首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月15日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The rise of the Chicago packers and the origins of meat inspection and antitrust.
  • 作者:Libecap, Gary D.
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:1992
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 关键词:Antitrust law;Meat inspection

The rise of the Chicago packers and the origins of meat inspection and antitrust.


Libecap, Gary D.


The Meat Inspection Act of 1891 and the Sherman Act of 1890 are closely tied. This link makes clearer Congress' intent in enacting the legislation. Both laws were products of economic conditions after 1880 and reflected, in part, widespread concern about the market power of Chicago meat packers. The concerns of local slaughterhouses, which were being displaced by new, low-cost refrigerated beef,, and of farmers, who sold livestock to the large Chicago packers, were echoed elsewhere by other small businesses and farmers, who feared for their livelihood during a time of structural change in the economy.

I. INTRODUCTION

In the few years between 1887 and 1891, the legislative basis was established for major intervention by the federal government into the American economy: The Interstate Commerce Act of 1887, the Sherman Act of 1890, and the Meat Inspection Act of 1891.[1] With these laws the federal government became directly involved in the regulation of railroad rates, antitrust enforcement, and the inspection and certification of food quality for consumers. Representing a significant break from what had previously been considered an appropriate role for the federal government, this legislation provided a new and permanent mandate for government regulation in the market economy.

Despite the importance of these laws, the link between the economic and political environment in the United States in the late nineteenth century on the one hand, and the legislative histories of the laws on the other, has not been thoroughly explored. As a result, the motives of Congress for enacting these laws remain both unclear and controversial. Consider meat inspection and antitrust. Although most attention in the literature is focused on the 1906 Meat Inspection Act, made popular by the publication of Upton Sinclair's The Jungle, the initial legislation, the Meat Inspection Act of 1891, came fifteen years earlier, and it addressed the production and consumption of fresh beef. But as reported in this paper, there is no evidence of a major health crisis regarding the consumption of beef at the time. Something else appears to have been on the mind of Congress when it passed the legislation in 1891. The objectives of Congress in enacting the Sherman Act are even more controversial because of the prominence of the law. Debate revolves around whether the Sherman Act was designed to promote competition and consumer welfare or to limit competition and protect special interests.2

This paper argues that to gain a better understanding of the origins of this important legislation and its early economic effects, the laws must be placed into the context of the extraordinary changes taking place in the American economy in the late nineteenth century. The linkages among the laws help to identify the underlying political and economic forces behind the legislation.

Three broad characteristics of the economy must be kept in mind in analyzing this period: First, the post-Civil War period was a time of general deflation. Between 1864 and 1900 the consumer price index fell by 47 percent (U.S. Department of Commerce [1975, 211]). In general, prices for farm products followed the overall pattern, but prices for cattle fell in real terms after the mid-1880s. Fluctuations in farm prices also appear to have coincided with periods of agrarian unrest.3 Second, as described by Higgs [1971] and Chandler [1977], the period after 1880 was a time of major structural change in the economy. The economy was becoming more industrial, and biased technological change, economies of scale in production, distribution, and marketing, as well as the lowering of transportation costs were fundamentally altering production methods and products. This affected the competitive positions of many firms, creating winners and losers (James [1983]; Burns [1983]; Atack [1985]). Emerging large firms expanded from local to national and international markets, and existing small firms found their local markets threatened by new competitors. Concentration levels in many industries rose, although as indicated by Nutter and Einhorn [1969], timeseries data on concentration for documenting this are limited. Those firms adversely affected by technological change had incentives to appeal to the federal and state governments to mold and control the effects of new technology in ways similar to that described in a broad context by Mokyr [1990]. Large firms became very visible and were obvious targets for those who were disadvantaged and sought redress through the federal government.

Third, by the late nineteenth century, the federal government had begun to displace state and local governments as the focus of interest group lobbying. The rapid integration of the national economy, as well as the growth of the federal government in the post-Civil War period, meant that only the federal government had the requisite jurisdiction and size to broadly influence economic events.

This paper examines the origins of the first federal food quality guarantees in the Meat Inspection Act of 1891 and of the first federal antitrust provisions in the Sherman Act of 1890. Both laws were products of the changing economic and political environment in the country, which brought new demands on Congress for intervention into the economy. The origins of the laws were closely linked by a common concern about the Chicago packers, the Beef trust. The Chicago packers and their new product, refrigerated (dressed) beef, were an integral part of the demand for government inspection of meat. Additionally, although certainly other trusts or combinations were targeted in congressional debate over antitrust, the Beef trust played a more prominent role in the events leading to the enactment of the Sherman Act than has been recognized in the literature.

In brief, my arguments are as follows: The rise of the Chicago packers, following the introduction of refrigeration around 1880, fundamentally altered both demand and supply conditions in the meat-packing industry. Small, local slaughterhouses, which previously had characterized the industry, were displaced rapidly in most markets because they could not compete with the new, low-cost substitute from Chicago. To counter, local slaughterhouses charged that the Chicago packers used diseased cattle and that dressed beef was unwholesome. This disease issue damaged export markets for cattle and beef products and may also have threatened the growth of domestic demand for dressed beef. One remedy, urged especially by midwestern cattle raisers, was federal meat inspection to promote demand. But meat inspection alone was not enough in the view of midwestern farmers, who not only raised grains but were the country's major producers of cattle. Even though the popularity of refrigerated dressed beef supported an increase in the derived demand for cattle, cattle raisers were wary of the feared market power of the Chicago packers. They believed that the Chicago packers were responsible for the severe fail in cattle prices after 1885. Promoting demand through meat inspection would be of little benefit if the Chicago packers colluded to hold down cattle prices. Accordingly, state and federal antitrust legislation was demanded as a solution to this problem. This relationship between meat inspection and antitrust legislation provides new insight into the economy of the late nineteenth century and the intent of Congress in enacting the laws.

II. THE DISEASE ISSUE AND THE INCENTIVES OF THE CHICAGO PACKERS TO CHEAT ON MEAT QUALITY

Before examining the political and economic ramifications of the disease issue, it is useful to address the incentives of the Chicago packers to cheat on product quality. This helps to place the debate over federal meat inspection and its link to antitrust into perspective.

Asymmetric product quality information between consumers and producers can lead to various private and, in some cases, governmental arrangements to assist consumers in market choices.4 Klein and Leffler [1981] argue that firms will provide and adhere to quality standards if the expected present discounted value of the stream of returns from long-term sales exceeds any short-term wealth increase from quality deception and lower-cost production. Firm adherence to quality guarantees depends, in part, on the extent of investment in firm-specific (nonsalvageable) capital. If a firm has significant investments with limited alternative uses, it will have more at stake in maintaining a long-term relationship with consumers and will gain less from deception.

