Teaching tools: teaching methods in undergraduate economics.
Becker, William E. ; Watts, Michael
I. INTRODUCTION
In 1970 Nobel Laureate George Stigler argued that "economics
belongs in everyone's education once we have learned how to teach
it." But because the logic of economics is not easy to learn or
teach, he concluded that "Economics is not yet ready to be made a
part of the basic curriculum of all educated men" [p. 80]. We now
have new models for teaching economics. In fact, as in other areas of
economics, we have competing models, with new approaches being offered
to supplement extensively, if not replace entirely, the lecture pedagogy
used nearly exclusively by economists at the time Stigler's
comments were published. Yet in major Commission and Committee reports
and daily conversations held in faculty lounges around the world,
alternatives to the lecture approach, in which the teacher often serves
as a preacher and students as passive receptacles into which great
thoughts and wisdom are poured, still appear to be either unknown or
tacitly dismissed as unworkable.
In this journal, for example, McCloskey [1992] tells of an exchange
between George Stigler and Milton Friedman. Friedman argued that while
individuals pursue their self-interest they are often ignorant and
require education to see that something they thought was in their
personal or national interest was not - e.g., tariffs and quotas.
Stigler called Friedman a preacher. He argued that people find their own
self-interest with or without education, and that no amount of preaching
or lecturing about economics would change that self-interest.
In the "Report of the Commission on Graduate Education in
Economics" by Krueger et al. [1991], considerable attention was
given to bringing "real-world issues into the classroom." But
the Commission's assumed instructional mode was still the lecture:
It is our impression that most Ph.D. programs devote little or no
attention to teaching or encouraging the development of expository
skills....We suspect the lack of emphasis on communication in most Ph.D.
programs reflects partly the scarcity of teaching time, partly
instructors' lack of confidence in their ability to teach
communications skills, and partly a judgment that the appropriate style
of professional communication is something students can figure out for
themselves by watching their teachers. [p. 1049]
The report of the Committee on College Faculty by Kasper et al.
[1991], representing the nation's premiere liberal arts colleges,
emphasized the need for breadth in content coverage in economists'
graduate training, but did not even mention the need for breadth in
instructional methods, or training in those areas.
Despite these intentional or unintentional slights, in literature
from the past twenty-five years we found that many economists have spent
a great deal of time developing and applying new teaching methods to
actively engage students in the learning process. In what follows we
summarize those alternative approaches to make it easier for others to
consider and access these articles on innovative instructional methods
in economics.
II. CLASSROOM GAMES, SIMULATIONS, AND LABORATORIES
Although Edward Chamberlin and others working in the area of
imperfect competition were developing artificial markets in the
classroom as early as the 1940s, Joseph and Saunders [1970] were perhaps
the first economists to publish an extensive account on how to use such
games to teach basic economic concepts. The approach soon proved to be
quite popular, at least with the developers of these activities. The
National Council on Economic Education (then known as the Joint Council
on Economic Education) published the first edition of its Guide to Games
and Simulations for Teaching Economics in 1971, written by Lewis and
Wentworth, with references to some ninety different activities and
publications.
In recent years commercially published games and simulations in
economics have continued to appear, often featuring mainframe
econometric models or microcomputer programs written specifically as a
classroom simulation. Examples of such activities include Blackburn and
Case [1985]; Gold, Pray, and Dennis [1984]; and Lumsden and Scott
[1995]. Yoho and Walstad [1990] recently published a review article on
microcomputer software for principles courses.
Perhaps more novel are the articles that have been published to
explain the pedagogical advantages of a particular game or simulation in
teaching a certain economic idea or concept, or in overcoming gaps in
student understanding that stubbornly persist after traditional textbook
and lecture treatments. For example, Sulock [1990] described two games
used to teach the free-rider problem, voting paradoxes, and the Coase
Theorem. Hester [1991] developed an extensive simulation of a commercial
banking system for use in large-lecture money and banking courses at the
University of Wisconsin. Hemenway, Moore, and Whitney [1987] describe an
oligopoly/cartel game that can be played in one class period, even by
students who have no prior knowledge of oligopoly theory. Halstead
[1989] developed a short simulation of central planning processes and
problems. Yoho [1989] reviewed classroom exercises featuring the
Fairmodel, which replicate different periods of recent U.S. economic
history, involve students in sessions of economic forecasting, and
simulate the effects of alternative macroeconomic stabilization
policies.
