Imperfect competition and basing-point pricing.
Gilligan, Thomas W.
I. INTRODUCTION
Basing-point pricing occurs when firms that are geographically
differentiated use a common location to formulate the transportation
costs, and thus delivered prices, charged to consumers. Consumers are
not generally permitted to purchase the commodity at free-on-board mill
prices since such prices exist only for firms located at the
basing-point. Basing-point pricing is sometimes associated with other
seemingly unusual practices such as cross-hauling, the systematic
transshipment of apparently identical commodities, freight absorption,
the shipment of identical commodities longer distances at delivered
prices that do not reflect additional transportation charges, and
phantom freight, the assessment of fictitious transportation charges.
Basing-point pricing has a rich history in the United States and more
recently was widely practiced by firms in the softwood plywood industry.(1)
Economists have long been interested in the determinants of
basing-point pricing.(2) Their inquires have generally led them to
conclude that basing-point pricing is adopted to facilitate
collusion.(3) This view is articulated by Stigler |1949~ who combined
two important branches of the literature to formulate a theory of how
basing-point pricing and, more generally, any delivered pricing system can solve the problems of cartel instability confronting firms that are
geographically differentiated and face stochastic demand.(4) Examining
the case of multiple production centers with limited numbers of firms
serving geographically uncertain demand, Stigler |1949, 1148~ argued
that the "unpremeditable flexibility of mill prices would make it
extremely difficult to maintain collusion among firms at the production
center, and even more difficult to maintain collusion between firms at
different production centers." The systematic freight absorption
associated with any delivered pricing system provides a solution to
these problems.
|With a delivered pricing system~, there is a single price at each
point in the market (if transportation charges are agreed upon), so
price rivalry is eliminated. One production center can sell in the
"natural" territories of other production centers when this is
necessary to obtain its share of the industry's sales; these
distant sales involve freight absorption, moreover, and are therefore
partly self-limiting. The various prices need not change often, so
collusion is possible. Given the unstable geographical pattern of demand
and the antitrust laws, systematic freight absorption permitted
efficient collusion.
Stigler also provided some evidence, such as the general magnitude of
demand variability in those industries characterized by basing-point
pricing, to support his hypothesis that delivered prices and
basing-point pricing facilitate collusion. Building upon Stigler's
theory, McGee |1954~ argued that cross-hauling is a symptom of the
collusion facilitated by basing-point pricing.
In a recent paper, Haddock |1982~ challenged this view and argued
that basing-point pricing can arise if a firm at other than the base
site takes the delivered price of the basing-point product as given when
formulating its production decision. Given this behavior, a non-base
site firm faces a kinked marginal revenue schedule that supports
basing-point pricing for a wide range of marginal production and
transportation cost schedules. The non-base firm earns a markup on its
product in a particular market equal to the difference between the
delivered price charged by base site firms and the non-base site
firm's costs of production and delivery. The behavior and markups
earned by firms located at the base point are not restricted in
Haddock's model and, presumably, can include Bertrand behavior and
competitive markups. The behavior of non-base site firms is explicitly
monopolistic. Haddock also provided some non-collusive rationales for
cross-hauling. In contrast to the view that basing-point pricing is
adopted to facilitate collusion among all firms in the industry,
Haddock's argument is that basing-point pricing can have little to
do with pervasive collusion and may at most be associated with positive
markups and phantom freight charges by firms on the periphery of
production.(5)
The purpose of this article is to develop a theoretical model to
explore the relationship between imperfect competition and delivered
prices in a spatially differentiated industry. The model consists of two
production sites with multiple firms at both sites employing linear
homogeneous technologies to produce for a fixed demand that is uniformly
distributed along a line connecting the two sites. The equilibrium of
the model is assessed under various assumptions regarding the behavior
of the firms in the industry. It is shown that mill pricing emerges in a
delivered pricing model if firms at all production sites are Bertrand
competitors; no firm believes that it can affect the total sales made in
any given market. Single basing-point pricing emerges if firms at the
base site are Bertrand competitors, firms at the non-base site are less
than perfectly competitive with each other and are von Stackleberg
leaders with respect to base site production, and the products produced
at alternative sites are perfectly homogeneous. Firms at the base site
must be Bertrand competitors for basing-point pricing. Cooperation among
non-base site firms is sufficient (given von Stackleberg behavior) but
not necessary for basing-point pricing. Cross-hauling results from
product heterogeneity under mill pricing and basing-point pricing and is
not sufficient for collusion. In general, the theoretical analysis
integrates the two views and indicates that single basing-point pricing
can be unrelated to collusion among firms located at both the base and
non-base sites and occurs when the only deviation from perfect
competition is that non-base site firms take the delivered price of the
base point product as given when formulating their production decisions.
Thus, existing theoretical analyses, even Haddock's |1982~, tend to
overstate the amount of cooperation necessary to sustain basing-point
pricing.
The current analysis leaves many important issues unresolved. For
instance, scholars have long been interested in the effect of
alternative spatial pricing policies on the locational decisions of
firms in the economy. What are the consequences of basing-point pricing
for the geographic concentration of production? This is the question
addressed in Greenhut's |1956~ seminal analysis and the focus of
the more recent work of Soper, Norman, Greenhut, and Benson |1991~. In
contrast to the current analysis, these analyses fix the spatial pricing
policy and examine its effects on the distribution of firms in the
economy. An analysis that blends both concerns would look at the
emergence of pricing policies and locations of firms as a function of
firm behavior. Additionally, in a recent paper Thisse and Vives |1988~
examine the effects of precommitment on the formation of spatial pricing
policies. In a simple two site, duopoly model they show that
basing-point pricing would never arise as an equilibrium policy under
non-cooperative behavior and conclude that, therefore, it may be best to
think of basing-point pricing as a coordinating or collusive device,
although clearly they provide no analysis of this type. They also fail
to examine the consequences of multiple firms located at identical
sites, a feature that in a non-cooperative setting is likely to
undermine discriminatory pricing of the type they find.
The results of the analysis suggest that single basing-point pricing
is indicative of imperfectly competitive, von Stackleberg leadership by
non-base site firms and Bertrand behavior among base site firms. These
findings raise some interesting theoretical issues that have yet to be
addressed. For instance, how does this configuration of behavior emerge?
