Incomplete ownership, rent dissipation, and the return to related investments.
Deacon, Robert T.
I. INTRODUCTION
When ownership rights to a resource are costless to enforce, trades
occur and an equilibrium price emerges. In such cases it is a price and
a transfer of wealth from one agent to another that rations use of the
resource. Absent ownership no price is charged and use is rationed by a
transaction cost. Acquiring a barrel of oil or an acre foot of water
from a shared reservoir is a transaction--a resource in the common
domain is transformed into property by the act of lifting it to the
surface where ownership can be enforced. The relevant transaction cost
in this case is the cost of pumping. In a fishery the relevant
transaction cost is the cost of locating and capturing a portion of the
unowned stock.
The marginal transaction cost limits each individual's use and
accomplishes the necessary task of equating demand to the
resource's supply. Users of the resource are in equilibrium when
this marginal transaction cost equals the resource's marginal
value. The transaction cost also eliminates all or part of the rent the
resource would earn if owned, however, and the size of this loss depends
on the relationship between average transaction cost and the
resource's marginal value.
This suggests that the amount of rent an unowned resource will yield
in equilibrium, after netting out relevant costs, depends on the shape
of the cost function for acquiring it. If marginal cost is much greater
than average cost, as in cases where marginal cost is steeply rising,
the equilibrium rent will be relatively large.(1) While the shape of the
cost function depends on the nature of the resource, it is not
immutable. For example, it can be altered by imposing constraints on the
inputs or the technology used. It follows that users of a resource would
benefit collectively if the technology or inputs used were constrained in a way that causes the marginal cost of obtaining it to rise steeply.
The optimal choice of such constraints is a well-formulated second-best
policy problem.
This specification of the problem is incomplete, however, because the
intensity of competition for the shared resource can also be changed by
actions that affect it only indirectly. An innovation or investment that
lowers the individual's cost of acquiring it, for example by
reducing the price of an input used, has this effect. So does an action
that raises the resource's marginal value product, possibly by
affecting the price or availability of a substitute. Such actions
increase competition for the shared resource and raise the equilibrium
cost of actions taken to acquire it. In this sense the rent dissipation that is normally thought to characterize competition for shared
resources can spread to related actions or investments.
Both of these considerations are pursued in what follows. Second-best
policy toward a shared resource is examined by considering regulations
that can control some but not all of the inputs needed to acquire it. It
is shown that the optimal input constraint and the fraction of potential
rent such a policy can capture depend on two determinants--the
elasticity of substitution between, and relative price of, regulated and
unregulated inputs.
It is also shown that competition for the shared resource can
eliminate all or part of the return to related actions, i.e., actions
that result in a shift in the relevant private cost or benefit function.
The size of such losses depends in a simple way on the elasticities of
relevant cost and benefit functions. These additional losses can occur
even in cases where direct competition causes complete rent dissipation.
As a result, the loss that results from free access can exceed the rent
the resource would earn in a complete markets equilibrium. This
phenomenon, termed excess dissipation, is illustrated with a number of
examples. Investments that reduce the percolation of groundwater back
into a common aquifer or expenditures to prevent fish from escaping from
a net and returning to the natural population during the process of
capture are shown to have this effect. Such conservation actions lower
the cost of obtaining the resource and they can lower welfare because
the individual's incentive to conserve is excessive in such
circumstances. Examples of other actions, such as marginal cost pricing
for a substitute resource and innovations that affect the productivity
of the unowned resource, are also presented.
This work is related to several streams of literature. Some of the
propositions developed on rent dissipation are reminiscent of findings
in the rent-seeking literature developed by Gordon Tullock [1980a],
Richard Posner [1980], and others. The excess dissipation result in
particular is similar to a result presented by Tullock [1980b]. The
questions raised and results obtained share similarities with analysis
by Braverman and Stiglitz [1982] on share-cropping. In cases where the
landlord cannot directly control the amount of effort the worker
supplies, they show that the landlord can benefit by altering prices or
taking other actions that appropriately shift the worker's private
marginal cost and benefit schedules for effort. In the present context,
users of the shared resource can benefit by mutually refraining from
activities that lead to lower private marginal costs or higher marginal
private benefits. Wijkander [1985] and Sandmo [1976] have studied the
problem of regulating an externality indirectly, by altering prices of
complements and substitutes to the item of direct interest. Finally,
Deacon and Sonstelie [1991] have examined the losses that arise from
price controls and rationing by waiting. Their analysis stresses the
notion that privately rational adjustments to rationing by waiting can
be socially self-defeating if they intensify competition for the
price-controlled item.
While this paper shares common features with these works, it is
directed toward different objectives and reaches several new
conclusions. In particular, the finding that the loss from free access
competition can exceed the rent a resource would earn with complete
markets, and the observation that returns to privately rational actions
may be dissipated by competition for a related resource that is unowned,
appear to be new. Another novel feature is the precise characterization
of factors that determine the efficacy of second-best input controls
when the technology has constant elasticity of substitution.
The analysis begins by examining two extreme property rights regimes,
complete ownership with costless transactions and free access. While
these extremes may not accurately describe any actual resource, the
examination of polar cases is often a productive way to gain insight on
the more typical regimes that lie in between.(2) A class of intermediate
cases is then developed by specifying limits on the use of some but not
all of the inputs needed to acquire the resource in question. These
limits amount to partial ownership, e.g., rights to operate a fishing
vessel or a water well. The model is formulated in such a way that
'excessive' use of the shared resource degrades its quality or
accessibility and increases the cost of acquiring it. This continues
until the marginal cost and marginal benefit of obtaining the resource
are equated at a level of use that does not cause further degradation.
The following section lays out the notation and general structure of the
model.
II. A MODEL ECONOMY WITH A SHARED INPUT
Consider an economy with N identical agents, each of whom is a
self-sufficient producer-consumer. Each agent owns a firm that produces
a consumption good and each consumes its own firm's output. Trade
among individuals is possible, but none occurs in equilibrium because
individuals are identical. A shared (unowned) input is necessary for
production of the consumption good. To fix ideas, imagine an economy in
which the shared resource is a stock of fish and where each individual
fishes from the common stock and consumes his or her own catch. The
number of firms, N, is large enough that all take prices as given and
ignore the effect of their own actions on the quality or accessibility
of the shared resource.(3)
The firm's production function is
(1)q = q(z)
where q is output of the consumption good per firm and z is the
firm's use of the shared resource.(4) As a consumer, the
individual's preferences are represented by
(2)w = u[q(z)] + x
where x is leisure, the numeraire. Both U(-) and q([center dot]) are
assumed concave so W([center dot]) is concave as well. Where no
confusion can arise utility is abbreviated to U(z) + x, the first term
of which is the total value product of the shared resource, z.(5)
In order to obtain z the firm must use two ordinary inputs, energy
(e) and capital (k). The reason for introducing two inputs becomes clear
later. The amount of z obtained for given e and k depends on the quality
or accessibility of the resource, D. By convention an increase in D
makes the resource more difficult to acquire. For fish, D would be
inversely related to the abundance of the stock, so the effort required
for search and capture is greater for greater D. The production function
for obtaining the shared resource is
(3)z = z(e/D, k/D)
where z([center dot]) is concave. Doubling D doubles the amounts of e
and k needed to obtain a given level of z. D is common to all firms and
each takes its level as given.
