Friedman tax cuts vs. Buchanan deficit reduction as the best way of constraining government.
Lee, Dwight R. ; Vedder, Richard K.
I. INTRODUCTION
Both Milton Friedman and James Buchanan believe that the federal
government spends more than can be justified on the basis of economic
efficiency. Both also agree that the reason for excessive government
spending is that the political process allows people to realize the
benefits from government spending without fully paying the cost of that
spending. But Friedman and Buchanan are in apparent disagreement on the
effectiveness of alternative approaches at constraining government. By
considering Friedman and Buchanan's apparent disagreement at the
level of fiscal policy, it is possible to better understand their
agreement at the level of constitutional policy.
Milton Friedman has argued that a reduction in taxes (and tax
revenues) with an increase in the budget deficit serves the useful
function of restraining government spending. For example, Friedman
|1982, 60-61~ has written, "I want to cut tax rates; but if the
Lafferites were correct in the extreme form--that a particular cut in
taxes increased revenue--then my conclusion would be that we hadn't
cut tax rates enough, because what I want to cut is government revenue.
That's what feeds government spending... What they |the big
spenders~ want is to increase taxes so they will have more money to
spend and won't have to cut spending. The triumph, in my opinion of
the |tax cutting~ policy that President Reagan has been following is
that he has made the big spenders talk on his terms. For the first time,
they have to face up seriously to cutting spending."(1)
In contrast, James Buchanan argues that reducing taxes and increasing
debt financing lowers the perceived cost of government spending and,
consequently, increases government spending. For example, Buchanan and
Wagner |1977, 138-139~ state, "the replacement of current tax
financing by government borrowing has the effect of reducing the
'perceived price' of government goods and services" with
the result that taxpayers "increase their demands for such goods
and services. Preferred budget levels will be higher and these
preferences will be sensed by politicians and translated into political
outcomes."
In discussing the economic policy of the Reagan Administration,
William Niskanen (who was a member and acting chairman of the
President's Council of Economic Advisers during the Reagan
presidency) takes note of the conflicting views of Friedman and
Buchanan. According to Niskanen |1988, 109~, "Milton Friedman
promoted a view that tax rates should be reduced at every opportunity,
believing that the resulting increase in the deficit would increase
pressure to reduce federal spending...James Buchanan...expressed a
directly contrary view that a tax increase would reduce spending by
increasing the perceived price of government services to the current
voters."
Niskanen continues by expressing his leanings toward the Buchanan
view, a leaning based on his own research (Niskanen |1978~). He points
out, however, that recent empirical work is inconclusive, with some
supporting Friedman's position and some supporting Buchanan's.
Niskanen |1988, 109~ concludes his discussion of the difference of
opinion between Friedman and Buchanan by observing that,
"Economists and politicians unfortunately do not yet share a clear
understanding of these |taxing, spending, and budget deficit~
relations."
A simple model of taxation, spending, and deficit determination
provides a framework for examining systematically the conflict between
Friedman and Buchanan. It makes clear that the relationships among these
variables cannot be determined by empirical investigation alone. Because
both the Friedman and Buchanan positions emerge as special cases of a
more general model, it is not surprising that empirical studies can be
found to support either position. Indeed, we demonstrate that historic
episodes exist which support the positions of both men.
II. THE MODEL
Political decisions, like market decisions, are made in response to
benefits and costs. Politicians spend money to provide public services and finance government transfers because there are political benefits
from doing so. Government expenditures, however, are limited by the fact
that there are political costs associated with increased taxation.
Although these political benefits and costs reflect real social benefits
and costs of diverting resources out of private activities and into
public ones, there is no reason for believing the reflection is an
accurate one. Indeed, as Friedman and Buchanan both recognize, the
political process tends to magnify the benefits of government
expenditures and obscure the costs since the benefits are typically
concentrated on relatively small and politically active interest groups
while the costs are typically diluted over the large and politically
unorganized general public. The political bias in favor of spending is
not particularly relevant to our objective, however. Our purpose is not
to evaluate the social welfare implications of different levels of
government spending and taxation, but rather to consider how these
levels are determined. In this case, it is the political benefits and
costs that are decisive.