Haddock |1982, 296-98~ illustrates that it is frequently optimal for an
isolated firm at the periphery of production to take the delivered price
of base site production as given when formulating its production plans
for distant markets.(6) Is the sequential development of geographically
differentiated productive capacity necessary for the emergence of
basing-point pricing, as a casual study of its most famous uses would
seem to suggest? And once having emerged, how is basing-point pricing
sustained in the presence of a growing number of non-base site
producers? Such growth should undermine the von Stackleberg behavior of
firms located at other than the base site. Does the delivered price
gradient generated from Bertrand behavior by base site firms provide a
focal price coordinating the repeated interactions of non-base site
producers? The importance of inquiries on causes and consequences of
basing-point pricing and delivered pricing more generally seems to rest
on the answers to such questions.
And lastly, the current analysis is silent on the proposition that
basing-point pricing is used to support cooperation among geographically
differentiated competitors, as many past and contemporary scholars
appear to believe. The analysis does, however, identify some
inconsistencies in this argument. For one, it is easy to show within the
context of the current model that perfectly colluding firms would not
choose basing-point pricing, but instead would select a more complex
system of non-linear discriminatory prices. In a recent insightful
paper, Espinosa |1992~ shows that in an infinite-horizon, repeated play
duopoly model, basing-point pricing can be consistent with a wide range
of behavior, including perfect competition. Clearly, additional research
on this issue is warranted.
This article is organized as follows. The next section presents a
theoretical framework to explore the relationship between the nature of
competition among geographically differentiated firms and the
characteristics of a delivered pricing system. Section III identifies
the properties of spatial prices under Bertrand competition while
section IV uncovers the behavioral determinants of single basing-point
pricing. Section V contains a comparative statics analysis of the
imposition of mill pricing on an industry practising basing-point
pricing. Section VI is the conclusion.
II. ASSUMPTIONS AND THE MODEL
The purpose of this section is to construct a theoretical model to
identify the behavioral determinants of alternative spatial pricing
policies. The chief assumption of the model is that firms in the
industry choose the amount of output to deliver to each market in the
economy in order to maximize profits subject to the constraint that
equilibrium delivered prices provide no opportunities for intermarket
arbitrage among consumers. The model places no restrictions on the type
of pricing policy (e.g., mill pricing, basing-point pricing, or more
complicated nonlinear delivered price schedules) that can emerge in
equilibrium, but instead derives equilibrium delivered pricing
characteristics from assumptions regarding the competitive interactions
among and equilibrium behavior of firms in the industry.(7) The model is
also used to examine the consequences of imposing a mill pricing
constraint on firms whose pricing policies resemble basing-point
pricing.
To begin, consider an economy with a continuum of identical consumers
distributed uniformly along a line of unit length. Production of two
goods, |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~, occurs at the end points of the line.(8)
There is a competitive numeraire sector. Table I provides a convenient
summary of the variables used in the model. Table I also contains brief
definitions of these variables.
A representative consumer located at some h |is an element of~ |0, 1~
has a utility function that is linear and separable in the numeraire
good. The consumer maximizes u(|q.sub.0~, |q.sub.1~) -
|p.sub.0~(h)|q.sub.0~ - |p.sub.1~(h)|q.sub.1~ where |p.sub.0~(h) and
|p.sub.1~(h) are the per unit delivered prices paid by the consumer
located at h for goods |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~, respectively. The
function u(|center dot~) is assumed quadratic, (strictly) concave and
symmetric in |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~. Thus, |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ where |Alpha~ |is greater than~ 0, |Beta~ |is greater than or
equal to~ |Gamma~ |is greater than~ 0. Goods |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~,
which are substitutes given |Gamma~ |is greater than~ 0, are perfect
substitutes if and only if |Beta~ = |Gamma~. Inverse demands at any
point h are given by |p.sub.0~(h) = |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h) -
|Gamma~|Q.sub.1~(h) and |p.sub.1~(h) = |Alpha~ - |Gamma~|Q.sub.0~(h) -
|Beta~|Q.sub.1~(h) where |Q.sub.0~(h) and |Q.sub.1~(h) are the aggregate
levels of sales for goods |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~, respectively, in the
hth market.
Production of |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~ occur at h = 0 and h = 1,
respectively. There are |n.sub.0~ and |n.sub.1~, firms, indexed by i and
j, at these respective locations. Firms at either production site face
constant and equal marginal costs which, for convenience, are set equal
to zero. Transportation costs vary according to the location of the
market. For a market located at some arbitrary h, the per unit transport
costs are th|q.sup.i~(h) and t(1 - h)|q.sup.j~(h) for the ith firm
located at h = 0 and for the jth firm located at h = 1, respectively,
where t is the per unit distance transport costs and |q.sup.i~(h) and
|q.sup.j~(h) are the sales of the ith and jth firms in the hth market.
The (non-negative) profits to the ith and jth firms derived from the hth
market are ||Pi~.sup.i~(h) = |p.sub.0~(h)|q.sup.i~(h) - th|q.sup.i~(h)
and ||Pi~.sup.j~(h) = |p.sub.1~(h)|q.sup.j~(h) -t(1 - h)|q.sup.j~(h),
respectively. Total profits for these firms are given by
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Firms in the industry choose the amount of output to deliver to each
market in the economy in order to maximize profits subject to two
important conditions. First, the equilibrium delivered prices must
preclude all opportunities for inter-market arbitrage among consumers. A
delivered price schedule that permits a consumer to purchase and
profitably resell a commodity at some other site is unsustainable in
equilibrium absent some additional assumptions, such as informational or
other transactional difficulties, that limit arbitrage among consumers.
Second, the output choices must depend on the conjectural industry
output variations held by firms in the industry. A firm located at a
given production site must postulate how total sales in a given market
are affected by changes in that firm's sales choice in that market.
