very) but not in the [delta]y
equation. In regression 10, however, lagged values of both [delta]p and
[delta]m are significant (at .015 and .052 levels) in the [delta]s
equation. These results suggest a role for bank failures (s) in the
model, but note that the effects operating between s and other variables
are not very strong. For examine, inclusion of this variable in the
[delta]m and [delta]p equations increases the [R.sup.2] of these
equations only marginally: by .043 and .027, respectively (compare
regression 7 with 1, and 9 with 3). The [R.sup.2] of the [delta]s
equation, moreover, is only .160.
We begin with simulations based on the basic vector error correction
model (5) with three variables. We estimate this model using three lags
for=each variable.(14) Although our interest is primarily in the Great
Contraction period, we simulate the behavior of [delta]y and [delta]p
under the constant money growth policy for the whole interwar period. We
focus on the two variants of the constant money growth policy discussed
above. The weak case for this policy is represented by model I defined
as model (5) with its [delta]m equation replaced by (8). Model II, on
the other hand, represents the strong case. This model is defined as
model (5) in which not only is the [delta]m equation replaced by (10)
but also [Mathematical Expression Omitted] in the [delta]y and [delta]p
equations are replaced by [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (estimated
as residuals in regressions of [Mathematical Expression Omitted]). In
both models I and II, [theta] is set equal to .00738 (the mean value of
Am for 1921.11941.4).(15)
Figure 3 shows the simulated behavior of m, p, and y for models I and
II, and compares it to the actual behavior of these variables. The
actual and counterfactual monetary policies are contrasted in panel (a)
of the figure. Note that even the weaker constant money growth rule
(used in model I) would have resulted in only minor decreases in the
money stock during 1931 to 1933.
The basic question raised in this paper is addressed in panel (b) of
Figure 3. As this figure shows, a fall in output would have occurred
starting in 1929 in model I, but the simulated decline (-21.6 percent
cumulative and -6.61 percent at an annual rate) would not have been as
severe and prolonged as the decline in the Great Contraction (-36.2
percent cumulative and -12.1 percent at an annual rate). In fact, under
this counterfactual a recovery would have begun in 1933 and output would
have reached its 1929 level by early 1934. The 1929-33 output decrease
in this case would have represented a major but not an exceptional
recession. Model I assumes that the constant money growth policy would
not have had any influence on money supply shocks. However, if this
policy had eliminated these shocks according to the identifying
assumptions of model II, then as the model II simulations in Figure 3(b)
show, output would have declined only modestly (-11.1 percent cumulative
and -3.30 percent at an annual rate) during 1929 to 1931 and this
episode would not have been considered a major recession. Interestingly,
in both models a constant money growth policy does not appreciably
change Output until 1931, which is consistent with Romer's [1990]
position that the 1929-30 contraction was due to nonmonetary
forces-specifically, the stock market crash. It is also interesting to
note that the level of output in both models stays well above the actual
level not only during the Great Contraction period but also throughout
the subsequent recovery period. Figure 3(c) shows that the behavior of
the price level would also be significantly altered under both
counterfactuals, but deflation still persists in both cases.
As discussed above, money supply shocks in model II need riot be
neutral in the long run. Panel (a) of Figure 4 shows the impulse
response of output to a (one standard deviation) money supply shock as
identified in model II. The figure suggests that money supply shocks
affect output permanently. One explanation of this result (indicating
non-neutrality of money in the long run) is that monetary shocks led to
a collapse of financial (highlighted by Bernanke [1983]) during the
Great Contraction, and this collapse had long-term effects. We examine
this issue further in the next section.
Table 2 presents some measures of the performance of the two models
(as well as some other models discussed below). First, to examine the
average difference between the counterfactual and actual output levels,
the table shows the mean of [y.sub.t] - [y.sub.t], where [y.sub.t]
represents the simulated value of [y.sub.t]. This statistic is shown for
the whole 1921.1-1941.4 period as well as subperiods 1929.3 to 1941.4
and 1929.3 to 1933.1. For both models I and II the mean difference for
the subperiod including the recovery is even higher than the Great
Contraction subperiod. Although the main issue is the effect of the
constant money growth policy on the level of output, the table also
shows the ratio of the variance of [delta][y*.sub.t] to that of
[delta][y.sub.t] for the whole period. As the table shows, this ratio of
variances is below 1.0 for model I and much lower than 1.0 for model II.