In its broadest sense taxation refers to any means whereby a
government transfers resources from private to public control. Taxation
can refer to inflation (a tax on cash balances), regulation (taking
public control over nominally private resources), and borrowing
(deferred taxation), as well as explicit taxation of income, property,
etc. Since our concern is with the determination of budget deficits as
conventionally measured, we will ignore government regulation. Inflation
is relevant to the discussion since it affects the amount of tax revenue
raised both directly (e.g., through bracket creep) and indirectly (e.g.,
by reducing the political costs of raising revenue). In developing our
model, however, we ignore inflation and concentrate on explicit
taxation.
In Figure 1, the elements of our deficit determination model are
diagrammed in their simplest form. The marginal political benefit from
government spending as a percentage of national income is showed as
|D.sub.s~. This marginal benefit curve has a natural interpretation as
the political demand curve for government spending, with it reasonable
to assume that it slopes downward as do other demand curves. Since the
political demand for spending can be expected to change (typically
increase) with increases in national income, by measuring demand as a
percentage of national income we eliminate the need to consider constant
shifts in demand due to economic growth.
On the supply side of government spending are the marginal political
costs of raising government revenue. For reasons discussed above, we
confine ourselves to the political costs of raising revenue either
through direct taxation or through government debt--deficit financing.
In Figure 1, M|C.sub.t~ represents the marginal political cost of direct
taxation and M|C.sub.d~ represents the marginal political cost of
increasing the deficit. As with the political demand for spending, the
marginal costs of any absolute level of tax and deficit financing can be
expected to change (typically decrease) as national income increases, so
it is again convenient to relate these marginal costs to revenue raised
as a percentage of national income. The reasonable assumption is that
both M|C.sub.t~ and M|C.sub.d~ slope upward, indicating that political
resistance to transferring more revenue to the government increases as
the amount of revenue yielded increases. It also seems reasonable to
assume that M|C.sub.d~ is greater at any positive level of government
revenue than M|C.sub.t~ . Even though it has been argued that government
debt is equivalent (or nearly so) to taxation,(2) if voters behaved as
if they accepted this argument, then politicians would be indifferent
between deficit financing of expenditures, taxation, or any mix of these
two methods.(3) The relative position of M|C.sub.t~ and M|C.sub.d~ in
Figure 1 is consistent with the observation that annual revenues from
taxation consistently exceed the annual deficit. The horizontal
summation of M|C.sub.d~ and M|C.sub.t~ yields the marginal political
cost of obtaining revenue when the mix of deficit financing and taxation
is such that the total political cost of obtaining revenue is minimized.
This marginal cost curve is given by M|C.sub.s~ in Figure 1.
Government spending as a percentage of national income is determined
by the intersection of |D.sub.s~ and M|C.sub.s~. As the curves are
constructed in Figure 1, this intersection occurs at the relative level
of government spending given by G*. At spending level G* the political
cost minimizing levels of deficit financing and taxation are given by
|G.sub.d~ or |G.sub.t~ respectively. At any other combination of deficit
financing and taxation which yields the revenue necessary to finance
spending of G*, the marginal political cost of one source of revenue is
greater, and the marginal political cost of the other source is less,
than the marginal political benefit the revenue provides.
III. RECONCILING FRIEDMAN AND BUCHANAN
Although the model developed in section II is simple, it can be used
to resolve the question of whether cutting taxes will increase the
constraint on government spending or reduce the constraint on government
spending. The fact is, not all tax cuts are created equally, and
therefore there is no reason to believe that all tax cuts have equal
consequences. Tax cuts do not simply materialize out of thin air; they
depend on the political environment. A reduction in taxes can follow
from a reduced demand for government services, an increased tolerance of
deficits, or a reduced tolerance of taxes, but the impact on spending
and deficits is different in each case. If a tax cut is to serve as a
constraint on government spending, it has to result from a reduction of
tax supply.