The individual is endowed with [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
units of leisure per period. Leisure can either be consumed or
transformed into e and k. The unit costs of e and k, [p.sub.e] and
[p.sub.k], are assumed constant. The individual's consumption of
leisure is thus constrained by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The individual, as owner of a representative firm, uses amounts of e
and k that minimize [p.sub.e]e + [p.sub.k]k, the cost of acquiring z,
subject to (3). The resulting cost function,
(5) C = h([p.sub.e],[p.sub.k], z) D,
is homogeneous of degree one in D and exhibits non-decreasing
marginal costs for z. The homogeneity property occurs because doubling D
doubles the amounts of e and k needed to obtain a given z. Note that
[C.sub.ZD] [is greater than] 0, so increasing D raises the marginal cost
of acquiring the shared input. Where no confusion can result the cost
function is abbreviated to h(z)D.(6)
While each individual regards D as given, its level is determined by
the economy-wide use of z. If use is high, quality or accessibility
declines and D increases. The resource is capable of natural
regeneration, however, so D will fall if use is low enough. This process
is represented by
(6) D = g(Nz - NR)
= f(z - R),
where R is natural regeneration per firm, assumed fixed. The fixed
number of firms, N, has been suppressed. It is further assumed that
f[prime] [is greater than] 0, f(0) = 0, and D [is greater than or equal
to] [Delta], where [Delta] is a positive constant. The rationale for
bounding D away from zero is explained later. In a steady state z = R,
and any D [is greater than or equal to] [Delta] can be sustained as a
steady state so long as the individual chooses z=R at the value of D
specified.(7)
Combining (2), (4), and (5), utility can be written
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
which is the utility from consuming q(z) plus that portion of the
leisure endowment not used to acquire z. The next section examines
steady-state utility under alternative ownership regimes. Since z = R in
a steady state, (7) implies that the only variable that can vary across
alternatives is D, the quality or accessibility of z.
A few stylized examples will make the model more concrete. In each
case increased use of the resource impairs its availability and
increases the cost of acquiring it. This increased cost, in turn,
rations use. For the fishery, z is catch, which serves as an input to
the production of food, q. Fishing inputs are vessel capital (k) and
labor (e). For mnemonic purposes, let D be the 'dispersion' of
the stock and let R be 'recruitment'. Fishing disperses the
stock, raising the effort required to make a given catch, and natural
growth replenishes it.
For application to groundwater, interpret z as water used to irrigate a farm output, q. Each grower uses a pump (k) and fuel to run the pump
(e) to acquire z. The accessibility of groundwater is determined by the
'depth' of the aquifer, D, and the greater the depth the
greater is the cost of pumping a unit of water to the surface. Depth is
increased by pumping and reduced by 'recharge', R, the natural
inflow of water.
A third example involves firms that withdraw water from a common
source, perhaps a lake, and return equal volumes of effluent to it.
Here, z is clean water needed to produce an output, q. Since water
obtained from the source is polluted it must be treated before use, and
k and e represent inputs used in treatment. The quality of the resource
is measured by D, an index of how 'dirty' the source of water
is, and the cost of treatment is positively related to D. Using more of
the lake's water results in increased emissions and increases in D.
The lake is capable of natural 'regeneration', however, which
cleanses it of R units of effluent per period.
While obviously simplified, the model captures a phenomenon that is
important for many actual resources. Use of a resource beyond some level
impairs its quality, making it more costly to acquire for those who use
it, and this cost, in turn, rations use.
III. STEADY-STATE WELFARE AND EXCESS DISSIPATION
The objectives of this section are twofold, to show how the degree of
rent dissipation under free access is related to the elasticity of the
cost function for acquiring the resource and to demonstrate that the
losses that result from free access can spread to related investments.
To examine the rent dissipation issue it is first necessary to determine
the rent the resource would earn with ownership. This rent is identified
by exploiting the fact that complete ownership results in an allocation
that maximizes the present value of utility. Attention is focused
exclusively on steady states to provide a clear exposition of the rent
dissipation issue.
The first step is to characterize the efficient steady-state
allocation. Starting in a steady state, consider a temporary departure
that marginally increases z in one period only. The consumer values the
temporary increase in z at [U.sub.z](z) - [h.sub.z](z)D. Temporarily
increasing z also increases D by f[prime](0), however, and this effect
persists in all future periods. The consequent increase in present value
extraction cost is h(R)f[prime](0)/r, where r is the rate of interest.
If the economy is in an efficient steady state, the marginal benefit and
marginal cost of temporarily increasing z are equal, which implies(8)
(8) [U.sub.z](R) - [h.sub.z](R)D = h(R)f[prime](0)/r.
Equation (8) implicitly gives the optimal steady-state value of D:
(9) D* = [[U.sub.2](R) - h(R)f[prime](0)/r]/[h.sub.2](R).
If the resource were owned and its flow sold competitively, the owner
would charge a price equal to the opportunity cost of withdrawing a
marginal unit. This opportunity cost is given by the right-hand side of
(8). With complete markets, then, the rent is [Rho]* = h(R)f[prime](0)/r
per unit z. Since the resource yields R units of z per year, its total
steady-state rent would be
(10) [Rho]*R = Rh(R)f[prime](0)/r
per year.
Absent ownership each individual considers the quality or
accessibility of the resource as fixed and chooses a level of z that
maximizes utility. The steady-state equilibrium with free access is thus
found by maximizing (7) with respect to z taking D as given and setting
z = R in the result. The first-order condition and steady-state D are
(11)[U.sub.z](R) - [h.sub.z](R)D = 0
(12)[D.sup.c]= [U.sub.z](R)/[h.sub.z](R).
Notice incidentally that (9) and (12) coincide if the interest rate
is infinite--in this case the free access solution is efficient.(9)
Steady-state welfare in the two ownership regimes can be obtained
from (7) by setting z=R and alternately substituting (9) and (12) for D.
Letting W* and [W.sup.c] denote steady-state welfare in the two regimes,
the dissipation due to free access is
(13) W* - [W.sup.c] = ([D.sup.c] - D*)h(R)
= [Rh(R)f[prime](0)/r][h(R)/R[h.sub.z](R)].
The first bracketed term is the steady-state rent the resource would
earn with complete markets. Let [Sigma][is equivalent
to]R[h.sub.z](R)/h(R) denote the output elasticity of the cost function
for acquiring z evaluated at the steady state, and note that convexity implies [Sigma][is greater than or equal to]1. Then (13) may be summed
up as follows.
PROPOSITION 1: The steady-state welfare loss that results from free
access use of the shared input is W* - [W.sup.c]= [Rho]*R/[Sigma], where
[Rho]*R is the steady-state rent the shared resource would earn with
complete markets and [Sigma] is the output elasticity of the cost
function for acquiring it.
This establishes the promised link between rent dissipation and the
elasticity of the cost function.(10)
Figure 1 illustrates the model and provides some intuition for the
preceding proposition. The downward sloping curve labeled private
marginal value is [U.sub.z], the marginal value product of z. The curve
labeled social marginal value is [U.sub.z] - hf[prime]/r, the marginal
value product of z less the associated opportunity cost of degrading the
resource. The upward sloping curves give marginal and average costs of z
for different values of D. If the resource were owned, the efficient
steady-state would be established with resource quality D*, which
equates the marginal cost of z to its social marginal value at z=R. The
resource earns a steady-state rent equal to area abcd.