The equilibrium sales choices of a firm must recognize its guesses about
the nature of competition among firms in the industry.(9) The vector
|Theta~ = (||Theta~.sub.00~, ||Theta~.sub.01~, ||Theta~.sub.10~,
||Theta~.sub.11~) summarizes the relevant information about conjectural
variations held by firms.(10) The term ||Theta~.sub.00~ =
|Delta~|Q.sub.0~(h)/|Delta~|q.sup.i~(h) represents firm i's
conjecture of how total sales in a given market by all firms also
located at h = 0 respond to changes in its sales level. If
||Theta~.sub.00~ = 0, for example, firm i believes that total sales of
|q.sub.0~ in a given market are unaffected by its level of sales in that
market since its competitors at site h = 0 will change their sales to
counter its alterations. Since changes in its sales do not affect total
sales and therefore TABULAR DATA OMITTED price, ||Theta~.sub.00~ = 0
implies competitive or Bertrand behavior among firms at site h = 0. The
term ||Theta~.sub.01~ = |Delta~|Q.sub.1~(h)/|Delta~|q.sup.i~(h) is firm
i's guess about how total sales in market h by firms located at the
other end of the economy, h = 1, respond to changes in its sales level.
If ||Theta~.sub.01~ = 0 for example, a firm at h = 0 believes that sales
of |q.sub.1~ will not be affected by changes in its sales. The term
||Theta~.sub.10~ = |Delta~|Q.sub.0~(h)/|Delta~|q.sup.j~(h) represents
firm j's conjecture of how total sales in a given market by firms
located at h = 0 respond to changes in its sales. If ||Theta~.sub.10~
equals the true reaction of site h = 0 firms to firm j's sales
choice, for example, firm j is avon Stackleberg leader with respect to
site h = 0 production. And ||Theta~.sub.11~ =
|Delta~|Q.sub.1~(h)/|Delta~|q.sup.j~(h) is firm j's guess of how
total sales in a market by firms also located at h = 1 respond to
changes in its level of sales. If, for example, ||Theta~.sub.11~ =
|Q.sub.1~(h)/|q.sup.j~(h) so that each firm is matching exactly the
behavior of all other firms at h = 1, these firms are behaving
cooperatively. Conjectural variations are a convenient way of
summarizing firm behavior in alternative competitive environments.
Nash behavior is used to characterize the stationary points of the
model. These points have the property that equilibrium in a market
exists when no firm can increase its profits by changing its sales in
that market given the sales of all other firms in that market.
Equilibrium in the economy obtains when each market is in equilibrium.
Inter-market arbitrage by consumers must also be precluded. Formally,
DEFINITION: An equilibrium is the set {|q.sup.i~(h)*, |q.sup.j~(h)*},
|q.sup.i~(h)* |is greater than or equal to~ 0 and |q.sup.j~(h)* |is
greater than or equal to~ 0, i = 1,...,|n.sub.0~, and j =
1,...,|n.sub.1~, such that |for every~ h |is an element of~ |0,1~ given
|Theta~, (1) ||Pi~.sup.i~(h)(|q.sup.i~(h)*, |q.sup.j~(h)*) |is greater
than or equal to~ ||Pi~.sup.i~(h)(|q.sup.i~(h), |q.sup.j~(h)*); (2)
||Pi~.sup.j~(h)(|q.sup.i~(h)*, |q.sup.j~(h)*) |is greater than or equal
to~ ||Pi~.sup.j~(h)(|q.sup.i~(h)*, |q.sup.j~(h)); (3) |p.sub.0~(h)* |is
less than or equal to~ |p.sub.0~(h|prime~)* + t/h - h|prime~/ |for
every~ h, h|prime~ |is an element of~ |0,1~; and (4) |p.sub.1~(h)* |is
less than or equal to~ |p.sub.1~(h|prime~)* + t/h - h|prime~/ |for
every~ h, h|prime~ |is an element of~ |0,1~.
Conditions (1) and (2) comprise the standard definition of a Nash
equilibrium when the strategy space of firms is output. These conditions
imply that for |q.sup.i~(h)* |is greater than~ 0 and |q.sup.j~(h)* |is
greater than~ 0,
(1) |Alpha~ - |q.sup.i~(h)*||Beta~(|n.sub.0~ + ||Theta~.sub.00~) +
|Gamma~||Theta~.sub.01~ - |Gamma~|n.sub.1~|q.sup.j~(h)* - th = 0
and
(2) |Alpha~ - |q.sup.j~(h)*||Beta~(|n.sub.1~ + ||Theta~.sub.11~) +
|Gamma~||Theta~.sub.10~
- |Gamma~|n.sub.0~|q.sup.i~(h)* - t(1-h) = 0.
Conditions (3) and (4) preclude arbitrage by requiring that a
consumer who purchases a unit of the good at one location cannot
profitably offer this good for sale at some alternative location
utilizing the same transportation technology as the firms in the
industry. The equilibrium delivered price of, say, |q.sub.0~ at some
particular location (|p.sub.0~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h)* -
|Gamma~|Q.sup.1~(h)*) must be no greater than its delivered price at
some other locations plus the costs of transshipment
(|p.sub.0~(h|prime~)* + t/h - h|prime~/).
The equilibrium sales of firms can be used to derive the delivered
price schedules of goods |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~, the ultimate objects
of the current inquiry. This is done by substituting |Q.sub.0~(h)* and
|Q.sub.1~(h)* into the inverse demand equations yielding |p.sub.0~(h)* =
|Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Gamma~|Q.sub.1~(h)* and |p.sub.1~(h)* =
|Alpha~ - |Gamma~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Beta~|Q.sub.1~(h)*. Differences in the
delivered prices of the goods as markets become more or less distant
from the site of production can be derived through total
differentiation. These derivatives have implications for the spatial
pricing policies observed in equilibrium. Mill pricing obtains if and
only if d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh = (t and d|p.sub.1~(h)*/dh = -t; the delivered
price of both commodities increases by t per unit of output for each
unit of distance the market is farther from the production site.
Basing-point pricing occurs if and only if (d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh) =
(d|p*.sub.1~(h)/dh) = t or (d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh) = (d|p*.sub.1~(h)/dh) =
-t; the delivered price of both commodities increases by t per unit of
output for each unit of distance the market is farther from one, but not
both, production sites. Below we examine the relationship between the
competitive interaction of firms in the industry, as summarized by
|Theta~, and the gradient of the delivered price schedules.
III. SPATIAL PRICES UNDER BERTRAND COMPETITION
Suppose that |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.1~ = (0,0,0,0) for all i and j.
No firm in the industry believes that it can change the total quantity
of sales made in any market by altering its level of sales into that
market. Since these conjectures yield price-taking behavior, we refer to
||Theta~.sub.1~ as Bertrand competition. The following result is
well-known.(11)
PROPOSITION 1: d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh = t and d|p.sub.1~(h)*/dh = -t if
|Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.1~.
