The influence of economics on antitrust law.
Kovacic, William E.
Economists today play prominent roles in formulating antitrust
policy and litigating antitrust cases. This paper explains why economics
influences antitrust law and describes how economic theories enter and
shape the antitrust system. Antitrust policy and doctrine change over
time in response to developments in economic theory, and the
decentralization of the antitrust adjudication system and the wide
latitude accorded judges in interpreting antitrust statutes ensure that
legal rules will reflect advances in the economic literature concerning
the appropriate content of standards governing business conduct.
I. INTRODUCTION
Twenty-five years ago, George Stigler [1976] asked whether
economists matter in the formulation of public policy. A century of
experience with the federal antitrust laws indicates that they do.
Whereas assessments of their impact vary, most observers regard
economists as important participants in the antitrust system. Eisner
[1991] emphasizes the modern imprint of Chicago School economic
perspectives upon antitrust enforcement and litigation. Rowe [1984] and
Hovenkamp [1989] show that economists and economic theory have
influenced antitrust doctrine and policy throughout the period since the
passage of the Sherman Act. As a rough contemporary market test, one can
simply note the expanding number of economic consulting firms for whom
antitrust counselling and litigation are staples of the practice.[1]
This allocation of society's resources is a reliable sign that
economic analysis is significant in the prosecution and adjudication of
antitrust cases.
This paper suggests why economists and economic learning matter to
antitrust policy and describes how the work of economists affects
antitrust litigation. The discussion is divided into four parts. The
first identifies features of the antitrust system that permit or require
economic ideas to be taken seriously. The second part considers how
antitrust-relevant economic ideas are generated and absorbed into the
antitrust system. The third part examines factors that determine how
deeply economic ideas influence antitrust adjudication. The paper
concludes by discussing how economics will influence the antitrust
system in the Sherman Act's second century. II. THE OPENNESS OF
THE ANTITRUST
SYSTEM TO ECONOMIC IDEAS
Economic analysis influences antitrust litigation because the
federal antitrust system is unusually permeable. This permeability is
the result of three important features of the antitrust system. The
first is the wide range of analytical criteria that courts are permitted
to consider in resolving antitrust disputes. Federal judges play a
central role in determining the content of the antitrust statutes-
Outcomes under the Sherman Act depend crucially upon the construction of
ambiguous terms such as "conspiracy in restraint of trade" and
"monopolize." As Salop and White [1988, 37] point out, the
decision to cast the statutes in general terms has given judges
substantial discretion to determine litigation outcomes by defining the
content of the statutes' operative terms.
In conferring this interpretive role upon the federal courts,
Congress has allowed judges to devise standards of conduct at least in
part by reference to the likely economic effects of various forms of
business behavior. Despite sharp disagreement over the weight Congress
meant to accord productive and allocative efficiency as judicial
decision making criteria,[2] few scholars seriously argue that Congress
intended that courts treat such concerns as irrelevant. Economists would
play a far less important part in antitrust adjudication if Congress had
precluded judicial consideration of efficiency in implementing statutory
commands. The open ended language and indeterminate goals of the
antitrust statutes allow economists to affect adjudication and rule
formulation to a degree unattainable under most other federal regulatory
schemes.
The second feature of the antitrust system is the large number of
parties who can give a new idea judicial standing. Interpretation of the
antitrust statutes occurs in a highly decentralized adjudication
framework. Thirteen courts of appeals, ninetyfour district courts, and
the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) share power to decide cases and
formulate liability standards. One federal district judge or a single
court of appeals panel can establish a new theory or a proposed conduct
standard as an acceptable basis for decision.3 The Supreme Court hears
few antitrust cases, and genuine differences in analytical approaches
among the lower federal courts are common. Broadly dispersed
adjudicatory power offers a wide array of paths through which litigants
can inject new economic theories in the system.
The third feature is the number and diversity of parties who can
file antitrust suits. Congress gave antitrust standing to numerous
potential claimants. Consumers, private companies, the federal antitrust
agencies, and state attorneys general all have standing to pursue
antitrust suits. No single gatekeeper controls access to the courts or
determines what ideas may be asserted to support antitrust claims.