In the case at hand, the four Chicago packers had considerable investments in stockyards, centralized slaughterhouses, refrigeration cars, and wholesale units, whose values depended upon consumer acceptance of refrigerated beef.s

Firm adherence to quality standards also depends upon market share. Larger firms, facing downward-sloping demand schedules, must reduce price to sell the additional products made possible through deception and lower production costs. In general lower prices reduce the returns to cheating on quality. If the price and cost of a homogeneous product are functions of product quality as well as total output, then a firm would consider lowering quality only if the losses in revenue from the negative industry price effects were less than its cost savings. For firms with exceedingly small market shares, the price effects will be close to zero, while the cost savings may be substantial, depending on the technology involved. Under these circumstances, small firms are more likely to cheat on quality. Additionally, producers with large market shares absorb more of the industry-wide losses of a demand shift to substitutes if consumers cannot isolate the violating firm.[6]

In this case as well, the large Chicago packers had reasons to adhere to quality standards. Relative to the much smaller local slaughterhouses, the Chicago packers had large market shares and would have borne most of the losses of consumer rejection of dressed beef. As noted by Yeager [1981, 67] in 1890 Armour accounted for 27 percent of the cattle slaughtered in Chicago, by far the country's largest packing center, while Swift had 26 percent, Morris 24 percent, and Hammond 12 percent. These firms, as well as Cudahy and Schwarzschild and Sulzberger, also headquartered in Chicago, were virtually the only producers of refrigerated dressed beef through 1906.

In addition to the likely interest of the packers in maintaining consumer confidence in their product, consumers had the assistance of local retail butchers for assessing beef quality. Retailers who switched from local to refrigerated beef had strong incentives to maintain quality because the retail industry was very competitive. Even though consumers could not easily differentiate Armour from Swift beef, they could switch from any retailer who sold poor quality meat, and retailers could turn to a different supplier or drop dressed beef altogether.

A third factor that encourages firm adherence to quality standards is an expected growth in demand.7 If product demand is expected to grow, the rate of quasi-rent flow from high quality and associated higher-priced production increases relative to the short-term gains from deception.

For the dressed-beef trade in the late nineteenth century, the Chicago packers clearly believed that they had a product with enormous long-term potential and invested accordingly. Centralized production was not only low cost, but refrigeration allowed for year-round consumption of beef and the greater export of fresh beef products. With this stake in the industry, the firms were less likely to have been tempted by the tradeoff provided by any short-term wealth gain from cheating on quality and thereby possibly compromising consumer acceptance of their product.

Finally, the greater the frequency of repeat purchases, the more likely quality will be maintained by a firm. With small, repeat purchases, firm cheating provides only limited returns relative to those from a long-term relationship between producers and consumers.

With scarce household refrigeration in the late nineteenth century, beef and other meats were purchased in small amounts on at least a weekly basis by consumers, suggesting that long-term relationships between local retailers and consumers were important. Under these circumstances, local retail butchers would have monitored the quality of the meat purchased from wholesalers in order to retain their customers.

Overall, placing the charges of quality deception into the context of economic theory raises questions about alleged cheating by the Chicago packers. Indeed if anything, the theory suggests that the packers had very important reasons for maintaining the quality of their dressedbeef product. Federal intervention as a third party guarantor of quality still may have been warranted had a significant health risk existed from the consumption of beef from diseased cattle. But the record does not indicate that the incidence of diseased cattle or their consumption was very great, and there is no evidence of a major health issue at that time over beef consumption.8 Nevertheless, there was an intense political debate over beef inspection in certain states and in the federal government that culminated in the Meat Inspection Act of 1891. Accordingly, while not ruling out a health issue, the theory suggests a look elsewhere is warranted for understanding the timing and nature of the first federal meat inspection law. This look also reveals the ties between the origins of federal meat inspection and antitrust.

III. THE UNEVEN ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF THE INTRODUCTION OF NEW TECHNOLOGY

Impact on Small Slaughterhouses

According to census data from the U.S. Department of the Interior [1904, 318] and the U.S. Department of Commerce and Labor [1913, 442] slaughtering and meat packing was either the first or second most valuable U.S. industry from 1880 through 1910. Prior to the introduction of refrigeration, the industry was characterized by small wholesale slaughterhouses and packing plants, located near or in urban areas. They slaughtered both local livestock and those shipped from the Midwest. As shown by the U.S. Department of the Interior [1904, 318] in the census, the number of slaughter and packing firms in the industry was large, with 872 in 1880 for example. Local slaughterhouses often had retail outlets, but there were also numerous specialized small retail butchers. Both local wholesale and retail markets were competitive with ease of entry and relatively large numbers of firms in each community. For example, according to the leading industry trade journal, National Provisioner, [13 February 1892, 11; 10 June 1893, 13] in 1892 there were 1,950 wholesale and retail butchers in Chicago alone and some 80,000 nationwide.

Refrigeration allowed for the centralized, large-scale slaughtering of cattle in Chicago or other leading western packing centers and the shipment of carcasses to eastern markets and export. Centralized slaughtering offered economies that the older, live cattle trade could not match. As noted by the Bureau of Animal Industry [1885, 233] and Skaggs [1986, 94], carcasses could be shipped from Chicago at onethird the cost of transporting live cattle. In addition Clemen [1923, 195] reported that there were weight losses of 10 to 15 percent and injuries from crowding in shipping live cattle that could be avoided with dressed beef. Besides lower transportation costs, there were economies of scale in slaughtering, packing, and canning, and in the use of by-products.9

The Chicago packers, Swift, Armour, Morris, and Hammond, who were not involved in the live cattle trade, pioneered the use of refrigeration and centralized slaughter. To distribute the dressed-beef product, they invested in refrigerator railroad cars and wholesale branch units. By 1917, according to the Federal Trade Commission [1919a, 153, 260], the major packers had 1,165 branch houses for the storage and distribution of dressed beef and 15,454 refrigerator cars, 93 percent of the U.S. total. As early as 1884, 84 percent of the cattle slaughtered in Chicago were by the 'big four' packers.[10] Additionally, the Chicago packers established slaughter and packing plants in other midwestern cities, such as Omaha, East St. Louis, Kansas City, South St. Paul, and Ft. Worth.

Table I illustrates the change in production size that followed the introduction of refrigeration. The table shows the average capital of the slaughter and packing plants in the western packing states of Illinois (Chicago), Kansas (Kansas City), and Nebraska (Omaha) and those in the eastern consuming areas which had been supplied by local slaughterhouses. As late as 1880, the average capital of slaughterhouses in the western states was not dramatically larger than in the east. By 1890, however, the firm size differences in the two regions are clear. According to census data from the U.S. Department of the Interior [1883, 474; 1904, 389], in 1880, Illinois, Kansas, and Nebraska accounted for 35 percent of the total value of U.S. meat production of $303,562,413; by 1900, those states accounted for 55 percent of total production valued at $790,252,586.

