Consumers are not Ricardian: evidence from nineteen countries.
Evans, Paul
I. INTRODUCTION
In conventional macroeconomic analysis, government debt affects the
economy because households view it as net wealth. The larger the
government debt is, the wealthier households feel and the more they
consume. In principle, however, households need not view government debt
as net wealth. David Ricardo pointed out that they might conceivably
treat the future taxes servicing the government debt as exactly
offsetting it.(1) Robert Barro |1974~ has shown that maximizing
households will actually do so if they accurately anticipate future
taxes, if they face perfect capital markets, and if they have
effectively infinite horizons. Ricardian equivalence is said to hold if
households do treat future servicing taxes as an exact offset to the
government debt.
Many empirical papers on consumption have investigated whether
Ricardian equivalence is consistent with observation. Kochin |1974~,
Barro |1978~, Tanner |1979~, Seater |1982~, Kormendi |1983~, Aschauer
|1985~, Seater and Mariano |1985~, Kormendi and Meguire |1986; 1990~,
Leiderman and Razin |1988~, Evans |1988~, and Evans and Hasan |1993~
have reported evidence consistent with Ricardian equivalence. By
contrast, Blinder and Deaton |1985~, Feldstein |1978; 1982~, Boskin and
Kotlikoff |1985~, Modigliani and Sterling |1986; 1990~, and Feldstein
and Elmendorf |1990~ have reported evidence inconsistent with Ricardian
equivalence. Unfortunately, most of these studies do not estimate
regression equations that derive from well-specified theoretical models
nesting both Ricardian equivalence and an alternative theory in which
budget deficits and current taxes are not equivalent. Consequently,
their results are often hard to interpret. Moreover, these studies
consider the data for only one country, typically the United States. As
a result, the tests that are performed may not have much power to
distinguish an economy for which Ricardian equivalence would be a good
approximation from one for which it would be a bad approximation.
Olivier Blanchard |1985~ has provided one of the few models in the
literature that tractably nests Ricardian equivalence and an alternative
in which households view government debt as net wealth. Depending upon
whether a crucial parameter is zero or positive, households have
infinite horizons, internalize all future generations, and exhibit
Ricardian behavior; or have finite horizons, are at least somewhat
disconnected from future generations, and exhibit non-Ricardian behavior
that strengthens as the parameter becomes larger. The model has testable
implications that this paper examines using annual data for nineteen
countries. When the data for the countries are pooled, the tests have
sufficient power not only to reject Ricardian equivalence in favor of
Blanchard's alternative but also to yield a precise estimate of the
deviation from Ricardian equivalence. This estimated deviation is
approximately what one would expect if capital and insurance markets
were perfect and households did not have altruistic bequest motives. The
deviation is, however, also economically unimportant for many purposes.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II lays out
Blanchard's model and derives the testable implications of
Ricardian equivalence. Section III tests these implications. Section IV
summarizes the findings of the paper and interprets them.
II. EMPIRICAL IMPLICATIONS OF RICARDIAN EQUIVALENCE
In the stochastic variant of Blanchard's model formulated in
this section, the economy is inhabited by a constant population of
households that have finite horizons and face perfect capital and
insurance markets.(2) Each household has a finite horizon because it has
a probability p of "dying" each period and being replaced by
another household from which it is entirely disconnected. With the
population normalized to unity, the number of households born 0, 1, 2,
... periods earlier is always p, p(1-p), p|(1-p).sup.2~, ... since each
cohort is initially of size p and a fraction 1-p of households in each
cohort survives each period.
It may be more appropriate to interpret p metaphorically as a measure
of how disconnected current households feel from future households
rather than literally as the birth and death rate of the population.
Under this interpretation, current households treat future households as
continuations of themselves and have infinite horizons if p = 0 and feel
disconnected to some extent from future households and have finite
horizons if p |is greater than~ 0. Modeling households as if they have
finite horizons is also a substitute for modeling capital-market
imperfections and bounded rationality, which may lead households to act
as if they have short horizons.(3,4) One may therefore wish to entertain
the possibility that p is larger than the birth rate of the population.