Proposition 1 shows that under Bertrand competition, mill pricing
obtains. The delivered price of any good, say |q.sub.0~, under
||Theta~.sub.1~ must equal the marginal costs of production plus the
marginal costs of delivery. Thus, |p.sub.0~(h)* = th and |p.sub.1~(h)* =
t(1 - h). It is thus clear that the delivered prices of the goods
increase by t for each unit of distance the market is further from the
production site. Figure 1 illustrates the delivered pricing equilibrium
for |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.1~.
Special competition under Bertrand behavior illustrates one
non-collusive determinant of cross-hauling. Cross-hauling occurs when
products with similar attributes are hauled in opposite directions past
one another. This so-called "trans-shipping" of commodities is
troublesome because of the implied inefficiencies of duplicative
transport costs. Define |h.sub.0~ and |h.sub.1~ as the first location
into which |q.sub.0~ is not shipped and |q.sub.1~ is shipped,
respectively. That is, |q.sub.0~ is sold in h |is an element of~ |0,
|h.sub.0~~ while |q.sub.1~ is sold in h |is an element of~ ||h.sub.1~,
1~ It is easy to calculate(12) that for |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.1~,
(3) |h.sub.0~ = ||Alpha~(|Beta~ - |Gamma~) + t|Gamma~~/t(|Gamma~ +
|Beta~)
(4) |h.sub.1~ = |a(|Gamma~ - |Beta~) + t|Beta~~/t(|Gamma~ + |Beta~).
Cross-hauling occurs if and only if |h.sub.0~ |is greater than~
|h.sub.1~. Inspection of (3) and (4) indicates that cross-hauling is
absent only if |Beta~ = |Gamma~; the two goods are perfect substitutes.
So long as there is some product heterogeneity, cross-hauling in
equilibrium is present, as illustrated in Figure 1. Haddock |1982,
293-94~ identifies some potential sources of product heterogeneity
between seemingly identical products, such as the diversification of
sources by buyers to insure against supply interruptions. This result
indicates that the existence and magnitude of cross-hauling are
functions of product heterogeneity and are not sufficient to infer
collusive behavior among firms in a spatially differentiated economy.
IV. BEHAVIORAL DETERMINANTS OF SINGLE BASING-POINT PRICING
Suppose that |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~ = (0,0,
|Delta~|Q.sub.0~(h)/|Delta~|q.sup.j~(h), |Q.sub.i~(h)/|q.sup.j~(h)).
Firms at site h = 0 are Bertrand competitors and take site h = 1
production as given when formulating their production decisions. Firms
at site h = 1 are von Stackleberg leaders with respect to site h = 0
production and act cooperatively in determining site h = 1 production.
Provided demand is large relative to unit transport costs (|Alpha~ |is
greater than or equal to~ 2t) and the products produced at the ends of
the economy are perfect substitutes (|Beta~ = |Gamma~), the following
result, which is illustrated in Figure 2, holds.
PROPOSITION 2: (d|p*.sub.0~(h)/dh) = *(d|p*.sub.1~(h)/dh) = t if
|Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~, |Beta~ = |Gamma~, and |Alpha~ |is greater
than or equal to~ 2t.
Proposition 2 shows that under ||Theta~.sub.2~, sufficiently large markets, and product homogeneity, single basing-point pricing obtains.
Since site h = 0 firms behave competitively, the delivered price of
|q.sub.0~ to any market must equal the sum of marginal production and
marginal transportation costs; |p.sub.0~(h)* = th. Site h = 0 firms
adjust their production to market conditions and site h = 1 production
to insure that |p.sub.0~(h)* = th holds. Under von Stackleberg
leadership, site h = 1 firms profitably substitute sales of good
|q.sub.1~ for |q.sub.0~ at the delivered price of |p.sub.1~(h)* =
|p.sub.0~(h)* = th. This substitution occurs only in markets that are
closer to site |h.sub.1~ than to site |h.sub.0~.(13) Cooperative
behavior among site h = 1 firms supports the delivered price gradient
established by site h = 0 firms. The assumption that all markets are
large relative to unit transport costs (|Alpha~ |is greater than or
equal to~ 2t) insures that site h = 1 firms, even under perfectly
cooperative behavior, have no incentive to reduce the delivered price of
good |q.sub.1~ below |p.sub.0~(h)* = |p.sub.1~(h)* = th for any market
in the economy. That is, |Alpha~ |is greater than or equal to~ 2t
insures that the monopoly delivered price of good |q.sub.1~ is greater
than |p.sub.0~(h)* = th for all h |is an element of~ |0,1~.
Proposition 2 is the classic illustration of single basing-point
pricing. The equilibrium delivered price of good |q.sub.1~ is increasing
in direct proportion to the true transportation costs (t) relative to h
= 0, the basing point, and not the actual production site (h = 1). That
is, the consumer is assessed a freight charge that depends on the actual
transportation technology but uses the base point, not the production
point, as the reference for calculating total freight charges. This case
also illustrates freight-absorption where some producers are shipping
goods for lower delivered prices to more distant locations. Producers at
site h = 1 are shipping |q.sub.1~ to more proximate consumers at higher
delivered prices than are charged more distant consumers.
The delivered pricing model with |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~, |Beta~ =
|Gamma~, and |Alpha~ |is greater than or equal to~ 2t shows that
cross-hauling of homogeneous products should not occur under
basing-point pricing.14 Similar to the case of |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.1~
and |Beta~ = |Gamma~, |h.sub.0~ = |h.sub.1~ = 1/2. Site h = 1 firms sell
more of their output to markets closer to h = 0 but do not sell in
markets more that half the distance to the basing-point, h = 0. The base
site product, |q.sub.0~, is sold primarily in markets closer to h = 0
and is not sold at all in markets more than half the distance to site h
= 1. Basing-point pricing and cross-hauling should not occur
simultaneously, since the former is implied only for homogeneous
products and the latter is possible only for |Gamma~ |is less than~
|Beta~.
