Political influence and regulatory policy: the 1984 drug legislation.
Olson, Mark K.
I. INTRODUCTION
In the late 1970s and early 1980s dissatisfaction with the length,
complexity and cost of the drug approval process combined with rising
prescription drug prices led to Congressional attempts at reform. These
focused on two issues: to compensate the developers of new drugs for the
increasing costs and delays associated with FDA approval and to increase
the availability of generic drugs. Until 1984, these reform attempts
failed.
I use the structure-induced equilibrium (SIE) theory of Shepsle and
Weingast [1981] to examine why regulatory reforms prior to 1984 were
stalemated, and why the 1984 drug legislation was ultimately enacted. My
results show that prior to 1984, the preferences of the members of the
key congressional committees were such that the proposed bills could not
beat the status quo. However, changes in both membership and turnover on
the House Subcommittee on Health and the Environment, combined with a
change in the majority party in the Senate, led to a situation in which
the 1984 drug legislation could defeat the status quo in both the House
and the Senate.
The Drug Price Competition Act facilitated the market entry of
generic drugs following patent expiration by allowing generic versions
of brand-name drugs patented after 1962 to use an abbreviated new drug
application (ANDA).(1) The Patent Term Restoration Act extended the
patent lives of brand-name drugs for up to five years to compensate for
patent life lost during the FDA approval process. Initial, unsuccessful
legislative reforms were introduced into Congress in 1978-79 and
1981-82, but no legislative reforms were passed until 1984. These
earlier unsuccessful reform efforts raise the following questions.
First, why did the status quo prevail until 1984 as the legislative
equilibrium? Second, what endogenous changes occurred to produce the new
legislative equilibrium in 1984?
While much of the previous literature about the pharmaceutical
industry has focused on the efficiency and distributive effects of
public policy, I focus on the theory of regulatory policy.(2) The
sequence of legislative actions leading to the 1984 drug legislation
shows how competing interest groups, representing brand-name and generic
drug firms, forced legislators to face trade-offs in accommodating their
interests. I look most closely at the members of the House and Senate
committees with jurisdiction over pharmaceutical regulation issues. Data
representing brand-name and generic firm or consumer interests are used
to construct estimates of legislative preferences (ideal points).(3)
Then, the SIE theory is used to generate predictions about legislative
behavior and outcomes to help explain the initial failure of regulatory
reform in 1979 and its ultimate success in 1984.
The results from the analysis explain both why the status quo
prevailed in 1979 and why it was overturned in 1984. The analysis also
illustrates how the industry and consumer groups represented on the
relevant committees can protect their interests. This occurred in both
1979, when the Senate passed legislation favorable to the generic drug
industry, and 1981, when legislation supported by the brand-name drug
firms was passed. In each case, representatives of the unfavored
interest group were able to block legislation in the House. Legislation
was possible only when the majorities on the House and Senate committees
could agree on a single policy which could defeat the status quo in both
committees. Moreover, this policy provided benefits to both sets of
industry interests represented by committee members.
The paper is organized as follows. In sections II and III, I describe
the theory of political outcomes used in this analysis and provide some
background on pharmaceutical regulation prior to the reforms. The
estimation of congressional ideal points is discussed in section IV.
Sections V and VI examine congressional responses to the 1979 drug
reforms and interest group activity in the 1980s. The endogenous changes
that occurred to produce the new equilibrium in 1984 are examined in
sections VII and VIII, and the results are discussed in the last
section.
II. POLITICAL INTERESTS AND POLICY MAKERS
Government regulation generates a distribution of benefits and costs
which typically fall unequally on the groups affected. This provides
incentives for the groups affected to try to influence regulatory policy
makers.(4) Specifically, interest groups try to provide legislators with
information and to make them aware of the groups' concerns
regarding various policy proposals. Given the numbers and diversity of
groups within a constituency, legislators often face trade-offs among
their legislative decisions regarding these groups. For example,
McCubbins, Noll and Weingast [1987; 1989] illustrate the trade-offs
involved in the case of federal clean air policy. In their case, the
problem involves a trade-off between the stringency of the regulatory
policy and protection for existing firms.(5) In this paper's
example, the trade-off lies between generic firms' or consumer
interests in the availability of lower-priced generic drugs and
brand-name firms' interests in alleviating the adverse effects of
regulatory delay on a branded drug's effective patent life.
Legislators differ in their policy preferences, depending on their
constituency's interests, their exposure to different interest
groups' concerns, and their own personal ideologies. A model that
incorporates differences in policy preferences generates predictions
about legislative behavior and outcomes, but constructing such a model
first requires a theory of how legislative outcomes arise. For this
purpose, I use the structure-induced equilibrium theory of Shepsle and
Weingast [1981].
The following example provides a simple illustration of the theory.
Consider three legislators 1, 2, 3 and two issues: (i) the availability
of generic drugs and (ii) incentives for brand-name firms to pursue
research and development (R&D). Let the availability of generic
drugs be represented on the horizontal axis and let brand-name
firms' incentives for R&D be represented on the vertical axis
in Figure 1. Each legislator has an ideal point [[Theta].sub.i] which
represents the legislator's most preferred policy combination in
this two-dimensional issue space. For simplicity, I assume that each
legislator has Euclidean preferences over this issue space, which
implies that legislators seek to minimize the Euclidean distance between
the location of their ideal point [[Theta].sub.i] and the policy outcome
[x.sub.k] and that legislators have circular indifference curves. Let
[x.sub.o] represent the existing policy or status quo in this issue
space. Then, on any given vote, the legislator i votes for [x.sub.k]
only if it is closer to his ideal point [[Theta].sub.i] than the status
quo [x.sub.o]. If [x.sub.o] is closer to [[Theta].sub.i], legislator i
votes against [x.sub.k] A proposed policy defeats the status quo only if
a majority of legislators vote for it. Define the winset of [x.sub.o] as
the set of policies for which a majority favors the proposed policy over
the status quo. In a three-person legislature, a majority consists of
any two legislators.