Decentralizing the decision to prosecute means that one entity's
rejection of certain theories does not bar others from using those
theories.[4]
The relative ease with which new economic concepts can enter the
courtroom has major implications for the direction of doctrine and
analysis over time. First, the antitrust system's porosity ensures
that today's accepted wisdom will face periodic challenges by rival
theories that eventually may become the prevailing analytical
approaches. Second, owing to the discretion conferred by the antitrust
statutes, litigation outcomes in close cases will depend substantially
upon the preferences of individual judges. A jurist's receptivity
to specific economic arguments will hinge largely upon her tastes,
training, and experience. Thus, a president can determine how economics
and particular economic views affect antitrust litigation by his choice
of judicial nominees.
III. THE CREATION AND ADOPTION OF NEW ECONOMIC IDEAS
The Sherman Act created an unparalleled opportunity for economists
to participate in the evolution of a national regulatory program. This
section examines the incentives that spur the creation and application
of new antitrust-relevant economic ideas and describes how the antitrust
system absorbs them.
Incentives for Creation
Economist as Scientist and Truthseeker. The creation of new
economic ideas results from a variety of motivations. One is the
economist's ethic of scientific inquiry. The processes of
hypothesis formulation and testing spur the discovery, refinement, and
displacement of analytical models over time. The antitrust system fuels
this process by offering an expansive menu of problems to be analyzed
and empirical data (generated by lawsuits and investigations) to be
evaluated. The incentives that guide academic economists in devising
research agendas ensure that prevailing models face continuing
examination and challenge by rival theories. In particular, a persuasive
attack on today's accepted wisdom may be an effective means for
drawing attention to the researcher's work.
Economist as Advocate. A second stimulus to research in antitrust
economics is the demand of various antitrust system participants for
useful economic ideas. The needs of corporate plaintiffs and defendants,
private attorneys, federal enforcement agencies, and state enforcement
bodies generate a demand for theories to support favored policy and
litigation outcomes. The largest and most prominent part of the demand
is for theories that exculpate defendants. This does not mean that the
demand for pro-enforcement theories is trivial.5 Firms sometimes find it
useful to press antitrust claims against suppliers, direct rivals, or
potential acquirers. Among other motivations, Baumol and Ordover [1985],
Hazlett [1986], and Shughart [1990] describe how firms can use antitrust
suits strategically to disadvantage competitors. Business plaintiffs
willing to make substantial investments in the development of
economically sophisticated theory may win significant legal victories
using causes of action that ordinarily fare poorly in the federal
courts.6
Thus, consumers of antitrust-relevant economic theories have an
incentive to support research to generate useful ideas or to take
existing ideas and devise applications that support favored litigation
outcomes. Since 1970, for example, corporations have extensively funded
antitrust research by individual academics, academic institutes, think
tanks, and foundations.7 Such inducements undoubtedly affect economists.
In particular, the demand for preferred applications of existing models
probably accounts for much of the modern increase in the number of
economists who provide antitrust consulting services in affiliation with
consulting firms or as independent contractors.
Over time, the financial rewards of litigation consulting can
render the economist less a truthseeker and more an advocate.8 The
imperative to develop and retain clients, rather than the disinterested
quest for knowledge, will exert an increasing pull upon the
consultant's analysis and research. Discussions about the
convergence of law and economics in antitrust cases usually focus on the
tendency of attorneys to absorb and apply economic learning. A less
noted aspect of this convergence is that industrial organization
economists increasingly have assumed ad hoc advocacy functions
ordinarily associated with attorneys. For example, in many litigation
settings, the economist must make a commitment to consult or testify for
a party before a full factual framework of the case is developed. When
subsequent investigation and discovery reveal facts that contradict the
economist's initial theory, there is a strong incentive for the
economist to modify her theory to accommodate new discordant facts, even
though the reformulated theory may stray significantly from the
economist's original assessment of the case.[9]
The Process of Absorption
Once devised, new economic ideas must be brought to the attention
of judges who decide antitrust disputes. In order to observe how judges
use economic ideas in their decisions, I have reviewed all fiftythree
Supreme Court decisions from 1890 through 1990 involving alleged
violations of the Sherman Act Section 2 prohibition upon monopolization,
attempted monopolization, and conspiracies to monopolize.[10] Section 2
disputes confront the Court with a rich collection of economic issues
involving market definition, market power measurement, and criteria for
identifying improper exclusionary conduct. These decisions provide one
context for considering how the antitrust system absorbs the ideas of
economists.