Bartlett and King [1990] described far more extensive,
department-wide experiences in setting up a computer laboratory for use
in several different undergraduate economics courses at Denison
University, under funding provided by the National Science Foundation.
Some simulations are used in this laboratory, but there is also a
concentrated effort to have students "gather their own data or use
existing data bases to contribute to their own learning. Students
confront real problems, make decisions, and suggest policy actions in
the laboratory" [p. 186].
III. EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS
As Vernon Smith has noted [1981, 369-70], much of the earliest work
in the young field of experimental economics was inspired both by
Chamberlain's games on imperfect competition and as a way to
introduce or partially replace traditional lectures on supply and demand
in principles courses. The experimental framework usually lends a
different cast to these classroom exercises than is seen in traditional
games and simulations, to be sure; but largely because of the direct
linkages to ongoing research programs, experimental economics appears to
be a fertile new source of pedagogical innovations. In fact, the Fall
1993 issue of the Journal of Economic Education is devoted entirely to a
collection of articles describing new classroom games and simulations
developed out of the experimental economics framework.
Williams and Walker [1993] describe a computerized application of
experimental economics developed at Indiana University, in which
students first act as monopolists facing an uncertain demand curve, then
as producers who must allocate an endowment of productive resources
between a private good and a public good, and finally as traders in a
market for a financial asset that yields an uncertain return over a long
time horizon. Classroom experiments developed by Leuthold [1993] at the
University of Illinois and Brock [1991] at the U.S. Air Force Academy
demonstrate the free-rider problem; and a trading activity developed by
Williams [1993] at Guilford College has students experience the effects
of diverse skills, aptitudes, effort, and initial resource endowments in
determining patterns of wealth distribution.
The April 1993 issue of Economic Inquiry features an article by
Daniel Levy and Mark Bergen that describes a multi-product barter
trading experiment, which has been used successfully at the University
of Minnesota, the University of California-Irvine, Pepperdine
University, the University of Chicago, and Union College. The experiment
demonstrates the role and functions of money, for example by using ice
cubes to show the desirability of a currency being made out of
substances that are durable and stable.
After reviewing twelve articles on the classroom use of experimental
economics, Fels [1993] offered an interesting summary and critique of
these classroom activities:
It was natural that those doing experimental research would use
experiments in their teaching and hold workshops to spread the word
about their method. They have the skills to do it without excessive
work, and there are spillovers in both directions.... The question now
is what, if anything, do their accomplishments...have to contribute to
other economics teachers.
In particular, Fels asked if the experimental economists had overcome
the high start-up costs of giving up the lecture method in order to make
greater pedagogical use of experiments and related classroom activities,
and whether they offered evidence that students learned more by doing
so, or responded more favorably to these instructional methods. He
concluded that "the cost has been reduced to manageable proportions
for some experiments but not others," and that "No serious
attempt...has been made to evaluate any of them" [p. 365].
To further reduce start-up costs for economists who want to begin
using experimental economics in their teaching, since 1985 the National
Science Foundation has funded summer training programs at the Economic
Science Library at the University of Arizona. The classroom activities
featured in this program are briefly described in an article by Wells
[1991].
IV. WRITING ASSIGNMENTS IN ECONOMICS COURSES
One of the latest instructional reform movements appearing on many of
the nation's campuses and in many different subject areas is
usually described as "Writing Across the Curriculum." This
approach promotes the development of better student writing skills in
the various content-area courses, not just in first-year English
composition classes.