Each household born in period t-h and still alive in period t
maximizes the objective function
(1) |summation of~ |(1 + |Rho~).sup.-i~ |(1 - p).sup.i~ where i = 0
to |infinity~
X |E.sub.t~|- 1/|Alpha~)exp(- |Alpha~|d.sub.h+i,t+i~)~,
|Rho~ |is greater than~ 0, 0 |is less than or equal to~ p |is less
than~ 1, |Alpha~ |is greater than~ 0, 0 |is less than~ |Delta~ |is less
than or equal to~ 1,
subject to the constraints
(2) |d.sub.ht~ |is less than or equal to~ |(1 - |Delta~)/(1 -
p)~|d.sub.h-1,t-1~ + |c.sub.ht~,
and
(3) |C.sub.ht~ + |a.sub.ht~ |is less than or equal to~ |w.sub.ht~ +
|(1 + r)/(1 - p)~|a.sub.h-1,t-1~,
h = 0, 1, 2,...,
with |d.sub.-1t~, = |a.sub.-1t~, = 0; where t is a discrete index of
time; |d.sub.ht~ is the household's stock of the consumption good
at the end of period t; |c.sub.ht~ is the household's expenditure
on the consumption good during period t; |a.sub.ht~ is the
household's stock of financial assets at the end of period t; and
|w.sub.ht~ is the household's disposable wage income during period
t; |E.sub.t~ is the expectation operator conditional on the information
available during period t; r, which is assumed to be constant, is the
real after-tax return to financial assets; |Rho~ is the subjective rate
of time preference; |Delta~ is the constant rate at which the
consumption good depreciates; and |Alpha~ is the coefficient of absolute
risk aversion. The momentary utility functions in the objective function
(1) take the negative exponential form in order to permit a closed-form
solution. Momentary utility depends on the stock of the consumption good
since the flow of consumption services is assumed to be proportional to
the stock. Because each household has a probability |(1-p).sup.i~ of
surviving at least i periods, this factor multiplies the expected
momentary utility for period t+i. The factor 1/(1-p) appears in
equations (2) and (3) because each household can make an actuarially
fair bet at the end of each period on whether it will be alive in the
next period. If it wins, it receives 1/(1-p) times its bet; if it loses,
it receives nothing. Because the household does not care about what it
will receive if it dies, it bets its entire wealth every period,
obtaining for each period that it survives the gross rates of return (1
- |Delta~)/(1 - p) and (1 + r)/(1-p), which exceed the gross rates of
return 1 - |Delta~ and 1 + r on the underlying assets.(5)
To complete the model, I must characterize the stochastic processes
generating the ws. I assume that the age-earnings profile always has the
same shape:(6)
(4) |w.sub.ht~ = |w.sub.t~ + ||Pi~.sub.h~|prime~ h = 0, 1, 2, ...,
where |w.sub.t~ is aggregate disposable wage income per household in
period t and the |Pi~s are parameters whose population-weighted average
is always equal to zero by construction. I further assume that
(|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~)|w.sub.t+i~ is normally distributed with a
variance that does not depend on t.
The appendix shows that these assumptions imply that(7)
(5) |Delta~|c.sub.t~ = |Beta~ - p|(r + p)/|(1 - p)~|a.sub.t-1~ +
|u.sub.t~ - (1 - |Delta~)|u.sub.t-1~,
where |c.sub.t~ is aggregate consumption expenditure, |a.sub.t~ is
the aggregate stock of financial assets, |Beta~ is a parameter, and
(6) |u.sub.t~ |is equivalent to~ |(r + p)/(r + |Delta~ + p -
|Delta~p)~
X |summation of~ ||(1 - p)/(1 + r)~.sup.i~(|E.sub.t~ -
|E.sub.t-1~)|w.sub.t+i~ where i = 0 to |infinity~
Because |u.sub.t~ is uncorrelated with all information available to
households in period t-1, the error term |u.sub.t~ - (1 -
|Delta~)|u.sub.t-1~ is a first-order moving average that is uncorrelated
with all information available to households in period t - 2.(8)
Therefore, estimating equation (5) with the intercept and |a.sub.t-2~ as
instrumental variables should yield a coefficient on |a.sub.t-1~ that
has a zero probability limit if Ricardian equivalence holds and a
negative probability limit if Blanchard's alternative to Ricardian
equivalence holds.(9) In addition, given the value of r, one can
estimate p.
III. TESTING RICARDIAN EQUIVALENCE
Ricardian equivalence was tested using annual data spanning the
period 1960-1988. The necessary data are available for the following
nineteen OECD countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the
Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the
United States. See the appendix for a description of the data and their
sources.
The only consumption series that is available for each of the
nineteen countries over the entire period 1960-1988 is real private
expenditure on consumption goods.(10) This series |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ differs from the series |c.sub.t~ to which equation
(5) applies because |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ results from
decisions made throughout year t rather than from a single decision made
at one discrete point in time. The appendix shows that time aggregation
confounds the parameter |Delta~ but does not necessarily create any
statistical problems. I therefore estimated the equation
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where |Theta~ is a parameter satisfying -1 |is less than~ |Theta~ |is
less than~ 1, and |v.sub.t~ is a serially uncorrelated error term with a
zero mean and a finite variance. Under the null hypothesis, using the
intercept and |a.sub.t-2~ as instrumental variables yields consistent
estimates. The estimates are also consistent under the alternative
hypothesis if |Delta~|a.sub.t~ has a sufficiently short memory.
TABLE I
T-Ratios for-p|(r+p)/(1-p)~
Australia +0.87
Austria -0.51
Belgium -0.71
Canada +1.32
Denmark -1.25
Finland +1.34
France -0.72
Germany -0.69
Greece -1.54
Ireland +1.00
Italy -0.06
Japan +0.56
Luxembourg +0.74
Netherlands -0.30
Norway -1.46
Sweden -1.82(*)
Switzerland +0.14
United Kingdom +0.44
United States -0.77
All -6.90(*)
* Statistically significant at the .05 level on a one-tailed
test.