With these production, distribution, and transportation advantages, refrigerated dressed beef could be provided to retail markets at lower cost than could be supplied by local slaughterhouses. Moreover, as the technology was improved by the late 1880s, dressed and local beef were perfect substitutes. Retail prices for beef for consumers fell. For example as reported by Yeager [1981, 70], between 1883 and 1889 the average price of beef tenderloins fell by 39 percent from $.275 per pound to $.1675. In addition with refrigerated storage, beef could be held for consumption year-round. Beef consumption rose. Clemen [1923, 255] noted that per capita consumption of beef, which was 77.8 pounds during the period 1870-1879, rose by 12 percent to 87.2 pounds during the period 1880-1889. Although consumers clearly benefitted from the new technology, many high-cost, local slaughterhouses could not compete with the centralized Chicago packers. Given this, Chicago dressed beef began to displace the shipment and local slaughter of live cattle. Table II documents the relevant patterns.

Impact on Cattle Raisers

As suppliers of the prime input for dressed beef, cattle raisers were also affected by the new technology. The lowering of production and distribution costs for beef and increases in demand for beef due to refrigeration raised the derived demand for cattle. Nominal cattle prices, which had declined from 1871 through 1879, rose to an average of $25.26 in 1884, their highest level since 1867, when data are first available through the U.S. Department of Agriculture [1937, 27]. This rise in value encouraged investment in cattle in what has been called the 1880-1885 'cattle boom' by historians of the livestock industry, such as Osgood [1929, 85-89, 106-14] and Dale [1930, 93-97, 105-159]. With increased profit expectations from these investments, the total stock of cattle grew. Based on data from the U.S. Department of Agriculture [1937, 27], in 1875 there were 35,361,000 cattle in the U.S.; in 1885, 52,563,000, an increase of 49 percent; and by 1890, 60,014,000, 70 percent greater than in 1875 and 14 percent more than in 1885.

There were three major cattle-producing regions: the corn belt, which accounted for 36 percent of the total stock of cattle in 1889; Texas and the southwest; and the western range states. Most midwestern farmers marketed at least some cattle, which were fed corn before slaughter in Chicago or shipped to eastern urban areas or exported. This accounts for the intense concern in the Midwest as cattle prices fell in 1885. Texas, New Mexico, and Arizona, which accounted for 19 percent of the stock of cattle in 1889, produced grass-fed cattle, often considered inferior in size and quality to midwestern cattle. The Chicago packers demanded large numbers of Texas cattle for the production of dressed and canned beef, and they were shipped north and often fed corn in the Midwest prior to slaughter.[11]

With the increase in the stock, the number of cattle marketed rose rapidly. In 1880 the total number of cattle received in Chicago was 1,382,477. By 1884, the number received was up by 31 percent to 1,817,697, and by 1890, 3,484,280 were marketed in Chicago, 152 percent more than in 1880 and 92 percent more than in 1884. Cattle prices, however, began to fall in 1885, ending the cattle boom. Nominal U.S. cattle prices declined gradually from their 1884 peak of $25.26 per head to $16.49 in 1891, a decline of 35 percent, and real prices fell by 24 percent between 1885 and 1890 from $28.71 to $20.67. This was the longest and most severe fall in cattle prices since the end of the Civil War. Although prices for other agricultural commodities, such as hogs and grains, also fell in the late nineteenth century, they had temporary recoveries during the 1884-1891 period.[12] The cattle price decline and ways to counter it became central issues in the efforts by cattle raisers to obtain inspection legislation and antitrust laws.

Midwestern farmers argued that the consolidation of cattle markets in Chicago with the rise of centralized slaughter and the market power of the big four packers were responsible for the decline in cattle prices. Although Chicago had been an important shipping center since the end of the Civil War, handling 29 percent of all cattle marketed in the U.S. in 1865, most cattle were shipped elsewhere for slaughter by small slaughterhouses. This changed with refrigeration, so that in 1883 Chicago received 40 percent of the cattle marketed in the U.S., and approximately half of those were slaughtered there. Additionally, most of the cattle received in the Kansas City stockyards, the second largest in the U.S. in 1883, were shipped on to Chicago for slaughter. In these markets the packers were the major purchasers. By 1888, the Chicago packers purchased over 50 percent of the cattle in Chicago and Kansas City. They also gradually obtained shares in thirty of the country's major stockyards where cattle were sold. The size and concentration of the packers in these markets made collusion a credible explanation for the fall in cattle prices to many cattle raisers.[13]

By available measures of concentration, the Chicago packers had large market shares, contributing to the notion that there existed a combine or Beef trust. In 1890, Armour, Swift, Morris, and Hammond slaughtered 89 percent of the cattle slaughtered in Chicago. Nutter and Einhorn [1969, 131-137, 140-142] provide a list of highly concentrated industries from 1895-1904 and the market shares of the leading firms. For meat packing, the four largest firms had over 50 percent of the market. Moreover, the ratios constructed by Nutter and Einhorn of value-added in highly concentrated sectors of the industry to the industry total value-added show that meat packing was one of the more concentrated industries at that time.[14]

Further, the Chicago packers attempted various pooling arrangements from 1886 through 1901 (the Allerton and Veeder Pools) to divide input and output markets and to set prices for dressed beef and other products. The pools had formal structures and the number of bargaining parties was relatively small, but any impact on cattle prices appears to have been short term. The pooling agreements were unstable with new entry, first by Cudahy and later by Schwarzschild and Sulzberger, and unauthorized expanded production by the member parties.[15] Nevertheless, the political reaction to declining cattle prices after 1884 took two directions. One was to limit the alleged market power of the packers through antitrust laws, and the other was to promote the demand for cattle and meat in domestic and export markets through inspection legislation.

IV. THE DISEASE ISSUE. MEAT INSPECTION,

AND THE SHERMAN ACT

The Disease Issue

Because of the importance of the disease issue, it is necessary to go into its origins in some detail, and these predate the rise of the Chicago packers. Initial cattle disease concerns arose as midwestern farmers charged that the Texas and southern cattle that were being driven or transported across the Midwest carried contagious livestock diseases. Various, and mostly unsuccessful efforts in the 1870s were made to restrict the flow of Texas cattle northward. As noted by Dale [1930, 161], the disease issue, however, became magnified after 1880 by rivalry among the cattle-producing regions, their ties to the Chicago packers, and the impact of disease on livestock and meat export markets.