The equilibrium for |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~ and |Beta~ = |Gamma~
also illustrates the markups of firms to consumers at alternative
locations. Under |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~, |Beta~ = |Gamma~ |Alpha~ |is
greater than or equal to~ 2t, |p.sub.0~(h)* = |p.sub.1~(h)* = th, the
sum of the marginal production and transportation costs for site h = 0
firms. The markup for firms at site h = 0 is obviously the delivered
price minus actual costs, or |p.sub.0~(h)* - th = 0. The markup on
|q.sub.0~ is independent of the consumer's location. The markup
charged by firms at site h = 1 is |p.sub.1~(h)* - t(1 - h) = t(2h - 1).
This markup is always non-negative since, given product homogeneity
(|Beta~ = |Gamma~), site h = 1 firms do not ship their products to
markets h |is less than~ 1/2. Moreover, the markup is higher for
consumers located further from site h = 0, the base point, and closer to
h = 1, the production point. Note that this markup is simply the phantom
freight assessed to the shipment, since t(2k - 1) = tk - t(1 - k), the
freight charges associated with the delivery of site h = 0 product minus
the actual transportation costs incurred from site h = 1. Figure 2
illustrates the markup charged for |q.sub.1~ as a function of the
consumer's location.
The base site product, |q.sub.0~, earns competitive profits. The
total profits on |q.sub.1~ derived from any market equal the markup per
unit of sales (t(2h - 1)) in a given market multiplied by the total
sales of |q.sub.1~ in that market ((|Alpha~ - th)/|Beta~).(15) The total
profits from |q.sub.1~ equal the integral of this product over site h =
1 firms' market area (|1/2, 1~). The average markup per unit of
|q.sub.1~, denoted MU(||Theta~.sub.2~), is simply the total profits on
|q.sub.1~ divided by total sales of |q.sub.1~, or
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
The average markup on |q.sub.1~, MU(||Theta~.sub.2~), is increasing
in transport costs (t) since the markup on any unit of |q.sub.1~ equals
the phantom freight charges. MU(||Theta~.sub.2~) is decreasing in
|Alpha~ since |Alpha~ increases sales but does not affect delivered
prices, which are th for both |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~. It can further be
shown that t/2 |is less than~ MU(||Theta~.sub.2~) |is less than~ t. The
average markup on |q.sub.1~ is less than the per unit distance
transportation fee but greater than half that amount.
Proposition 2 identifies a set of conditions sufficient for
basing-point pricing. The current model can also be used to highlight an
important necessary condition for basing-point pricing.
PROPOSITION 3: d|p.sub.0~(h)* = d|p.sub.1~(h)* = t only if
||Theta~.sub.00~ = 0.
Firms at the base point must behave as Bertrand competitors to yield
a delivered price gradient that reflects only transportation costs. When
firms at the base point are other than Bertrand competitors, the
delivered price gradient embodies spatial price discrimination leading
to delivered prices that are more than the simple combination of a
quoted mill price plus the actual shipping charges from the base site to
the consumer's location. Basing-point pricing is inconsistent with
non-competitive behavior by base site firms.(16)
Proposition 2 generalizes Haddock's result by allowing for more
than one non-base site producer. Any number of non-base site producers
is theoretically consistent with single basing-point pricing.
Proposition 4 also refines Haddock's result by showing that while
cooperative behavior among non-base site firms is sufficient to sustain
single basing-point pricing in the economy, as Haddock's model
suggests, perfect collusion among these firms is not necessary for
basing-point pricing.
PROPOSITION 4: Given |Theta~ = (0,0, |Delta~|Q.sub.0~(h) /
|Delta~|q.sup.i~(h), ||Theta~.sub.11~), d|p.sub.0~(h)* = d|p.sub.1~(h)*
= t only if ||Theta~.sub.11~ |is greater than or equal to~
|n.sub.1~t/(|Alpha~ - t).
Deviations from cooperative behavior are admissible if the size of
the markets in the economy (|Alpha~) are large relative to unit
transport costs (t) and the number of firms at the non-base location
(|n.sub.1~). Deviations from cooperative behavior by non-base firms can
be consistent with basing-point pricing. Cooperation is, under the other
values of ||Theta~.sub.2~, always sufficient for basing-point pricing.
Notice, however, that Bertrand behavior by non-base site firms is never
consistent with basing-point pricing. Proposition 4 quantifies the
degree of imperfect competition among non-base site firms necessary to
sustain basing-point pricing.
V. IMPOSITION OF MILL PRICING
The most frequently used antitrust remedy for basing-point pricing is
the imposition of mill pricing. The imposition of a mill pricing
constraint obviously has no effect on the prices charged by firms
located at h = 0 and at least one certain and one possible effect on the
other firms in the industry. First, the imposition of mill pricing
affects the delivered prices charged by site h = 1 firms independent of
any impact the constraint has on the competitive conjectures held by
firms in the industry. Under a mill pricing constraint and the
conditions of Proposition 2, site h = 1 firms cooperate in selecting a
mill price, |m.sub.1~, to maximize their joint profits given that
|q.sub.1~ replaces |q.sub.0~ under von Stackleberg leadership in any
market for which the delivered price of |q.sub.1~ is less than or equal
to the delivered price of |q.sub.0~, which is th. Given |Theta~ =
||Theta~.sub.2~ and |Beta~ = |Gamma~, the joint profits of site h = 1
firms are
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
where h(|m.sub.1~), the market in which the delivered prices of
|q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~ are equal under mill pricing, is given by
th(|m.sub.1~) = |m.sub.1~ + t(1 - h(|m.sub.1~)). The profit-maximizing
mill price, |m*.sub.1~, equates the additional revenues derived from a
small increase in |m*.sub.1~ with the lost sales occurring from this
increase. The lost sales result from the reduction in quantity demanded
in those markets for which the delivered price of |q.sub.1~ is less than
that of |q.sub.0~ plus the loss of market area that results from a
higher |m*.sub.1~. Figure 3 illustrates the delivered pricing
equilibrium for |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~ and |Beta~ = |Gamma~ under a
mill pricing constraint.
The profits earned by site h = 1 firms are obviously lower under the
mill pricing constraint when the competitive conjectures remain
unchanged. Mill pricing is an option for these firms absent any
constraint and is not chosen because basing-point pricing results in
higher profits. The markup per unit of |q.sub.1~ under the mill pricing
constraint is constant and equals |m*.sub.1~. Whether |m*.sub.1~ is
larger than MU(||Theta~.sub.2~) is subject to inquiry since, under the
mill pricing constraint, sales made in markets closer to h(|m*.sub.1~)
have larger markups while those made closer to h = 1 have lower markups
than those obtained under basing-point pricing. The following
proposition illuminates the relationship between |m*.sub.1~ and
MU(||Theta~.sub.2~).