Using instrumental variables, I fitted equation (7) to the data
described above for the sample period 1961-1988.(11) The estimates of
-p(r + p)/(1 - p) thus obtained are consistent, but their conventional
standard errors are inconsistent. The reason is that the error term is a
first-order moving average and is likely to be heteroskedastic as
well.(12) I therefore used the procedure developed by Hansen |1982~ to
obtain consistent estimates of the standard errors. I then calculated
t-ratios by dividing the coefficient estimates by these consistent
estimates of their standard errors. Table I reports the resulting
t-ratios. If Ricardian equivalence holds, the t-ratios should center
around zero and should not often differ significantly from zero. In
contrast, if Blanchard's alternative to Ricardian equivalence
holds, the t-ratios should tend to be negative and should often be
significantly so. The t-ratios are negative for eleven of the countries
and positive for eight. One t-ratio is significantly negative at the .05
level, and none is significantly positive. Therefore, the t-ratios
evidence neither a pronounced nor a statistically significant tendency
to be negative.
If p and r are the same for all of the countries, the coefficients on
a should be the same in all of the regressions. The test statistic for
the equality of these coefficients is 39.8. Since this test statistic is
approximately distributed as ||Chi~.sup.2~ with 18 degrees of freedom in
large samples, it is statistically significant at a level somewhat less
than .005. Therefore, p and r appear to differ across countries.(13) The
t-ratio on -p(r + p)/(1 - p) obtained from joint three-stage
least-squares estimation is reported in the last row of Table I.(14) If
the evidence against a common p and r were not so strong, this t-ratio
would enable one to reject Ricardian equivalence in favor of
Blanchard's alternative at any conventional significance level.
Nevertheless, it is probably a useful summary statistic even though one
cannot interpret it as a test statistic.(15)
My estimates of - p(r + p)/(1 - p) imply estimates of p given r, the
net real after-tax return on assets. Table II reports the two estimates
of p implied by assuming that r is .03 and .07 per annum.(16) Asymptotic
standard errors are also reported.(17) Sixteen estimates are zero, eight
lie between .00 and .01 per annum, seven lie between .01 and .03 per
annum, and seven lie between .03 and .08 per annum. Of these estimates,
seven are significantly positive at the .05 level, many more than would
be expected from chance alone. For some of the countries, like Sweden
and the United States, the estimates are small and precise; hence
deviations from Ricardian equivalence are likely to be small. In
contrast, for other countries, like Denmark and Norway, the estimates
are appreciable and less precise so that large deviations from Ricardian
equivalence are conceivable. When p and r are restricted to be the same
for all of the countries, the estimate of p is small and precise: .025
(.003) per annum if r is .03 per annum and .016 (.002) per annum if r is
.07 per annum. Because the restriction that all of the countries have
the same p and r can be rejected, however, these estimates only suggest
that p is positive, small, and slightly larger than the birth rates of
the nineteen countries considered.(18)
IV. SUMMARY AND INTERPRETATION
Using annual data from nineteen countries, this paper has tested
Ricardian equivalence against Olivier Blanchard's alternative
model. Taken separately, the tests for the individual countries provide
only weak evidence against Ricardian equivalence. Many of these tests,
however, have little power against alternatives that deviate
substantially from Ricardian equivalence. When the data are pooled, the
evidence against Ricardian equivalence becomes stronger: Ricardian
equivalence can be rejected resoundingly. Moreover, the rate at which
disconnected households flow into the economy is estimated to be around
2 percent per annum, which is only slightly larger than the birth rates
of the nineteen countries considered.
TABLE II
Implied Estimates of p and their Standard Errors
Country r = .03 r = .07
Australia .000(**) .000(**)
Austria .016 .010
(.025) (.018)
Belgium .034 .023
(.034) (.029)
Canada .000(**) .000(**)
Denmark .069(*) .055
(.037) (.035)
Finland .000(**) .000(**)
France .020 .012
(.021) (.016)
Germany .035 .024
(.035) (.030)
Greece .040(*) .028(*)
(.018) (.016)
Ireland .000(**) .000(**)
Italy .001 .000
(.018) (.008)
Japan .000(**) .000(**)
Luxembourg .000(**) .000(**)
Netherlands .008 .004
(.022) (.013)
Norway .072(*) .060*
(.034) (.032)
Sweden .013(*) .007(*)
(.006) (.004)
Switzerland .000(**) .000(**)
United Kingdom .000(**) .000**
United States .009 .005
(.010) (.006)
All .025(*) .019(*)
(.003) (.006)
* Statistically significant at the .05 level on a one-tailed
test.
** If the estimate of -p(r + p)/(1 - p) is positive, p is set
equal to zero, its lower bound. No effort is made to assign a
standard error to these zero estimates.
Does this formal rejection of Ricardian equivalence have important
implications for tax policy? To answer this question, I calculate the
effects of an unexpected tax cut that raises expected disposable wage
income by one unit in years t, t + 1, ..., t + N - 1 and reduces
expected disposable income by |(1 + r).sup.N~ - 1 in years t + N, t + N
+ 1, t + N + 2, ....(19) If consumption goods are not durable, equations
(5) and (6) imply that consumption expenditure jumps in year t by
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Table III reports the jumps in consumption expenditure for p = .01,
.02, and .03 per annum and N = 1, 3, 5, 10, 20, 50, and 100 years.