Assume that legislator 1 prefers policies which provide strong
incentives for R&D by brand-name firms and only modest generic drug
availability. Assume that legislator 2 prefers policies which provide
increased generic drug availability and modest incentives for
brand-name-firm R&D. Legislator 3 has preferences somewhere in
between those of 1 and 2. The ideal points corresponding to such
preferences are depicted in Figure 1. Using the configuration of
indifference curves for the three legislators and the status quo point,
it is possible to characterize the winset. To find the winset, draw each
legislator's indifference curve through the status quo. Since all
the points inside a legislator's indifference curve are closer to
his ideal point, the legislator prefers all points inside this
indifference curve to the status quo. Regions in which the indifference
curves of any two members intersect represent policies preferred by
those two members to the status quo. For example the cross-hatched petal
on the left side of Figure 1 represents policies preferred by
legislators 1 and 3 to the status quo. The cross-hatched petal on the
right of Figure 1 represents policies preferred by legislators 2 and 3
to the status quo. The winset of Figure 1 consists of all policy
proposals located in these two petals. Proposed policies which fall
outside these two petals will be defeated by the status quo. For
example, a bill located at point b is preferred by legislator 2, but
legislators 1 and 3 prefer the status quo to b. Notice that a policy
which provides increased generic drug availability and increased
incentives for R&D (points to the north-east of the status quo)
would be defeated in this way.
To illustrate the impact of new membership on the winset, suppose
that legislator 3 retires and is replaced by legislator 4. Legislator 4
has an ideal point [[Theta].sub.4] depicted in Figure 2. It is possible
to construct the new winset for these three legislators using the same
method as in the previous example. The new winset consists of the two
cross-hatched petals shown in Figure 2. The top petal represents
policies preferred by 1 and 4. The bottom petal represents policies
preferred by 2 and 4. Unlike the previous case, there are policies in
the winset which provide both increased generic availability and
increased incentives for R&D. The presence of legislator 4 enables
these policies to be enacted, whereas in the previous example the same
policies would have been defeated. This simple illustration highlights
the potential impact of new membership on the resulting winset.(6) Such
changes occurred in the House and the Senate between 1979 and 1984.
A key element of this theory is the role played by congressional
committees. Congressional committees and subcommittees have substantial
power over the issues in their jurisdiction as described in Denzau and
Mackay [1983] and Shepsle and Weingast [1987].(7) A primary source of
the committee's influence arises from its gatekeeping power: the
ability to prevent access to the floor of legislation in its policy
jurisdiction.(8) Since all bills must originate in a committee, the only
bills to reach the floor are those which the committee approves.
Committees, in particular committee chairs, may choose to keep the gates
closed on bills which they do not support. Weingast and Moran [1983]
find that the chair of the subcommittee has a greater impact over
subcommittee decisions than any other individual member. I also find
that the chair does have significant influence over a
subcommittee's policy proposal, but that the power of the chair to
implement a proposal can be constrained by an opposing majority on the
subcommittee.
The notion of committee power suggests that an examination and
measurement of congressional preferences over policy can be restricted
to the set of members on the relevant congressional committee or
subcommittee. Given the preferences of committee members over a
particular policy domain, the structure-induced equilibrium theory then
provides a framework to predict legislative outcomes.
Since these outcomes are sensitive to anything affecting either the
committee members' preferences or the designation of committee
members, there is a role for interest group involvement. Interest groups
try to influence congressional preferences, and try to influence the
designation of members in Congress through the electoral process as in
Welch [1980].
An addition to this theory that is illustrated in the case of the
1984 legislation is inter-committee bargaining between the two chairs of
the Senate and House subcommittees over the position of the proposed
policy. Successful reforms had to pass in both the House and the
Senate.(9) The past experience of two unsuccessful reform efforts
demonstrated a need for coordination between the Senate and House
subcommittee chairs to produce a policy proposal that would not be
vetoed by either subcommittee.(10) The consensus achieved at the
subcommittee and committee stages sent a signal to the floor that any
partisan differences were resolved in the committee negotiations.(11)
Hence, the lack of opposition or controversy over the bill on the floor
is not surprising given the responsiveness of the bill's
negotiators to the interests involved.
III. PHARMACEUTICAL REGULATORY POLICY
The 1962 Harris-Kefauver Amendments fundamentally changed the way
that drugs were regulated in the U.S. and created the basis for current
drug regulatory policy. The amendments were largely a response to an
international tragedy surrounding the drug Thalidomide. The 1962
Amendments, first, shifted the burden of proof for establishing safety
from the government to the individual firms and, second, created an
efficacy requirement in which firms had to present substantial clinical
evidence that the new drug was effective for its intended purpose.
Third, the FDA created a detailed bureaucratic process for firms to
follow to obtain new drug approval.
The immediate cost of this regulatory process was borne by firms
trying to gain approval for a new drug, but once approved, these drugs
were guaranteed monopoly rents over the duration of the drug's
patent life. The cost and time required to obtain FDA approval served as
a significant barrier to entry for new competition. For consumers, the
immediate benefit was a diminished probability of taking an unsafe or
ineffective drug for an illness. The costs to consumers entailed higher
prices for these prescription drugs. Some consumers also suffered from
an increase in the probability of a beneficial drug being delayed in
reaching the U.S. market.
Brand-name and generic drugs were treated in a similar manner under
the 1962 Amendments. It was not until the introduction of the
Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA) in 1969 that the FDA began
treating generics differently from branded drugs. The purpose of the
application was to speed up the introduction of generic substitutes once
a branded drug's patent had expired. The new application, which did
not require proof of efficacy, decreased the FDA review times for these
generic drugs. However, the abbreviated application was only available
for generic versions of drugs patented before 1962. At the time of the
application's introduction in 1969, no provisions were made for
generic versions of drugs patented after 1962.
Generic firms certainly benefitted from the ANDA because it reduced
the cost of introducing a generic drug. Consumers also benefitted from
the increased availability of cheaper generic drugs. However, beginning
in the late-1970s, as the post-1962 patented drugs came off patent,
consumers began to complain about the lack of availability of generic
versions of these drugs. Given that generic firms could not use the ANDA
for these drugs and given the costs associated with alternative approval
procedures, many generic firms were not willing to produce these drugs.
In fact, several brand-name drugs whose patents had expired faced no
generic competition in their respective markets. Consumers were facing
higher prescription drug costs and the available supply of generics was
stagnating.
Meanwhile, brand-name firms were very concerned about the increasing
costs and time associated with the approval process for brand-name
drugs. The period required for preclinical and clinical testing
increased from 30 months in 1960 to 100 months in 1970 to 120 months in
1980 (as shown by Wardell, May and Trimble [1982]). The period of time
over which brand-name drugs could collect monopoly rents was shrinking
as the regulatory delays wasted valuable patent life.