Heuropneumonia and Texas fever were the most commonly discussed cattle diseases. These diseases could devastate livestock herds, but there was no known impact on humans who consumed infected animals. Further, available evidence indicates that the contagious disease scare was more a political issue than an actual source of loss, since the incidence of the two diseases appears never to have been very great. In 1882, the Treasury Department investigated the location of pleuropneumonia and reported its findings in U.S. Senate [1882, 19]. The Treasury investigators found the disease confined to a few herds in the midatlantic states. The Bureau of Animal Industry [1885, 268; 1891, 71-73, 76-78; 1893, 17] also followed the extent of the disease. The agency argued that pleuropneumonia occasionally appeared in the Midwest, but only briefly and involved a limited number of animals. It reported that between December 1, 1888 and November 30, 1889, only 351 cattle were found infected of the 329,000 inspected in the midatlantic states. In 1891, the bureau declared the disease virtually eradicated.

The incidence of Texas fever, which was spread by ticks brought from the South, appears to have been similarly spotty. Bureau of Animal Industry reports [1885, 417-18, 444; 1886, 378] point to only isolated cases of the disease. For example in 1884, the agency condemned 720 cattle for Texas fever in Chicago, a number small relative to the 1,047,077 cattle shipped through the city that year. The disease was an annual hazard, since the ticks could not survive a frost, and by 1893 Texas fever was no longer considered a threat after new procedures for disinfecting railroad cars and stockyards were adopted for tick control.

Prior to 1893, a number of northern states enacted separate quarantine laws to restrict the transport of Texas cattle across their territory. Texas ranchers naturally opposed the quarantines, which they claimed were used by northern livestock raisers to limit their access to the market. Their position was supported by the Chicago packers, who feared the impact of any restrictions on cattle supplies. Federal legislation to establish the Bureau of Animal Industry in the Department of Agriculture to investigate livestock diseases and their prevention was debated between 1879 and 1884. The delay was due to disputes over Texas fever between members of Congress from Texas and other southern states and those from northern cattle states. Ultimately, to facilitate passage Texas fever was specifically declared not to be a contagious disease.[16]

Although there is no evidence of a major health problem for consumers of domestic beef, the debate over the incidence of cattle diseases and charges that the Chicago packers slaughtered diseased animals for human consumption gave credence to allegations by foreign competitors that American livestock and meat products were unwholesome. At the same time there was a bitter controversy over allegations of trichinosis in American pork that brought restrictions on American pork imports in Germany, France, Belgium, and other European countries. The Bureau of Animal Industry [1885, 476-477] countered that trichinosis was rare in the United States and more associated with European than American hogs due to differences in what hogs were fed in the U.S. Pork also generally was cooked in the United States prior to consumption. Protection of local hog producers from American competition appears to have been a motivation for German restrictions.17

European controls on American livestock and meat products not only accentuated the disease issue, but they became central in subsequent efforts to enact federal inspection legislation as cattle raisers began to argue that greater exports were required to raise cattle prices. For example, cattle exports ranged from 10 to 13 percent of the total cattle marketed in Chicago between 1880 and 1890. Charges of pleuropneumonia brought British controls on live cattle imports from the U.S. in 1878. Under those rules American cattle had to be slaughtered on the wharf within ten days of arrival. The Bureau of Animal Industry [1886, 177] estimated that these restrictions led to losses of $15 to $25 per head relative to comparable Canadian cattle for U.S. cattle exporters. Exports, mostly to Britain, which reached $14,304,000 in fiscal year 1881, fell sharply in 1882 and 1883, to $8,342,000. They rose in 1884, but declined again through 1887 to $9,172,000.[18]

The association between the Chicago packers and diseased cattle was made by local slaughterhouses, who through the Butchers' National Protective Association, organized in 1886, charged that the Chicago packers slaughtered cattle with Texas fever, pleuropneumonia, and other diseases.[19] They asserted that the use of these low-cost, diseased cattle allowed the Chicago packers to underprice local slaughterhouses, which used only healthy animals. The earlier opposition of the Chicago packers to restrictions on northern shipment of Texas cattle was given as additional evidence of the desire of the Chicago packers to have access to low-cost and low-quality supplies. Moreover, the Butchers' National Protective Association argued that consumers could not distinguish between wholesome and unwholesome beef and, hence, were at risk.

The use of derogatory claims about the quality of a competitor's products was a common competitive strategy in many industries in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. As production processes became more complex with new products and new technology and as consumers increasingly were separated from the production of the goods they consumed, a potential information problem rose that was exploited, generally by established producers against new, less wellunderstood products. For instance, discriminatory taxes or outright bans were placed on oleomargarine and compound lard, as well as certain kinds of baking powder, milk, whiskey, coffee, candy, and drugs, which were claimed by competitors to be adulterated. In most cases, no health hazard was ever identified.20 State Meat Inspection and State Antitrust

The political battle over the call for government inspection of cattle began at the state level, where the laws were designed to serve three purposes--to provide for inspection of livestock prior to slaughter, to limit the shipment of dressed beef, and to reduce the market power of the packers through state antitrust laws. In February 1889, Kansas Governor Lyman Humphrey sent a resolution to the governors of cattle-producing states, mostly from the Midwest, calling for joint legislation and a convention of legislators. The convention was to address meat inspection and the effects of the Beef trust on cattle prices in Chicago and Kansas City. In response, delegates from state legislatures were sent to St. Louis in March 1889 from Indiana, Illinois, Minnesota, Iowa, Missouri, Kansas, Nebraska, Colorado, and Texas.

The convention called on Congress to construct a deep-water port in Texas to compete with Chicago for livestock shipments and to enact an antitrust bill to prohibit contracts among the Chicago packers that "have united and combined for the purpose of controlling the market price of the cattle, pork, grain and other products of the country...." [21] In addition, the convention presented to each state sample antitrust legislation and a local meat inspection bill for adoption. Local inspection of livestock was to occur just prior to slaughter, and its goal was "...to render it impossible for Chicago dressed meat to be sold anywhere except in Chicago. The resultant effect of such measure would be...that butchers all over the country would resume business, and, competition being restored, the value of cattle would naturally rise.[22]

Twenty states subsequently considered the local inspection legislation in 1889, and four adopted the law. Local inspection as a solution to the disease issue, however, was short-lived as efforts quickly turned to the federal government. An examination of the journals of state legislatures in Colorado, Delaware, Illinois, Indiana, Minnesota, Missouri, Nebraska, New York, and Ohio from 1885 to 1892 shows that local inspection bills appeared only in the 1889 legislative sessions. The U.S. Supreme Court ruled against such legislation in Minnesota v. Barber (136 U.S. 313) in May 1890 because of the impact on interstate commerce.

While the states were considering local meat inspection legislation, they also were adopting antitrust prohibitions. In the 1889 St. Louis convention, agricultural interests, organized through groups like the Grange and Farmers' Alliance, were major proponents of state antitrust legislation. In 1889, twelve states (nine from the Midwest) passed antitrust laws for the first time.[23] Seager and Gulick [1929] report that by 1890, twenty-seven states had antitrust restrictions, either through statute or constitutional provisions.