Clearly, the departure from Ricardian equivalence is small for
short-lived tax cuts. As a result, unless countercyclical tax policy is
extremely aggressive, it cannot stabilize aggregate demand appreciably if households correctly perceive the required tax cuts and tax hikes as
short-lived.(20) An aggressive countercyclical tax policy, however,
would greatly destabilize the capital stock since each unit of
government debt that the policy generates (extinguishes) ultimately
crowds out (in) exactly one unit of capital.(21) Therefore, the case for
countercyclical tax policy may be even less strong if households have
long, but finite, horizons than if they have infinite horizons.
To make these points more concrete, consider the $50 tax rebate
proposed early in the Carter Administration. Suppose that p and r are 2
and 5 percent per annum and that this proposal, had it been implemented,
would have reduced total net taxes by $8 billion in the initial year and
raised them by $400 million in every future year. Even if output is
supplied perfectly elastically at predetermined price levels for periods
as long as a year, this policy would have raised output by only $8000 x
.02/(1-.02), or $163, million. This figure is only .0082 percent of GNP in 1977. Okun's Law predicts that the unemployment rate would have
been lowered less than .003 percentage points. In the long run, the
proposal would have reduced the capital stock by $8 billion and output
and consumption by $400 million. These appreciable long-term costs of
the proposal are likely to dwarf the scanty short-term benefits
calculated above. The proposal may not have been enacted for that very
reason.
TABLE III
The Momentary Marginal Propensity to Consume from a Tax Cut
Lasting N Years
N p = .01 p = .02 p = .03
1 .010 .020 .030
3 .030 .039 .087
5 .095 .096 .141
10 .090 .193 .305
20 .192 .332 .609
50 .395 .636 .782
100 .634 .868 .952
The long-term stance of tax policy is important, however long
households' horizons are so long as they are not infinite. For
example, a long-lived tax cut can produce a large consumption binge
early on that must eventually be paid for by a massive reduction in the
capital stock and a large reduction in consumption.(22) Therefore,
whether households have long, but finite, horizons or infinite horizons
has implications primarily for what the long-term stance of tax policy
should be.
An important caveat to the discussion above is that imperfect capital
markets have been assumed to affect consumption behavior only by
shortening the effective horizons of households. The calculations
reported in Table III reflect this assumption. A useful direction for
future research is to investigate whether imperfect capital markets
affect consumption in other ways.
APPENDIX
A. Derivation of Equation (5)
The first-order necessary condition for maximizing (1) subject to (2)
and (3) is
(A1) exp(- |Alpha~|d.sub.ht~) = |(r + |Delta~)/(1 + |Rho~)~ x
|E.sub.t~ |summation of~||(1 - |Delta~)/(1 + |Rho~)~.sup.i~ exp(-
|Alpha~|d.sub.h+1+i,t+1+i~) where i=0 to |infinity~.
Rearranging equation (A1) yields
(1 + |Rho~)/(r + |Delta~ = |E.sub.t~ |summation of~|(1-|Delta~)/|(1 +
|Rho~)~.sup.i~ where i=0 to |infinity~.
x exp|- |Alpha~(|d.sub.h+1=i,t+1+i~|-d.sub.ht~
(A2) = |E.sub.t~ |summation of~ ||(1 - |Delta~)/(1 + |Rho~)~.sup.i~ x
exp|- |Alpha~ |summation of~ (|d.sub.h+j+1,t+j+1~|-d.sub.h+j,t+j~)~
where j=0 to i.
Suppose that |d.sub.ht~-|d.sub.h-1,t-1~ is normally and independently
distributed with a mean |Lambda~ and a constant variance
||Sigma~.sup.2~. (I show below that this supposition follows from the
assumptions already made.) Equation (A2) then takes the form
|summation of~ ||(1 - |Delta~)/(1 + |Rho~)~.sup.i~ x where i=0to
|infinity~
exp|(-|Alpha~|Lambda~ + ||Alpha~.sup.2~||Sigma~.sup.2~/2)(i + 1)~ =
(1 + |Rho~)/(r + |Delta~)
or
(A3) |Lambda~ |is equivalent to~ |Alpha~||Sigma~.sup.2~/2 + 1/|Alpha~
ln|(1 + r)/(1 + |Rho~)~.
Since |d.sub.ht~ - |d.sub.h-1,t-1~ is independently distributed with
a mean |Lambda~,
(A4) |E.sub.t~|d.sub.h+i,t+i~ = |Lambda~i + |d.sub.ht~.
Similarly,
|E.sub.t~|d.sub.h+i-1,t+i-1~ = |Lambda~(i - 1) + |d.sub.ht~
= |Lambda~i + |d.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t-1~(|d.sub.ht~ - |d.sub.h-1,t-1~)
(A5) = |Lambda~i + |d.sub.h-1,t-1~ + (|d.sub.ht~ -
|E.sub.t-1~(|d.sub.ht~).
Subtracting 1 - |Delta~ times equation (A5) from equation (A4)
produces
(A6) |E.sub.t~||d.sub.h+i,t+i~ - (1 - |Delta~)|d.sub.h+i-1,t+i-1~~ =
|Lambda~ |Delta~i + |d.sub.ht~ - (1 - |Delta~)|d.sub.h-1,t-1~~ - (1 -
|Delta~)(|d.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t~|d.sub.ht~).