To explain why reforms prior to 1984 failed and why the 1984
legislation was adopted requires a closer examination of the
congressional response to reform efforts. The SIE theory discussed above
generates predictions about legislative behavior and outcomes in 1979
and 1984. However, the application of this theory requires finding a way
to measure legislative preferences of the key players.
The next section introduces the proxies used to estimate legislative
ideal points. Applying the SIE theory to these legislative ideal points
illustrates how the preferences of committee members may have changed
between 1979 and 1984 and, more importantly, explains why the drug
reforms could not succeed until 1984.
IV. THE ESTIMATION OF IDEAL POINTS
Congressional ideal points over drug reform are located in a
two-dimensional issue space that depicts the conflicts between the
competing interests, brand-name and generic pharmaceutical firms. The
Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association (PMA), representing the
existing prescription pharmaceutical industry, wanted regulation to
stimulate incentives for R&D and to provide extended protection for
brand-name drugs from the threat of generic competition. Generic drug
firms, representing relatively new entrants to the current prescription
pharmaceutical market, wanted regulatory reform to ease their entry.
Further, the entry of generics meant lower prescription drug costs,
which was an issue of significant concern to consumer groups such as the
American Association of Retired Persons (AARP). The proxies that are
used to estimate ideal points are described below. Although somewhat
crude, I believe these proxies correlate with the classes of interests
in each dimension.
The generic or consumer interest dimension reflects legislative
efforts to ease the restrictions on the approval of generics,
specifically for drugs patented after 1962. The benefits from doing so
would accrue to both the generic drug firms and consumers. As a proxy
for generic interests, the Americans for Democratic Action (ADA) scores
for individual congressmen are used. ADA scores, which range from 0 to
100, reflect "conservative/liberal" divisions. The ADA
supports policies in favor of consumer benefits and interests.(12) In
this context, a high ADA score is correlated with a congressional
preference to ease generic firms' entry and to provide consumers
with low-price generic substitutes. A low ADA score is correlated with a
low preference for regulatory involvement or change in this
dimension.(13)
The brand-name interest dimension reflects legislative efforts to
reduce the costs associated with the approval of new drugs to firms, to
extend patent life, and to otherwise increase incentives to conduct
R&D. The most immediate benefits would be increased protection from
competition and increased profitability for the brand-name firms.
Campaign contributions from the political action committees (PACs) of
brand-name pharmaceutical firms to individual members of Congress are
used as a proxy for brand-name interests. These contributions measure
expected access by these brand-name interests to members. Candidates
that receive contributions from a PAC are more likely to be aware of the
PAC's interests. By contributing to the campaign of a political
candidate, PACs increase their chances of gaining access to the
candidate once elected. Although money may not buy votes, it often buys
time. With access, PACs can make legislators aware of their positions on
key policy issues. The degree to which members accept contributions from
these brand-name PACs is assumed to serve as an indicator of their
awareness or their responsiveness to the policy preferences of PACs.(14)
As documented in Wright [1985], the direct effects of contributions
on voting behavior depend on the processes by which PACs raise and
allocate money.(15) If the sources of funding and the allocation
decisions are quite separate from the lobbying efforts, then the effect
of contributions on specific voting behavior or accessibility may be
quite limited. However, in the case of drug regulation, the source of
funding and the allocation decisions are closely related to the
individual lobbying efforts of the brand-name pharmaceutical firms.
Individual firm's PACs represent very well organized and
concentrated interests. Further, there is a clear authority or
hierarchical structure within a firm which controls and oversees the
allocation decisions and the lobbying activities. For such a PAC, we may
expect to see coordination between contributions and lobbying activity.
Thus, the assumption that PAC contributions serve as a measure of
expected access to legislators is a reasonable one in this case.
An examination of the correlations between ADA scores and
contributions from brand-name PACs to the different subcommittees
reveals that these measures are not proxies for each other.(16) The
contribution dimension is included in this analysis because it helps
explain why reform efforts prior to 1984 were defeated and why the 1984
legislation ultimately succeeded.
In addition to legislative ideal points, the analysis requires the
characterization of the status quo in the issue space.(17) The status
quo represents the location of the existing policy in the issue space.
The actual placement of the status quo is assumed to be in a location
that separates legislators in view of their known preferences on each
dimension. For example, the status quo would be located to the left of
legislators who preferred more generic drug use (liberal Democrats) and
to the right of legislators who preferred less genetic drug use
(Republicans and conservative Democrats) on the ADA dimension. On the
contribution dimension, the status quo would be located below
legislators who preferred more brand-name-firm provisions and above
legislators who preferred less brand-name-firm provisions. The
coordinates of the status quo are assumed to be (ADA=35,
$Contribution=1000) which is consistent with the above description.(18)
Data on the campaign contributions from fourteen major brand-name
pharmaceutical PACs to individual members of Congress are from the
Federal Election Commission over the periods 1979-80 and 1983-84.(19)
Interestingly enough, generic drug firms and the GPIA, their trade
association, made no contributions over the period of analysis. Data for
ADA scores are from the ADA's Voting Records for 1979-1984.(20)
V. REFORM ATTEMPTS
The first legislative response to consumer groups' concerns over
trends in prescription drug costs was the 1978 Drug Reform Bill drafted
by Carter administration officials and the commissioner of the FDA. It
contained a major provision to increase the availability of generic
drugs.(21) In essence, the policy required brand-name firms to publish a
descriptive standard, a monograph, for each approved drug which could be
utilized by generic firms following the drug's patent
expiration.(22) The monograph would allow firms to duplicate the drug
without duplicating the original set of tests by the existing brand-name
firm.
For brand-name firms, the policy reduced information requirements for
firms during the early test stages to speed the approval process.
However, because information disclosure during the final stages of
testing would increase substantially, large, R&D-intensive
brand-name firms opposed the legislation. Although extensive hearings
were held in both the House and the Senate on the 1978 proposal,
"neither side was able to bring out a bill because of the industry
objection and the technical difficulty of some of the issues."(23)
In 1979, Senator Kennedy introduced a bill which simplified and
shortened the FDA approval process for new drugs and reduced the
informational and disclosure requirements for brand-name firms by
allowing them to submit summaries of the clinical test results instead
of raw data. These particular provisions appealed to brand-name firms.
