Bank panics, suspensions, and geography: some notes on the "contagion of fear" in banking.
Smith, Bruce D.
BANK PANICS, SUSPENSIONS, AND GEOGRAPHY: SOME NOTES ON THE
"CONTAGION OF FEAR" IN BANKING
Recent attempts to understand bank panics tend to emphasize
informational asymmetries or the possibilities of multiple equilibria.
Such approaches stand in contrast to historical research that emphasizes
legal factors influencing the organization of the banking system. This
paper constructs a model of a banking system operating under regulations
similar to those in effect under the National Banking System and in
which information is complete. In all other respects the model resembles
that of Diamond and Dybvig [1983]. The results indicate that, given the
regulatory environment, it would have been surprising if suspensions of
convertibility had not recurred periodically.
I. INTRODUCTION
Traditional explanations of panics under the National Banking
System (1863-1913), offered both by scholars and contemporaries,
stressed three factors. (1) Limitations on branching created incentives
for the development and heavy use of correspondent banking relations.
(2) Regulations favored holding interbank deposits with (a relatively
small group of) New York banks. This concentrated the reserves of the
banking system in one location, guaranteeing that heavy withdrawals of
interbank balances from any source would affect New York banks, and
through them, the entire banking system. (3) Legal restrictions
prevented banks (especially those holding large interbank deposits) from
adjusting interest rates in order to "protect" those deposits
during periods of heavy withdrawal demand.(1)
This traditional explanation of the periodic recurrence of panics,
which emphasizes the organization of the banking system, stands in
marked contrast to more recent theories of panics, which tend to focus
on various informational asymmetries between banks and depositors.(2)
Most of the recent literature on panics follows Diamond and Dybvig
[1983] in modelling banks as a mechanism for pooling liquidity risks
faced by depositors. More specifically, potential depositors can invest
in the same primary assets available to banks. However, primary assets
are costly to liquidate, and depositors face random future liquidity
needs at the time they make their investment decisions. In such a
framework the role of banks is to create and issue liabilities more
liquid than their assets. This activity provides insurance to depositors
against random liquidity needs.
In Diamond and Dybvig's paper, exogenous shocks to
agents' "liquidity preference" motivate withdrawal
demand. Contracts between banks and depositors allow agents with
liquidity needs to liquidate deposits at a lower cost than would be
incurred in liquidating the primary asset. However, for each withdrawal
due to inopportune liquidity needs, a bank must liquidate primary assets
and bear these costs. Hence the provision of liquidity by banks is
feasible only if withdrawal demand is restricted to those actually
requiring liquidity.
In the model of Diamond and Dybvig,(3) panics can occur because the
liquidity needs of individuals are private information. In particular,
banks are assumed to be unable to observe whether any individual needs
liquidity and hence cannot limit payments to individuals who actually
need to withdraw funds. Banks are thus subject to "runs" as
the result of self-fulfilling prophecies: if all depositors fear a run
and they all seek to withdraw, it will not be feasible for the banking
system to provide liquidity to all of them. Thus the banking system must
either suspend payments or be rendered insolvent. Of course, a crucial
component of this reasoning is that banks cannot distinguish
"legitimate" from panic motivated withdrawals, and hence
cannot ration funds on this basis.
This model of panics provides no role for the organization of the
banking system. It therefore suggests that different countries (or
different regulatory regimes within the same country) should have
similar histories with respect to panics (so long as they had similar
deposit insurance schemes, and similarly behaving lenders of last
resort). However, this has been far from the case. For instance, while
the U.S. had recurring panics from 1863-1933, Canada had none. A model
of panics should be able to confront the different historical
experiences of the U.S. and Canada. Given that Canada had unlimited
branching, it might be reasonable to place some credence on the
traditional explanation of panics given above.