Finally, the table also provides estimates (for the whole period) of the
ratio of the variance of [delta][p*.sub.t] to that of [delta][p.sub.t],
where [p*.sub.t] is the simulated value of [p.sub.t]. This ratio is also
below 1.0 for both models I and II.
[TABULAR DATA 2 OMITTED]
Our simulations also have implications for issues recently raised by
Romer [1992]. Romer wishes to explain the determinants of the recovery
from 1933 to 1941. Based on money-income multipliers calculated for the
years 1921 and 1938 she simulates the behavior of real output from 1933
to 1941 if money growth had not deviated from the average (M1) growth
rate of 1923 to 1927 of 2.88 percent. Such a money growth rate would
have led to a 50 percent gap below potential in 1941. The fact that
actual output grew substantially faster makes her case that
gold-flow-induced expansionary money supply produced the recovery.
Our simulation also covers the recovery period from 1933 to 1941 but,
unlike Romer, who assumed that the money supply collapsed from 1929 to
1933, as it did, our simulation assumes that a constant money growth
rule for M2 was maintained over the entire interwar period. Our
simulations suggest that the extra monetary stimulus Romer documents
would have been unnecessary had stable money prevailed throughout the
interwar period.
VI. VARIATIONS OF THE BASIC MODEL
In this section we examine the sensitivity of our results to a number
of variations of our model. First, as there is controversy about the
view that the long-run money demand function is stable, we examine how
our results would change if the assumption that m - p and y are
cointegrated is dropped. In this case the error correction term v will
not appear in (2), (3) and (5). We thus resimulate models I and II using
estimates of a three-variable VAR including y, p and m (without the
error correction term). The performance measures for the resulting
simulations (referred to as models IA and IIA) are also shown in Table
2. Compared to model I, the mean (y* -y) for model IA is lower by a
small amount (.006) for the whole period but a somewhat larger amount
(.010) during the Great Contraction. Comparison of model II with IIA
shows similar results. The performance of a constant money growth policy
thus deteriorates somewhat if the error correction term is removed from
the model.
Next, we extend our model to include s or r as an additional variable
as discussed in section III. For this case we consider only the
simulations based on the weak counterfactual since the strong
counterfactual would require additional assumptions to identify money
supply shocks. The four-variable vector error correction model under the
weak monetary-control assumption is labelled model IB when the fourth
variable represents s and model IC when it represents r.(16) Measures of
performance for these two models are also shown in Table 2. Model IB
leads to a slightly higher level of output than model I during the Great
Contraction, but the overall performance of these two models is not much
different. Thus the introduction of variable s does not make an
appreciable difference to the results. The results change more
significantly under model IC. While this model produces greater
variability of both output growth and inflation, it also brings about a
higher level of output. On balance, its performance compares favourably
to that of model I.
Our data on y and p are the Balke-Gordon quarterly series on real GNP
and the GNP deflator. As these series use interpolations of annual data,
they allow future information to influence current values. To explore
whether this data problem may have introduced a serious bias in our
results, we also estimated our basic model using quarterly averages of
monthly data on industrial production and the wholesale price index as
alternative measures of y and p. The weak and strong versions of
the=basic model based on the alternative data set are labelled ID and
IID. Measures of performance for these two models in Table 2 show that
although the effect of the constant money growth policy on the
variability of [delta]y and [delta]p differs between the two models, the
policy substantially increases the level of output, especially during
the Great Contraction, in both models. Indeed, in terms-of the effect on
the level of output, the case for the constant money growth policy is
stronger if the data-on industrial production and the wholesale price
index are used instead of the Balke-Gordon estimates (compare model ID
with I and IID with II).
Our simulations assume not only that a constant money growth policy
would not have significantly altered the output and price equations but
also that these equations were stable throughout the interwar period.
This assumption is subject to the Lucas [1976] critique since the Great
Contraction could have represented a regime shift that would have caused
the parameters of the reduced-form relations to change. To explore this
issue, we tested our model for possible breaks at three different dates,
1930.1, 1931.4 and 1933.2, which represent the beginning, the middle and
the end of the Great Contraction. The Chow test of a break at a fixed
date indicates a shift in both the output and price equations in 1930.1
as well as in 1933.2. It may be thought that an equation explaining
nominal income would have been more stable than our separate output and
price equations. However, testing a comparable nominal-income equation
for stability, the Chow test indicates a break in this relation in
1933.2, though not in 1930.1.(17)
If, as the above-evidence indicates, the Great Contraction was
responsible for shifts in the output and price relations, then these
shifts would not have occurred under a constant money growth policy that
prevented the Contraction. This possibility suggests using :relations
estimated for the stable 1920s to construct the constant money growth
counterfactual for the whole interwar period. For this simulation, the
basic model was estimated separately for the subperiods 1921.1-1929.4
and 1930.1-1941.4 to calculate reduced-form shocks for the whole period.