Explicit Reliance on Economic Commentary. Citations to economic
scholarship in published opinions provide the most direct way to
identify a judge's sources of economic insight and assess how
economic ideas came to the judge's attention. Sixteen of the
fifty-three Supreme Court Section 2 decisions cite commentators from any
academic discipline (law, economics, or otherwise);11 eight of these
refer to economists.[12] Most of the Court's pivotal Section 2
decisions[13] cite no economists, and decisions that raise Section 2
issues but focus on other antitrust claims[14] likewise rarely mention
economists. As a group, these decisions permit several observations
about how economists affect judicial thinking.
Legal Scholars as Intermediaries. The economic references cited in
the Court's opinions usually consist of works by economically
sophisticated attorneys who have popularized the economic literature.15
In this century, attorneys such as Phillip Areeda, Robert Bork, Frank
Easterbrook, Ernest Gellhorn, Milton Handler, Edward Levi, Richard
Posner, and Donald Turner (who is also an economist) have made the
economic literature accessible to the Supreme Court and lower court
judges.16 Legal scholars serve as intermediaries who apply the insights
of economists to legal problems in terms that judges can readily
comprehend.[17] The influence of these intermediaries stems largely from
their attention to the administrability of proposed analytical models.
Judges tend to be wary of models whose complexity or sensitive
assumptions make such models prone to misapplication in the routine
decision of cases.
These legal intermediaries will be increasingly important in the
future. Comprehending new microeconomic scholarship increasingly demands
quantitative skills that few lawyers or judges possess. If game theory
insights are to significantly alter judicial analysis of exclusionary
conduct, it first will be necessary for the literature to be translated
into what Judge Stephen Breyer has termed "antitrust
lingo."[18] The technically exotic quality of modern industrial
organization scholarship probably means that the most important
translators of the new "new learning" in the future will
include attorney-economists such as lan Ayres, Jonathan Baker, and Louis
Kaplow who have the technical skills and legal training to evaluate the
new learning and convey its significance to judges.
Absorption Lags. The time required for legal scholars to perform
the steps of interpretation, evaluation, and reformulation means that
there will be a significant lag between the appearance of ideas in
economics journals and the acceptance of such ideas by antitrust courts.
Judges may be wary of citing state-of-the-art economic literature
because today's insight might soon be undercut by opposing views.
Rather, judges may prefer to wait until economic theories have undergone
testing in the academic debate and have received the endorsement of
economically astute legal scholars before citing them as bases for
decision.
As Langenfeld and Scheffman [1986] point out, absorption lags also
have figured prominently in the evolution of federal enforcement policy.
Post-World War II hostility toward industrial concentration originated
at the University of Chicago in the 1930s in the work of Henry Simons,
who argued that deconcentration was essential to the nation's
political and economic well-being.[19] From 1945 until the early 1970s,
many economists embraced Simons's enthusiasm for dispersing market
power and preventing further concentration via merger. Carl
Kaysen's and Donald Turner's Antitrust Policy [1959], the
chief "law and economics" antitrust text of its time, elevated
deconcentration to the status of a major antitrust goal in the 1960s and
early 1970s. President Johnson's White House Task Force Report on
Antitrust Policy [1968-69] used the Kaysen-Turner proposals to develop
its own deconcentration proposal. Task Force members who endorsed the
measure included economists (Paul MacAvoy, James McKie, Lee Preston) and
economically astute attorneys (William Baxter, William Jones, James
Rahl). As late as 1971, economists such as Roger Sherman and Robert
Tollison [1971, 89-90] backed deconcentration and strict antimerger
policies.