Thus in terms of our model Friedman is not simply recommending a
reduction in taxes. More precisely, he is recommending an increase in
the marginal political cost of taxation. As shown in Figure 2, if the
marginal political cost of taxation shifts up to |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ from M|C.sub.t~, then the marginal political cost of
spending increases to |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ from M|C.sub.s~
which, everything else equal, reduces tax revenues to |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ from |G.sub.t~, increases the deficit to
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ from |G.sub.d~, and reduces government
spending to G|prime~ from G*. It is only in this case that a reduction
in taxes serves to reduce government spending by reducing available
revenue and forcing more reliance on deficit financing. It is possible
to have both a reduction in taxes and an increase in the deficit because
of a reduction in the marginal political cost of deficit financing. But
as is easily shown, in this case the increase in the deficit more than
offsets the reduction in tax revenue, with total government spending
increasing. This is the case which is the focus of Buchanans concern.
In terms of our model, Buchanan is not simply recommending an
increase in taxes. In fact what Buchanan favors is an increase in the
marginal political cost of deficit financing. Referring to Figure 3, it
is seen that if the marginal political cost of deficit financing shifts
up to M|C.sub.d~+ from M|C.sub.d~, then the marginal political cost of
spending increases to M|C.sub.s~+ from M|C.sub.s~ which, everything else
equal, increases tax revenue to |G.sub.t~+ from |G.sub.t~, reduces the
deficit to |G.sub.d~+ from |G.sub.d~, and reduces government spending to
G+ from G*.
Both Friedman's position of favoring a reduction in taxes to
constrain government and Buchanan's favoring an increase in taxes
to constrain government are reasonable positions when properly
qualified. The difference between Friedman and Buchanan can be explained
as nothing more than the difference between movements along and shifts
in the marginal political cost of taxation and deficit financing curves.
Friedman favors an upward shift in the M|C.sub.t~ curve forcing an
upward movement along the existing M|C.sub.d~ curve. Buchanan favors an
upward shift in the M|C.sub.d~ curve in order to force an upward
movement along the existing M|C.sub.t~ curve.
The Friedman and Buchanan positions are similar in that they both
call for increasing the political cost of acquiring revenue for
political purposes. In both cases the effect is a reduction in
government spending as a percentage of national income. And there can be
no doubt that both Friedman and Buchanan favor the position of the
other, as qualified by our discussion. Buchanan certainly favors
measures that would increase the political cost of raising tax revenue,
even though the result would be higher deficits.(4) And in his support
of a balanced budget amendment to the Constitution, Friedman makes an
argument that is similar to Buchanans in favor of increasing the
political cost of deficit financing, even though the result would be
higher taxes.(5)
We would note that our model does not pretend to fully explain the
political process. Rather, given the political process, these curves
provide a resolution of the trade-offs facing legislators. Further
research is needed to explain the determinants of changes in political
costs and benefits.
IV. SOME EMPIRICAL OBSERVATIONS
In terms of our model, what has happened with respect to federal
spending, taxes, and deficits in modern times? In Table I, we indicate
the six possible combinations of spending, tax and deficit outcomes
resulting from increases or decreases in spending demand (represented by
shifts in the marginal benefit curve), and tax and deficit supply
(represented by shifts in the marginal cost of taxation and marginal
cost of deficit curves).
While it is possible that in any given period more than one curve
might shift, the outcomes in Table I indicate what the dominant factor
should be for any given observed change in the size of spending,
taxation and deficits in relation to the economy. Data on government
expenditures, taxation and gross national product are readily available
for the entire twentieth century from the U.S. Department of Commerce
|1975~ and the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers |1991~. Since 1929,
federal budget data are available for calendar years on a national
income accounting basis; prior to that date, administrative budgetary
data on a fiscal year basis are used.(6) Armed with this data, changes
in the three fiscal variables as a percent of GNP were calculated for
the period 1900-90.