For consumers and generic firms, the bill allowed generic firms to use
these summaries for the ANDA approval procedure for all drugs, including
drugs patented after 1962, after the original drug had been on the
market for seven years.(24)
Although the PMA favored some of the bill's provisions, it
opposed the legislation because it did not believe that approval times
would be shortened and because it strongly opposed any measures that
would simplify and stimulate the entry of generic drugs into the market.
Consumer groups (e.g., the AARP) concerned with increasing the
availability of cheaper-priced generics endorsed the bill. President
Carter, who was instrumental in the development of the 1978 reforms,
also supported the 1979 bill.
The bill was referred to the Labor and Human Resources Committee in
the Senate. Each committee member's ideal point is shown in Figure
3.(25) These ideal points consist of each senator's ADA score and
the campaign contributions received from pharmaceutical firms in
1979-80.
Figure 3 shows that the Senators' ideal points are distributed
along the ADA axis with little dispersion on the contribution dimension.
There appears to be two distinct clusters of ideal points. A majority of
eight Democrats are located toward the right edge of the ADA scale
including Kennedy, the chair of the subcommittee, and Williams (D-NJ),
the chair of the full committee. Of these eight Democrats, seven,
including Williams, were on the Health and Scientific Research
Subcommittee. The other cluster at the lower end of the ADA scale is a
minority group of four Republicans, one of whom was not on the
subcommittee. The two ideal points falling in between the clusters
belonged to members also not on the subcommittee. Using the method
described in section II, the set of policies preferred by a majority to
the status quo is constructed and the winset of the status quo is
depicted in the cross-hatched region in Figure 3. As indicated, points
in the circle to the lower right of the status quo represent policies
favored by the Democratic majority to the status quo. The points in the
smaller cross-hatched petal within the circle would also have the
support of the Republican minority on the subcommittee. Since the bill
was approved with the support of these Republicans after Kennedy
accepted some industry-backed amendments proposed by the senior
Republican on the subcommittee, this suggests that the Kennedy bill was
located in this leaf. Hence, the Kennedy bill, [b.sub.k] represented a
downward shift in brand-name interests and an increase in generic
interests. The theory predicts that Kennedy's bill would defeat the
status quo in the Senate and it did.
Figure 4 presents the estimated ideal points of the 1979 House Health
and Environment Subcommittee. Each legislator's ideal point
consists of his or her ADA score and the campaign contributions received
from brand-name drug firms in 1979-80. The ideal points are distributed
over the ADA dimension and exhibit more general dispersion over the
contribution dimension than was present in the Senate committee. Also,
unlike in the Senate case, there was greater dispersion among the ideal
points of the Democrats on the committee. Such dispersion could make
partisan policy agreement on the issue of drug reform difficult to
attain. With the presence of such conservative Democrats, such as
Satterfield (D-VA), Murphy (D-NY), Gramm (D-TX) and Shelby (D-AL) on the
ADA dimension, the possibilities for a coalition of conservative
Democrats with the Republicans would be a threat to the more liberal
Democrats.
The winset of the status quo is depicted by the two cross-hatched
petals in Figure 4. For an eighteen-member subcommittee, a majority
consists of at least ten members. The petal on the right-hand side of
the figure sloping upward shows the policies preferred by an
all-Democrat coalition.(26) This majority includes the most pro-consumer
(pro-generic) Democrats aligned with the most pro-business
(pro-brandname) Democrats, and hence only policies that provide more
benefits to both brand-name and generic interests are supported. The
petal on the left-hand side of this figure represents policies preferred
by a majority coalition of conservative Democrats and Republicans.(27)
Given that this petal contains policies that are preferred by two of the
conservative Democrats, Gramm and Shelby, to the ones offered in the
petal on the right-hand side, the conservative Democrat and Republican
coalition was probably more likely to form.(28)
Since the Kennedy bill was a shift down and to the right of the
status quo, it falls outside the winset for the House. Thus, the theory
predicts that the Kennedy bill would be defeated in the House. Because
the chairs of both the full committee and the subcommittee prefer the
status quo to the winset of the conservative Democrat and Republican
coalition (left leaf), we might expect to observe gatekeeping activity
on this bill. This is consistent with the actual House action on the
bill, which was stalled in the subcommittee and led to the bill's
death.(29) Thus, the status quo survived as the legislative equilibrium.
VI. INTEREST GROUP ACTIVITY IN THE 1980s
The failure of the 1979 reform simply meant that nothing was done to
lessen the problems of regulatory delay, to control sky-rocketing
prescription drug costs and to increase the supply of generic drugs. In
1981, brand-name pharmaceutical firms proposed that the patent lives of
drugs should be extended to reflect the portion lost during the lengthy
approval process.(30) The PMA argued that the decline in effective
patent lives reduced firms' incentives for R&D and hence
negatively affected the supply of innovative new drugs.
Patent extension accomplished two goals for the PMA. First, it
eliminated the complexities associated with changing the regulatory
process for drugs. Second, it shifted the jurisdiction in Congress from
the committees handling drug regulation to those which addressed patent
issues. In both the House and Senate, this meant that the Judiciary
Committees would have jurisdiction over legislation to grant a patent
extension. The maneuver proved successful in 1981 in the now
Republican-con-trolled Senate as legislation which extended patent terms
up to seven years was approved in the Judiciary Committee in May and on
the floor in July.(31)
Although generic manufacturers did not take an active role in the
legislative debate on prior drug reforms, the Senate bill served to
rally them in opposition to patent extension. In 1981 they formed the
Generic Pharmaceutical Industry Association (GPIA) and immediately began
to compile evidence against patent extension. During congressional
hearings on the relationship between patent extension and innovation,
testimony was heard by representatives of both brand-name and generic
interests--the PMA and the GPIA, respectively.
The GPIA argued that subsequent use, process, and other patents
extended the patent terms for many brand-name drugs so that these drugs
essentially maintained their monopoly markets.(32) The GPIA's
evidence showed that many drugs examined enjoyed a period of
"post-patent exclusivity" during which these drugs reaped
monopolistic rents.(33) The reason why generic firms were not entering
these markets immediately after patent expiration was due to the
restrictions on ANDA use for generic versions of drugs patented after
1962.