In their analysis of the Missouri state antitrust law, passed in 1889, Boudreaux and DiLorenzo [1990] find that farmers were the major special interest behind the legislation. According to Boudreaux and DiLorenzo, Missouri farmers blamed the Chicago packers for the fall in cattle prices.

Cattle accounted for one-quarter of Missouri's agricultural output, and cattle raising was the largest single contributor to agricultural gross product in the state.[24]

The Chicago packers naturally opposed the local inspection laws.[25] The packers, through the Chicago Board of Trade, were quick to respond. As reported in the Cincinnati Price Current on January 31, 1889, a resolution was passed by the Board of Trade claiming that local inspection legislation would "irretrievably embarrass and ruin the dressed beef industry .... "In testimony before the Vest Committee of the Senate, George Beck, a Detroit butcher, claimed that a major packer, Hammond, offered: "if you men will take down those cards/No Chicago Dressed Meat Sold Here] and if you will withdraw the petition you are now circulating through the state to go to the legislature for local cattle inspection, I will agree to keep out of Detroit myself with my dressed beef and to keep Mr. Armour and Mr. Swift out."[26] The Chicago Board of Trade charged that state inspection was a sham, designed primarily to prohibit the interstate shipment of dressed beef, and that it had the potential to discredit American meat products in foreign markets.

The protests of the Chicago packers were supported by the Bureau of Animal Industry. Between 1884, when the agency was established, and 1891, the bureau joined in refuting claims that dressed beef was unwholesome. For example, in 1885 it disputed articles in the press that diseased animals were slaughtered for food: "The facts seem to warrant the assertion made that the meat supply of Chicago is practically entirely wholesome. Self-interest leads the packers and the canners to use every available means for preventing even the shadow of suspicion resting upon the goods they have to sell; hence, they become most efficient aids to the health department."[27] While local inspection and antitrust legislation was being considered at the state level, more comprehensive efforts for meat inspection and antitrust were occurring at the federal level.

Federal Government Meat Inspection

The position of midwestern farmers and politicians on the issues of cattle diseases, the role of the packers in the decline in cattle prices, and federal inspection and antitrust legislation are reflected in the testimony and reports of the Senate Select Committee on the Transportation and Sale of Meat Products (the Vest Committee). The committee was approved by the Senate on May 14, 1888, following a resolution by Senator George Vest of Missouri, calling for an investigation as to "whether there exists or has existed any combination of any kind by reason of which the price of beef and beef cattle have been so controlled or affected as to diminish the prices paid the producer....[28] Five senators from cattle states, four of them from the Midwest, made up the Vest Committee, including Vest of Missouri, Preston Plumb of Kansas, Shelby Cullom and, later, Charles Farwell of Illinois, Charles Manderson of Nebraska, and Richard Coke of Texas.

Beginning in November 1888, and for the next thirteen months, the Vest Committee held hearings in St. Louis, Washington D.C., Chicago, Des Moines, Kansas City, and New York City. The committee elected to begin the hearings in St. Louis to coincide with the meetings of the International Cattle Range Association and the Butchers' National Protective Association. During the hearings, the committee listened to 111 individuals, including 57 cattle raisers and sales commission agents, 19 slaughterhouse owners and butchers, 'and S.B. Armour of Kansas City and P.D. Armour of Chicago.

As reported in the published testimony from the U.S. Senate [1889, 13, 81, 95, 137, 177, 180, 185, 189, 268], it was repeatedly charged that the packers colluded in purchasing cattle, which accounted for the fall in cattle prices, and that dressed and canned beef shipped from Chicago was from diseased animals and therefore was less healthy than locally slaughtered beef.

The report of the Vest Committee to the Senate on May 1, 1890 addressed the same two issues that had been raised earlier in the states: meat inspection and antitrust. In U.S. Senate [1890a], the committee recommended five pieces of legislation--two dealt with federal meat inspection and three dealt with various monopoly issues: SR78, which asked the President to obtain repeal of quarantine regulations against American cattle in Great Britain; $3717, which amended the Interstate Commerce Act to prevent discrimination by railroads in shipping rates for live cattle and dressed beef; $3718, which prohibited monopoly in transporting cattle to foreign countries; $3719, which provided for inspection of live cattle and beef products for export; and $1, which was the Sherman Antitrust bill, as passed by the Senate on April 8, 1890. Senate Resolution 78 was agreed to by the Senate on June 11, 1890.[29] The bills $3717, $3718, and $3719 also passed the Senate the same day, and were sent to the House.

During Senate debate on his committee's report, Vest argued that British cattle raisers wanted to block the importation of American cattle and that the cattle and beef inspection bill, $3719, should be passed to remove the pretense that diseased U.S. cattle were exported. In the House, $3719 was incorporated into $4155, another bill for the inspection of livestock and meat products, and was passed by both houses of Congress on March 2, 1891.30

The Meat Inspection Act of 1891 required that the Secretary of Agriculture inspect and certify all cattle to be exported or to be slaughtered for either interstate or export trade. Section 3 of the law also authorized inspection of hogs and sheep prior to slaughter and interstate shipment and discretionary examination of carcasses and meat products.[31] The Bureau of Animal Industry was given the mandate for inspection, and all slaughterhouses that desired to produce for interstate trade had to apply for government inspection.[32] With this law, the federal government, for the first time, was authorized to inspect and certify food quality for American consumers.

The Sherman Act

In its report to the Senate, the Vest Committee repeated the claim made in March 1889 at the convention of cattleraising states in St. Louis that inspection of cattle and meat products alone was insufficient to address the problems faced by farmers. If the demand for cattle were to rise with greater exports and domestic demand for beef, the gains could be captured by the Beef trust unless federal antitrust legislation also was enacted. Accordingly, the Vest committee included the Sherman bill, $1, in its report. Indeed, the Beef trust played an especially prominent role in congressional debate over federal antitrust between 1888 and 1890.