From equation (2), one has
(A7) |c.sub.ht~ = |d.sub.ht~ - (1 - |Delta~)|d.sub.h-1,t-1~;
hence
(A8) |d.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t-1~|d.sub.ht~ = |c.sub.ht~ -
|E.sub.t-1~|c.sub.ht~.
It follows from equations (A6)-(A8) that
(A9) |E.sub.t~|c.sub.h+i,t+i~ = |Lambda~|Delta~i + |c.sub.ht~ - (1 -
|Delta~)(|c.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t-1~|c.sub.ht~).
Solving equation (3) forward and applying the expectation operator
|E.sub.t~ to both members of the resulting equation yields
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where |Psi~ |is equivalent to~ (1 - p)/(1 + r). Substituting equation
(A9) into equation (A10) and rearranging the resulting equation then
produces (A11) |c.sub.ht~ = -|Lambda~|Delta~/|Mu~ + (1 -
|Delta~)|Psi~(|c.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t-1~|c.sub.ht~) + |Mu~|a.sub.h-1,t-1~
+ |Mu~|Psi~ |summation of~ ||Psi~.sup.i~|E.sub.t~|w.sub.h+i,t+i~ where
i=0 to |infinity~,
where |Mu~ |is equivalent to~ (r + p)/(1 - p).
I now show that conditional on the information available to
households in period t, |d.sub.ht~ - |d.sub.h-1,t-1~ is normally
distributed with a mean |Lambda~ and a constant variance. Applying the
operator 1 - |E.sub.t-1~ to both members of equation (A11), substituting
equation (4) into the resulting equation, letting v |is equivalent to~
(r+p)/(r+|Delta~+p-|Delta~p), and rearranging yields
(A12) |c.sub.ht~ - |E.sub.t-1~|c.sub.ht~ = v |summation of~
||Psi~.sup.i~(|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~)|w.sub.t+i~ where i=0 to
|infinity~
since (|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~)||Pi~.sub.h+i~ = 0. Equations (A9) and
(A12) then imply that
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
From equations (A7) and (A13), one has
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
It follows that
(A15) |d.sub.ht~ - |d.sub.h-1,t-1~ = |Lambda~ + v |summation of~
||Psi~.sup.i~(|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~)|w.sub.t+i~ where i=0 to
|infinity~.
The distributional assumptions made in section II insure that
|d.sub.ht~ - |d.sub.h-1,t-1~ is normally and independently distributed
with a mean |Lambda~ and a constant variance.
Substituting equation (A12) into equation (A11) yields the individual
consumption function:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
At time t, households of age h comprise a fraction p|(1 - p).sup.h~
of the population. Aggregating equation (A16) and substituting from
equation (4) therefore results in
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
or
(A17) |c.sub.t~ = |Kappa~ + (r+p)|a.sub.t-1~
+ v |summation of~ ||Psi~.sup.i~||E.sub.t~ - (1 -
|Delta~)|Psi~|E.sub.t - 1~~|w.sub.t+i~ where i=0 to |infinity~
where |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~.
Aggregating equation (3) produces
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
(A18) |c.sub.t~ + |a.sub.t~ = (1 + r)|a.sub.t-1~ + |w.sub.t~.
Lagging equation (A17) one period, multiplying the resulting equation
by 1/|Psi~ and subtracting from equation (A17), and substituting from
equation (A18) produces
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
or
(A19) |Delta~|c.sub.t~ = |Beta~ - p|Mu~|a.sub.t-1~ + v |summation of~
||Psi~.sup.i~|(|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~) where i=0 to |infinity~
- (1 - |Delta~)(|E.sub.t-1~- |E.sub.t-2~)~|w.sub.t+i~
where
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Equation (A19) is equivalent to equation (5) in the text.
B. The Data(23)
The data on real private final consumption expenditure come from the
OECD's National Accounts: Main Aggregates. Except for Canada,
Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States, my measure of
|a.sub.t~, the stock of financial assets, is
(B1) |a.sub.0~ + |summation of~ |(S.sub.j~ - |SG.sub.j~)/|P.sub.j~ -
(|I.sub.j~/|i.sub.j~)(1/|P.sub.j-1~-1/|P.sub.j~)~ where j=1 to t
where S is nominal net national saving, SG is nominal net government
saving, I is nominal net interest payments by the government, i is
typically the nominal long-term government bond rate, and P is the
deflator for the gross domestic product.(24) The term
(|I.sub.t~/|i.sub.t~)(1/|P.sub.t-1~ - 1/|P.sub.t~), my measure of the
inflation tax levied on the government's net nominal liabilities,
is subtracted in (B1) because |SG.sub.t~ fails to include it. The data
on S and P come from National Accounts: Main Aggregates; the data on SG
and I come from the OECD's National Accounts: Detailed Tables and a
computer tape provided by the OECD; and the data on i come from the
IMF's Yearbook of International Financial Statistics. Because the
estimate of -p(r+p)/(1-p) is not affected by the value of |a.sub.0~, it
can be equated to zero without loss. I did so when I use equation (8) to
generate |a.sub.t~.