The consensus among economists supporting deconcentration crumbled,
and scholars such as Meehan and Larner [1989] have extensively recounted
the demise of the structure-conduct-performance paradigm that supported
attacks on corporate size. However, as post-Simon Chicago perspectives
gained prominence in the late 1970s and the 1980s, the federal
enforcement agencies had started an expansive collection of
monopolization and shared-monopoly lawsuits that drew upon structuralist
economic theories. Kovacic [1989a] finds that the agencies'
commitment of massive resources to deconcentration in the late 1960s and
early 1970s would not have occurred without an apparent consensus of
support from economists. By the time the deconcentration measures were
fully launched, the consensus that inspired them had vanished.
The Role of Litigants. Litigants who appear before the federal
courts may themselves influence the degree and speed of absorption of
new ideas.[20] The Section 2 case data set and other Supreme Court
antitrust decisions indicate that litigants influence what literature
judges will consult and cite. Well-conceived briefs can shape the
Supreme Court's analytical approach.[21] Briefs in antitrust
matters before the Supreme Court infrequently cite economists but do
occasionally cite secondary materials written by legal scholars. This
underscores the importance of legal scholars as bridges between
economists and the courts.
Judicial Law Clerks. Law clerks affect the type of literature and
economic ideas that are reflected in published opinions. Carp and
Stidham [1991, 75-79] observe that judges often delegate important
research and analysis tasks to their law clerks. A clerk's
expertise and interests help shape the amount and content of information
that comes to the judge's attention.[22] Judges who hire clerks
with training in economics are more likely to be exposed to the relevant
industrial organization literature and to take such research into
account in deciding antitrust cases.
Implicit Reliance on Economic Models. Citations to economists and
economically oriented legal scholars provide the most readily observable
index of the Court's sources of economic insight. The absence of
such citations, however, does not mean that judicial decisions are not
informed by the jurist's views of economics. Opinions might not
specify the grounds for these perceptions, but there is considerable
evidence indicating that, despite the paucity of citations to
economically oriented literature, the ideas of economists affect how
judges resolve antitrust cases.[23] This phenomenon is apparent in the
Sherman Act's first decades, when legal formalism disinclined
judges to draw upon on other academic disciplines in conceiving legal
rules. Hovenkamp [1989, 167] finds that, in the late 1800s and early
1900s, legal formalists believed that "the law generated its own
supply of ideas and that lawyers need not look elsewhere."
Hovenkamp [1988] and May [1989] show that judicial opinions in economic
regulation cases at the turn of the century reflected prevailing views
of economists, even though courts did not mention their writings.
Consequently, the Court's early antitrust decisions were
fact-intensive discourses laden with citations to judicial opinions.[24]
Not until 1925, in Maple Flooring Manufacturers' Association v.
United States,[25] did the Court mention an economist in an antitrust
decision. Maple Flooring appeared amid the ascent of legal realism, and
its author (Harlan Fiske Stone) shared the legal realists'
willingness to acknowledge contributions from other disciplines in
judicial opinion writing. The writings and biographies of Supreme Court
justices reveal how the jurists' understanding of economics has
shaped antitrust outcomes. Mason [1946, 26] states that Louis Brandeis once complained that judges frequently "came to the bench
unequipped with the necessary knowledge of economic and social
science," and he warned that "a lawyer who has not studied
economics and sociology is very apt to become a public enemy." On
the Supreme Court, Brandeis approached antitrust and other economic
regulation issues with a fully formed view of the role of business
enterprise in society. Brandeisian economics had two basic tenets.
First, superior performance never produced persistently large corporate
size; predatory conduct invariably did. Thus, doctrines barring dominant
firm "exclusionary conduct" benefited society. Second, small
firms deserved wide latitude to adopt practices that enabled them to
compete with larger companies. Brandeis urged that smaller manufacturers
be allowed to set resale prices and that small firms have broad freedom
to form trade associations and other collective arrangements.[26]
As suggested above, formal citation patterns may reflect the
background and expertise of individual jurists and their law clerks.