The Chicago packers, along with the Standard Oil, sugar, whiskey, tobacco, cotton bagging, and oil trusts, were the most frequently cited examples of the evils presented by the great enterprises of the day. It is no coincidence that studies by Atack [1985] and Burns [1983] show that meat packing, whiskey, and tobacco were among the industries evidencing the greatest structural changes due to scale economies, biased technological change, and lower transportation costs by 1900. The Beef trust in particular, appears to have attracted the attention of those lobbying Congress for antitrust legislation. Although there was reference in Congress to "a great clamor" about trusts, in fact most of the lobbying came from farm groups, especially from the Midwest, where grains and cattle were the major products. For example, of the fifty-nine petitioins regarding trusts sent to the 51st Congress prior to the enactment of the Sherman Act, all but two came form Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, and Tennessee, and were presented by groups, such as the Farmers Union, Farmers Alliance, Farmers Mutual Benefit Association, and Patrons of Animal Husbandry.[33]

This lobbying appears to have had the desired impact on members of Congress from the Midwest. At least thirteen of the sixteen antitrust bills introduced in the House, 50th Congress, 1st session, and all eighteen of the bills introduced in the House, 51st Congress, 1st session, were sponsored by midwestern or southern representatives. In the Senate, three antitrust bills were introduced in the 50th and 51st Congresses, also by midwestern or southern Senators-Cullom of Illinois (50th Congress), Sherman of Ohio, Reagan of Texas, and George of Mississippi (51st Congress).[34]

The Beef trust also played a prominent role in congressional hearings on the impact of trusts in the economy. Between 1888 and 1890, there were three major congressional hearings on trusts: two were conducted by the House Committee on Manufacturing during 1888 on the sugar, Standard Oil, whiskey and cotton bagging trusts and reported in U.S. House of Representatives [1888; 1889], and one was by the Senate Vest Committee on the Beef trust, reported in U.S. Senate [1890].[35] In the House Committee on Manufacturing hearings, testimony was taken regarding combinations amongsugar refiners, efforts of oil producers to reduce oil production in Pennsylvania and New York fields, and alleged agreements among distillers and cotton bag producers. These investigations were reported early in congressional deliberations on antitrust (30 July 1888 and 2 March 1889), and provided no recommended legislation. The Vest Committee report, however, was introduced two months prior to adoption of the Sherman Act and, hence, was timely enough to have had some influence on the debate. further, as noted above, unlike the other two committee reports, the Vest Committee provided a draft of the Sherman Act as a remedy for the problems it uncovered in the meat-packing industry. In general, the members of the Vest committee were influential proponents of antitrust legislation, especially Senator Cullom, who introduced his own antitrust bill S3510 in 1888, and Senators Vest and Coke, who were on the Judiciary Committee, which drafted the final version of the Sherman Act.

Finally, on May 1, 1890 Representative Richard Balnd of Missouri directly targeted the Beef trust in an amendment to the Sherman Act that became a point of contention between the House and Senate. the amendment at least delayed congressional approval from Appril 8, 1890, when it passed the Senate, to June 20, 1890, when the same bill finally passed the House. Disputes over the amendment had the potential to prevent final adoption of the law. Letwin [1965,90] noted that other antitrust bills, including earlier versions of teh Sherman Act, were introduced into Congress after 1888 only to languish in various committees.

Antitrust was a new and vague area for Congress, and in the May 1, 1890 House debate on the Senate-passed bill there was especial concern as to just whate contracts, trusts, or combinations would be prohibited as restraints of trade under the general wording of the proposed law. Since congressional antitrust authority was based upon the commerce clause of the constitution, there was the question of when commercial activity fell under the jurisdiction of the federal government. Moreover, there were related issues of how federal and state antitrust statutes would blend.[36] Indeed, Representative David Culbertson of Texas argued that answers to these questions would not be known until the courts had interpreted the provisions of the proposed act. He speculated, however, that resale price maintenance contracts to drive out competitors and purchase contracts to fix prices at some specified (low) level in interstate commerce would be illegal under the new law. Contracts by the Beef trust with retail butchers and with agents purchasing cattle to fix prices across state lines, along with similar actions taken by Standard Oil, were presented as specific examples of likely violations of the law. But the concerns about the coverage of the law, and particularly about how the chicago packers would be affected, continued to be raised. Representative David Henderson of Iowa pointed to the Vest committee report and asked if the bill would prohibit the actions of the Beef trust 'to reduce the price of Western cattle from one-third to one-half....[37]

Finally, after some discussion of various antitrust issues concerning the roles of state laws, congressional jurisdiction over corporations, and the contribution of the tariff to trusts, Representative Balnd introduced his amendment: "Every contract or agreement entered into for the purpose of preventing competition in the sale or purchase of any commodity transported form one State or Territory to be sold in another, or so contracted to be sold, or for the transportation of persons or property form one State or Territory into another, shall be deemed unlawful within the meaning of this act...[38]

The Bland amendment went beyond the Sherman bill in a number of ways It prohibited the 'intent' to restrict competition, a provision which was not explicit in the Sherman bill. Further, it targeted contracts to prevent competition in the sale or purchase of goods that had been or would be transported across state lines, as well as contracts directly affecting interstate commerce. Accordingly, contracts to restrict trade within a state, but involving goods that would be or had been shipped in interstate commerce would fall under the provisions of the new federal law. Bland wanted to make clear Congress's intent to limit the market power of the Chicago packers in both the purchase of cattle and in the sale of meat and not to leave the issue to the discretion of the courts: "We know the contract with the Big Four, so called, covers every State in this Union. They compel butchers in every town of any population, East or West, to purchase of them or else they establish by the side of those butchers other shops for the sale of beef and, by underselling for a short time, they compel the home seller to submit to their dictation...I want my friends to join with me to make this definite and certain, for there is no trust in this country that today is robbing the farmers of the great West and Northwest of more millions of their hard-earned money than this so-called Big Four beef trust of Chicago.[39]

After discussion, the House passed the amended Sherman Act and sent it back to the Senate. The Senate Judiciary Committee, however, believed that the Bland amendment went too far--beyond the "constitutional power of Congress. The mere fact that an article has once been the subject of transportation from one state to another does not authorize the Congress to treat forever after the dealing in that article as interstate commerce," and it rewrote the amendment to focus solely on contracts directly affecting competition in interstate transport.[40] A House-Senate conference committee meeting was held to resolve the dispute, and it forwarded the Senate version to the House. Senator Vest and Representative Bland, who were members of the conference committee, supported the original amendment and did not sign the committee report.

The House overwhelmingly rejected the Senate amendment, with Bland arguing that his original wording was necessary so that the question of which contracts were in restraint of trade "is no longer a judicial question at all. It is simply a question of fact." Again Bland wanted to insure Congress's ability to police the actions of the Chicago packers "in relation to the purchase of beef, cattle, and hogs that are shipped from the Northwest and Western States to Chicago." He did not want the matter referred to the courts: "We do not know what the court will hold in regard to contracts to prevent fair competition in interstate commerce or in restraint of trade.[41] As debate continued, prospects for enacting any antitrust legislation appeared to dim, and the House voted on June 12, 1890, 106 to 98, with 123 abstaining, to remove the Bland amendment. Thorelli [1955, 209] argues that the close vote reflected strong support in the House for the Bland amendment. A final House-Senate conference committee struck all amendments from the bill, and the House approved the original Sherman Act on June 20, 1890, 242 to 0 with 85 abstentions. The bill was signed by President Harrison on July 2, 1890.[42]

V. CONCLUDING REMARKS

Coinciding with congressional enactment of the country's first law for federal inspection and guarantees of food quality, the Meat Inspection Act of 1891, was the passage of the first federal antitrust law, the Sherman Act of 1890. The timing of this legislation was no coincidence. Both laws were the product of fundamental changes taking place in the American economy in the late nineteenth century. The rise of the Chicago packers, or Beef trust, exemplified the irreversible effects of new technology; economies of scale in production, marketing, and shipment; and falling transportation costs, which were bringing about the rise of the modern industrial economy. The concerns of local slaughterhouses, which were being displaced by low-cost dressed beef, and of cattle raisers, who sold their products to the large Chicago packers, were echoed across the economy by small businesses, farmers, and other sellers of primary and intermediate products, who feared for their competitive positions during a time of structural change in the economy.