Many economists are clearly sympathetic to these goals and methods,
and some have written brief articles about their experiences in these
programs. Four such articles appeared in a recent issue of the Journal
of Economic Education. In the first, Hansen [1993] describes eight
writing assignments - initially rather short and simple, but leading up
to much more extensive projects - which he incorporated into a labor
economics course taught at the University of Wisconsin. Davidson and
Gumnior [1993] describe class projects involving both an economist and a
writing specialist as instructors in an international macroeconomics
policy course at Indiana University. Cohen and Spencer [1993] report on
a similar joint effort involving an economist and writing specialist in
a history of economic thought course taught at York University. Abdalla
[1993] required undergraduate students in international or development
economics courses at Illinois State University to prepare a series of
reports on economic conditions and policies in some nation, and later to
expand the reports into more substantial term papers.
Although these authors all report that they and their students were
generally pleased with the results of these writing assignments, both in
terms of the amount of economics learned and improvements in
students' writing skills, Fels's comments about the papers on
experimental economics apply just as well here. Teachers with special
interests and skills in writing are most likely to undertake and support
this kind of classroom project, and more likely to successfully
"sell" the approach to their students. Articles reporting
their experiences with this approach can help to reduce start-up costs
and uncertainty facing other instructors who are considering using such
an approach; but in many of the more extensive projects (such as those
involving "outside" writing specialists) those are still very
serious concerns. And while there is some anecdotal and
student-course-evaluation data lending support to the use of such
extensive writing projects, there has been no formal evaluation of gains
in student learning under these programs, especially as compared to
student learning and interest in traditional lecture classes, or across
large samples of students and instructors.
V. ECONOMICS IN LITERATURE AND DRAMA
If assignments in economics courses can be used to develop good
writing skills and, arguably, improve students' learning and
interest in economics at the same time, perhaps it is not surprising
that it has also been claimed that good reading - in the form of
literature and drama - can also be used to help students learn more
economics, and motivate them to do so. Watts and Smith [1989] provide a
list of seventy-five literary passages, written by over forty different
authors, dealing with economic concepts and issues. They also review a
surprisingly extensive group of academic articles and books dealing with
the sometimes complementary but often uneasy relationship between the
literary and economic ways of thinking.
Many economists have used literary allusions and epigrams in their
articles and textbooks, and under George Stigler's editorship the
Journal of Political Economy began printing a literary excerpt dealing
with economics on the back cover of each journal issue. None of this has
led, as yet, to a full-blown course or teaching method in undergraduate
economics, but the seeds for such programs are now available.
VI. THE NOBEL LECTURES AS A TEACHING TOOL
The first Nobel prize in economics was awarded in 1969. Each year,
the recipient's speech (or the recipients' speeches, if there
are multiple winners) is published in Le Prix Nobel and widely reprinted
in economics journals. Since the immediate audience for these speeches
is made up of many noneconomists, the speeches tend to be nontechnical
and suitable for use in undergraduate courses. In fact, reviewing the
first twenty-six lectures, delivered from 1969 to 1988, Zahka [1990]
concluded that fifteen of the lectures were "readily adaptable to
upper-level undergraduate economics courses and honors programs"
while the remaining eleven were "especially geared to graduate
school students, who are more skilled in econometrics" [p. 397].
VII. TEACHING ECONOMICS WITH THE POPULAR AND BUSINESS PRESS
Turning to more prosaic forms of reading and writing, economics has
been frontpage news on a regular basis through most of this century, and
seems to command a larger percentage of the typical daily
newspaper's front page with each passing decade. This has led
economists such as Kelley [1983] to offer suggestions on how media
reports can be used to help motivate and teach economics, and to an
article by Marks [1988] offering specific questions and assignments to
use in having students deal with the economic concepts presented in a
highly controversial article published in The New Republic.