A further feature of panics that needs examination is what Friedman
and Schwartz [1963] term geographic "contagion." Many
historical panics, such as those in 1893 and 1930-33, originated in
distinct geographic locations and were transmitted to money center banks (and hence the remainder of the banking system) through correspondent
banking relations. This suggests the importance of interbank relations
in originating and transmitting systematic panics. Of course, an
understanding of the role of correspondent banking relationships must
involve some understanding of the total organizational and institutional
structure of the banking system in place.
Relatedly, one feature of post-Civil War panics in the U.S. was
that the most important component of withdrawal demand from New York
(money center) banks was the demand for withdrawal of interbank
deposits. In many instances withdrawals by interior banks seem to have
had a large speculative component,(4) and interbank withdrawals were
rationed in practice (even by banks meeting all non-bank withdrawal
demand). Thus actual suspensions often treated bank and non-bank
customers asymmetrically. This again indicates the necessity of
understanding the nature of interbank relations. It also raises a
further issue. As noted above, models following Diamond and Dybvig give
rise to runs only if banks cannot limit withdrawals to agents with
legitimate liquidity needs. Such models therefore require either that
liquidity needs be unobservable, or that banks not be permitted to
ration funds to depositors who are speculating on their solvency.
However, in practice, banks have actively attempted to distinguish among
depositors and to ration funds on this basis during panics. At times
banks have restricted interbank withdrawals while meeting withdrawal
demands by individual customers with demonstrable liquidity needs. To
the extent that banks were able to accurately distinguish among
depositors, this suggests the importance of explaining panics without
appealing too heavily to the possession of private information by
depositors.(5)
Finally, to return briefly to the theme of geographic contagion,
Rolnick and Weber [1985] argue that the susceptibility of the banking
system to this contagion was lower during the Free Banking period than
it was to be later. If true, geographic contagion is more or less likely
under different regulatory regimes, which again focuses attention on the
organization of the banking system.
While there are many reasons to prefer the "traditional"
explanation of panics, then, this explanation has yet to be formalized.
I show here that such a formalization is easily accomplished by drawing
on the insights of the Diamond-Dybvig analysis. In particular, the
Diamond-Dybvig model provides an explicit framework for thinking about
liquidity provision by banks, and about how this provision of liquidity
makes banks vulnerable to heavy withdrawal demand. This paper takes a
version of the Diamond-Dybvig model and adds several features meant to
resemble legal restrictions imposed under the National Banking System.
It then shows that these regulatory features, by themselves, tend to
favor the development of correspondent banking relations and the
concentration of reserves discussed above. Moreover, under legal
restrictions limiting variability in interest rates on interbank
deposits, the banking system will be prone to periodic suspensions
whenever there are heavy withdrawals of interbank deposits. This
formalizes the "traditional" explanation of panics and
suspensions of convertibility. Finally, to emphasize that this can be
done without appealing to private information, all information is
assumed to be publicly available, and banks are free to utilize it
except when legal restrictions prevent them from doing so. Thus this
paper resembles earlier literature (e.g., Kareken and Wallace [1978]) in
attributing banking instability to the consequences of regulation.
In the next section of the paper I review some of the historical
features of the National Banking System and identify some particulars
that a model of panics might want to address. Not surprisingly, given
the "traditional" explanation of panics described above, I
argue that it is important for the model to provide an incentive for the
formation of interbank relations. Another important feature that the
model should capture is that under the National Banking System deposits
with designated "reserve agent" banks were counted as
reserves, which favored concentration of interbank deposits. Finally,
reserve agent banks argued that legal restrictions limited their ability
to vary interest rates according to level of withdrawal demand, and
hence prevented them from altering deposit rates enough to
"protect" their deposits during panics. Since Diamond and
Dybvig also rely on this same inability, I think it is useful to explore
the implications of taking this seriously as a feature of the National
Banking System. (This issue is discussed further in section II.)
With respect to the observations to be explained, section II shows
that panic related withdrawal demands (on New York banks) came heavily
from interior correspondent banks. And restrictions of payments by New
York (and other money center) banks fell much more heavily on
correspondent banks than non-bank depositors. Thus it is important to
address the role of interbank relations in panics.