Then, using output and price equations estimated for the 1921.1-1929.4
subperiod and letting [theta]= .00822 (the mean value of [delta]m for
this subperiod), the behavior of m, y and p was simulated under both the
weak and strong monetary control assumptions. These simulations are
referred to as models IE and IIE, respectively, and are illustrated in
Figure 5.
As Figure 5 shows, the behavior of output y and the price level p
under both model IE and IIE is dramatically different from previous
simulations. The most remarkable difference is in the behavior of y
which, unlike in previous cases, does not exhibit any significant
contraction during the 1929-33 period under both the weak and strong
forms of the constant money growth rule. This result fully supports the
underlying assumption of the simulation that by preventing the Great
Contraction the constant money growth policy would have preserved the
1920s output and price relations. Performance measures for models IE and
IIE in Table 2 show that although these models would have made a
marginal difference to the variability of the price level, they would
have produced a substantially higher level of output and a significantly
lower output variability.
As noted above, the collapse of financial intermediation could have
accounted for the result that money shocks had long-term effects on
output in model II. If money is otherwise neutral in the long run, we
would not expect money shocks to exert a permanent effect on output in a
model based on the period before the financial collapse. This prediction
is supported by panel (b) of Figure 4, which shows that in contrast to
model II, [[eta].sup.m] does not have a marked long-run effect on y in
model IIE.
VII. CONCLUSION
This paper reconsiders the long-debated question of whether stable
money could have averted the Great Contraction in the United States. Our
approach follows McCallum's methodology of using an empirical model
of the economy based on interwar data to examine how a counterfactual
policy would have performed. Our study, however, departs from
McCallum's in considering a different monetary policy rule and
estimating separate relations for output and the price level. We also
allow the form of our rule to depend on information available to the Fed
and on contemporaneous relations between money and other variables.
We consider two variants of Milton Friedman's constant money
growth rule that represent limiting cases for a wide range of
assumptions about monetary control. While one of these variants assumes
that output and the price level do not affect money in the same period
and lets the=Fed observe money supply shocks contemporaneously, the
other allows any pattern of instantaneous causality between money and
economic activity and assumes that the Fed can react to shocks with only
a one-period lag.
Basic simulations of both variants produce results consistent with
claims that, had a stable money policy been followed, the Great
Contraction would have been mitigated and shortened. A severe recession
would have occurred but not of the extraordinary character of the Great
Contraction. If it is further assumed that a stable money policy would
have prevented shifts in the output and price relations, our alternative
simulations produce the much stronger result that there would have been
no recession at all during the Great Contraction under both variants of
the constant money growth rule.
If our simulations are valid, then the extra monetary stimulus that
Romer [1992] argues was essential to produce recovery after 1933 would
not have been necessary. In fact, under all of our constant money growth
counterfactuals, simulated output is well above the actual output
throughout the 1933 41 period.
Eichenbaum [1992] has argued that, "After all, aside from the
time consistency issue, there is little theoretical reason to recommend
a k percent rule." The view that a k percent rule (our constant
money growth rule) is suboptimal compares economic performance under
constant money growth with alternative rules or discretions that yield a
superior outcome. Our focus, however, is on the constant money growth
policy relative to actual performance during the Great Depression. On
that basis, constant money growth was clearly preferable.
[Figures 1 to 5 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
APPENDIX A
Data Sources
Quarterly Data
Real-Gross National Product and Gross National Product Implicit Price
Deflator: Balke-Gordon [1986], Table 2.
Suspended Bank Deposits: Federal Reserve Bulletin, September 1937,
909; McCallum [1990].
Money Stock (M2): Friedman and Schwartz [1970], Table 2, 61-73.
Monetary Base: Friedman and Schwartz [1963], Appendix B, Table B-3,
799-808.
Interest Rate: Commercial paper rate in Balke-Gordon [1986], Table 2.