The involvement of the GPIA created both a stumbling block for the
proponents of patent-term extension and a renewed interest in changing
the regulatory process for generics. Although the patent extension bill
was reported by the House Judiciary Committee in August 1982, it met
significant opposition from pro-consumer, anti-business advocates on the
House floor as well as from Henry Waxman (D-CA).(34) The ultimate
outcome was the defeat of the patent extension bill in the House.(35)
The status quo was still the equilibrium.
The failure of the 1982 bill in the House was not surprising for two
reasons. First, it provided no off-setting benefits for generic drug
firms. Second, patent-term extension did serve to redirect the bill to a
more receptive committee in the House, but it probably created a
jurisdictional dispute between the Judiciary Committee and the Energy
and Commerce Subcommittee on Health and the Environment. The chairs of
the full Energy and Commerce Committee and the Health and Environment
Subcommittee, Dingell and Waxman, each voted against the patent
extension bill.
VII. CHANGING MEMBERSHIP AND TURNOVER
The House Health and Environment Subcommittee experienced substantial
turnover in the early 1980s. Turnover resulted in a 44 percent change in
1980 committee membership and another 30 percent change in 1982
committee membership. In addition to turnover, Democrats gained an
additional seat on the subcommittee while Republicans lost two seats, so
that the new ratio of Democrats to Republicans increased to 13:6 from
the previous 12:8 margin prior to the 1982 election. One consequence
from these changes was that Waxman now possessed a working majority of
Democrats on the subcommittee. The threat of a conservative Democrat and
Republican coalition, once present in the 1979 subcommittee, was no
longer a factor.(36)
In the Senate the key change occurred in 1980 when the Republicans
gained majority party control. One consequence of this party turnover
was a change in the party of the chairs of all Senate committees and
subcommittees. In the Labor and Human Resources Committee, the chair
shifted from Harrison Williams (D-NJ) to Orrin Hatch (R-UT). In
addition, Republicans gained four seats on the committee while Democrats
lost one so that the ratio of Republicans to Democrats increased from
6:9 in 1979 to 10:8 in 1984. With respect to membership, six of the
eight Democrats in 1984 were from the 1979 committee. Four Republicans
from 1979, including Hatch, were among the 1984 committee members, but
six new Republicans also joined this group. The effect of these changes
on the legislative equilibrium is illustrated in the next section.
TABLE I
House Subcommittee
TurnoverSize
Democrats Republicans Total Members
1980 election 5 3 20
1982 election 3 3 19
VIII. THE NEW LEGISLATIVE EQUILIBRIUM
Figure 5 shows the ideal points of the members of the 1984 House
Health and Environment Subcommittee and reveals substantial change from
Figure 4. The ideal points in 1984 appear to be more polarized than in
1979. The majority, like Waxman, have high ADA scores, but several also
have substantial contributions from brand-name PACs. Four senior
Democrats, Waxman, Scheuer, Luken and Dingell, the chair of the full
committee, have high contributions from brand-names as well as high ADA
scores. It is not necessarily the case that the increase in
contributions reflected a shift in preferences for these members. The
increase in contributions to Waxman and Dingell may reflect the desire
by PAC's to increase their access to someone who has a lot of
power, e.g., committee chairs. Further, the increase in contributions
may simply reflect the fact that PACs increased their contributions over
time.(37) In any event, the final legislative outcome does not depend on
the extent of the contributions to these four members and hence is not
conditioned on a change in preferences along this dimension. The key
changes in the House occurred on the ADA dimension largely as a result
of a new, more liberal Democratic membership on the subcommittee and the
higher ratio of Democrats to Republicans discussed in the previous
section.
The winset in Figure 5 consists of all policies in the large leaf to
the right of the status quo. The policies in this region are supported
by the members of the Democratic majority on the subcommittee. As Figure
4 shows, in 1979 the winset had two petals, one of which (left petal)
represented the policies supported by the conservative Democrat and
Republican coalition. By 1984, the left petal disappeared leaving only a
large petal on the right. It was this Democratic majority that approved
a one-page bill introduced by Waxman in August 1983 that would allow
generic firms to use the ANDA-expedited approval procedure for post-1962
patented drugs.(38) The bill contained no provisions for brand-name
firms and it was sure to meet opposition from these firms if it
proceeded to the floor. In the Senate, the bill would encounter
opposition from the Labor and Human Resources Committee.
Figure 6 shows a plot of the ideal points of the 1984 Senate Labor
and Human Resources Committee, chaired by Hatch. A majority cluster of
Democrats and two Republicans is located at the right edge of the ADA
scale. This cluster is not very different from the majority cluster on
the 1979 Senate committee in Figure 3. The Republicans are more spread
over the contribution space in 1984 than in 1979, but few receive
significant contributions. The major difference between 1979 and 1984 is
the presence of Orrin Hatch as the chairman of the full committee. He is
located in the upper left corner of the graph with high contributions
and a low ADA score. Hatch was a major proponent of patent-term
extension, which is consistent with his location in the figure.
The winset in the Senate is shown in Figure 6 by the petal to the
right of the status quo pointing upward. The policies are supported by a
majority coalition of Hatch with the majority cluster of members with
ADA scores at or above 60. The policies in this winset include the
preferred brand-name alternative, patent extension, as well as some
measures to ease generic firm entry. Any bill without some benefits for
brand-names would not get through the Senate committee given the
presence of Hatch as the chair.(39)
Unlike 1979, however, there was an opportunity to implement a
successful reform in both the House and the Senate committees because
each would support bills which provided benefits to both brand-names and
generics. This can be seen by examining each chamber's winset and
noting that each contained policies located to the right of and above
the status quo. Recognizing such an opportunity, Hatch initiated a
series of private negotiations with Waxman and members from the PMA and
the GPIA to develop a bill to accommodate both brand-names and generics.
The willingness of each side to come to the bargaining table may have
been strengthened by the previous two legislative failures in 1979 and
1982.(40)
The outcome from a ten-month period of negotiations was a
forty-four-page bill termed the Waxman-Hatch compromise (HR 3606, S
2748). The bill extended the use the ANDA to generic versions of drugs
patented after 1962 and granted patent extensions up to five years for
the first patent on a brand-name drug.(41) In addition, the bill
provided four years exclusive marketing rights for non-patented New
Chemical Entities (NCEs) and made it legal for generic firms to begin
the required testing in anticipation of expiration of the exclusive
marketing date.(42) The bill was supported by the board of the PMA and
the GPIA. It was also supported by the AARP, consumer groups and labor
unions, largely due to the provision for generic drugs.(43)
This winset depicted in Figure 7 represents a set of preferred
policies by Hatch and by the coalition of Democrats, including Waxman,
on the House subcommittee.(44) This winset reflects a set of policies
which could have passed in both the House subcommittee and the Senate
committee and is characterized as providing benefits to both brand-name
and generic firms as did the compromise.