If ownership were abolished and replaced by free access each
individual would rationally take D as given and choose z to equate marginal cost to private marginal value. Starting where D=D* this causes
withdrawal to exceed natural replenishment, so D increases and the
marginal cost schedule shifts up. The free access equilibrium is
established at point b, where D has risen to [D.sup.c] and the private
marginal benefit and marginal cost of z are equal at z = R.
When ownership is abolished, the amount by which marginal private
cost rises at z = R just equals the resource's rent. At the margin,
then, rent is exactly dissipated. Exact dissipation need not apply to
inframarginal units, however. Average dissipation equals the increase in
average cost at z=R, so total dissipation is the shaded area fghi. This
equals 1/[Sigma] times the complete markets rent.(11) If the unit cost
of z were constant ([Sigma] = 1) marginal and average cost would
increase by the same amount, eliminating the entire rent. Cost functions
with high values of [Sigma] exhibit steeply rising marginal costs and
small degrees of dissipation, and functions with low values, the
converse.
The discussion turns next to the question of how free access can
affect the return to related investments. Consider two kinds of costly
actions. The first kind reduces the marginal cost of acquiring the
resource. One specific example is effort spent inventing a more
efficient groundwater pump. Development of a new fishing method or a
sensing device that reduces the search cost needed to locate a stock of
fish is another. The per period amount spent on such actions is denoted
[Phi] and the effect on cost is captured by writing the cost function as
Dh(z, [Phi]), where [h.sub.[Phi]][h.sub.z[Phi]] [is less than] 0. The
second kind of action raises the marginal value product of z. An
investment that lowers the cost of transporting fish to market is one
example because it raises the value of fish at the dock. Another is a
farmland improvement that allows the production of crops irrigated by
groundwater. This second kind of action costs 0 per period and its
effect on demand for z is captured by writing U = U(z,[Theta]), where
[U.sub.[Theta]], [U.sub.z[Theta]] [is greater than or equal to] 0.
With these modifications utility becomes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Free access use of z implies [U.sub.z](z,[Theta]) = D[H.sub.z](z,
[Phi]), so steady-state D is
(15) D([Phi], [Theta]) = [U.sub.z](R,[Theta])[h.sub.z](R, [Phi]).
It can be verified that [Delta]D/[Delta][Theta] [is greater than or
equal to] 0 and [Delta]D/[Delta][Phi] [is greater than or equal to] 0,
so steady-state D increases if either action is taken. In words, actions
that either reduce the marginal cost or raise the marginal value of the
unowned resource intensify competition for it and further degrade its
quality.
To determine the size of such effects consider a cost reducing action
first and let [W.sup.[Phi]] and [D.sup.[Phi]] be the corresponding
steady-state utility and resource quality with free access. Using
superscript c to denote free access values without the action, the
steady-state net return to [Phi] is
(16) [W.sup.[Phi]] - [W.sup.c] = [D.sup.c]h(R) -
[D.sup.[Phi]]h(r,[Phi]) - [Phi].
Using (12) and (13) this can be written
(17) [W.sup.[Phi]] - [W.sup.c] = [U.sub.z](R){[h(R)/[h.sub.z](R)]
-[h(R, [Phi])/[h.sub.z](R, [Phi])]} - [Phi]
= R[U.sub.z](R)[(1/[Sigma]) - (1/[[Sigma].sup.[Phi]])] - [Phi],
where [[Sigma].sup.[Phi]] is the elasticity of the cost function
given the action [Phi], evaluated at z = R. The return to action [Phi]
under free access can now be summarized as follows.
PROPOSITION 2: Let [Phi] be expenditure on an action that lowers the
marginal cost of acquiring the shared resource. The steady-state gross
return to this action is zero unless the action changes the elasticity
of the total cost function, evaluated at z = R. If the elasticity is
changed by the action, then the gross return to [Phi] is positive if the
elasticity rises and negative if it falls.
When action [Phi] is available, the loss due to free access can
exceed the rent the resource would earn with complete markets, a
phenomenon termed excess dissipation. If the resource were owned it
would earn [Rho]*R per period. Suppose, instead, that it is allocated by
free access and that [Sigma] = 1, but action [Phi] is not available. By
Proposition 1 the rent [Rho]*R is exactly dissipated. If action [Phi]
then becomes available and the elasticity of total cost is unchanged,
steady-state utility falls by [Phi] as Proposition 2 states. In total,
the loss due to free access exceeds, by [Phi], the rent the resource
would earn if owned.(12) The action temporarily earns a positive return
during the transition between old and new steady states, but this return
necessarily vanishes in the long run.
If [Phi] changes cost elasticity, its steady-state gross return will
either be positive or negative. There is no compelling reason to expect
[Sigma] to change one way or the other, however, and under fairly weak
conditions it necessarily remains constant. For example, if the
production function for acquiring the resource is homothetic then the
cost function takes the form C = Df([p.sub.e], [p.sub.k])m(z), where
m([center dot]) is a monotone increasing function. In this case actions
that reduce input prices [p.sub.e] and [p.sub.k] have no effect on
[Sigma]. Investments that yield Hicks-neutral technological improvements
also leave [Sigma] unchanged in this case.(13)
While the return to action [Phi] either partially or completely
vanishes in the long run, it is important to note that the individual
was not myopic in pursuing it and would not choose to undo the action
once the new equilibrium is reached. To the individual, who properly
takes D as given, some positive expenditure on action [Phi] is rational
so long as [Delta]W/[Delta][Phi] [is greater than] 0 when evaluated at
the free access steady state. This condition is met if
(18) -[D.sup.c][h.sub.[Phi]](R,0) [is greater than] 1,
and nothing in the model rules this out.(14) When undertaken such
actions cause D to increase and steady-state utility to fall. The
individual has no incentive to undo the action when the new equilibrium
is reached, however. Rather, condition (18) is more likely to be met
after D has been raised by the action, that is, [Phi] looks more
attractive in hindsight than it did when first considered.
Figure 2 illustrates the intuition of Proposition 2 for the case
where the shared resource is acquired at constant cost. The free access
equilibrium without [Phi] occurs at point a, with D = [D.sup.c]. The
marginal cost of z is MC([D.sup.c], 0), which just equals its private
marginal value at z = R. A device is then invented that costs [Phi] per
period and lowers the marginal and average cost of acquiring z. Given
[D.sup.c], marginal cost falls to MC([D.sup.c], [Phi]) and the
individual who adopts the device stands to gain a per period amount
equal to the shaded area less [Phi]. Assume this is positive so the
device is adopted. The lower marginal cost is not sustainable because
use of the resource exceeds natural replenishment. This causes D to
increase and marginal cost to shift up. In the new equilibrium D =
[D.sup.[Phi]] so marginal cost, now MC([D.sup.[Phi]], [Phi]), again
limits use of z to R. The long-run gross return to adopting the device
is zero, so steady-state utility is reduced by [Phi].
Turning next to an action that raises the private marginal value of
z, let [W.sup.[Theta]] and [D.sup.[Theta]] denote steady-state utility
and resource quality under free access if action [Theta] is undertaken.