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
In Table II the six possible fiscal outcomes are summarized, and the
years in which each outcome dominated are listed below it. All six
possible changes are observed, although no single one dominates. The
most common change was a decrease in deficit supply (representing an
increase in the marginal cost of deficits), observed in twenty-four
years. This is the type of change envisioned by Buchanan. Nearly as
common, however, was the opposite change, an increase in deficit supply
(twenty years). Shifts in tax supply were much less common, with
decreases (envisioned by Friedman) occurring in eight years and
increases in but six.
Changes in the demand for governmental services (the marginal benefit
curve) were rather common as well, with increases in demand being
observed in nineteen years. Moreover, the increases in demand tended to
be large in magnitude, resulting in changes of more than one percent of
GNP in twelve of nineteen years, and of at least 3 percent of GNP in
seven years. By contrast, there were fewer (fourteen) decreases in
government demand, and proportionally fewer of them were large in
magnitude. Similarly, the short-term shifts in tax supply typically were
very modest in magnitude. Increases in deficit supply (representing a
fall in the marginal cost of deficits) tended to be both numerous and of
large magnitude, with one or more of the variables moving more than 1
percent of GNP in twelve of twenty years (heavily concentrated in the
heyday of the Keynesian Revolution in the 1940s and 1950s).
Many of the observed shifts reflected short-run events and thus were
ephemeral in character. For example, nearly half of the increases in
government demand could be attributed to wartime mobilization; a large
number of the observed increases in deficit supply occurred in recession
years when the desire to do something about adverse cyclical conditions
lowered the political costs of running budget deficits. Similarly,
several of the reductions in government demand or decreases in deficit
supply seemed to reflect postwar or post-recession returns to normalcy
regarding those variables.
To reduce the impact of these short-term influences and better
ascertain long-term trends, we calculated ten-year changes in each of
the fiscal variables and observed the resulting behavioral shifts. The
largest single behavioral shift, dominating the sixty-year period since
1930, is an increase in demand (rise TABULAR DATA OMITTED TABULAR DATA
OMITTED in the marginal benefit of spending). The two modern exceptions
were during the 1940s, when there was a fall in the marginal cost of
taxation, and the 1980s, when there was a fall in the marginal cost of
deficit spending, although the latter shift was a very small one. Over
the entire period 1900-1990, federal spending increased by about 20
percent of GNP, taxes by about 17 percent of GNP, and deficits by about
3 percent of GNP, consistent with a significant shift to the right in
the demand for spending curve.
We do believe, however, that some caution must be exercised in
attributing the rise in the size of government and its deficits
exclusively to an increase in demand for government. For example, a
decline in the marginal cost of taxation would explain increases in
government spending and taxation, but not the deficit, while a fall in
the marginal cost of deficits would explain rising spending and
deficits, but not taxes. It is possible that increases in demand have
been accompanied by important secondary increases in tax and/or deficit
supply.
The dominance of an increase in the demand for government spending
over the long run relative to the short run in part reflects the fact
that many short-run increases were of very large magnitude (during the
two world wars and the Great Depression), and were not offset in other
years by what were much weaker reductions in the short-run demand for
spending. This is highly consistent with Robert Higgs's |1987~
interpretation of the growth of modern government.