PROPOSITION 5: Given a mill pricing constraint, |Beta~ = |Gamma~, and
|Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~, 0 |is less than~ |m*.sub.1~ |is less than~
MU(||Theta~.sub.2~).
The average markup on |q.sub.1~ is strictly positive but lower under
the mill pricing constraint.
The imposition of a mill pricing constraint may also affect the
competitive conjectures of site h = 1 firms. The delivered price
gradient of th established by site h = 0 firms may serve as a focal
point coordinating the behavior of site h = 1 firms. If the ability of
site h = 1 firms to cooperate and lead site h = 0 production is somehow
enhanced by the practice of basing-point pricing, the imposition of mill
pricing may result in the loss of this coordination, more competitive
conjectures, and even lower mill prices than those obtained under the
conditions of Proposition 5.
PROPOSITION 6: Given a mill pricing constraint and |Theta~ =
||Theta~.sub.1~, 0 = |m*.sub.1~.
Whether the imposition of mill pricing affects the competitive
conjectures of firms in the industry is an empirical issue. If mill
pricing induces more competitive conjectures, specifically |Theta~ =
||Theta~.sub.1~, the reduction in the site h = 1 markup should equal the
average phantom freight charged under basing-point pricing;
MU(||Theta~.sub.2~). If mill pricing leaves the conjectural variations
unchanged, the reduction in the site h = 1 markup should be less than
average phantom freight charges under basing-point pricing.
VI. CONCLUSION
Basing-point pricing emerges in a delivered pricing system when firms
at the base site are Bertrand competitors and firms at non-base sites
are imperfectly competitive with each other and are von Stackleberg
leaders vis-a-vis base site production. Basing-point pricing is
associated with competitive pricing and zero markups for base site firms
and positive markups for non-base firms equal to the magnitude of
phantom freight collected in a given market. Basing-point pricing is not
consistent with collusive conjectures for base site firms since
collusion results in a non-linear delivered price schedule. Cooperation
among non-base site firms is sufficient but not necessary for
basing-point pricing. The imposition of mill pricing on firms practicing
basing-point pricing lowers the markups charged by non-base site firms
but does not affect base site pricing. If the imposition of mill pricing
induces competitive conjectures, the reduction in non-base site markups
equals the average phantom freight charges occurring under basing-point
pricing. Cross-hauling can result from product heterogeneity and has
little to do with the nature of competition among firms in an industry.
More generally, cross-hauling, freight-absorption, and phantom freight
can all emerge when a preponderance of the industry's production is
conducted under maximally competitive conditions.
One implication of the above model is that the imposition of mill
pricing on firms in an industry that practises basing-point pricing
should not affect the markups of firms located at the basing-point but
can reduce the markups of firms at distant sites by as much as the their
total phantom freight collections. In a companion empirical piece, we
found that the imposition of mill pricing by antitrust authorities in
the softwood plywood industry had no effect on the markups earned by
firms at the base site (Portland) but reduced the markups of firms
located in the southeastern U.S. (Gilligan |1992~). Indeed, consumers
located the greatest distance from the basing-point found that
basing-point pricing increased the difference between the price of the
non-base and base site products by nearly 65 percent of the
transcontinental rail costs of shipping plywood. We argue that these
results are consistent with Haddock's |1982~ model and the one
presented above and somewhat inconsistent with the notion that
basing-point pricing supports industry-wide collusive pricing.
APPENDIX
Proof of Proposition 1: Given the assumption that goods |q.sub.0~ and
|q.sub.1~ are not perfectly substitutable, three cases must be
considered. These cases correspond to the availability of the two goods
in a particular market. Let |h.sub.0~ be the last market into which good
|q.sub.0~ is sold and |h.sub.1~ the first market into which good
|q.sub.1~ is sold. That is, |q.sub.0~ is sold in markets h |is an
element of~ |0,|h.sub.0~~ while |q.sub.1~ is sold in h |is an element
of~ ||h.sub.1~,1~ Solving for these three cases and substituting
||Theta~.sub.1~ into (1) and (2), the equilibrium sales for a firm
located at h = 0 and h = 1 into market h are given by
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
The market boundaries |h.sub.0~ and |h.sub.1~ are arrived at by
finding those parameter values such that |q.sup.i~(h)* and |q.sup.j~(h)*
equal zero, respectively. Calculation yields |h.sub.0~ = ||Alpha~(|Beta~
- |Gamma~) + t|Gamma~~/t(|Gamma~ + |Beta~) and |h.sub.1~ =
||Alpha~(|Gamma~ - |Beta~) + t|Beta~~/t(|Gamma~ + |Beta~); both
|h.sub.0~ and |h.sub.1~ approach 1/2 as |Beta~ |approaches~ |Gamma~. The
equilibrium delivered prices are obtained through simple substitution of
the equilibrium sales levels into the inverse demand equations;
|p.sub.0~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Gamma~|Q.sub.1~(h)* and
|p.sub.1~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |Gamma~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Beta~|Q.sub.1~(h)*.
The change in the delivered price of |q.sub.0~ as h increases is
obtained by total differentiation; d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh =
-|Beta~d|Q.sub.0~(h)* / dh - |Gamma~d|Q.sub.1~(h)* / dh = t. The change
in the delivered price of |q.sub.1~ as h increases is given by
d|p.sub.0~(h)* / dh = -t. It is easily verified that consumer arbitrage
opportunities are absent in equilibrium.