Dissent and Renegotiation
The theory predicts that a bill inside the winset in Figure 7 would
be supported as a new legislative equilibrium by the House and the
Senate committees. The resulting compromise bill, [b.sub.1], from the
Waxman-Hatch negotiations was located inside this winset. However, a
dissenting group of eight firms, later joined by three additional firms,
from the PMA wanted more compensation, in terms of exclusive marketing
rights, than the existing compromise provided them.(45) They wanted to
shift up the location of the bill in the winset.
The dissenting group attempted to mobilize opposition to the bill
outside the committee. The threat of amendments on the floor which would
weaken the legislation forced Waxman and Hatch to address, at least in
part, the group's demands. The new bill included an extended
provision for non-patent exclusive marketing rights.(46) They also
included a provision to appease the dissident group which would allow
brand-name firms to choose which patent to extend. In addition, Waxman
also agreed to include an unrelated textile-labeling amendment to the
bill.(47,48)
The dissenting group's opposition to the original compromise
played a role in shifting the location of the bill inside the winset in
Figure 7. The bill shifted upward in the direction of brand-name
interests from [b.sub.1] to [b.sub.2]. The division within the PMA
actually worked in favor of all PMA members by providing broader
exclusive marketing rights.
The new bill served the purpose of thwarting any expected opposition
on the floor. Although three amendments were proposed in the House that
would upset the balance of interests achieved in the bill, all three
measures were strongly rejected.(49) On final consideration, the bill
was unanimously accepted by the House and then subsequently approved on
a voice vote in the Senate in September of 1984. No member wanted to
vote against a measure that was supported by all the major interests
involved in the compromise.
IX. DISCUSSION
This example demonstrates that an understanding of the relevant
institutions is useful in understanding the legislative process. In this
case, the key institutions are (i) the congressional committees in the
House and Senate which preside over drug regulation issues and (ii) the
mechanisms which enable these committees to exert influence over such
policy. Knowledge of interest group activities alone is not enough to
explain why some legislative reforms fail and others succeed. This study
provides answers to questions that can not be addressed by theories that
focus solely on interest groups. Explaining the failure of reform in
1979 and its success in 1984 requires an understanding of how brand-name
and genetic drug interests are represented in the key congressional
committees or subcommittees.
As membership and preferences on these committees change over time,
the set of policies which can be supported by a majority on the
committee will also change. Thus, new membership on a committee
corresponds to new legislative opportunities. In addition, these
committees can act as gatekeepers and prevent access to the floor of
legislation in their policy jurisdiction. This affords them substantial
influence over the development of any policy within their jurisdiction.
It further implies that successful legislation must have the support of
both the relevant House and Senate committees; otherwise, one chamber
may block the progression of a bill by keeping it shut up in committee.
Thus, we would expect to see such gatekeeping activity if the interests
represented on the House committee differ significantly from those of
the Senate. This, indeed, was the case regarding the drug reforms prior
to 1984.
With respect to the degree of independent influence of the
subcommittee chair, the observed behavior of Waxman's subcommittee
in 1979 suggests that the power of a chair to pursue his own interests
is limited by the subcommittee. However, these limitations vanished as
the ideal points of the subcommittee members changed over time and the
Democratic majority moved closer to Waxman. This suggests that a
subcommittee chair may possess some power by his ability to influence
the membership on the subcommittee over time.(50)
In conclusion, this analysis highlights several key factors that
economists need to consider to understand the timing of legislation.
First, economists need to know the distribution of preferences of
committee members because this distribution determines the set of
policies that can be supported as an equilibrium outcome. Second,
economists should consider the differences in the preferences between
the House and Senate committees because successful legislation must have
the support of the relevant committee in each chamber. Third, it is
important to know the identity of the chair because the chair can
prevent bills from reaching the floor. An implication is that successful
legislation must be preferred by the committee chair to the status quo.
Finally, it is important to understand how the distribution of committee
preferences and the winset are altered over time by new committee
membership, turnover, or a shift in the pattern of PAC contributions.
1. Prior to this legislation, only generic versions of drugs with
patents granted prior to 1962 were eligible for this expedited approval
procedure using the ANDA. This implied that generic versions of
brand-name drugs patented after 1962, whose patent had expired, had to
reproduce a substantial portion of the safety and efficacy data required
for FDA approval.
2. Baily [1972], Peltzman [1973], Grabowski, Vernon and Thomas [1978]
and Wiggins [1981] are classic articles which have examined the impact
of the 1962 Harris-Kefauver Amendments. Comanor [1986] provides an
excellent survey of the existing literature.
3. The data represent both an ideological component to legislative
behavior as in Kalt and Zupan [1984] and a financial or contribution
component as in Chappell [1982].
4. This view is taken by Stigler [1971] and Peltzman [1976]. Wilson
[1980] also characterizes different types of regulatory policy by its
distribution of costs and benefits.
5. Most regulatory issues are characterized by some kind of trade-off
among various interests.
6. A similar phenomena can occur if the preferences of existing
members change from one period to another.
7. For more on congressional committees, see Manley [1970], Fenno
[1973], Shepsle [1978], Smith and Deering [1984], and Dodd and
Oppenheimer [1985].
8. Another source of committee power is the ex post veto because they
usually control the conference committee. Krehbiel [1987] suggests that
the use of alternative institutions within the House may erode the ex
post veto power of the subcommittee.
9. The ideal point of the President could easily be incorporated into
the analysis without providing any additional insight.
10. outcomes in which opposing sides are able to realize joint gains
from compromise are discussed in Quirk [1989] and Perotti [1990].
11. This seems to be a case in which the relevant action occurred at
the subcommittee or committee stage. Consideration of floor votes does
not yield any additional insight for this analysis.
12. High scores are given to members who vote in favor of consumer
policies, such as jobless benefits, public works programs, regulation of
toxic waste, and other regulatory attempts to correct for market
failures in which consumers may be adversely affected. From ADA Voting
Records, 1979-84.