Monthly Data
Consumer Price Index: 1910-40, NBER Business Cycle Series no. 04072;
1941-61, NBER Business Cycle Series no. 04052.
Industrial Production: 1919-66, NBER Business Cycle Series no. 01303.
Money Stock (M2): Friedman and Schwartz [1970], Table 1, 8-52.
(1.) See also Feldstein and Stock [1992] who simulate the effect of
an optimal monetary policy rule on nominal GDP over the 1959-92 period.
(2.) The argument in chapter 10 of Eichengreen [1992b], that the
Federal Reserve would not have been able to expand the money supply in
he 1931 episode because it would have violated the free gold constraint
and forced the United States off the gold standard, is incorrect, as
shown by Bordo [19941. First, the author argues that since M1 fell by $2
billion between August 1931 and January 1932, a $2 billion open market
operation would have been required to offset the decline, and this would
have forced the United States, with only $400 million in free gold, off
the gold standard. This argument ignores the arithmetic of money supply
relationships. The ratio of M1 to high-powered money fell between August
1931 and January 1932 from 3.2 to 2.8--the average money multiplier over
the period was approximately 3. Thus an open market operation to
increase the monetary base by $600 650 million was all that would have
been needed if no other forces were at work. According to Friedman and
Schwartz 11963], other forces were present so that a $1 billion purchase
would have been needed. But would the $1 billion purchase have exhausted
free gold? It would have if the open market purchase, as Eichengreen
assumes, were absorbed by a dollar-for-dollar increase in currency,
which had to be backed 40 percent by gold and 60 percent by eligible
paper. But if the purchase had increased bank reserves by $1 billion,
which would have had the effect of calming depositors' fears about
bank safety, then free gold would not have been exhausted.
(3.) We use the Balke-Gordon [1986] data based on the
Kuznets-Commerce sources. Romer 11988] has criticized this data set and
constructed her own series. Her data considerably reduce the severity of
the 192324, 1926-27, and 1937-38 recessions but not that of the Great
Contraction of 1929-33.
(4.) We also estimated the model using M1. The results were quite
similar.
(5.) Romer [1990] attributes the decline in output from 1929 to 1930
to the effects of the stock market crash, not the decline in the money
stock.
(6.) Temin [1978] disputes Friedman and Schwartz's contention
that banking panics were the cause of the collapse in the money supply
His regressions show that the banking failures of the 1930s entirely
reflected the decline in economic activity. A number of subsequent
papers refute this finding as in Anderson and Butkiewicz [1980], Wicker
11980], Mayer [1978], Boughton and Wicker [1979].
(7.) McCallum [19901 uses this measure. Bernanke [1983] uses the real
value of suspended bank deposits as a proxy for the nonmonetary
influence of the banking failures on economic activity.
(8.) According to White [19841, however, the majority of banks that
failed after 1930 had characteristics similar to those that failed in
the 1920s.
(9.) See, for example, Blanchard [1990].
(10.) For each of these variables, the augmented Dickey-Fuller test (both with and without a time trend) does not reject the hypothesis that
the variable contains a unit root.
(11.) See Lucas [1988] who argues that U.S. long-run money demand is
stable. Also see Hafer and Jansen [1991] for evidence supporting a
cointegrated money demand relation for M2 over the period from 1915 to
1988. For a contrary view, see McCallum [1993] who argues that shocks to
the money demand function are likely to include permanent stochastic changes in technology affecting transactions.
(12.) In the case where [z.sub.t]= [s.sub.t], s is included in (2)
and (3) for reasons discussed by Bernanke [1983].
(13.) Existing evidence, for example, Lucas 11988] and Hoffman and
Rasche 11991], suggests that the income elasticity of money demand is
close to one. The assumption that [[alpha].sub.2] = 0 is relaxed later
in simulations based on the extended model that includes the interest
rate. Note that [[alpha].sub.0] (the intercept in the demand for money)
is left out and is included in the constant terms of the regressions.
(14.) We also tried four lags for each variable but the additional
lagged terms were not significant.
(15.) It might be argued that at the onset of the Great Contraction,
the Fed would not have known the average interwar money growth rate and,
thus, it would be more appropriate to set [theta] equal to some rate
reflecting the 1920's experience. The average value of [delta]m for
1921-29 is, in fact, greater than the interwar average. As discussed
above, however, we eschew using a higher rate of money growth in the
present simulations on the grounds that estimated parameters of our
model are likely to reflect the average experience of the whole interwar
period. In the next section, we do set [theta] equal to the average
[delta]m value for 1921.11929.4 in an alternative simulation based on a
model estimated for the same period.