On the other hand, Kennedy [1992] asked not what the press could do
for economics, but what economics should be doing to help students
better understand articles in the press. He found that five
macroeconomic concepts are regularly and prominently featured in
business sections of leading national papers, but not emphasized in
macroeconomics textbooks. Accordingly, he called for more classroom and
textbook coverage on: (1) the discouraged/encouraged worker hypotheses
and paradoxical changes in unemployment statistics, (2) the role of
inventory levels in macro forecasts of the national economy, (3) effects
of money supply growth on the bond market, (4) the effects of inflation
in foreign exchange markets, and (5) the effects of international
differences in nominal interest rates on foreign exchange rates.
Actually, the national media has a pronounced effect on much of the
work economists do, including their undergraduate teaching. For example,
the reason so many departments and textbooks teach the principles of
macroeconomics before microeconomics is that macroeconomic concepts and
issues are more frequently discussed in the daily media, and therefore
innately more interesting to a larger number of students. This
instructional pattern was first popularized by Samuelson's
path-breaking principles textbook in 1948, but that has been somewhat
reversed in the past two decades, with many newer textbooks and a large
number of departments adopting a "micro-first" strategy in
order to stress microeconomic concepts as key building blocks for many
macroeconomic concepts and issues. The debate over the most effective
order is still a lively one, however, and Alan Blinder [1991] for one
sees the issue potentially coming down to a fundamental trade-off:
Suppose teaching micro first is sounder but macroeconomics brings in
the crowds. Then putting micro first would mean that fewer students
would be getting a slightly better education. Teachers of economics
believe that some exposure to economics is good for students. So which
is better: giving more students less, or giving fewer students more? The
answer is not obvious... [p. 253]
Wood [1985] argued that the full potential of using media reports in
economics classes cannot be realized because too many editors and
reporters do not know economics, resulting in stories that are flawed
with errors and important omissions. Cochran and Brown [1989] see
journalistic mistakes and inexact use of economic terms more in terms of
an opportunity to show students the important differences between
economic and journalistic analysis, but they too realize the inherent
difficulty instructors face in trying to catch and correct all of the
errant journalistic passages in classes where students are expected to
read financial newspapers or magazines throughout the semester.
A recent study by Becker, Walstad, and Watts [1994] finds empirical
support for the argument that economists and journalists approach
economic topics and issues quite differently. The authors compared
survey responses by economists, journalists (including members of the
Society of American Business Editors and Writers), and teachers, using
items dealing with a wide range of economics issues that were originally
developed by Alston, Kearl, and Vaughn [1992]. It turned out that the
general samples of economists and economic educators held very similar
opinions on these items; and that the journalists, high school economics
teachers, and other high school social studies teachers held very
similar opinions; but the economists and economic educators had very
different opinions from those expressed by the journalists and high
school teachers. This has important implications for teachers of
undergraduate economics courses, in terms of the knowledge and attitudes
entering students are likely to hold on a variety of contemporary
economic issues, whether or not they have taken a high school course on
economics.
VIII. CASE STUDIES IN UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS CLASSES
The case method has long been a favorite teaching method in MBA
programs at Harvard and other leading universities. Economists at
Harvard and at the Pew Case Study Center at Georgetown University have
developed a number of cases that may be purchased and used in upper
division undergraduate courses. One fullblown textbook in macroeconomics
by Ruckstad [1992], featuring several extensive case studies, was
developed out of the Harvard programs. This particular textbook is
succeeding in the marketplace (at least to the extent of reaching a
third edition), and other books of cases dealing with topics usually
taught in upper division undergraduate and graduate courses are starting
to appear from other sources, such as Schumann, Rogers, and Reitzes
[1992]. At the introductory level, however, while there have been
occasional attempts to develop a case-study textbook - most recently by
Fels, Buckles, and Johnson [1979], so far as we have been able to
determine - such efforts have not yet met with success in the
marketplace, probably because of instructor reluctance to use the case
method with students who have such limited backgrounds in economics.