Judges might omit references to non-lawyers because other disciplines
are alien to their academic training and experience. Expertise imparts
confidence to rely upon nonlegal analytical tools, including
economics.[27] It is unsurprising that the first Supreme Court Section 2
opinion to cite an economist (the Standard Oil patents case[28] in 1931)
was written by Brandeis, who was conversant in economic thinking.
Justices who have cited economically oriented works in antitrust
cases--for example, Harlan Fiske Stone,[29] William Douglas,[30] Thomas
Clark,[31] John Paul Stevens,[32] and Antonin Scalia33tend to be former
academics who taught economic regulation (Stone, Douglas, Scalia) or
former antitrust practitioners (Clark and Stevens).
IV. THE EXTENT OF ECONOMIC'S INFLUENCE IN ANTITRUST
ADJUDICATION
To this point, the discussion has focused upon how judges absorb
new economic ideas. This section discusses factors that determine how
judges will respond to various economic ideas once such ideas are
brought to their attention.
Judicial Preferences
Judges enjoy considerable discretion to determine the content of
antitrust rules. Outcomes in close cases depend significantly upon the
policy preferences of judicial appointees. Short of gaining amendments
to the antitrust statutes, the power to appoint federal judges is a
president's surest means for seeing that his antitrust preferences
endure. The judicial nominee's pre-appointment training and
ideology influence the nominee's receptivity to various economic
arguments and her ability to adjust doctrine through opinion-writing and
discussions with colleagues. Preference shaping also can occur in
post-appointment training programs such as the Economics Institutes for
federal judges conducted by Henry Manne's Law and Economics
Center.[34]
Recent experience provides a useful context for assessing the
impact of judicial selection upon antitrust doctrine. Ronald Reagan
chose three Supreme Court justices and 46 percent of all federal judges
holding office in January 1989. The Reagan Administration altered the
federal judiciary's ideological perspective by choosing individuals
who, among other traits, doubted the efficacy of government economic
regulation. Kovacic [1991] has found that Reagan appointees to the
courts of appeals have adopted unfavorable positions toward antitrust
intervention to bar mergers, single-firm exclusionary conduct, and
vertical restraints more often than judges nominated by President
Carter. To an unusual extent, President Reagan appointed academics with
strong law and economics credentials. Through scholarship and study in
antitrust economics, judges such as Robert Bork, Frank Easterbrook,
Douglas Ginsburg, Richard Posner, Antonin Scalia, and Ralph Winter are
well-positioned to see that appellate decisions reflect careful
attention to economic learning and Chicago perspectives in particular.
These individuals have written important, economically sophisticated
opinions that promise to exert a disproportionately large influence on
antitrust doctrine.3s The opinions of Reagan law-and-economics judges
demonstrate that an appointee's intellectual capital shapes
performance on the bench.
Political Environment
As Rowe [1984], Kaplow [1987], and Kovacic [1989a] observe, the
political environment affects how heavily judges and enforcement
agencies rely upon economic analysis and the type of economic theory
used as a basis for decision making. Changes in the political climate
toward business determine whether antitrust enforcement policy and
judicial doctrine take expansive or narrow paths. Economic analysis
plays essentially two roles in this process. First, economic ideas
provide intellectual rationales for adjustments in policy and doctrine.
By itself, an intellectual vision may have little impact, but it may
offer a goal toward which to divert political currents. An inventory of
ideas helps determine whether discontent with existing policies and
doctrine will be translated into genuine change. The degree to which
public moods shape antitrust doctrine and policy often depends upon the
availability of an intellectual justification for change.
Second, broad acceptance of economic analysis retards the adoption
of policies that would depart radically from preexisting practice. Since
the mid-1970s, law school graduates have absorbed large doses of Chicago
School learning, and Chicago's analytical techniques have become
well-engrained in the antitrust culture as a result. As Kwoka and White
[1989, 5] conclude, future shifts in antitrust thinking are probable,
but wholesale abandonment of Chicago perspectives is improbable.