(16.) In model IC, v is measured as m - p - y [[alpha].sub.2]r with
[[alpha].sub.2]=-.04. This estimate of a2 was derived by applying the
dynamic OLS procedure in Stock and Watson [1989] to the money demand
relation (1), constraining [[alpha].sub.1] equal to one and using four
leads and lags.
(17.) Nominal income growth was regressed on a constant, lagged value
of v, three lagged values of [delta]m and three of its own lagged
values. McCallum's [1990] nominal-income equation is slightly
different (it includes only one lagged value of [delta]m and no
error-correction term) but this equation also breaks in 1933.2 according
to the Chow test. However, as McCallum notes, a break at this date is
not indicated if two dummy variables for the 1930.2 and 1930.3 quarters
are also included in the equation.
REFERENCES
Anderson, Barry, and James Butkiewicz. "Money, Spending, and the
Great Depression." Southern Economic Journal, October 1980,
388-403.
Balke Nathan S., and Robert J. Gordon. "Historical Data" in
The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, edited by R Gordon.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986, 781-850.
Bernanke, Ben. "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in
the Propagation Of the Great Depression." American Economic Review,
June 1983, 25776.
Bernanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler. "Agency Costs, Net Worth and
business Fluctuations." American Economic Review, March 1989,
14-31.
--. "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1990, 87-114.
Betts, Caroline, Michael Bordo and Angela Redish. "A Small Open
Economy in Depression: Lessons from Canada in the 1930's."
Canadian journal of Economics, (1995, forthcoming). Blanchard, Olivier.
"Why Does Money Affect Output? A Summary," in Handbook of
Monetary Economics, edited by B. M. Friedman and E H. Hahn. Amsterdam:
North Holland Publishers, 1990, vol. 2, chapter 15.
Bordo, Michael. "The Contribution of A Monetary History of the
United States, 1867-1960 to Monetary History," in Money, History,
and International Finance: Essays in Honor of Anna J. Schwartz, edited
by M. D. Bordo. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989, 15-70.
--. "Review of Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters: The Gold
Standard and the Great Depression." Journal of International
Economics, February 1994, 193-97.
Boughton, James M., and Elmus R. Wicker. "The Behavior of the
Currency-Deposit Ratio during the Great Depression." Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, November 1979, 405-18.
Brunner, Karl, and Allan H. Meltzer. "What Did We Learn from the
Monetary Experience of the United States in the Great Depression?"
Canadian Journal of Economics, May 1968, 336-48.
Calomiris, Charles. "Financial Factors in the Great
Depression." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(2), Spring 1993,
61-85.
Cecchetti, Stephen G. "Prices During the Great Depression: Was
the Deflation of 19.30-1932 Really Anticipated?", American Economic
Review, March 1992, 141-56.
Cecchetti, Stephen G., and Georgios Karras. "Sources of Output
Fluctuations During the Interwar Period: Further Evidence on the Causes
of the Great Depression." Review of Economics and Statistics,
February 1994, 80-102.
Eichenbaum, Martin. `Comment on `Central Bank Behavior and the
Strategy of Monetary Policy: Observations from Six Industrialized Countries' by Ben Bernanke and Frederic Mishkin," in NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1992, edited by O. Blanchard and S. Fisher, 1992,
233.
Eichengreen, Barry. "The Origins and Nature of the Great Slump
Revisited." Economic History Review, May 1992(a), 213-39.
--. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression,
1929-Z939. New York: Oxford University Press, 1992(b).
Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffrey Sachs. "Exchange Rates and
Economic Recovery in the 1930s." Journal of Economic History,
December 1985, 925-46.
Evans, Martin, and Paul Wachtel. "Were Price Changes during the
Great Depression Anticipated?" Journal of Monetary Economics,
August 1993, 3-34.
Feldstein, Martin, and James Stock. "The Use of a Monetary
Aggregate to Target Nominal GDP," in Monetary Policy, edited by
N.G. Mankiw, Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1994, 7-62.
Field, Alexander J. "Asset Exchanges and the Transaction Demand
for Money, 1919-1929." American Economic Review, March 1984, 43-59.