Statistics Canada's National Balance Sheet Accounts, 1961-1985,
provides year-end Canadian data on the net worths of the nation as a
whole and of the government from which the net worth of the private
sector can be calculated. I deflated by the consumer price index for
December to obtain a, the real net worth of the private sector, for
1961-1985. I extended the series back to 1959 and forward to 1987 by
decumulating or accumulating real net private saving from the 1961 and
1985 values of the real net worth of the private sector. The consumer
price index for Canada, as well as those for Japan, the United Kingdom,
and the United States, comes from the SAS Citibase tape.
The Economic Planning Agency's Report on National Accounts from
1955 to 1969 and Annual Report on National Accounts provide year-end
Japanese data on the net worths of the nation and of the government. My
measure of a is the difference between these series divided by the
consumer price index for December.
The Central Statistical Office's Economic Trends and United
Kingdom National Accounts provide year-end U.K. data for 1975-1987 on
the net worths of the nation as a whole and of the government from which
the net worth of the private sector can be calculated. I deflated by the
consumer price index for December to obtain a, the real net worth of the
private sector, for 1975-1987. Using the 1975 value of this series as a
benchmark and the procedure described above for Canada, I extended the
series back to 1959.
My measure of a for the United States is the nominal net worth of the
private sector at the year end less the nominal stock of consumer
durables at year end divided by the consumer price index for December.
The data on net worth and consumer durables come from the Board of
Governors' Balance Sheets for the U.S. Economy, 1949-88.
C. Time Aggregation
Let the index t be measured in units of time equal to the decision
period of households, and let a year contain n such periods. Lagging
equation (5) 0, 1, ..., n-1 times and adding the resulting equations
together yields
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Lagging equation (C1) 0, 1, ..., n-1 times, adding the resulting
equations together, and dividing each member by n then produces
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ and
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
since
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Note that |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ and that |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ and |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, i = 2, 3, 4,
..., under the null hypothesis that p = 0. If |Delta~|a.sub.t~ has no
memory, |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ and |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ also hold under the alternative hypothesis. With these
restrictions imposed, equation (C2) can be reindexed as
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
|Tau~ is an index of time measured in years, and |v.sub.|Tau~~ is the
serially uncorrelated error term for which |v.sub.|Tau~~ +
|Theta~|v.sub.|Tau~-1~ has the same representation as |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~. By construction, |v.sub.|Tau~~ is uncorrelated with
all information available to households in period |Tau~-1. Note that
|Beta~|prime~ and p|prime~ in equation (C4) have units of reciprocal
years and are therefore n times the |Beta~ and p in equation (C2), which
have units of reciprocal decision period. In contrast, |Mu~ is
dimensionless and hence would not change, were compounding continuous.
For expositional convenience, I do not distinguish between the time
indices t and |Tau~ in the text.
1. See his "Funding System" in Sraffa |1951~. Ricardo
himself regarded his point as purely hypothetical. See O'Driscoll
|1977~.
2. Allowing for nonzero population growth as in Weil |1987~ would
complicate the exposition without adding materially to the theoretical
analysis. The empirical analysis, however, takes population growth into
account.
3. Consider a household facing a binding constraint on its assets T
periods from now. Even if the constraint is temporary and the household
has an expected lifetime much longer than T periods or regards future
households as continuations of itself, it maximizes its utility over the
next T periods subject to a terminal wealth constraint and therefore
behaves as if it has a horizon of at most T periods. Woodford |1990~ has
provided an example of such a model.
4. Cochrane |1989~ has shown that near-rational intertemporal
allocations of consumption can entail trivial costs. Boundedly rational
households may therefore choose to behave myopically, acting as if their
current decisions do not affect allocations beyond some horizon.
5. Nothing material depends on the assumption that such bets can be
made on consumer durables so long as they can be made on financial
assets. If such bets cannot be made on either type of asset, Ricardian
equivalence can be shown to hold in this model, however short horizons
are. If only actuarially unfair bets can be made on financial assets,
households act as if their ps are reduced. See Evans |1991~. Note also
that capital-market imperfections that drive borrowing rates above
lending rates are likely to have effects qualitatively similarly to
those produced by a positive p.
6. This assumption can be relaxed somewhat. Assuming that
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
is uncorrelated with all information known in period t - 1 yields the
same basic result.
7. If population grows at a constant exogenous rate g, equations (5)
and (6) hold if r is replaced by (r - g)/(1 + 8), the net interest rate,
and if p is replaced by (p + g)/(1 + g), the rate at which disconnected
households flow into the economy; i.e., the "birth" rate.
Ricardian equivalence holds if all new households are connected to old
households; i.e., if p = -9. In that case, households act as if their
memberships are growing at the same rate as population is growing. If
instead households act as if their memberships are growing less rapidly
than population is growing, then Blanchard's alternative to
Ricardian equivalence holds.
8. This result is similar to one derived by Mankiw |1982~, who
assumed that momentary utility is quadratic in the stock of consumption
goods.
9. This proposition must be modified if the momentary utility
function takes the form -exp|-|Alpha~(|d.sub.ht~ - ||Epsilon~.sub.t~)~,
where ||Epsilon~.sub.t~ is an aggregate preference shock. Suppose that
the innovations to |Delta~|Epsilon~ are normally, independently, and
identically distributed with a finite variance. Then |a.sub.t-1~ is
correlated with |u.sub.t~ unless |Delta~|Epsilon~ has no memory. Lagging
the instrumental variables sufficiently, however, may eliminate this
problem.