The action's steady-state net return is
(19) [W.sup.[Theta]] - [W.sup.c] = {[U(R, [Theta] -
[D.sup.[Theta]]h(R)] - [U(R) - [D.sup.c]h(R)]} - [Theta] ={U(R, [Theta])
- [R[U.sub.z](R, [Theta])/[Sigma]]} -{U(R) - [R[U.sub.z](R)/[Sigma])]} -
[Theta]
where (12) and (15) have been used. A useful way to express this is
(20) [W.sup.[Theta]] - [W.sup.c] = R{[U(R, [Theta]) - U(R)/[Sigma]
-[[U.sub.z](R, [Theta]) - [U.sub.z](R)]/[Sigma]} - [Theta].
The expression in brackets {[center dot]} is the gross return per
unit z to action [Theta], and it can be explained as follows. The action
raises the value of output, and the size of the increase per unit z is
the increase in average value product. This increase is the first
fraction in brackets. The action also raises the marginal value product
of z, however, and this causes competition for z to intensify and D to
rise. The cost of this competition is greater the greater is the
increase in the marginal value product of z, and the smaller is the
elasticity of the cost function for acquiring z. The second fraction in
brackets gives the steady-state cost of this increased competition.
Recalling that [Sigma] [is greater than or equal to] 1, the gross return
is necessarily positive if average value product rises more than
marginal value product.
The net return can also be written
(21) [W.sup.[Theta]] - [W.sup.c] = U(R, [Theta]) {1 -
[[Eta].sup.[Theta]]/[Sigma]]} - U(R){1 - [[Eta]/[Sigma]]} - [Theta],
where [Eta] and [[Eta].sup.[Theta]] are elasticities of U(z) and U(z,
[Theta]) with respect to z, evaluated at z = R. Concavity and convexity
assumptions guarantee 0 [is less than or equal to] [Eta]/[Sigma] [is
less than or equal to] 1 and 0 [is less than or equal to]
[[Eta].sup.[Theta]]/[Sigma] [is less than or equal to] 1. In some
instances [Theta] may shift U([center dot]) without changing its
elasticity at z = R. (This is necessarily true if the effect of [Theta]
is multiplicative, i.e., if U(z, [Theta]) = g([Theta])U(z).) In this
case (21) takes a simple form and can be interpreted as follows.
PROPOSITION 3: Let [Theta] be expenditure on an action that raises
the total and marginal value product of a free access resource, z. If
the action does not change [Eta], the elasticity of U([center dot])
evaluated at z = R, then the net return to [Theta] is [W.sup.[Theta]] -
[W.sup.c] = [U(R, [Theta]) - U(R)][1 - ([Eta]/[Sigma])] - [Theta]. This
return approaches the limiting value of -[Theta], indicating complete
dissipation, as [Eta]/[Sigma] approaches 1. This is the case of constant
cost and constant marginal value product of z. Alternatively, the return
approaches the limiting value of U(R, [Theta]) - U(R) - [Theta], or no
dissipation, as [Eta]/[Sigma] approaches 0. The zero dissipation limit
is approached if the marginal cost schedule is nearly vertical or the
total value product schedule is relatively flat, when evaluated at z =
R.
No figure is presented to illustrate this result, although the effect
is easily visualized. Starting from the free access equilibrium where
private marginal value equals marginal cost and D = [D.sup.c], action
[Theta] raises the private marginal value schedule. If D remained fixed
the value of the action would equal the increase in area under the
private marginal value schedule for z [is less than or equal to] R. The
increase in marginal value causes z to rise above R, however, so D
increases and the marginal cost schedule shifts up. This process stops
only when D has risen to [D.sup.[Theta]] where marginal cost equals the
new private marginal value schedule at z = R. This cost increase
eliminates at least part of the value [Theta] would otherwise earn.
IV. EXAMPLES AND EVIDENCE
Four practical examples involving groundwater are used to illustrate
the finding that privately rational actions can be socially
self-defeating if they intensify competition for a shared resource. The
first two examples are cost reducing: improvements in groundwater
pumping technology and investments in water conserving irrigation systems. The next two examples involve increased marginal values:
changes in irrigation technology and increased prices for surface water.
Before proceeding, a brief comment on groundwater institutions and
the applicability of the model is in order. In this paper free access is
defined to exist when any user can pump as much water as he or she
wishes, without quantitative restrictions or controls on the method of
withdrawal. Among the legal doctrines applied to groundwater, this most
closely resembles 'absolute ownership'. As described by
Tarlock [1989, 4.04] and Aiken [1980, 923-24], absolute ownership
applies the rule of capture to groundwater and anyone owning a parcel of
land overlying an aquifer is eligible to participate. Absolute ownership
was inherited from the English common law and is still in general use in
the U.K. Most arid states in the U.S. have departed from it to varying
degrees, although it is still practiced in Texas. Outside of the west,
absolute ownership is more common; Connecticut, Louisiana, Maine, Rhode
Island, and Indiana still practice it.
The doctrine of 'beneficial use' is a modified rule of
capture. Tarlock [1989, 4.05] and Aiken [1980, 924-25] explain that it
limits the use of water to applications on land overlying the aquifer
and prohibits patently wasteful or malicious uses. The uses described in
the stylized model of this paper would not be judged per se
'unreasonable' by these criteria, so the model is generally
applicable in areas where this doctrine is applied. This includes the
states of Alabama, Florida, Kentucky, Maryland, New York, North
Carolina, Tennessee, Illinois, and Oklahoma. In addition, Nebraska and
Arizona apply reasonable use outside of specially designated groundwater
management areas.(15)
'Prior appropriation', the other major doctrine, is the
most common rule applied in western states. Under prior appropriation a
right to withdraw water from an aquifer is established when a permit is
granted by the relevant government agency and water is actually
withdrawn and used, as Aiken [1980, 926-27] explains. Whether states
practicing this doctrine are subject to the rent dissipation
characterized in the model depends on how the appropriation rule is
applied. If the courts interpret such rights quantitatively, and either
limit use efficiently or assess damages accurately, the result will
approximate the complete markets outcome.(16) While the degree to which
this occurs is not known exactly, correct assessment of damages seems
unlikely and quantitative limits on use are not the general rule in
practice. For correct damage assessment, a pumper withdrawing an acre
foot of water must be liable for damages equal to the present value of
all future pumping cost increases imposed on other users--and the charge
must be assessed on each acre foot withdrawn. At a minimum this would
require knowledge of how much is withdrawn by individual users. By
contrast, Bowman's [1990] survey of groundwater policy in the U.S.
identified only twenty states in which governments even collect
information on water use, either by metering or self-reporting, and
fewer yet that place any quantitative controls on amounts withdrawn.
Absent quantitative limits on amounts used or accurate damage
assessments, the value of groundwater in situ will not be a part of the
opportunity cost faced by the individual user. If the user faces no
charge, explicit or implicit, the free access model portrayed earlier
applies.
With these qualifications, then, groundwater appears an appropriate
vehicle for illustrating the model's implications.
Pumping Technology, Pumping Costs and Groundwater Levels
The model predicts that improvements in pumping technology or
reductions in prices of pumping inputs will increase the depth to water,
dissipating at least part of the return that would otherwise result.
There is much evidence in agreement with this prediction.(17) The
deep-well turbine pump was introduced for use in irrigation in the
1920s. Andrews and Fairfax [1984, 164, 165, 170], Dunbar [1977, 663;
1983, 153], and California Department of Water Resources [1982, xix, 9,
28] all implicate this innovation, together with other technical
improvements and declining energy prices, for the rapid growth in
groundwater use and consequent decline in water levels that occurred
after 1930 in Texas, California, and other parts of the western U.S.