Fisher, Irving. "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great
Depressions." Econometrica, October 1933, 339
Friedman, Milton. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham
University Press, 1960.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna J.-Schwartz. A Monetary History of the
United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
--. Monetary Statistics of the United States. New York: Columbia
University Press for NBER, 1970.
Hafer, Rik W., and Dennis W. Jansen. "The Demand for Money in
the United States: Evidence from Cointegrating Tests." Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, May 1991, 155-68.
Hamilton, James D. "Monetary Factors in the Great
Depression." Journal of Monetary Economics, March 1987, 145-70.
--. "Was the Deflation During the Great Depression Anticipated?
Evidence from the Commodity Futures Market." American Economic
Review, March 1992, 157-78.
Hoffman, Dennis, and Robert H. Rasche. "Long-Run Income and
Interest Elasticities of Money Demand in the United States." Review
of Economics and Statistics, November 1991, 665-74.
Kindleberger, Charles. The World in Depression. Berkeley: University
of California, 1973.
Laidler, David. The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1991.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "Economic Policy Evaluation: A
Critique," in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy, edited by K. Brunner and A. H. Meltzer. Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1, 1976, 1946.
--. "Money Demand in the United States: A Quantitative
Review," in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
edited by K Brunner and A. H. Meltzer, 29, 1988, 137-68.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Could a Monetary Base Rule Have Prevented
the Great Depression?" Journal of Monetary Economics, August 1990,
3-26.
--. "Unit Roots in Macro-economic Time Series: Some Critical
Issues." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Quarterly, 79(2), Spring
1993, 13-44.
Mayer, Thomas. "Money and the Great Depression: Some Reflections
on Temin's Recent Book." Explorations in Economic History,
April 19.78, 127-45.
Mishkin, Frederic S. "The Household Balance Sheet and the Great
Depression." Journal of Economic History, December 1978, 918-37.
Modigliani, Franco. "Some Empirical Facts of Monetary Management
and Rules Versus Discretion." Journal of Political Economy, April
1964, 211-45.
Nelson, Daniel B. "Was the Deflation of 1929-30 Anticipated? The
Monetary Regime as Viewed by the Business Press." Research in
Economic History, 13, 1992, 1-66.
Romer, Christina D. "World War I and the Postwar Depression: A
Reinterpretation Based on Alternative Estimates of GNP." Journal of
Monetary Economics, July 1988, 91-115.
--. "The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great
Depression." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1990, 597-624.
--. "What-Ended the Great Depression?" Journal of Economic
History, December 1992, 757-84.
--. "The Nation in Depression." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 2, Spring 1993, 19-39.
Schwartz, Anna J. "Understanding 1929-1933," in The Great
Depression Revisited, edited by K. Brunner. Boston: Martinus Nijoff,
1981, 5-48.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. "A Simple MLE of
Cointegrating Vectors in General Integrated Systems." NBER
Technical Working Paper No. 83, 1989.
Temin, Peter. Did Monetary Factors Cause the Great Depression? New
York: Norton, 1978.
--. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989.
--. "Transmission of the Great Depression." Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 7(2), Spring 1993, 871-102.
U.S. Department of Commerce. Long-Term Economic Growth, 1860-1970.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973.
Warburton, Clark. "Monetary Theory, Full Production, and the
Great Depression," in Depression, Inflation, and Monetary Policy.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966, chapter 5.
Wheelock, David. "Monetary Policy in the Great Depression: What
the Fed Did and Why." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
March/April 1992, 3-28.
White, Eugene N. "A Reinterpretation of the Banking Crisis of
1930." Journal of Economic History, March 1984, 119-38.
Wicker, Elmus R. "Federal Reserve Monetary Policy, 1922-33: A
Reinterpretation." Journal of Political Economy, August 1965,
325-43.
ANNA J. SCHWARTZ, Professor, Rutgers University, Professor, Carleton
University; Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research. We
thank the Harry and Lynde Bradley Foundation for its support. For
helpful comments and suggestions we thank Ben Bernanke, Steve Cecchetti,
Charles Evans, Bennett McCallum, Bob Rasche, Pierre Siklos, Jim Stock,
Paul Wachtel, Tom Willett, and participants at the Rutgers
Mini-Conference on the Great Depression, February 1993, and the NBER
Macro History Conference, April 1993. For able research assistance we
thank Jakob Koenes.