10. I also fitted the model to an expenditure total that excludes
expenditure on durables and to one that excludes expenditures on both
durables and semidurables. These expenditure totals are available only
for a subset of the countries and only over subsets of 1960-1988,
however. No inferences are affected by the choice of expenditure
aggregate.
11. Because changes in the preference shock |Epsilon~ defined in
footnote 9 may have a positive memory, I also fitted equation (7)
employing the intercept and |a.sub.t-3~ as instruments. No inferences
were affected.
12. The variances of (|E.sub.t~ - |E.sub.t-1~)|w.sub.t+i,i~ = 0, 1,
2, ..., and hence of |u.sub.t~ are likely to have grown over the sample
period t because of growth in population and technological progress.
13. I also attempted to model the coefficients on a as depending on
such demographic variables as the population growth rate, the birth
rate, and the fraction of population of working age. None of these
variables explains how these coefficients vary across countries or
enables the regressions to be pooled.
14. I used the intercept, |z.sub.1t-2~, and |z.sub.2t-2~ as the
instrumental variables, where |z.sub.1t~ and |z.sub.2t~ are the first
two principal components of the nineteen |a.sub.t~ series. These
principal components account for over 99 percent of the variation in the
nineteen series.
15. These results appear to be insensitive to the countries included
in the sample. The pooling restrictions are strongly rejected for
samples that exclude the four poorest countries, the four richest
countries, and the two poorest and two richest countries. Conditional on
accepting the pooling restrictions, one can also strongly reject
Ricardian equivalence in favor of Blanchard's alternative for these
samples.
16. According to the OECD's National Accounts, Volume II:
Detailed Tables, 1975-1987, the ratio of net operating surplus to net
capital stock in manufacturing averaged .122 per annum between 1975 and
1987 in Australia, Canada, Finland, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the
United States. Part of this return was taxed away, part was a return to
bearing risk, and the population growth rate must also be netted off
against it. (See footnote 7.) The values considered in Table II are
therefore likely to span the range of reasonable values for the
parameter r.
17. The standard errors probably understate the uncertainty in the
estimates of p because the parameter r is treated as if it is known with
certainty. The understatement may not be large, however, since the point
estimates reported in Table II are not especially sensitive to r. The
low sensitivity of the point estimates to r also means that the
inferences drawn below are insensitive to the value assigned to r.
18. The interpretation of p as a birth rate, however, is not
supported by the evidence discussed in footnote 13.
19. For i = 0, 1, ..., N-1, one unit of government debt issued in
year t+i requires r|(1+r).sup.N-i~ of servicing taxes beginning in year
t+N. Summing this expression over i yields |(1+r).sup.N~-1.
20. This point has been made previously by Poterba and Summers |1987~
inter alia.
21. Using equations (A17) and (A18) in the appendix, one can easily
show that |a.sub.t~ is stationary if p |is greater than~ 0 and if
|w.sub.t~ is either trend- or difference-stationary; see Evans and Hasan
|1993~. If the economy is closed,
|a.sub.t~ = |k.sub.t~ + |d.sub.t~,
where |k.sub.t~ and |d.sub.t~ are the stocks of capital and
government debt at the end of year t. A countercyclical tax policy makes
|d.sub.t~ difference-stationary. Moreover, the more aggressive the
policy is, the greater is the unconditional variance of
|Delta~|d.sub.t~. Four results follow immediately: (i) under a
balanced-budget policy, |k.sub.t~ is stationary; (ii) under a
countercyclical tax policy, |k.sub.t~ is difference-stationary and
cointegrated with |d.sub.t~ with the cointegrating vector (1,-1); (iii)
a permanent increase of one in |d.sub.t~ ultimately produces a permanent
reduction of one in |k.sub.t~; and (iv) the more aggressive the
countercyclical tax policy is, the greater is the unconditional variance
of |Delta~|k.sub.t~.
22. In a more complete model in which the interest rate is
endogenous, this conclusion may not hold since the tax cut would raise
the interest rate, thereby preventing consumption from jumping as much
as reported in Table III. Indeed, my 1991 paper shows that in the
general equilibrium of a closed economy, the momentary marginal
propensity to consume from a long-lived tax cut is only about .08 for p
= .04 per annum and the long-run effects on the capital stock and
consumption are fairly small.
23. My data and programs are available upon request.
24. Assuming that r is constant is tantamount to assuming that saving
as measured in national accounts is the change in net worth. In that
case, my procedure for measuring a is likely to produce a good
approximation. In contrast, if revaluations of the stock of assets are
empirically important, my procedure may instead produce a poor
approximation. See Bradford |1990~ for evidence that revaluations may be
important.
REFERENCES
Aschauer, David A. "Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand."
American Economic Review, March 1985, 117-28.
Barro, Robert J. "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" Journal
of Political Economy, December 1974, 1161-76.
-----. The Impact of Social Security on Private Saving: Evidence from
the U.S. Time Series. Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1978,
1-36.
Blanchard, Olivier J. "Debt, Deficits, and Finite
Horizons." Journal of Political Economy, April 1985, 223-47.
Blinder, Alan S., and Angus Deaton. "The Time Series Consumption
Function Revisited." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 2,
1985, 465-511.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Balance Sheets for
the U.S. Economy, 1949-88. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, 1989.