Prior to 1930 the use of groundwater for irrigation was negligible. By
1945 groundwater accounted for 21 percent of all water used for
irrigation and by 1975 the share had risen to 39 percent, as Frederick
[1982, 71-73] notes. This growth was accompanied by a general decline in
water levels. Cooper [1968, 116] reports reductions as great as ten to
thirty-five feet per year in some parts of California. Mapp and Eidman
[1976, 9] report that water levels fell 2.06-3.6 feet per year in the
central basin of the Ogallala formation during the 1960s and 1970s.
Martin and Archer [1971] compiled data on pumping costs and
groundwater levels in Arizona between 1891 and 1967 and Figure 3
displays some of this information. The scale on the vertical axis is for
the pumping cost per unit lift, expressed in 1967 cents per acre foot of
water, per foot of lift.(18) Prior to 1920 the power sources used were
varied and often primitive, involving mules in some cases, and pumping
cost data for these years are unreliable. Prices of energy and pumping
units fell dramatically after about 1920 while the durability and
reliability of pumps increased, as Martin and Archer [1971, 27] explain.
This is reflected in the steady reduction in pumping cost per unit lift,
from $.20 per foot in 1925 to less than $.04 in 1967.
Mean depth levels rose rapidly, from 55 feet in 1925 to about 350
feet by 1967. Since the increase in depth approximately canceled the
reduction in cost per unit lift, the pumping cost per unit water (the
product of depth and pumping cost per unit lift) remained roughly
constant. Aside from a jump in the early 1940s, it only varied from
$11-$14 per acre foot.(19) In summary, the decline in water levels and
pumping cost per unit lift, at the same time and approximately the same
rate, clearly agrees with the model's prediction.(20)
Conserving Water Lost in Conveyance and Application
Only a fraction of the water pumped from an aquifer for irrigation
actually is consumed by crops. For the nation as a whole the U.S. Soil
Conservation Service [1976, 13, 14] estimates that about 59 percent of
the water pumped from aquifers and diverted from streams is lost to
seepage back into aquifers and rivers, evaporation, and consumption by
unwanted flora and fauna. These losses can be cut substantially by
investing in water-conserving systems for conveying water on the farm
and applying it to crops. The following discussion evaluates such
investments.(21)
One leading conservation strategy is replacement of unlined
distribution ditches with lined channels or pipes. A second is
installation of tail-water recovery systems. Some of the water applied
using furrow irrigation collects in pools at the ends of furrows and is
lost to evaporation or percolation into the ground. Installation of
pumps and pumping equipment allows the farmer to recover and reapply this water. Land leveling is a third method, since it reduces runoff and
prevents irrigation water from pooling on the land where it can
evaporate or seep back into the ground. Where the irrigation source is
groundwater, most of the water saved would otherwise percolate back to
the aquifer.
The model must be modified slightly to evaluate such actions. Let
[Mu] denote the fraction of pumped groundwater that the crop consumes.
Since the level of farm output depends on water consumption, utility is
U([Mu]z) + x. The pumping cost function is unchanged. Let [Pi] represent
the per period cost of the system that distributes water and applies it
to crops. With these modifications, welfare is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Next, assume the water lost in distribution, (1-[Mu])z, percolates
into the soil and eventually re-enters the aquifer.(22) Since this
return flow is an additional source of recharge, the equation governing
D becomes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Thus, when return flow is allowed, changes in depth are determined by
water consumption rather than the rate of withdrawal and the
steady-state condition becomes [Mu]z = R.
Suppose there are several ways to distribute irrigation water from
the well to the field, indexed by i. An alternative with a high [Mu] is
a water-conserving strategy and is relatively costly, so [[Pi].sub.i]
and [[Mu].sub.i] are positively related. Given any distribution system,
the farmer chooses an extraction rate that maximizes utility given D.
This implies U[prime]([[Mu].sub.i]z)[[Mu].sub.i] = D[h.sub.z](z), or
(24) U[prime]([[Mu].sub.i]z) = D[h.sub.z](z)/[[Mu].sub.i]
under alternative i, where U[prime] is the first derivative of
U([[Mu].sub.i]z). This condition requires equality between the marginal
benefit and marginal cost of water consumed by the crop.
Evaluating (24) at the steady-state where [[Mu].sub.i]z = R gives the
steady-state depth in implicit form. Substituting this into (22) yields
the following expression for steady-state utility.
(25) [Mathematical Expression Omitted], or [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]
where [[Sigma].sup.[Mu]] is the elasticity of the cost function
evaluated at the steady state. If the cost elasticity is independent of
the pumping rate then it is also independent of [Mu]. This, in turn,
implies that equilibrium welfare is independent of [Mu], the fraction of
pumped water that is consumed by the crop. In this case the gross return
to an investment that improves the system's effectiveness in
conserving water is zero in the long run, so the net return is
-[[Pi].sub.i]. If [Sigma] varies with the pumping rate, the gross social
return to such investments may be positive or negative.
The intuition of this result can be grasped by imagining an aquifer
with a distribution system so leaky that two units of water are pumped
for each unit consumed by the crop. In long-run equilibrium the marginal
cost of an acre foot of water consumed by the crop equals the marginal
cost of pumping two acre feet out of the ground. If this system were
replaced by one that eliminated distribution losses, the cost of water
applied to the crop would fall by half even though the cost of pumping
is not changed. Given the initial depth farmers would choose to increase
water consumption, causing D to increase until the marginal cost of
water consumed rises to its former level.
During the 1970s the U.S. government undertook a major effort to
identify and evaluate strategies for reducing losses of irrigation water
in distribution and conveyance. A federal interagency task force of the
U.S. Department of the Interior [1979] identified strategies such as
lining distribution ditches, tailwater recovery, and land leveling and
estimated that $14.6 billion (1977 dollars) would be needed to install
state-of-the-art measures.(23) The report estimated that these measures
would save 38.6 million acre feet of water per year. Of this total,
however, true losses to the system due to evaporation, consumption by
unwanted plants, and so forth, amounted to only 3.3 million acre feet,
or about 8.5 percent of the estimated gross saving. The balance, 35.3
million acre feet, would have returned to aquifers in the absence of
conservation measures. Irrigation water that percolates back into an
aquifer must, of course, be lifted to the surface again before it can be
used and this requires the expenditure of energy. As described by the
U.S. Department of the Interior [1979, 95], the proposed investments
would have reduced re-pumping and an anticipated energy saving was the
primary benefit attributed to the project. Reducing the cost of water
available for consumption by crops causes users to increase consumption,
however, and the water level to decline. In the long run the apparent
energy saving that water conservation yields by avoiding re-pumping is
dissipated by an increase in the distance that each unit of groundwater
consumed is lifted.
Although the long-run social return to such investments is zero, they
may well pass a private benefit cost test and hence be undertaken. The
individual's incentive to conserve water, to prevent it from
percolating back into the aquifer, is socially excessive. Any water that
seeps away truly is lost to the farmer who pumped it, but it remains
valuable to the community because it eventually will be available for
reuse. Hence, the private benefit to conserving water exceeds the social
benefit.(24) A similar conclusion applies to the fishery. When the net
is being hauled the individual fisher's incentive to prevent fish
from escaping is excessive from a social perspective, since some of
those that escape will eventually be caught by someone else.