The interrelationship of political forces and economic analysis is
apparent in modern antitrust treatment of large firm conduct. In the
mid-1970s, the increased competitiveness of foreign companies in world
markets raised concerns that the United States no longer was the
world's foremost source of technological progress. Large domestic
firms whose size and "predatory" conduct once elicited calls
for deconcentration either had lost their market leadership or were now
seen as valuable sources of innovation. In their study of antitrust
decisions from 1975 through 1981 involving claims of anticompetitive
exclusion, Hurwitz and Kovacic [1982, 113-28] found that judges stopped
reciting the social benefits of curbing dominant firm discretion and
disavowed liability rules that might reduce incentives to innovate.
Warren-Era Supreme Court antitrust decisions emphasized non-efficiency
goals when American firms faced relatively few threats from abroad. By
1980 it was difficult for courts to slight efficiency and vindicate
non-economic goals. Economists provided the justifications for giving
dominant firms greater discretion to choose pricing and product
development strategies, but fundamental change in the political
environment made their ideas persuasive to courts and enforcement
agencies.
Structure and Leadership of the Public Enforcement Agencies
Several factors determine how seriously economic analysis affects
public enforcement. Eisner [1991] shows that one influence is the
establishment of economic analysis bureaus within the federal
enforcement agencies. At a minimum, such bureaus ensure that the agency
will identify and assess the economic consequences of proposed or
ongoing enforcement initiatives.36
Elzinga [1987] demonstrates that a second, equally important factor
is the background of the agency leadership. The agency's leadership
establishes how substantial a role economists and economic analysis will
play in the decision to prosecute. The Assistant Attorney General for
Antitrust and the FTC Chairman decide when and how much agency
economists will participate in case selection and analysis. Economists
approach equality with attorneys in this respect only when economists
(James Miller at the FTC in the 1980s) or economically oriented
attorneys (such as William Baxter and Douglas Ginsburg at the Antitrust
Division in the 1980s) run the enforcement agencies. Whether the views
of nominally important economic analysis offices will be decisive in the
decision to prosecute depends crucially upon the preferences of top
management.
V. CONCLUSION: ECONOMICS AND ANTITRUST'S SECOND CENTURY
Modern adjustments in policy and doctrine are simply the latest
signs of how changing economic visions affect the antitrust system.
Antitrust law and industrial organization economics have evolved in
tandem, with doctrine and enforcement policy lagging behind the
formation of a consensus among economists about appropriate liability
rules. This process will continue as developments in economic learning,
debate among researchers about the proper interpretation of business
phenomena, and changes in the political environment move courts and
enforcement agencies to modify doctrine and policy. The evolution will
be gradual, as the interaction of these elements generally discourages
dramatic swings in doctrine.
In the Sherman Act's second century, the interaction of supply
and demand in the marketplace for ideas will yield changes in the
intellectual equilibrium concerning important antitrust issues such as
merger control, vertical restraints, and single-firm conduct. As Baker
[1989] points out, Chicago captured the dominant intellectual market
share in the 1980s, but Chicago views today face extensive challenge in
economic commentary. The antitrust system's permeability means that
new perspectives can gain a foothold with no more than a persuasive
opinion by one federal court or a single enforcement decision by a
government agency.
Recent years have featured the emergence of a new industrial
organization literature (largely rooted in game theory) that identifies
ways in which conduct such as predation and leveraging can decrease
efficiency.[37] The policy implications of this literature dictate
greater concern, in devising liability standards and public enforcement
policy, with conduct that Chicago deems benign or procompetitive.
However, the complexity of this literature raises basic questions about
the capability of courts and enforcement agencies to apply its ideas
skillfully in adjudication and case selection.
One must begin by asking whether courts can absorb and apply
correctly the insights from the new generation of complex,
quantitatively sophisticated economic models. Three considerations
suggest that judges will absorb the new game theoretic literature
relatively slowly. First, most judges will be put off by the
mathematical orientation of modern microeconomics, and few will feel
comfortable applying this literature without extensive analysis and
restatement by legal scholars. Second, if judges are to use new
analytical approaches widely, intermediaries must provide administrable
standards that can be applied in the courtroom environment of incomplete
facts, disputed interpretations, and limited judicial economic
training.[38] Third, applying game theory to antitrust disputes will
pose significant informational demands that courts may be reluctant to
compel litigants to satisfy. Not only may judges doubt their (or a
jury's) ability to interpret such information properly, but the
time needed to collect and assimilate the required data may mean that
the industry in question changes significantly between the date the
complaint is filed and a decision on liability is rendered.