Boskin, Michael J., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. "Public Debt and
United States Saving: A New Test of the Neutrality Hypothesis."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series for Public Policy, Autumn 1985,
55-86.
Bradford, David F. "What Is National Saving? Alternative
Measures in Historical and International Context." National Bureau
of Economic Research Working Paper No. 3341, April 1990.
Central Statistical Office. Economic Trends. London: Her
Majesty's Stationery Office, May 1987.
-----. United Kingdom National Accounts. London: Her Majesty's
Stationery Office, 1989, 1990.
Cochrane, John H. "The Sensitivity of Tests of the Intertemporal
Allocation of Consumption to Near-Rational Alternatives." American
Economic Review, June 1989, 319-37.
Economic Planning Agency. Annual Report on National Accounts. Tokyo:
Okura-sho Insatsu-kyoku, 1990a.
-----. Report on National Accounts from 1955 to 1969. Tokyo:
Okura-sho Insatsu-kyoku, 1990b.
Evans, Paul. "Are Consumers Ricardian? Evidence for the United
States." Journal of Political Economy, October 1988, 983-1004.
-----. "Is Ricardian Equivalence a Good Approximation?"
Economic Inquiry, October 1991, 626-44.
Evans, Paul, and Iftekhar Hasan. "Are Consumers Ricardian?
Evidence for the United States." Quarterly Journal of Economics and
Finance, forthcoming, July 1993.
Feldstein, Martin S. "Reply," in The Effect of Social
Security on Private Saving: Evidence from the U.S. Time Series, edited
by Robert J. Barro. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute,
1978, 37-47.
-----. "Government Deficits and Aggregate Demand." Journal
of Monetary Economics, January 1982, 1-20.
Feldstein, Martin S., and Douglas W. Elmendorf. "Government
Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector Behavior Revisited:
Comment." American Economic Review, June 1990, 589-99.
Hansen, Lars Peter. "Large Sample Properties of Generalized
Method of Moments Estimators." Econometrica, November 1982,
1029-54.
International Monetary Fund. Yearbook of International Financial
Statistics, 1989. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1990.
Kochin, Levis A. "Are Future Taxes Anticipated by Consumers?
Comment." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, August 1974,
385-94.
Kormendi, Roger C. "Government Debt, Government Spending and
Private Sector Behavior." American Economic Review, December 1983,
994-1010.
Kormendi, Roger C., and Philip Meguire. "Government Debt,
Government Spending and Private Sector Behavior: Reply." American
Economic Review, December 1986, 1180-87.
-----. "Government Debt, Government Spending and Private Sector
Behavior: Reply and Update." American Economic Review, June 1990,
604-17.
Leiderman, Leonardo, and Assaf Razin. "Testing Ricardian
Neutrality with an Intertemporal Stochastic Model." Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, February 1988, 1-21.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. "Hall's Consumption Hypothesis and
Durable Goods." Journal of Monetary Economics, November 1982,
417-26.
Modigliani, Franco, and Arlie G. Sterling. "Government Debt,
Government Spending and Private Sector Behavior: Comment." American
Economic Review, December 1986, 1168-79.
-----. "Government Debt, Government Spending and Private Sector
Behavior: A Further Comment." American Economic Review, June 1990,
600-603.
O'Driscoll, Gerald P., Jr. "The Ricardian Nonequivalence
Theorem." Journal of Political Economy, February 1977, 207-10.
Organization for Co-operation and Development. Department of
Statistics. National Accounts, Volume II: Detailed Tables. Paris: OECD
Publications, 1972, 1982, 1985, 1988, 1990.
-----. National Accounts, Volume I: Main Aggregates, 1960-1988.
Paris: OECD Publications, 1990.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers. "Finite Lifetimes
and the Saving Effect of Budget Deficits." Journal of Monetary
Economics, September 1987, 369-92.
Seater, John J. "Are Future Taxes Discounted?" Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, August 1982, 376-89.
Seater, John J., and Roberto S. Mariano. "New Tests of the Life
Cycle and Tax Discounting Hypotheses." Journal of Monetary
Economics, March 1985, 195-215.
Sraffa, Piero. The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, vol. 4.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951.
Statistics Canada. National Balance Sheet Accounts, 1961-1985.
Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, 1986.
Tanner, J. Ernest. "An Empirical Investigation of Tax
Discounting: A Comment." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, May
1979, 214-18.
Weil, Philippe. "Permanent Budget Deficits and Inflation."
Journal of Monetary Economics, September 1987, 393-410.
Woodford, Michael. "Public Debt as Private Liquidity."
American Economic Review, May 1990, 382-388.
PAUL EVANS, Professor of Economics, Ohio State University. I am
grateful for helpful comments from Dick Sweeney, an anonymous referee,
and participants in seminars at the University of Michigan, the Osaka
Institute of Economic and Social Research, Keio University, and the
Tokyo Center for Economic Research. Bob Barsky, Martin Evans, Miles
Kimball, Atsushi Maki, and Naoyuki Yoshino, Yoshino made especially
helpful comments. I carried out some of the research reported in this
paper while visiting the Osaka Institute of Economic and Social
Research. I am grateful for the hospitality and financial support
provided by the Institute.