Carlson and Schodt [1995] have also argued that "one obstacle to
the more widespread adoption of case teaching in economics, apart from a
simple lack of information, appears to be that, in [the] minds of many
economists, any shift from the traditional lecture format involves an
inevitable sacrifice of theoretical rigor." However, after
attending a training session on the case method at Harvard and using the
method in their own undergraduate and master's levels classes,
Carlson and Schodt claim that
Case method teaching, while no panacea for all that may ail
contemporary instruction in economics, ...provide(s) a means for the
active engagement of students with their learning, for having them do
economics, and, ultimately, for their learning how to think like
economists.
They also report that their students were very enthusiastic about the
use of case studies, based on responses to course evaluation surveys.
Velenchik [1995] reports that the case method was particularly
successful in motivating students who were not economics majors but
taking a policy-oriented undergraduate course in international economics
to learn and apply economic theory, and also to enhance their skills in
using and presenting quantitative evidence.
IX. COOPERATIVE LEARNING
All of the above alternatives to the standard lecture approach can be
incorporated into small group activities in which students work together
toward a common goal, and the instructor serves as an observer who often
provides feedback only after the groups complete various kinds of
assignments. For example, in a classroom experiment exercise, student
groups might act as firms trying to maximize profits, and the instructor
serve as a government agency/overseer. Or, using the Nobel lectures,
student teams might debate whether common themes, problems, and
suggested policy remedies appear over time in various subsets of the
lectures, with the instructor serving as a moderator.
For large classes, a simple cooperative exercise called "Think,
Pair, Share" requires only a few minutes to do, but provides a
break in standard lectures that actively involves students and allows
instructors to quickly assess what students know. Students are required
to think about a question posed by the instructor; compare, discuss, and
refine their answers with a neighboring student; and share their
responses with the class if their team is called on by the instructor.
Maier and Keenan [1994] describe the "Think, Pair, Share"
activity and the use of other cooperative learning techniques to teach
basic economic concepts, such as the supply curve. Citing the general
education literature on cooperative learning, they claim that compared
to standard lecture methods students working in groups learn more, use
higher level reasoning, express more satisfaction with their classes,
are less likely to drop out, and become more tolerant of ethnic and
racial differences.
Johnson and Johnson [1991], two of the leading general education
authorities on cooperative learning, offer a good survey and comparison
of cooperative, competitive, and individual learning methods.
There is an inherent free-rider problem in assigning grades in
cooperative learning activities. Bartlett [1995] describes an innovative
method of avoiding the free riding. Students are given the option of
forming groups or not. Then, when an exam or in-class presentation comes
due, Bartlett uses a random-number process to choose one member of the
group to take the exam or make the presentation, and the grade earned by
the student is assigned to all members of the group. Obviously, this
creates incentives for all members of the group to be sure that they and
all of the other members are well prepared for each assignment.
X. CONCLUSIONS
Anecdotal evidence in both collegial discussions and recent books
such as Anderson's Impostors in the Temple holds that economists,
like professors from other disciplines, often express disdain for
teaching, and implies that economists are perhaps especially loathe to
spend their valuable time developing and experimenting with new teaching
methods. That point of view is refuted, or at least severely strained,
by our review of what many economists are actually doing in the
classroom, and encouraging other economists to do. This is, of course,
also anecdotal evidence; but there is presently little or no hard
evidence available about the amount of time academic economists in
different kinds of schools are devoting to their teaching, let alone how
well they succeed in raising students' level of economic
understanding and critical thinking skills.
Though not supported by findings from formal research, it is tempting
to conclude that the variety of teaching methods available for use in
undergraduate economics classes is broad enough to offer the means for
virtually any instructor to achieve respectable teaching ratings, given
reasonable amounts of preparation and a modicum of sensitivity to
student responses in the classroom. Moreover, there is an important
place for specialization and comparative advantage in teaching
economics, based on student and instructor differences in preferences
and effective learning and teaching styles. Some students and teachers
are natural born listeners and lecturers, some are talkers and
discussion leaders, and some seem to learn or teach best using group
activities that feature "hands on" demonstrations of economic
concepts and relationships.