In addition, I argue that it is not necessary to have panics result
from any unusual weaknesses of the banking system, or any
"mistrust" of banks by depositors. Panics under the National
Banking System typically did not involve unusual depositor losses or
high bank failure rates. Finally, panics need not result from low levels
of reserves or unusual monetary circumstances.
A model should also be able to confront the observed
"geographic contagion" of panics, in which regionally
localized banking problems are transmitted to New York (and because of
concentration of reserves, the entire banking system) via correspondent
banking relations. However, in doing so the model should be able to
address why the banking system appears to be more susceptible to
geographic contagion under some regulatory regimes than others.
Relatedly, it should also be able to explain the different histories of
countries operating under alternative regulatory regimes (say the U.S.
and Canada).(6)
Section III develops a model that draws heavily on Diamond and
Dybvig [1983] and Bhattacharya and Gale [1985], and incorporates some of
the features listed above. As in Diamond and Dybvig, there is a set of
identical (ex-ante) agents, who choose between investment in an illiquid primary asset and deposits in a bank. As in Bhattacharya and Gale,
depositors and banks are assigned to specific locations and, after
investment decisions are made, each location experiences a shock to the
liquidity preference of its members. However, unlike Diamond and Dybvig
or Bhattacharya and Gale, these shocks are publicly observable.
In keeping with the regulations under the National Banking System,
each location has a bank that cannot branch. Thus correspondent banking
relations are desirable as a means of pooling risk across locations. In
order to capture the concentration of reserves in New York, it is
assumed that regulations force interbank deposits to be held in one
location, where the bank is designated as a "reserve agent."
In order to illustrate starkly the incentives for risk pooling
across locations, the model is set up so that a desire for liquidity in
any location implies that banks in that location will want to liquidate,
and hence withdraw any interbank deposits. In addition, the number of
locations experiencing these shocks to liquidity preference is itself
random. Thus when a large number of locations desire liquidity, reserve
agent banks will face heavy withdrawal demand. In keeping with the
discussion above, reserve agents are not allowed to make payments to
these liquidating banks state contingent. Hence, as in Diamond and
Dybvig, if withdrawal demand is too high, the reserve agent will find it
infeasible to provide liquidity to all correspondent banks needing it.
The reserve agent must therefore either restrict payments to
correspondents or be rendered insolvent. Thus panics (associated
definitionally with suspensions by New York reserve agent banks) will
occur whenever enough locations experience "difficulties."
These difficulties are transmitted to reserve agents by correspondent
banking relations and affect the banking system generally by
necessitating suspension.
Finally, to illustrate how the regulatory regime affects the
susceptibility of the banking system to panics, the behavior of the
model when correspondent links are ruled out is considered. In some
respects, this makes the model resemble a stylized version of the Free
Banking System. As will be seen, this system is substantially more
resistant to panics than was the National Banking System. Nevertheless,
the model shows it to be a highly inefficient system, indicating that
efficiency and "stability" of the banking system need not be
at all related. This issue is explored somewhat further in the
conclusion.
II. SOME HISTORICAL OBSERVATIONS
The National Banking System
This section undertakes a capsule description of the National
Banking System circa 1873. The year 1873 is chosen since it contains the
panic that was least complicated "because of the comparatively
small number of state banks and trust companies" (Sprague [1910,
3]).
In 1873 national banks, and many state banks, were prohibited from
branching. As a result, unit banks were the rule. These banks could be
divided into three categories. Adopting contemporary terminology,
"country banks," which constituted most of the banking system,
were banks outside of designated "reserve" or "redemption
cities." These banks were required to hold vault cash equal to 6
percent of deposit liabilities, and until 1874, 6 percent of their
outstanding bank notes. Their remaining 9 percent required reserve could
be held as deposits with approved "reserve agents" in reserve
cities. In fact, in 1873, country banks held reserves exceeding
one-third of deposits, with amounts due from reserve agents routinely
exceeding cash [Sprague, pp. 11-12].