Development of Improved Irrigation Technologies and Rural
Transportation Systems
To illustrate actions that intensify competition and cause
dissipation by raising demand for z, consider improvements in irrigation
technology. In 1949 Frank Zybach of Columbus, Nebraska developed the
center pivot sprinkler, an innovation that eventually revolutionized
irrigation in the Midwest. As Aiken [1980, 949-58] explains, this capped
a decade of sprinkler technology development that led to extensive
application in the 1950s. Before sprinklers, irrigation was by gravity
methods and worked only on level land. The new technologies allowed use
of rougher land without costly leveling operations and increased the
demand for groundwater and surface water.
Evidence compiled by Aiken [1980, 949-58] indicates how this
increased competition for groundwater and led to greater depths.
Following the introduction of early sprinkler irrigation, the number of
irrigation wells installed in Nebraska during the 1950s was four times
higher than in the preceding decade and the number of acres irrigated
with groundwater rose from 500,000 to two million. The center pivot
technology began widespread application in the 1960s and the acreage
irrigated by groundwater rose again, to over 3.5 million acres in
Nebraska. Spurred partly by these developments and partly by high farm
prices, the acreage irrigated by groundwater continued to rise through
the early 1970s, reaching 7.4 million acres, or almost fifteen times the
acreage involved in 1950. The consequent decline in groundwater levels
was sufficient to spur some changes in regulation of groundwater use.
Aiken [1980, 957] notes, however, that most parts of the state still do
not place quantitative limits on amounts used by individuals.
A similar analysis applies to the development of rural transportation
systems. The farmer must transport the crop from the field to the point
of final consumption. The per unit transport cost acts much like a tax
on the final product, and it can be avoided or reduced by improving a
road, buying a new truck, and so forth. Each such investment involves a
per period cost and, in return, reduces transport costs. Reducing the
transport cost raises the net price received for the crop, however, and
thereby raises the derived demand for groundwater. Water use increases,
D increases, and marginal cost shifts up until it intersects the new
higher derived demand schedule at z = R. Part of the return the improved
transport system would otherwise earn is thereby dissipated. These
actions will, of course, earn temporary returns during the transition
between pre-investment and post-investment steady-states, and the period
involved may be long in some instances.
Pricing Surface Water at Marginal Cost
The final example illustrates a completely different kind of
demand-increasing action. Irrigation water often can be obtained from
both ground and surface sources. Assume this is the case and that the
two are perfect substitutes. Absent distortions elsewhere in the
economy, efficiency in the allocation of resources requires that surface
water be priced at its marginal cost. In practice, however, surface
water usually is offered to irrigators at a price below marginal
cost.(25) Suppose this is true here and that farmers are allowed to
purchase as much surface water as desired at price [Mathematical
Expression Omitted].
One might anticipate a welfare gain from raising the price of surface
water to equal its marginal cost. Groundwater and surface water are
perfect substitutes, however, so raising the surface water price shifts
up the demand for groundwater and increases the rate of withdrawal.
Starting from a free access steady state this increases D and marginal
cost shifts up. Equilibrium is re-established only when the depth to
water has increased to a point where the marginal cost of pumping R
units equals the higher price of surface water. The steady-state total
cost of pumping groundwater is increased as a result, eliminating at
least part of the welfare gain expected from 'correctly'
pricing surface water.
Figure 4 illustrates this example. The private marginal value of
water is downward sloping and depends on the sum of ground and surface
water use, [z.sub.g] + [z.sub.s]. Surface water is initially priced at
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The marginal cost of surface water is
MCS and is assumed constant. Given any D, the unit cost of pumping
groundwater is assumed constant. Two conditions describe 'a
steady-state equilibrium. First, farmers are indifferent between a
marginal unit of water obtained from either source, which implies
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [D.sup.0] is the depth to
groundwater in the initial equilibrium. Second, groundwater consumption
equals natural recharge, R. Thus the use and marginal cost of
groundwater in the initial equilibrium are indicated by point a, and
total water use is shown by
point b.
Absent distortions elsewhere one would anticipate a welfare gain
equal to area A from raising the price of surface water to [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], its marginal cost. The two sources of water are
perfect substitutes, however, so the demand for groundwater is perfectly
elastic at the price charged for surface water. Increasing the surface
water price from [Mathematical Expression Omitted] to [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] raises groundwater consumption above R causing D to
increase. Groundwater use in the new equilibrium is at point c, where
the depth to water has risen to [D.sup.1] and marginal cost is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The increase in steady-state pumping
cost equals area B and the change in welfare from pricing surface water
at marginal cost is A-B, which may be either positive or negative. In
summary, pricing surface water at marginal cost is not optimal when
irrigators have access to both surface water and unowned
ground-water.(26)
V. THE VALUE OF SECOND-BEST REGULATION
Proposition 1 stated that the rent dissipation caused by free access
is inversely proportional to [Zigma], the elasticity of cost with
respect to z. This suggests that those who use the resource might gain
by agreeing to a regulation that causes this elasticity to increase.
This can be accomplished by fixing some of the inputs used to acquire
the resource--in effect, forcing users to operate along a relatively
steep 'short-run' marginal cost schedule. This is formalized in what follows by assuming k can be regulated but e cannot. Actual
regulation of resource use often works in just this way. In a fishery it
is common to limit the number of vessels (k) but not the number of days
each operates (e). With groundwater, the number of wells permitted is
often limited (k), but not the rate at which each pumps (e). Regulation
may take this form because k is easier to observe and control than e.
Clearly, controlling both k and e would be equivalent to exercising
control over z directly.
The analysis starts by deriving a short-run or 'restricted'
cost function with k fixed and examining when a marginal reduction in k
will improve resource quality and raise welfare. The technology for
acquiring z is hereafter assumed to be linearly homogeneous. This
implies f(e/D, k/D) = f(e,k)/D = z, which can be inverted to obtain the
input requirement function e = e(k,zD). The restricted cost function for
z, given fixed k, can now be written as [p.sub.k]k + [p.sub.e] e(k,zD).
Choosing units so that [p.sub.e] = 1, this is written [p.sub.k]k +
V(k,zD), where V([center dot]) is variable cost. Given that the marginal
productivities of e and k in acquiring z are positive and diminishing,
one can verify that [V.sub.k] [is less than] 0 and [V.sub.z], [V.sub.zz]
[is greater than] 0, where [V.sub.z] denotes the partial derivative of
V([center dot]) with respect to its second argument.
For given k, utility is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and free access use of z implies
(27) [U.sub.z](z) = [V.sub.z](k,zD)D.
Setting z=R in (27) gives D(k), the steady-state quality of the
resource as a function of k, in implicit form: [U.sub.z](R) =
[V.sub.z](k,RD(k)) D(K). Differentiating with respect to k yields
(28) [[V.sub.z](k,RD) + RD[V.sub.zz](k,RD)]dD/dk + D[V.sub.zk](k,RD)
= 0.
This implies that dD/dk and [V.sub.zk] have opposite signs. It can be
verified that [V.sub.zk] [is less than] 0 unless k is an inferior input,
and inferior inputs have been ruled out by assuming f(e,k) to be
linearly homogeneous. Hence dK/dk [is less than] 0, which is summed up
as follows.
PROPOSITION 4. Let k be the regulated level of an input used to
acquire the shared resource. Starting from a steady-state equilibrium in
which all inputs are unregulated, a marginal reduction in k improves the
steady-state quality or accessibility of the resource.