Issues of institutional competence also arise with regard to the
capability of the government enforcement agencies to use the insights of
game theory in formulating antitrust policy. The modern track record of
the Justice Department and FTC in applying state-of-the-art economic
theory dealing with exclusionary conduct and interdependent behavior has
been decidedly unimpressive. In the 1970s, the FTC pursued ambitious,
innovative cases involving strategic entry deterrence and market
signalling. Despite the commitment of some of the agency's best
human capital to these matters, the resulting cases fared poorly.[39]
The agencies' poor performance when going beyond the Chicago School
agenda of prosecuting explicit horizontal output restrictions and large
horizontal mergers requires one to explain why a new round of
state-of-the-art initiatives will do better.
The future influence of economics upon antitrust policy will depend
upon how successfully economists and attorneys come to grips with the
institutional incentives that determine whether new economic ideas are
translated into cases.
Upper-level government managers rarely hold office for more than a
few years, and they have weak incentives to invest resources in
activities that may not yield full appropriable returns during their
tenure. Detailed industry analysis, theory development, and
post-litigation evaluations are the research and development on which
sound antitrust programs are built, but they generate outputs that are
not readily appropriable by individual managers and therefore want for
adequate levels of support. By contrast, initiating new cases or
announcing new enforcement programs are events for which the agency
manager can claim credit immediately.
Today's manager probably will be gone when the new initiatives
reach their end, and there are too few incentives for the manager to
take precautions to ensure that heralded take-offs ultimately are
followed by smooth landings.[40] During antitrust revivals,
credit-claiming generates a surplus of innovative enforcement ventures
that yield few enduring successes and excessive failures. Thus, the
challenge for economists goes well beyond distilling the teachings of
game theory or other new models into operational enforcement principles.
An equally important and difficult task is to cure weaknesses in the
enforcement mechanism through which new models will be applied.
REFERENCES
Ayres, lan. 'Playing Games with the Law.' Stanford Law
Review, May 1990, 1291-1317. Baker, Jonathan B. 'Recent
Developments in Economics That Challenge Chicago School Views.'
Antitrust Law Journal 58(2), 1989, 645-55.
Baumol William J., and Janusz Ordover. 'Use of Antitrust to
Subvert Competition." Journal of Law & Economics, May 1985,
247-65.
Carp, Robert A., and Ronald Stidham. The Federal Courts.
Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1991.
DeSanti, Susan S., and William E. Kovacic. 'Matsushita: Its
Construction and Application by the Lower Courts." Antitrust Law
Journal 59(2), 1991, 609-53.
Eisner, Marc A. Antitrust and the Triumph of Economics. Chapel
Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1991.
Elzinga, Kenneth G. "Comment: Decision Makers Do
Matter," in Economic Liberties and the Judiciary, edited by James
A. Dom and Henry G. Marine. Fairfax, Va.: George Mason University Press,
1987, 301-7.
Fisher, Franklin M. "Games Economists Play: A Noncooperative
View.' RAND Journal of Economics, Spring 1989, 113-24.
Fox, Eleanor M., and James T. Halverson, eds. 'Judicial
Precedent and the New Economics,' in Antitrust Policy in
Transition: The Convergence of Law and Economics. Chicago: American Bar
Association, 1984a, 5-21.
"Are Economists Taking Over?,' in Antitrust Policy in
Transition: The Convergence of Law and Economics, Chicago: American Bar
Association, 1984b, 2341.
Fraenkel, Osmond K., ed. The Curse of Bigness--Miscellaneous Papers
of Louis D. Brandeis. New York: Viking Press, 1934.