While a detailed empirical investigation must await another paper, we
would note that the nature of long-run behavioral shifts is different in
the earlier part of the century, with shifts in the tax supply curve
dominating. Those shifts seem to have been submerged in the short run
but were moderately strong over longer time horizons, at least until
World War II. Long-term increases in tax supply occurred only in decades
of major wars. It is interesting to note that the tolerance to taxation
rose during periods in which U.S. investment abroad was sharply
curtailed because of wartime conditions.(7)
It is also worth observing that fifteen of the nineteen short-run
increases in the demand for government spending occurred in Democratic
Administrations, while nine of fourteen reductions in such demand
occurred during Republican Administrations. Did rising demand for
government services lead to the election of Democratic presidents, or
did those presidents use their position of leadership to change the
curves themselves? Similarly, most (six of eight) of the years where the
marginal cost of taxation rose occurred during Republican
Administrations. Was this a cause, an effect, or a coincidence? These
questions must await further analysis.
Both Buchanan and Friedman advocate what in our model are supply side
influences (Friedman, a decrease in tax supply, Buchanan, a decrease in
deficit supply). Yet the evidence seems to suggest that over the long
run increases in government spending have been in large part demand
driven. Is their attempt to find a way to constrain government barking
up the wrong tree?
Not necessarily. Both Friedman and Buchanan favor a balanced budget
amendment to the Constitution that would not only bar budget deficits in
most situations but would also prevent the growth of government spending
in relation to total income or output. Both of these constitutional
strictures are inconsistent with continued increases in the demand for
governmental services. A balanced budget amendment would alter outcomes
in the direction the two economists want, assuming the past historical
trends were to continue.
It might be argued, however, that a balanced budget amendment would
merely create a disequilibrium situation, where, because of continuing
rising demand for spending, the governments constitutionally constrained
spending, taxes, and deficits are below the politically optimal level
indicated by our model. According to this scenario, politicians will
attempt to reach equilibrium by finding creative ways to redefine
deficits or government spending. For example, they might create a
separate capital budget, put social insurance programs on budget or off
budget (whichever best serves their purposes), move much activity to
quasigovernmental private corporations like Fannie Mae, mandate that
social spending be undertaken by the private sector (e.g. mandatory
private provision of health insurance), or impose off-budget user fees.
Yet it is also possible that by constitutionally changing the
budgetary rules of the game for politicians, the previously observed
increases in the marginal political benefits of government spending will
cease, and that rent-seeking coalitions will be less able to exert their
influence on the demand side. According to this view, constitutional
change will bring about a reduction in the demand curve that will
prevent such a disequilibrium situation from developing. Term-limitation
amendment advocates perhaps are motivated by similar considerations.
V. CONCLUSIONS
We have shown that the conflict between Friedman and Buchanan is more
apparent than real, in that both arguments are special cases of a more
general model. A related controversy is also easily defused by our
model. On one side of this controversy are those who argue that
increasing taxes for the purpose of reducing the budget deficit is an
exercise in folly since the extra revenue will be used to increase
spending, not to reduce the deficit. Some empirical studies support this
position. Manage and Marlow |1986~ and Vedder, Gallaway, and Frenze
|1987~ find that increased tax revenues cause at least an equal increase
in government spending. On the other side, Anderson, Wallace, and Warner
|1986~ and von Furstenberg, Green and Jeong |1986~ find that it is
government spending that causes increases in tax revenue which keep the
deficit lower than it would otherwise be.
As in the controversy between Friedman and Buchanan, both points of
view on the effects of a tax increase on the deficit are correct under
conditions which are special cases of our model. Whether or not a tax
increase results in an increase or a decrease in the deficit depends
upon the causes of the tax increase. In our model a tax increase
resulting from an upward shift in the marginal political cost of deficit
financing curve will result in deficit reduction. However, a tax
increase caused by an upward shift in the demand for government spending
curve will result in a deficit increase.
Our model of deficit, taxation, and spending determination is a
simple one; deceptively simple. It is tempting to dismiss the
implications we have derived from the model as obvious once they are
stated. But as obvious as these implications may be, the failure to
recognize them has been responsible for much controversy that could
otherwise have been avoided and much argument over important issues in
public finance that could otherwise have been clarified.