Indeed, congressional debate and hearings over the Sherman Act emphasized the protection of small businesses and farmers, who were being 'crushed' by the new industrial combines. Senator James George of Mississippi, a leading proponent of antitrust, although a critic of the original Sherman Act, commented on the changes in the economy during Senate debate: "It is a sad thought to the philanthropist that the present system of production and of exchange is having that tendency which is sure at some not very distant day to crush out all small men, all small capitalists, all small enterprises".[43]

Meat inspection legislation was a consequence of these changing competitive conditions, and there is no evidence that a documented consumer information problem or a domestic health threat were the principal factors behind adoption of the 1891 law. Instead, the disease issue was stressed by local slaughterhouses in an effort to limit or redirect the economic effects of the introduction of refrigeration. Similarly, midwestern farmers, who blamed the Beef trust for low cattle prices and who had other concerns about trusts and low agricultural prices, were the most active lobbyists for state and federal antitrust legislation.

The paper argues that the meat-packing industry played a more prominent role in the enactment of the Sherman Act than has been previously recognized. At the state level, concerns regarding falling cattle prices and the perceived role of the Chicago packers in their decline led to the 1889 St. Louis convention, attended largely by delegates from midwestern states, to consider local inspection and state antitrust laws. Twenty states considered local inspection laws, and four adopted them in 1889, but these laws were dismissed by the U.S. Supreme Court in Minnesota v. Barber in 1890. In 1889, twelve states adopted antitrust legislation, the greatest outpouring of such legislation for any year. At the federal level, nineteen antitrust bills were introduced into the 50th Congress and twenty-one into the 51st Congress. Midwestern and southern members of Congress were the major proponents, sponsoring sixteen bills in the 50th Congress and all twenty-one in the 51st Congress. The principal lobbyists for federal antitrust legislation came from Midwest farm groups. Of the three major congressional investigations into trusts between 1888 and 1890, only the Vest Committee report on the Beef trust in May 1890 suggested a specific legislative remedy. Finally, the Bland amendment, added in the House in May 1890 to strengthen the provisions of the Sherman Act, focused on the Beef trust, and it raised difficult jurisdiction and definition issues that were to persist in judicial interpretation of the Sherman Act.

The outcome of this judicial review, of course, was the concern of Representative Bland, Senator Vest, and others in their efforts to amend the Sherman Act. Indeed, the Supreme Court in United States v. E.C. Knight Co. 156 U.S. 1 (1895) took a narrow view of the commerce clause, separating contracts affecting the 'flow of commerce' from those involving the manufacture of goods within a state. This was exactly the interpetation feared by Bland. Nevertheless, the intensity of concern about the market power of the Chicago packers abated temporarily after 1890. Cattle prices rose after 1891, peaking in 1900, and charges of anti-competitive behavior in cattle markets disappeared. When prices began to decline in 1901, however, monopsony charges again were raised. As outlined by Letwin [1965, 240-44], Thorelli [1955, 585], and Yeager [1981, 181-95, 21932], antitrust investigations into the actions of the Chicago packers by the Justice Department and the Bureau of Corporations began in 1902. They led to the 1912 dissolution of the National Packing Company by Armour, Swift, and Morris, as well as the FTC investigation and 1920 judicial consent decree which required divestiture of ownership in stockyards, terminal railways, and cold storage facilities.[44]

The analysis of antitrust and meat inspection legislation indicates how closely tied were major legislative efforts in the late nineteenth century to expand the federal government's role in the economy. This record reaffirms the argument made by North [1978, 970-78] that a more thorough understanding of government regulation requires identification of the winners and losers in economic events, such as the introduction of new technology, and their efforts to construct institutions to mold those events to their benefit.

REFERENCES

Aduddell, R., and L. Cain. "Location and Collusion in the Meat Packing Industry.'" in Business Enterprise and Economic Change: Essays in Honor of Harold E Williamson, edited by L.P. Cain and P.J. Uselding. Kent, Ohio: Kent State University Press, 1973, 8.5117.

"Public Policy Toward the Greatest Trust in the World." Business History Review, Summer 1981a, 217-42.

"The Consent Decree In the Meatpacking Industry: 1920-1956." Business History Review, Autum 1981b, 359-402.

Akerloff, G. "The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1970, 488-500.

Atack, J. "Industrial Structure and the Emergence of the Modern Industrial Corporation." Explorations in Economic History, January 1985, 29-52.

Bork, R.H. "Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1966, 7-48.

Boudreaux, D.J., and T.J. DiLorenzo. "Antitrust Before the Sherman Act: The Political Economy of Missouri State Antitrust Legislation." George Mason University Working Paper, 1990.

Bowman, J.D., and R.H. Keehn. "Agricultural Terms of Trade in Four Midwestern States, 1870-1900." Journal of Economic History, September 1974, 592609.

Bureau of Animal Industry. Annual Reports. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1884-1910.

Burns, M.R. "Economies of Scale of Tobacco Manufacture, 1897-1910/' Journal of Economic History, June 1983, 461-74.

Chan, Y., and H. Leland. "Prices and Qualities in Markets with Costly Information." Review of Economic Studies, October 1982, 499-516.

Chandler, A. The Visible Hand. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1977.

Cincinnati Price Current. Cincinnati: selected issues.

Clemen, R.A. The American Livestock and Meat Industry. New York: The Ronald Press, 1923.

Congressional Record. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 15(1-4); 19(5); 21(3-7); 22(4).

Dale, E.E. The Range Cattle Industry. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1930.

Darby, M.R., and E. Karni. '"Free Competition and the Optimal Amount of Fraud." Journal of Law and Economics, April 1973, 67-83.

DiLorenzo, T.J. "The Origins of Antitrust: An Interest-Group Perspective," International Review of Law and Economics, 5, Fall 1985, 73-90.

DiLorenzo, T.J., and J.C. High. '"Antitrust and Competition, Historically Considered." Economic Inquiry, July 1988, 423-35.

Federal Trade Commission. Report of the Federal Trade Commission on the Meat-Packing Industry, Summary and Part L Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1919a.