Green, Mark J., Beverly C. Moore, Jr., and Bruce Wasserstein. The
Closed Enterprise System. New York: Grossman Publishers, 1972.
Hazlett, Thomas W. "Is Antitrust Anticompetitive?'
Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, Spring 1986, 277336.
Hovenkamp, Herbert. 'The Political Economy of Substantive Due
Process." Stanford Law Review, January 1988, 379-447.
"The Antitrust Movement and the Rise of Industrial
Organization.' Texas Law Review, November 1989, 105-68.
Hurwitz, James D., and William E. Kovacic. '"Judicial
Analysis of Predation: The Emerging Trends.' Vanderbilt Law Review,
January 1982, 63-157.
Kaplow, Louis. "Antitrust, Law & Economics, and the
Courts.' Contemporary Policy Issues, Autumn 1987, 181-224.
Kaysen, Carl, and Donald F. Turner. Antitrust Policy: An Economic
and Legal Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1959.
Kovacic, William E. "Failed Expectations: The Trou - bled
Past and Uncertain Future of the Sherman
Act as a Tool for Deconcentration.| Iowa Law Re - view, July
1989a, 1105-,50.
. "Federal Antitrust Enforcement in the Reagan
Administration: Two Cheers for the Disappear - ance of the Large
Firm Defendant in Nonmerger
Cases." Research in Law & Economics 12, 1989b,
173-206.
. "Comments and Observations." Antitrust Law
Journal 59(1), 1990a, 119-30.
. "The Antitrust Paradox Revisited: Robert Bork
and the Transformation of Modern Antitrust Pol - icy." Wayne
Law Review, Summer 1990b, 1413-71.
. "The Reagan Judiciary and Antitrust in the
1990s.| Fordham Law Review, October 1991, 49 - 124.
Kwoka, Jr., John E., and Lawrence J. White. 'Introduc -
tion,' in The Antitrust Revolution, edited by John
E. Kwoka, Jr. and Lawrence J. White. Glenview,
Ill.: Scott, Foresman and Co., 1989, 1-5.
Langenfeld, James, and David T. Scheftman. "Evolu - tion or
Revolution--What Is the Future of Anti - trust?" Antitrust
Bulletin, Summer 1986, 287-300.
Mason, Alpheus T. Brandeis--A Free Man's Life. New
York: The Viking Press, 1946.
May, James. 'Antitrust in the Formative Era: Political
and Economic Theory in Constitutional and An - titrust Analysis,
18804918.| Ohio State Law Jour - nal 50(2), 1989, 257-395.
Meehan, Jr., James W., and Robert J. Larner. "The
Structural School Its Critics, and Its Progency,
in Economics & Antitrust Policy, edited by Robert
J. Larner and James W. Meehan, Jr. New York:
Quorum Books, 1989, 179-208.
Rowe, Frederick M. "The Decline of Antitrust and the
Delusions of Models: The Faustjan Pact of Law
and Economics.| Georgetown Law Journal, June
1984, 1511-70.
Salop, Steven C., and Lawrence 1. White. 'Private An -
titrust Litigation: An Introduction and Frame - work," in Private
Antitrust Litigation, edited by
Lawrence J. White. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1988, 3-60.
Shapiro, Carl. "The Theory of Business Strategy."
RAND Journal of Economics, Spring 1989, 125-37.
Sherman, Roger, and Robert Tollison. |Public Policy
Toward Oligopoly: Dissolution and Scale Econo - mies.'
Antitrust Law & Economics Review, Sum - mer 1971, 77-90.
Shughart IlL William F. Antitrust Policy and Interest
Group Politics. New York: Quorum Books, 1990.
Simons, Henry C. Economic Policy for a Free Soc/ety.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948.
Stigler, George J. "Do Economists Matter?' Southern
Economic Journal, January 1976, reprinted in G.
Stigler, The Economist as Preacher and Other Essays.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982, 57 - 67.
Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist. New York:
Basic Books, 1988. White House Task Force on Antitrust Policy.
"Report
of the White House Task Force on Antitrust Pol - icy. Antitrust
Law & Economics Review, Winter
1968-1969, 11-52.