13. Since there are no recorded votes on legislation involving
generic drugs prior to 1984, it is not possible to examine the
correlation between voting behavior and ADA scores in this case.
However, Weingast and Moran [1983] established a direct relationship
between ADA scores and legislative support for a pro-consumer FTC.
Efforts to ease generic entry were strongly supported by consumer
interests including the AARP, Ralph Nader and various consumer groups
concerned about drug pricing.
14. This does not preclude the possibility that PACs also give money
to legislators who already agree with them to help them get reelected.
15. This helps explain the mixed conclusions found in the literature
regarding the effects of contributions on voting behavior. For example,
see Silberman and Durden [1976], Chappell [1981; 1982], Kau and Rubin
[1982], and Welch [1982].
16. The correlations are: (i) -.5 in the 1979 House subcommittee;
(ii) -.1 in the 1979 Senate committee; (iii) -.6 in the 1984 House
subcommittee; and (iv) -.4 in the 1984 Senate committee. Although the
two measures exhibit some negative correlation, there appears to be a
reasonable amount of unexplained variance in contributions to support
this two-dimensional representation. In contrast, the correlation
between two different ideological ratings, ADA and ACA, showed a much
higher (almost perfect) negative correlation in each case.
17. Given the restrictions placed on ANDA's and the effects of
regulatory delay on brand-name drug approvals, the status quo
corresponds to a relatively low ADA score and a moderate position on the
contribution dimension.
18. The analysis is not dependent on this assumption. Other locations
for the status quo in this general region yield similar results.
19. The PACs represent the following firms: Bristol-Myers,
Ciba-Geigy, Eli-Lilly, Johnson and Johnson, Merck, Pfizer, SmithKline,
Abbott, American Home Products, Hoffman-La Roche, Marion Laboratories,
Sandoz, Upjohn, and the PMA. This sample reflects the major brand-name
interests and thus should represent the majority of the campaign
contributions to Congress from brand-name firms.
20. The use of raw data values in each dimension to estimate
legislative ideal points avoids the indeterminacies of some scaling
methods.
21. Congressional Hearings before the Subcommittee on Health and
Scientific Research on S. 1831 to amend the Food, Drug and Cosmetics
Act, U.S. Senate, 26 July 1977.
22. For drugs not eligible for patents, the FDA would grant five
years of exclusive marketing privileges in exchange for the monograph.
23. Congressional Quarterly Almanac, 1979, p. 486.
24. Congressional Quarterly Weekly, 20 October 1979, pp. 2349-56.
25. The preferences of the full committee are examined over the
period to maintain consistency. Although the Senate Subcommittee on
Health and Scientific Research was referred the bill in 1979, this
subcommittee was eliminated from the Labor and Human Resources Committee
by 1984.
26. This group consists of the liberal Democrats, Waxman, Mikulski,
Leland and Walgren, aligned with the more conservative Democrats Preyer,
Staggers and Luken, and ultra-conservative Democrats Gramm and Shelby.
27. The Democrats are Satterfield, Murphy, Luken, Gramm and Shelby,
along with Republicans Stockman, Carter, Madigan, Dannemeyer, Lee and
Broyhill.
28. All other possible majorities that could form have winsets which
are subsets of those shown in Figure 4.
29. Congressional Quarterly Weekly, 20 October 1979, pp. 2349-56.
30. A study by Eisman and Wardell [1981] of 168 New Chemical Entities
(NCEs) introduced between 1966 and 1979 showed that the average
effective patent life declined from 13.6 years in 1966 to 9.5 years in
1979 due to the time required for FDA approval.
31. Congressional Quarterly Almanac, 1982, p. 400.
32. GPIA, "Fact Sheet on Patent Extension," Hearings before
the Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight of the Committee on
Science and Technology, U.S. House of Representatives, 97th Congress, 4
February 1982, p. 214.
33. One study cited in the hearing "showed that after patents
expired, each of 12 major drugs (including Librium and Darvon) retained
more than a 90 percent share of the drugstore market and more than an 80
percent share of the hospital market."
34. E. Clay Shaw (R-FL) thought the legislation would simply protect
brand-name drugs from competition for a longer period of time and hence
keep prescription drug prices high, which would hurt consumers,
especially the elderly. Henry Waxman opposed the legislation because
pharmaceutical firms had already been granted a 25 percent R&D
credit through the 1981 tax bill.
35. Although the bill's sponsor attempted to get the bill
approved under suspension of the rules to ward off amendments that he
thought the opposition might make to weaken it, the bill died as the
suspension proposal fell five votes short of the required two-thirds
majority (250-132). From Congressional Quarterly Almanac, 1982, p. 400.
36. Several conservative Democrats were either defeated or retired.
Richardson Preyer, a North Carolina Democrat, who had substantial
holdings in a major R&D-intensive pharmaceutical company,
Richardson-Merrell, was defeated in the 1980 election. David
Satterfield, a senior Virginia Democrat, who was considered too
conservative by his own party retired in 1980. Another senior Democrat
who retired, Harley Staggers, the chair of the Commerce Committee, was
an heir to the P&G fortune. From Michael Barone and Grant Ujifusa,
The Almanac of American Politics, 1982.
37. Another explanation could be that these particular members became
more concerned with campaign fund-raising or more inclined to take
contributions during this period.
38. During the past five years, the FDA had twice attempted to revise
its own rules with respect to the generic approval procedure, but
lawsuits from brand-name drug companies prevented any procedural
changes.
39. Hatch could always keep the gates closed for bills that
didn't have such provisions.
40. The failure of the 1982 patent restoration attempt was largely
due to the opposition of the GPIA. Similarly, the attempts to increase
generic availability in 1978 and 1979 were stifled by the PMA.
41. Total patent life was not to exceed fourteen years for any
brand-name drug. Drugs receiving FDA approval between 1982 and the date
of enactment of the bill would qualify for the ANDA procedure only after
ten years of exclusive marketing. Drugs approved after the enactment of
the bill would qualify for the ANDA procedure after the expiration of
their patents, including any extensions authorized by the bill.
42. Congressional Quarterly Almanac, 1984, p. 452. 43. During the
period of negotiations to develop the compromise bill, the FDA was
between commissioners and did not appear to play any role in these
negotiations. If anything, the agency favored a more gradual transition
for ANDA eligibility for drugs patented after 1962 to allow the FDA time
to adjust to the additional workload.