Proof of Proposition 2: Given ||Theta~.sub.00~ = ||Theta~.sub.01~ =
0, (1) reduces to |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h) -
|Gamma~|n.sub.1~|q.sup.j~(h) = 0 and the true reaction of site h = 0
production to increases in |q.sup.j~(h) is |Delta~|Q.sub.0~(h) /
|Delta~|q.sup.j~(h) = -|Gamma~|n.sub.1~ / |Beta~. Since |Beta~ = |Gamma~
(goods |q.sub.0~ and |q.sub.1~ are perfect substitutes) and site h = 1
firms are von Stackleberg leaders with respect to production, good
|q.sub.1~ replaces |q.sub.0~ in all markets in which the delivered price
is as least as low as the delivered price of good |q.sub.0~. Two case,
thus, must be considered; markets in which only |q.sub.0~ is sold and
markets in which only |q.sub.1~ is sold. Substituting |Theta~ =
||Theta~.sub.2~ and |Beta~ = |Gamma~ into (1) and (2), the equilibrium
level of sales by firms located at h = 0 and h = 1 into market h is
given by
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
|p.sub.1~(h)* = th is the highest price site h = 1 firms can charge
and secure all sales in market h. It must be confirmed that site h = 1
firms do not wish to charge less than th in all markets in which
|q.sub.1~ is sold. For h |is greater than or equal to~ 1/2, the
unconstrained optimal level of output for a firm located at site h = 1
is ||Alpha~ - t(1 - h)~/2|Beta~|n.sub.1~; the monopoly optimum. However,
this level of sales results in a delivered price for |q.sub.1~ greater
than the price at which site h = 0 firms are willing to supply all of
that particular market's demand. |q.sub.i~(h)* = (|Alpha~ -
th)/|Beta~|n.sub.1~ is the lowest output level, and thus the highest
delivered price, at which firms at site h = 1 secure all of the sales in
the h-th market. The assumption |Alpha~ |is greater than or equal to~ 2t
guarantees that ||Alpha~-t(1-h)~/2|Beta~|n.sub.1~ |is less than or equal
to~ (|Alpha~ - th)/|Beta~|n.sub.0~. The equilibrium delivered prices are
|p.sub.0~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Gamma~|Q.sub.1~(h)* and
|p.sub.1~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |Gamma~|Q.sub.0~(h)* - |Beta~|Q.sub.1~(h)*.
The change in the delivered price of |q.sub.0~ as h increases is given
by d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh = -|Beta~d|Q.sub.0~(h)*/dh -
|Gamma~d|Q.sub.1~(h)*/dh = t. The change in the delivered price of
|q.sub.1~ as h increases is given by d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh = t.
Proof of Proposition 3: Under perfect substitutability (|Beta~ =
|Gamma~), the two goods are never sold in the same markets. Thus,
|p.sub.0~(h)* = |Alpha~ - |n.sub.0~|(|Alpha~ - th)/(|n.sub.0~ +
||Theta~.sub.00~ + ||Theta~.sub.01~)~, and (d|p.sub.0~(h)*/dh) =
|n.sub.0~t/(|n.sub.0~ + ||Theta~.sub.00~ + ||Theta~.sub.01~). The
delivered price gradient, which is linear, differs from the gradient of
the true transport cost by those factors (the number and behavior of
firms) that affect the perceived marginal revenue of a firm at site h =
0.
Proof of Proposition 4: At the equilibrium delivered price of
|p.sub.1~(h)* = th, the marginal revenue of any firm at site h = 1
equals |MR.sup.j~(h) = th - |q.sup.j~(h)*|Beta~||Theta~.sub.11~ - t(1 -
h) = th - (|Alpha~ - th)||Theta~.sub.11~/|n.sub.1~ - t(1 - h). For
|p.sub.1~(h)* = th, |MR.sup.j~(h) |is less than or equal to~ 0; no firm
at site h = 1 must have an incentive to increase its sales in any
market. |MR.sup.j~(h) can be strictly less than zero since, at
|p.sub.1~(h)* = th, any reduction in |q.sup.j~(h) will increase the
delivered price of |q.sub.1~ resulting in the loss of all sales to site
h = 0 firms. Rearranging the expression for |MR.sup.j~(h) implies that
||Theta~.sub.11~ |is greater than or equal to~ |n.sub.1~ |th - t(1 -
h)~/(|Alpha~ - th). The right-hand side of this expression takes its
greatest value for h = 1; the market at the production site of
|q.sub.1~. Substituting h = 1 into this expression implies that
||Theta~.sub.11~ |is greater than or equal to~ |n.sub.1~t/(|Alpha~ - t).
Since the smallest value the denominator of this expression can take is
|Alpha~ = 2t, the largest value the left-hand side can attain is
|n.sub.1~. Thus, ||Theta~.sub.11~ = |n.sub.1~ is sufficient behavior
among non-base site firms to sustain the basing-point pricing
equilibrium. Notice, however, that for |Alpha~ |is greater than~ 2t, the
conjectures held by firms at h = 1 need not necessarily be perfectly
collusive. If |Alpha~ is large relative to t and |n.sub.1~, imperfect collusion among non-base site firms can be sufficient for basing-point
pricing.
Proof of Proposition 5: Under |Theta~ = ||Theta~.sub.2~, the joint
profits of site h = 1 firms equal
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
where h is the endogenously determined lower boundary of site h = 1
firms' market. Maximizing with respect to h implies that the
equilibrium market boundary must satisfy |h.sup.2~4t - h2(2|Alpha~ + t)
+ 3|Alpha~ - t = 0, which implies that h |is less than~ 3/4. h |is less
than~ 3/4 implies that |m*.sub.1~ |is less than~ t/2, which is lower
than MU(||Theta~.sub.2~).
Proof of Proposition 6: From Proposition 1 above, |Theta~ -
||Theta~.sub.1~ implies that |p.sub.1~(h)* = t(1 - h), or |m*.sub.1~ =
0.
1. Machlup's |1949~ important work catalogues many prominent
uses of basing-point pricing, including steel, cement and corn products.
Wilcox |1966~ also provides an illuminating history of basing-point
pricing, including its first recorded use in the steel industry under
the "Pittsburgh-plus" plan. The Federal Trade Commission
|1978~ provides a comprehensive description of how basing-point pricing
was practised in the plywood industry during the early and middle parts
of the 1970s.
2. Many inquires have focused on cost-based determinants of
basing-point pricing, such as economies in the production or
transportation of geographically differentiated goods. This article
ignores such cost-based arguments. Also, apart from the determinants of
basing-point pricing, economists and policy-makers have also been
concerned with its effects. DeCanio |1984~ provides an analysis of the
relative consequences of mill and multiple basing-point pricing under
varying degrees of competition.