Great orators should lecture. The rest of us should consider using a
variety of teaching methods to actively engage our students and reduce
the amount of time we spend lecturing to audiences that are often
captive in the short run, but all too willing and able to vote with
their feet in the long run, as recent enrollment trends in economics
documented by Siegfried and Scott [1994] have shown. Variety in the pace
and format of undergraduate classroom instruction - across different
class periods and even within a particular class - may well be the
missing spice of good teaching and more enthusiastic learning.
REFERENCES
Abdalla, Adil E. A. "A Country Report Project for an
International Economics Class." Journal of Economic Education,
Summer 1993, 231-36.
Alston, Richard M., J. R. Kearl, and Michael B. Vaughn. "Is
There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990s?" American Economic
Review, May 1992, 203-09.
Anderson, Martin. Imposters in the Temple: The Decline of the
American University. New York: Simon & Schuster, 1992.
Bartlett, Robin. "A Flip of the Coin - A Roll of the Die:
Economic Instruction and Collaborative Learning." Journal of
Economic Education, Spring 1995, 131-39.
Bartlett, Robin, and Paul King. "Teaching Economics as a
Laboratory Science." Journal of Economic Education, Spring 1990,
181-93.
Becker, William, William B. Walstad, and Michael Watts. "A
Comparison of the Views of Economists, Economic Educators, Teachers and
Journalists on Economic Issues," in An International Perspective on
Economic Education, edited by William B. Walstad. Boston: Kluwer
Academic Publishers, 1994, 65-87.
Blackburn, Anthony J., and Karl E. Case. Fairmodel Student Manual.
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1985.
Blinder, Alan S. "Research in Economic Education and the
Teaching of Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1991,
251-54.
Brock, John R. "A Public Goods Experiment for the
Classroom." Economic Inquiry, April 1991, 395-401.
Carlson, John, and David Schodt. "Beyond the Lecture: Case
Teaching and the Learning of Economic Theory." Journal of Economic
Education, Winter 1995, 17-28.
Cohen, Avi J., and John Spencer. "Using Writing Across the
Curriculum in Economics: Is Taking the Plunge Worth It?" Journal of
Economic Education, Summer 1993, 219-30.
Cochran, John P., and R. Michael Brown. "What's Wrong
Here?" Economic Inquiry, July 1989, 541-45.
Davidson, Lawrence S., and Elisabeth C. Gumnior. "Writing to
Learn in a Business Economics Class." Journal of Economic
Education, Summer 1993, 237-43.
Fels, Rendigs. "This Is What I Do, and I Like It." Journal
of Economic Education, Fall 1993, 365-70.
Fels, Rendigs, Stephen Buckles, and W. L. Johnson. Casebook of
Economic Problems and Policies. St. Paul, Minn.: West Publishing, 1979.
Gold, Steven C., Thomas F. Pray, and Terry L. Dennis. Microsim: A
Computerized Microeconomic Simulation. New York: Macmillan, 1984.
Halstead, Jim. "Sovplan: An In-Class Simulation of Central
Planning." Economic Inquiry, April 1989, 357-61.
Hansen, W. Lee. "Teaching a Writing Intensive Course in
Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1993, 213-18.
Hemenway, David, Robert Moore, and James Whitney. "The Oligopoly
Game." Economic Inquiry, October 1987, 727-30.
Hester, Donald D. "Instructional Simulation of a Commercial
Banking System." Journal of Economic Education, Spring 1991,
111-43.
Johnson, David W., and Roger T. Johnson. Learning Together and Alone:
Cooperative, Competitive, and Individualistic Learning, 3rd ed.
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall 1991.
Joseph, Myron, and Phillip Saunders. "Playing the Market
Game," in Recent Research in Economics Education, edited by Keith
G. Lumsden. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1970, 158-65.
Kasper, Hirschel, et al. "The Education of Economists: From
Undergraduate to Graduate Study." Journal of Economic Literature,
September 1991, 1088-107.
Kelley, Allen C. "The Newspaper Can Be an Effective Teaching
Tool." Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1983, 56-58.