44. Putting both Hatch from the Senate and the House Democrats on the
same graph should be interpreted cautiously. The construction of this
winset is only meant to be suggestive of the compromise region for the
two chairs.
45. The thirty-four member governing board of the PMA agreed to
endorse the compromise 22-12. The twelve firms who voted against the
endorsement represented several of the largest R&D-intensive
pharmaceutical firms with major patents either just expired or about to
expire and were generally opposed to the provision for expedited
approval of generic drugs. The eleven dissenting firms were from this
group. As a result of the controversy, the president and two other PMA
negotiators were fired in August 1984. From: John Barry, "CEOs Make
the Best Lobbyists," Dunn's Business Monthly, January 1986, p.
36.
46. Non-patented NCEs would receive five years of exclusive marketing
and drugs which were not NCEs but which required substantial clinical
testing would receive a three-year exclusive marketing period.
Non-patented drugs approved between 1982 and the date of enactment would
receive a two-year exclusive marketing period.
47. Congressional Quarterly Weekly, 15 September 1984, p. 2241.
48. The inclusion of this amendment ensured further support of the
bill by certain members of Congress.
49. The first amendment would have reduced the delay for ANDA
approval in the event of litigation from thirty months to eighteen
months. This was rejected 66-304. The second amendment would have
exempted over-the-counter drugs from revisions in the bill for genetic
drug approval. This was rejected 24-347. A final amendment extended the
time for compliance with the textile clause and was rejected 36-323.
50. Although the subcommittee assignments are made by the Democratic
Steering and Policy Committee, Waxman may have influenced the
composition of the subcommittee between 1981 and 1983 by contributing to
the campaigns of various Democrats on the subcommittee (with his own
PAC) and by obtaining the most favorable margin of Democrats to
Republicans possible for his subcommittee. In addition, two
conservative, less-senior Democrats on the subcommittee who generally
opposed Waxman's interests were replaced in 1983 by two other
subcommittee chain, Ottinger and Wirth, whose campaigns had received
contributions from Waxman during the election.
REFERENCES
Baily, Martin N. "Research and Development Costs and Returns:
The U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry." Journal of Political Economy,
January/February 1972, 70-85.
Chappell, Henry. "Campaign Contributions and Voting on the Cargo
Preference Bill: A Comparison of Simultaneous Models." Public
Choice, 36(2), 1981, 301-12.
-----. "Campaign Contributions and Congressional Voting: A
Simultaneous Probit-Tobit Model." Review of Economics and
Statistics, February 1982, 77-83.
Comanor, William S. "The Political Economy of the Pharmaceutical
Industry." Journal of Economic Literature, September 1986,
1178-1217.
Denzau, Arthur, and Robert J. Mackay. "Gatekeeping and Monopoly
Power of Committees: An Analysis of Sincere and Sophisticated
Behavior." American Journal of Political Science, November 1983,
740-61.
Dodd, Lawrence, and Bruce Oppenheimer. Congress Reconsidered.
Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1985.
Eisman, Martin, and William Wardell. "The Decline in Effective
Patent Life of New Drugs." Research Management, January 1981,
18-21.
Fenno, Richard. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Little, Brown and
Co., 1973.
Grabowski, Henry, John Vernon, and Lacy G. Thomas. "Estimating
the Effects of Regulation on Innovation: An International Comparative
Analysis of the Pharmaceutical Industry." Journal of Law and
Economics, April 1978, 133-63.
Kalt, Joseph, and Mark Zupan. "Capture and Ideology in the
Economic Theory of Politics." American Economic Review, June 1984,
279-300.
Kau, James, and Paul Rubin. Congressmen, Constituents, and
Contributors. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff, 1982.
Krehbiel, Keith. "Why Are Congressional Committees
Powerful?" American Political Science Review, 81(3), September
1987, 929-35.
Manley, John. The Politics of Finance. Boston: Little, Brown &
Co., 1970.
McCubbins, Mathew, Roger Noll, and Barry Weingast.
"Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political
Control." Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Fall 1987,
243-77.
-----. "Structure and Process, Politics and Policy:
Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies."
Virginia Law Review, March 1989, 431-82.
Peltzman, Sam. "An Evaluation of Consumer Protection
Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments." Journal of Political
Economics, September/October 1973, 1049-91.
-----. "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation."
Journal of Law and Economics, August 1976, 211-40.
Perotti, Rosanna. "Resolving Policy Conflict: Integrative
Bargaining in Immigration Reform." Manuscript, Case Western Reserve
University, May 1990.
Quirk, Paul. "The Cooperative Resolution of Policy
Conflict." American Political Science Review, September 1989,
905-21.
Shepsle, Kenneth. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle: Democratic Committee
Assignments in the Modern House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1978.
Shepsle, Kenneth, and Barry Weingast. "Structure-Induced
Equilibrium and Legislative Choice." Public Choice, 37(3), 1981,
503-19.
-----. "The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power."
American Political Science Review, March 1987, 85-104.
Silberman, Jonathan, and Garey Durden. "Determining Legislative
Preferences on the Minimum Wage: An Economic Approach." The Journal
of Political Economy, April 1976, 317-29.
Smith, Steven, and Christopher Deering. Committees in Congress.
Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1984.
Stigler, George. "The Theory of Economic Regulation." Bell
Journal of Economics, Spring 1971, 2-21.
Wardell, William, Maureen May, and Gene Trimble. "New Drug
Development by U.S. Pharmaceutical Firms." Clinical Pharmacology and Therapeutics, October 1982, 407-17.
Weingast, Barry, and Mark Moran. "Bureaucratic Discretion or
Congressional Control: Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade
Commission." Journal of Political Economy, October 1983, 765-800.
Welch, William P. "The Allocation of Political Monies: Economic
Interest Groups." Public Choice, 35(1), 1980, 97-120.
-----. "Campaign Contributions and Legislative Voting: Milk
Money and Dairy Price Supports." Western Political Quarterly,
December 1982, 478-95.
Wiggins, Steven. "Product Quality Regulation and New Drug
Introductions: Some New Evidence From the 1970s." Review of
Economics and Statistics, November 1981, 615-19.
Wilson, James Q., ed. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic
Books, 1980.
Wright, John. "PACs, Contributions, and Roll Calls: An
Organizational Perspective." American Political Science Review,
June 1985, 400-14.