3. This wisdom is reflected in the conduct of contemporary public
policy towards basing-point pricing. In Federal Trade Commission |1978~,
the government argued that the effects of the use of basing-point
pricing in the plywood industry were, among other things, to
"reduce and hinder actual and potential competition among |firms~
in the sale and distribution of softwood plywood." Karlson's
|1986~ response to Haddock's |1982~ article also takes this view.
Wilcox |1966, 229~ shares this view and reports that, "where
delivered prices have regularly been matched by all sellers, the
practice has usually been facilitated by some sort of an agreement or
understanding with respect to many, if not all, of the factors that
influence the prices that are charged. The possibility that variations
in price may result from differences--whether deliberate or
inadvertent--in the methods of selling and pricing employed by different
members of the industry is thus removed."
4. Machlup's |1949~ arguments are consistent with this view,
too.
5. Benson, Greenhut, and Norman |1990~ also show that basing-point
pricing can arise when production at the basing point is competitive
while production at the periphery is monopolized. In contrast to
Haddock, they focus on the behavior of the non-base site firm to
highlight the non-rivalrous foundations of basing-point pricing. In
their model, they further show that monopolized periphery production is
necessary for basing-point pricing. Below we show that this is not
generally true.
6. Karlson |1986~ identifies the conditions necessary for this result
and some important exceptions.
7. Other authors that have provided derivations of equilibrium
spatial pricing policies under a variety of imperfectly competitive
conditions include Greenhut and Greenhut |1975~ and Spulber |1981~. The
present model differs from Greenhut and Greenhut in that it entertains a
more complex set of competitive relationships among firms in the
industry. Spulber examines the spatial pricing policies of a monopolist
assuming that consumer arbitrage possibilities are limited.
8. Thus, the locations of firms in the model are assumed fixed and
exogenous. To be sure, spatial pricing policies affect the distribution
of firms throughout the economy, as the seminal work of Greenhut |1956,
chapter II~ and the more contemporary effort of Soper et al. |1991~
show. The spatial policies in these analysis are exogenous. A more
complete analysis than the present one would solve for the equilibrium
spatial pricing policy and the equilibrium distribution of firms as a
function of firm behavior.
9. As always, this conceptualization is not analogous to a dynamic
model of intra-industry behavior. Rather, it is a static framework that
incorporates differing assumptions about the degree of
non-competitiveness among firms in the industry. For a further
discussion of these issues, see Tirole |1988, 244-5~.
10. As the notation indicates, it is assumed that (1) firms at a
given location hold identical conjectures and (2) the conjectures are
not market specific. The later assumption implies that, for instance, if
a firm believes that it is a Bertrand competitor with all other firms in
one market, it also believes that it is a Bertrand competitor with these
same firms in all other markets.
11. Proofs to the propositions are contained in the Appendix.
12. See the proof of Proposition 1 in the Appendix for the
derivation.
13. Greenhut |1956, 57-83~ recognized the necessity of this behavior,
which he termed "restrained price competition," for
basing-point pricing. His focus, however, was on the effects of
restrained price competition on firm location.
14. The absence of cross-hauling under basing-point pricing is
informally referred to as an illustration of "spontaneous
basing-point pricing." Clearly, there are historical uses of
basing-point pricing that involve rampant cross-hauling--the
"Pittsburgh-plus" system in the U.S. steel industry. The
current analysis thus supports McGee's |1954~ contention that
cross-hauling of identical products should not generally occur under
spontaneous basing-point pricing. Greenhut |1956, Chapter II~ provides
an analysis of the locational choices of firms under basing-point
pricing with cross-hauling.
15. Recall that the inverse demand for |q.sub.1~ in any market is
given by |p.sub.1~(h) = |Alpha~ - |Beta~|Q.sub.1~(h).
16. Capozza and Van Order |1977~ present a similar result and Haddock
|1982, 299-300~ exposes its implications for the hypothesis that
basing-point pricing is associated with collusion among base-site firms.
REFERENCES
Benson, Bruce L., Melvin L. Greenhut, and George Norman. "On the
Basing-Point System." American Economic Review, September 1990,
584-88.
Capozza, Dennis R., and Robert Van Order. "Pricing Under Spatial
Competition and Spatial Monopoly." Econometrica, September 1977,
1329-44.
DeCanio, Stephen A. "Delivered Pricing and Multiple Basing Point
Equilibria: A Reevaluation." Quarterly Journal of Economics, May
1984, 329-49.
Espinosa, Maria Paz. "Delivered Pricing, FOB Pricing, and
Collusion in Spatial Markets." Rand Journal of Economics, Spring
1992, 64-85.
Federal Trade Commission. Findings, Opinions and Orders in the Matter
of Boise Cascade Corporation, et al. Federal Trade Commission Decisions,
1978.
Gilligan, Thomas W. "Imperfect Competition and Basing-Point
Pricing: Evidence from the Softwood Plywood Industry." American
Economic Review, December 1992, 1106-19.
Greenhut, Melvin L. Plant Location in Theory and in Practice: The
Economics of Space. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
1956.
Greenhut, John G., and Melvin L. Greenhut. "Spatial Price
Discrimination, Competition and Locational Effects." Economica,
November 1975, 401-19.
Haddock, David D. "Basing Point Pricing: Competitive vs.
Collusive Theories." American Economic Review, June 1982, 289-306.
Karlson, Stephen H. "Basing-Point Pricing Isn't
Competitive." Working Paper, Northern Illinois University, 1986.
Machlup, Fritz. The Basing-Point System. Philadelphia, PA: Blakiston
Publishing Company, 1949.
McGee John S. "Cross-Hauling--A Symptom of Incomplete Collusion
Under Basing Point Systems." Southern Economic Review, October
1954, 369-78.
Soper, Jean B., George Norman, Melvin L. Greenhut, and Bruce L.
Benson. "Basing-Point Pricing and Production Concentration."
The Economic Journal, Fall 1991, 539-58.
Spulber, Daniel F. "Spatial Nonlinear Pricing." American
Economic Review, December 1981, 923-33.
Stigler, George J. "A Theory of Delivered Price Systems."
American Economic Review, December 1949, 1143-59.
Thisse, Jacques-Francois, and Xavier Vives. "On the Strategic
Choice of Spatial Price Policy." American Economic Review, March
1988, 122-37.
Tirole, Jean. The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge,
Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1988.
Wilcox, Clair. Public Policies Toward Business. Homewood, IL: Richard
D. Irwin, Inc., 1966.