Kennedy, Peter. "On Journalists' Use of Macroeconomic
Concepts." Economic Inquiry, January 1992, 194-201.
Krueger, Anne O., et al. "Report of the Commission on Graduate
Education in Economics." Journal of Economic Literature, September
1991, 1035-53.
Leuthold, Jane H. "A Free Rider Experiment for the Large
Class." Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1993, 353-63.
Levy, Daniel, and Mark Bergen. "Simulating a Multi-product
Barter Exchange Economy." Economic Inquiry, April 1993, 314-21.
Lewis, Darrell R., and Donald R. Wentworth. A Guide to Games and
Simulations for Teaching Economics. New York: Joint Council on Economic
Education, 1971.
Lumsden, Keith G., and Alex Scott. Running the U.S. Economy. New
York: National Council on Economic Education, 1995.
Maier, Mark H., and Diane Keenan. "Cooperative Learning in
Economics." Economic Inquiry, April 1994, 358-61.
Marks, Stephen V. "Teaching Guide: Abortion Economics."
Economic Inquiry, January 1988, 175-79.
Ruckstad, Michael G. Macroeconomic Decision Making in the World
Economy: Text and Cases, 3rd ed. Fort Worth, Tex.: Harcourt Brace
Jovanovich, 1992.
Schumann, Laurence, Robert P. Rogers, and James D. Reitzes. Case
Studies on the Price Effects of Horizontal Mergers. Washington, D.C.:
Federal Trade Commission, 1992.
Siegfried, John J., and Charles C. Scott. "Recent Trends in
Undergraduate Economics Degrees." Journal of Economic Education,
Summer 1994, 281-86.
Smith, Vernon. "Experimental Economics at Purdue," in
Essays in Contemporary Fields of Economics in Honor of Emanuel T.
Weiler, edited by George Horwich and James P. Quirk. West Lafayette,
Ind.: Purdue University Press, 1981, 369-73.
Stigler, George J. "The Case, if Any, for Economic
Education." Journal of Economic Education, Spring 1970, 77-84.
Sulock, Joseph M. "The Free Rider and Voting Paradox
'Games.'" Journal of Economic Education, Winter 1990,
65-69.
Velenchik, Ann D. "The Case Method as a Strategy for Teaching
Policy Analysis to Undergraduates." Journal of Economic Education,
Winter 1995, 29-38.
Walstad, William B., and Michael Watts. "The Principles of
Economics Textbook: History and Content," in The Principles of
Economics Course: A Handbook for Instructors, edited by Phillip Saunders
and William B. Walstad. New York: McGraw-Hill 1990, 141-60.
Watts, Michael, and Robert F. Smith. "Economics in Literature
and Drama." Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1989, 291-307.
Wells, Donald A. "Laboratory Experiments for Undergraduate
Instruction in Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Summer
1991, 293-300.
Williams, Arlington, and James Walker. "Computerized Laboratory
Exercises for Microeconomics Education: Three Applications Motivated by
the Methodology of Experimental Economics." Journal of Economic
Education, Fall 1993, 291-315.
Williams, Robert B. "Market Exchange and Wealth Distribution: A
Classroom Simulation." Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1993,
325-34.
Wood, William C. "The Educational Potential of News Coverage of
Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Winter 1985, 27-35.
Yoho, DeVon L. "Fairmodel: Microcomputer Software to Teach
Macroeconomic Concepts." Journal of Economic Education, Winter
1989, 107-13.
Yoho, DeVon L., and William B. Walstad. "Microcomputer Software
for Principles of Economics Courses," in The Principles of
Economics Course: A Handbook for Instructors, edited by Phillip Saunders
and William B. Walstad. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990, 161-79.
Zahka, William J. "The Nobel Prize Economics Lectures as a
Teaching Tool." Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1990, 395-401.
WILLIAM E. BECKER and MICHAEL WATTS, Professors of Economics at
Indiana University and Purdue University, respectively. Becker is the
Editor and Watts the Associate Editor for the Instruction Section of the
Journal of Economic Education.