Report of the Federal Trade Commission on the Meat-Packing Industry, Part 11, Evidence of Combination among Packers. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1919b.

Fisher, J.R. "The Economic Effects of Cattle Disease in Britain and its Containment, 1850-1900.' Agricultural History, April 1980, 278--93.

Gilligan, T.W., W.J. Marshall, and B.R. Weingast. 'Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice: The Interstate Commerce Act of 1887." Journal of Law and Economics, April 1989, 35-62.

Haziett, T. "The Demand for Antitrust Legislation: The Sherman Act Re-examined.' University of California-Davis Working Paper, 1989.

Higgs, R. The Transformation of the American Economy, 1865-1914. New York: Wiley, 1971.

High, J., and C.A. Coppin. "Wiley and the Whiskey Industry: Strategic Behavior in the Passage of the Pure Food Act." Business History Review, Summer 1988, 286-309.

Hovenkamp, H. "State Antitrust in the Federal Scheme," Indiana Law Journal, 58(3), 1983, 375404.

Hoy, S., and W. Nugent. "Public Health or Protectionism? The German-American Pork War, 18801891." Bulletin of the History of Medicine, 63, 1989, 198-224.

James, J.A. 'Structural Change in American Manufacturing, 1850-1890." Journal of Economic History, June 1983, 433-60.

Journal of the House of Representatives of Texas, 21st Legislature, Regular Session. Austin, Texas: Smith, Hicks, and Jones, State Printers, 1889.

Klein, B., and K. Leffler. "The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance." Journal of Political Economy, August 1981, 615-42.

Lande, R.H. "Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged." The Hastings Law Journal, September 1982, 67-151.

Leech, H., and J.C. Carroll. Armour and His Times. New York: Appleton-Century-Crafts, 1938.

Leland, H.E. 'Quacks, Lemons, and Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality Standards." Journal of Political Economy, December 1979, 1328-46.

Letwin, W. Law and Economic Policy in America: The Evolution of the Sherman AntiTrust Act. New York: Random House, 1965.

McGuire, R.A. "Economic Causes of Late Nineteenth Century Agrarian Unrest." Journal of Economic History, December 1981, 835-52.

Mokyr, J. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New York: Oxford University Press, 1990.

Moody, J. The Truth About Trusts: A Description and Analysis of the American Trust Movement. New York: Moody Publishing Co, 1904.

National Provisoner. Chicago: selected issues.

Nebraska Senate Journal. Lincoln, Nebraska: FebruaryMarch, 1889.

North, D.C. "Structure and Performance: The Task of Economic History." Journal of Economic Literature, September 1978, 963-978.

Nutter, G.W., and H.A. Einhorn. Enterprise Monopoly in the United States: 1899-1958. New York: Columbia University Press, 1969.

Okun, M. Fair Play in the Market Place, The First Battle for Pure Food and Drugs. Dekalb, IL: Northern Illinois University Press, 1986.

Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965.

Osgood, E.S. The Day of the Cattleman. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1929.

Perfin, R. "The North American Beef and Cattle Trade of Great Britain, 1870-1914." Economic History Review, August 1971, 430-44.

Seager, H.R., and C.A. Gulick Jr. Trust and Corporation Problems. New York: Harper and Row, 1929.

Shapiro, C. "Consumer Information, Product Quality, and Seller Reputation.' Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1982, 20-35.

Sinclair, U. The Jungle. New York: Doubleday and Co, 1906.

Skaggs, J.M. Prime Cut, Livestock Raising and Meat Packing in the United States, 1607-1983. College Station: Texas A&M University Press, 1986.

Sklar, M.J. The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism, 1890-1916. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988.

Stigler, G.J. Five Lectures on Economic Problems. New York: Macmillan.

"The Origins of the Sherman Act,' Journal of Legal Studies, January 1985, 1-12.

Sullivan, E.T. The Political Economy of the Sherman Act, The First One Hundred Years. New York: Oxford University Press, 1991.

Temin, P. "The Origin of Compulsory Drug Prescriptions." Journal of Law and Economics, April 1979, 91-105.

Thorelli, H.B. The Federal Antitrust Policy: Origin of an American Tradition. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1955.

U.S. Department of Agriculture. Report of the Secretary. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1890.

Report of the Secretary. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1891.

Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Livestock on Farms, January 1, by States, Revised Estimates of Numbers, Value per Head, and Total Value, 18671919. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1937.

U.S. Department of Commerce and Labor, Commissioner of Corporations. Report on the Beef Industry. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1905.

Thirteenth Census of the United States, Volume X, Report for Principal Industries. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1913.

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Historical Statistics of the United States. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1975. U.S. Department of the Interior, Bureau of Census. Report on the Manufacturers of the United States at the Tenth Census. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1883.

Census Reports, Volume IX, Manufactures, Part 111, Special Reports on Selected Industries. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1904. U.S. House of Representatives. Trusts. 50th Congress, 1st Session, House Report No. 3112. Serial Set Number 2606. Washington D.C.: Government

Printing Office, 1888.

Trusts. 50th Congress, 1st Session, House Report No. 4165, Serial Set Number 2675. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1889.

U.S. Senate. Report of the Treasury Cattle Commission on the Lung Hague of Cattle or Contagious Pluero-Pneumonia. 47th Congress, 1st Session, Senate Executive Document No. 106, Serial Set 1990. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1882.

Testimony Taken by the Select Committee of the United States Senate on the Transportation and Sale of Meat Products. 51st Congress, 1st Session, Serial Set 2705. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1889.

Senate Report No. 829from the Select Committee on the Transportation and Sale of Meat Products, Report to Accompany S3717, 3718, 3719 and Senate Joint Resolution 78. 51st Congress, 1st Session, Serial Set 2705. Washington D.C., 1890a.

Committee on Agriculture and Forestry, Report 1366 to Accompany 83991. 51st Congress, 1st Session, Serial Set 2710. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1890b.

Bills and Debates in Congress Relating to Trusts, 50th Congress-57th Congress, 1st Session, 57th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document 147, Serial Set 4429. Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1903.

Van Hise, C.R. Concentration and Control: A Solution of the Trust Problem in the United States. New York: Macmillan, 1912.

Wiggins, S.N., and G.D. Libecap. "Firm Heterogeneities and Cartelization Efforts in Domestic Crude Oil", Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Spring 1987, 1-25.

Wilcox, C. Competition and Monopoly in American Industry. U.S. Senate, Temporary National Economic Committee, Monograph No. 21, 76th Congress, 3rd Session, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1940.

Wood D.J. Strategic Uses of Public Policy: Business and Government in the Progressive Era. Marshfield, MA: Pittman Publishing, 1986.

Yeager, M. Competition and Regulation: The Development of Oligopoly in the Meat Packing Industry. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1981.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有