One can now derive the welfare effect of a marginal reduction in k
evaluated at the unregulated equilibrium. Set z = R in (26) and
differentiate with respect to k:
(29) dW/dk = -[p.sub.k] - [V.sub.k](k,RD) - [V.sub.z](k,RD)RdD/dk =
-[V.sub.z](k,RD)RdD/dk,
since -[p.sub.k] - [V.sub.k](k,zD)=0 in the unregulated equilibrium.
Recalling [V.sub.z] [is greater than] 0, as well as Proposition 4, this
result can be described as follows.
PROPOSITION 5. Let k be the regulated level of an input used to
acquire the shared resource. Starting from a steady state in which all
inputs are unregulated, a marginal reduction in k raises steady-state
utility.
Figure 5 illustrates the way regulation works. The unregulated
equilibrium is at point a. The horizontal line MC([D.sup.c]) is marginal
cost and [D.sup.c] is the equilibrium quality or accessibility of the
resource, absent regulation. A regulation is imposed that fixes capital
at [k.sup.r], below the level used without regulation. Given [D.sup.c]
the effect is to make marginal cost less elastic and to shift it
leftward to MC([k.sup.r][D.sup.c]). The immediate outcome is at point b.
Since z is less than R, D falls and marginal cost declines. The
regulated equilibrium is established at point a, when D has fallen to
[D.sup.r].
The quality of the resource in the regulated equilibrium is improved
to [D.sup.r] [is less than] [D.sup.c], in keeping with Proposition 4. It
is not clear from the figure whether total cost has been raised or
lowered by the regulation. While the area under MC([D.sup.c]) is
expenditure on e and k, the area under MC([k.sup.r], [D.sup.r]) is
expenditure on e alone because expenditure on k is a fixed cost.
Proposition 5 guarantees, however, that a marginal reduction in k lowers
total cost and raises welfare.(27)
Given that utility generally can be raised by restricting an input
needed to acquire the resource, it is natural to ask how large such
gains might be. The following analysis shows that the size of the gain
and the k constraint that achieves it depend on the shape of the
production function for acquiring z because this is what determines the
elasticity of the restricted cost function, and on the relative prices
of constrained and unconstrained inputs.
The general second-best problem of finding a k regulation policy that
maximizes the present value of utility is beyond the scope of this
paper, but the issues involved can be illuminated by solving a related
problem--choosing a k constraint that maximizes steady-state utility.
The first-best solution to this problem involves setting D as small as
possible and attains utility [Mathematical Expression Omitted], where
[Delta] is a physically determined lower limit on D.(28) Absent a
positive lower bound on D, extraction cost would be zero for an
unexploited resource, a feature that does not appear to characterize
actual resources of any importance. For simplicity in describing the
results obtained, the lower bound is taken to be arbitrarily small in
what follows, although the reader can substitute different values and
obtain more general results. With [Delta] arbitrarily small, the
steady-state utility attainable from controlling z directly is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], and in what follows this is compared
to steady-state utilities attainable by controlling k alone. The
technology for acquiring the resource is assumed to be CES and the text
illustrates three special cases, the Cobb-Douglas, Leontief, and linear
technologies. A general treatment appears in the appendix.
If the elasticity of substitution is unity, the production function
takes the Cobb-Douglas form, z = [e.sup.[Alpha]][k.sup.1-[Alpha]]. Let
[k.sup.r] be the constrained level of k. The restricted total and
marginal cost functions in this case are:
(30) C = [p.sub.e][([k.sup.r]).sup.1-[Gamma]][(zD).sup.[Gamma]] +
[p.sub.k][k.sup.r],
(31) [C.sub.z] = [Gamma][p.sub.e][([k.sup.r]).sup.1-[Gamma]][(zD).sup.[Gamma]-1]D,
where [Gamma] = 1/[Alpha]. Notice that these functions are defined
only if [k.sup.r] [is greater than] 0.
Steady-state D is established where [U.sub.z](R) = [C.sub.z]R. Making
this substitution and solving for D yields [D.sup.c]([k.sup.r]) =
[{[U.sub.z](R) [([k.sup.r]/R).sup.[Gamma]-1]/[Gamma][p.sub.e]}.sup.1/[Gamma]]. Substituting [D.sup.c]([k.sup.r]) into the cost function, the
equilibrium value of total cost is R[U.sub.z](R)/[Gamma] +
[p.sub.k][k.sup.r] and steady-state utility is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Setting [k.sup.r] arbitrarily small maximizes steady-state utility
and in the limit attains(29)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The shared resource would earn the rent R[U.sub.z](R) with complete
markets, and (33) indicates that the share [Alpha] is dissipated under
second-best regulation.(30) Equivalently, the share that is captured
(not dissipated) equals (1-[Alpha]), the share of total cost that would
be spent on k in the unregulated equilibrium. In the Cobb-Douglas case,
then, the steady-state welfare gain from second-best regulation of an
input is equal to the unregulated expenditure on that input. This result
clearly extends to cases where several inputs are used to obtain the
resource and more than one can be controlled.
Consider, next, the Leontief case where the elasticity of
substitution is zero. Intuitively, controlling a single input allows one
to control both since inputs are used in fixed proportions, so
controlling k alone should suffice to maximize steady-state utility. The
following analysis shows that this is true.
The production function in this case is z = min(e, k)/D. Setting
k=[k.sup.r] results in a marginal cost function that is horizontal at
[p.sub.e]D per unit for the first [k.sub.r]/D units of z and then
vertical. If D rises, this schedule shifts upward and to the left, and
conversely if D falls. Given [k.sub.r], D is in a steady-state
equilibrium when the vertical segment of marginal cost crosses the
marginal value schedule at z=R. This implies R=[k.sup.r]/D, or
RD=[k.sup.r]. Since e and k are used in fixed proportions, total cost is
([p.sub.e] + [p.sub.k])[k.sup.r]. Accordingly, steady-state welfare is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
which is maximized by setting [k.sup.r], and hence D, as small as
possible. In the limit utility is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
In the Leontief case controlling k alone preserves the
resource's entire rent--no dissipation occurs. The appendix shows
that this zero dissipation result extends to any elasticity of
substitution less than unity. In all such cases the regulated input is
essential in that a specific minimum level is needed to obtain a given
value of zD. By setting [k.sup.r] appropriately, the marginal cost
schedule can be made to approximate the schedule for the Leontief
technology.(31)
If the elasticity of substitution is infinite, the technology is
linear: z=(e+k)/D. Regulating k clearly accomplishes nothing if
[p.sub.k] [is less than] [p.sub.e], since only the cheaper of the two
inputs will be used. In this case exact dissipation occurs--total cost
equals RU[prime](R), the resource's entire rent.
Assume, therefore, that [p.sub.k] [is less than] [p.sub.e]. With k =
[k.sup.r] capital expenditure is a fixed cost and the marginal cost of z
is a step function. Given D, marginal cost is zero for the first
[k.sup.r]/D units and is constant at [p.sub.e]D thereafter, and the
vertical segment is a discontinuity. Since [p.sub.e] [is greater than]
[p.sub.k] it is socially desirable to avoid using e in the steady state.