The point of the analysis, however, is that there can be no prospect
of reducing government spending or eliminating chronic budget deficits
without changes in the prevailing political benefits and costs of
spending, taxing and deficit financing. Such changes are the proper
concern of constitutional reform, not the likely outcome of ordinary
politics.
1. Actually, Friedman's position is somewhat more sophisticated:
"I distinguish sharply between the possibility of having a deficit
and the existence of a deficit. The possibility of having a deficit
where there is none undoubtedly encourages additional spending. The
existence of a deficit tends to discourage spending, and the larger the
deficit the larger the discouragement of spending" |Friedman 1991~.
2. See Barro |1974; 1989~.
3. However, see Barro |1979~.
4. Buchanan |1975, 158~ argues, "Because taxes cannot be lowered
in a differential manner, there is a public good barrier which inhibits
independent politician initiative toward tax reduction. By contrast,
because the benefits of government spending may be differentially
directed toward particular subgroups in the community, politicians are
motivated to initiate the formation of coalitions that will exploit
these latent demand opportunities...Because of this asymmetry in the
effective fiscal constitution, aggregate spending will tend to be
inefficiently large." Buchanan is clearly arguing here that the
political benefit from reducing taxes is too low from the perspective of
efficiency, which is equivalent to saying that the political costs of
increasing taxes is also inefficiently low.
5. For example, accordingly to Friedman and Friedman |1984, 12~,
"Deficit financing also has a major political cost. It enables our
legislative representatives to vote for expenditures that their
constituents want without having to vote for the taxes to pay for
them...If Congress were required to balance the budget, this shell game
would end."
6. For fiscal years 1900 to 1929, the fiscal variables are related to
GNP levels prevailing in the calendar year in which the fiscal year
began. There is no observation for the period July 1, 1929 to December
31, 1929, owing to the switch in the data from a fiscal to a calendar
year basis.
7. We are indebted to William Niskanen on this (and several other)
points.
REFERENCES
Anderson, William, Myles S. Wallace, and John T. Warner.
"Government Spending and Taxation: What Causes What?" Southern
Economic Journal, January 1986, 630-39.
Barro, Robert J. "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" Journal
of Political Economy, November/December 1974, 1095-1117.
-----. "On Determination of the Public Debt." Journal of
Political Economy, October 1979, 940-71.
-----. "The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits." Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Spring 1989, 37-54.
Buchanan, James M. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and
Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975.
Buchanan, James M., and Richard E. Wagner. Democracy in Deficit: The
Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. San Diego: Academic Press, 1977.
Friedman, Milton. "Supply-Side Policies: Where Do We Go From
Here," in Supply-Side Economics in the 1980s: Conference
Proceedings. Sponsored by Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and Emory
University Law and Economics Center. Westport, Connecticut: Quorum Books, 1982.
-----. Letter to authors, 18 July 1991.
Friedman, Milton, and Rose Friedman. Tyranny of the Status Quo. San
Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1984.
Higgs, Robert. Crisis & Leviathan. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1987.
Manage, Neela, and Michael L. Marlow. "The Causal Relation
Between Federal Expenditures and Receipts." Southern Economic
Journal, January 1986, 617-29.
Niskanen, William A. Reaganomics: An Insiders Account of the Politics
and the People. New York: Oxford University Press, 1988.
-----. "Deficits, Government Spending, and Inflation: What Is
the Evidence?" Journal of Monetary Economics, August 1978, 594-602.
U.S. Department of Commerce. Historical Statistics of the United
States, Colonial Times to 1970. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing
Office, 1975.
U.S. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Report of the President.
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1991.
Vedder, Richard, Lowell Gallaway, and Christopher Frenze.
"Federal Tax Increases and the Budget Deficit, 1947-86: Some
Empirical Evidence." Congressional Record, 30 April 1987, S5754-55.
von Furstenberg, George R., Jeffrey Green, and Jin-Ho Jeong.
"Tax and Spend, or Spend and Tax?" Review of Economics and
Statistics, May 1986, 179-88.