An equilibrium in which k alone is used must satisfy two conditions. The
first is [k.sup.r]/D = R, which ensures that k is large enough to obtain
R units of the resource. The second is [p.sub.e]D [is greater than or
equal to] [U.sub.z](R), which implies that the marginal cost of
obtaining additional units of z by using e is at least as great as the
marginal value of z. This guarantees that resource users have no
incentive to use input e in the steady state. The first condition
implies the steady-state cost level [p.sub.k][k.sup.r] = [p.sub.k]RD, so
minimizing cost is equivalent to minimizing D. The second condition
implies that the minimum sustainable value of D is [D.sup.r] =
[U.sub.z](R)/[p.sub.e].
Combining these results, the optimal capital regulation is [k.sup.r]
= R[D.sup.r] = R[U.sub.z](R)/[p.sub.e] and the minimum steady-state cost
is ([p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e])R[U.sub.z](R). Recalling that exact dissipation
results if [p.sub.e] [is less than] [p.sub.k], second-best regulation
attains welfare
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
in the steady state.
Figure 6 illustrates this case. The marginal cost curve under the
optimal policy is abcd. Expenditure on [k.sup.r] is a fixed cost given
that k is constrained. Its magnitude is shown as the diagonally lined
area. The amount of rent captured (not dissipated) is shaded.(32)
This figure illustrates for a special case the way that second-best
regulation of k works more generally. Absent regulation, marginal cost
would be horizontal with equilibrium established at point c. In the
unregulated equilibrium both inputs earn only their opportunity costs,
[p.sub.e] and [p.sub.k], and the rent the resource would earn if owned
is exactly dissipated. Fixing k alters the shape of the marginal cost
function, forcing users onto a restricted marginal cost schedule that is
less elastic than the unregulated schedule. The constrained input, k,
then earns a rent, the shaded area, that partially offsets the rent the
common property input would earn with complete markets. In effect,
second-best regulation works by transferring some or all of the rent the
resource would earn if owned to the regulated input.
The appendix presents more general results on second-best regulation
with the CES technology. These results can be summed up as follows.
PROPOSITION 6. Let [k.sup.r] be the regulated level of an input used
to acquire the shared resource and let the goal of second-best
regulation be maximization of steady-state utility. Assume the
technology exhibits constant elasticity of substitution, [Sigma], and
that D can be made arbitrarily small.
a. If [Sigma] [is less than] 1 the second-best policy sets [k.sup.r]
arbitrarily small and achieves the welfare level attainable with
complete markets.
b. If [Sigma] = 1 the second-best policy sets [k.sup.r] arbitrarily
small and raises welfare by an amount that equals expenditure on k in
the unregulated equilibrium.
c. If [Sigma] [is greater than] 1 both the second-best capital
constraint and the second-best welfare level depend on [Sigma] and
[p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e], i.e., [k.sup.r]=[k.sup.r] ([Sigma],
[p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e]) and W = W([Sigma], [p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e]). Given
[Sigma], both [k.sup.r] and W are decreasing in [p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e].
Given [p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e], [k.sup.r] is single-peaked and W is U-shaped
when plotted as functions of [Sigma].
d. If the extraction technology is linear and [p.sub.k] [is less
than] [p.sub.e] the second-best policy sets [k.sup.r] = R[U.sub.z](R)
/[p.sub.e] and captures the fraction (1 -[p.sub.k]/[p.sub.e]) of the
shared resource's complete markets rent.
A common sense interpretation of Proposition 6 runs as follows. The
benefit of constraining k lies in the fact that it limits competition
for z by making the cost schedule for acquiring it less elastic. Loosely
speaking, the degree of cost inelasticity achieved for a given k
constraint is greater when the elasticity of substitution between
controlled and uncontrolled inputs is low than when it is high.
Constraining k also has a cost, however; it distorts the mix of inputs
used so the cost of obtaining a given z is not minimized. When [Sigma]
[is less than] 1 the benefit of limiting k dominates, and in the
stylized model examined here maximum steady-state utility is attained.
If [Sigma] [is greater than or equal to] 1, however, the regulated input
is nonessential and the efficacy of a capital constraint in limiting
competition for z and raising welfare falls discontinuously. In such
cases substantial dissipation can persist even when the capital
constraint is optimized and the amount lost depends on the exact level
of [Sigma] and on the relative prices of controlled and uncontrolled
inputs. The appendix illustrates these relationships graphically.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
The act of withdrawing an acre foot of groundwater from an aquifer is
a transaction. Lifting it to the surface transforms it from a shared
resource, accessible to anyone who owns a parcel of land and requisite
pumping equipment, into property, a good for which rights are defined,
enforceable, and vested in a specific individual. The relevant
transaction cost is the cost of inputs used to withdraw it. Absent any
price for water in the reservoir, this transaction cost is the only
device that rations demand and equilibrium is established only when it
is high enough at the margin to limit demand to the available supply. A
similar characterization applies to the fishery, where the relevant
transaction cost is the expense of inputs needed to find and catch fish,
and to water withdrawn from a source that is polluted by use, where
withdrawals are limited by the cost of treatment.
Innovations or other actions that either lower the cost of obtaining
the resource or raise its marginal value product once acquired need not
improve social welfare, even if they pass a seemingly sensible benefit
cost test.(33) Rather, they intensify competition for the resource and
further degrade its quality. Under plausible conditions their long-run
net social return is negative even though they are rational to the
individuals who undertake them. The same general conclusions appear
applicable to the government goods and privileges that are prominent in
the rent-seeking literature. The items at issue typically are in the
'government domain', available to those who can compete most
effectively. The cost of acquiring rights to such privileges, through
lobbying, contributions, and so forth is the factor that limits demand.
The argument advanced here suggests that improvements in the technology
of lobbying, e.g., better communication methods, more sophisticated
methodologies for research aimed at influencing policy, and more
efficient fund-raising techniques, may be socially self-defeating.(34)
Corrective policies often limit some but not all of the inputs needed
to acquire an unowned resource. These policies can improve welfare by
causing the marginal cost function to become steeper, so rent can be
received for inframarginal units. This rent is attributable to the input
fixed by regulation, so the policy effectively transfers all or part of
the rent the resource would earn if owned to the regulated input. Such
policies tend to avoid dissipation when the elasticity of substitution
between controlled and uncontrolled inputs is low and when the relative
price of the controlled factor is low.
These results extend the analysis of rent dissipation for unowned
resources begun by Gordon [1954] and further developed and applied by
Cheung [1970], Johnson and Libecap [1982] and others. Casting the
problem in an explicit general equilibrium framework is found to be
advantageous because it enables exact characterization of the rent the
resource would earn with complete markets and the degree to which it is
dissipated when ownership is absent. Others have claimed that
dissipation is exact when agents using the resource are homogeneous. The
introduction of costly complementary actions--actions that either raise
the marginal value or lower the private marginal cost of the
resource--shows that dissipation can either exceed or fall short of the
rent the resource would earn with complete ownership. In particular, the
finding that dissipation can exceed what the resource would earn if
owned contrasts rather sharply with the received literature. In
addition, characterization of the social gains to partial control of how
the resource is used and the finding that these gains are related in a
rather simple way to elasticities of substitution and relative prices,
is new. Finally, the examples used to illustrate these results indicate
that these principles are not understood in policy circles, at least
among those concerned with policy toward groundwater. It seems likely
that, with a bit of effort, examples of socially self-defeating
innovations and government initiatives toward fisheries, degradable water courses, and other resources could be found as well.
APPENDIX
The first section of this appendix presents the dynamic optimization
problem and the second section examines the second-best regulation
problem when the technology for obtaining the shared input exhibits
constant elasticity of substitution.