In the model below, country (or "interior") banks hold
all of their "reserves" with reserve agents. This
simplification does not violence to the observed behavior of country
banks in times of difficulty. During the panic of 1873 (specifically,
from September 12 to October 13) the deposits of country banks fell by
$45,000,000. Meanwhile, these banks increased their cash reserves by
$3,000,000, while reducing deposits with reserve agents by $26,000,000
[Sprague, p. 86]. This experience, which is typical of the actions of
country banks in crises, suggests that these banks drew only on reserve
agents at these times. In fact, cash reserves of country banks were
"almost stationary" in normal periods [Sprague, p. 19], and
generally rose during panics. Hence nothing is lost by abstracting from
cash reserve holdings by country banks.
The remaining banks, located in fifteen designated redemption
cities, fell into two groups. Those banks outside New York were required
to hold a reserve of 25 percent, half of which could be deposited with
New York banks. Until 1887 only New York was designated a "central
reserve" city, giving the New York banks a unique position at the
heart of the banking system. These banks motivate the "reserve
agent" to be modelled below. In the model there is a single reserve
agent. While not an accurate description of the banking system, it also
does little violence to reality. First, although there were fifteen
reserve cities, and in New York alone fifty national banks, seven New
York banks held 70 percent--80 percent of all the bankers' deposits
in the city [Sprague, p. 15]. Moreover, during the panic of 1873 all the
national banks of New York "were converted, to all intents and
purposes, into a central bank [which]...included virtually all the
banking power of the city" [Sprague, p. 90]. Thus it is not
unreasonable to develop a model with a single reserve agent.
In the model, the reserve agent holds only bankers' deposits,
i.e., it has no individual depositors. Again this simplification does
little violence to reality. The seven large New York reserve agents had
liabilities to bankers three times as great as those to individuals.(7)
As stated by Sprague [p. 18], it "seems clear that these banks
...were carrying on their operations almost wholly upon the unstable
basis provided by the deposits of the out-of-town banks." Moreover,
he notes "the movement of loans and reserves [of the New York
banks] was in close correspondence with known movements of bankers'
deposits" [Sprague, p. 22]. This is particularly true of call
loans, which were an important component of the assets of the New York
reserve agents. The volume of call loans "moved closely with the
volume of bankers' balances in New York" (James [1978, 103]).
Finally, during much of the period bankers' balances averaged
nearly one-half of total loans for all national banks of New York. Thus,
the events affecting reserve agents during panics (and more generally)
involved interbank deposits in a crucial way. It is therefore reasonable
to focus on bankers' balances and to abstract from the holding of
individual deposits by reserve agents.
A last fact to be noted is the perceived lack of latitude of
reserve agents to vary interest rates according to economic
circumstances. According to the New York Clearinghouse report of 11
November 1873, "the associated banks of New York...are deprived by
usury laws of the power, which is so effectively used by the principal
banks in Europe, of protecting or augmenting their resources by
adjusting the rate of interest to the necessities of the
occasion."(8) This suggests the appropriateness of following
Diamond and Dybvig in not permitting (reserve agent) banks to make
interest payments contingent on withdrawal demand. Here, however, this
should be viewed as a legal restriction.
The Panic of 1873
Prior to the panic of 1873 there were no significant changes in the
monetary circumstances of the U.S., nor was there any unusual expansion
of bank credit [Sprague, pp. 5-6]. Bank reserves were high by historical
standards [Sprague, p. 10],(9) and the panic did not appear to be a
response to the arrival of "bad news" about banks or the
banking system. According to Sprague,
All of the failures which occurred during the crisis were...due
to the "criminal mismanagement of their officers or to the neglect
or violation of the National Bank Act on the part of their
directors."
It would not be difficult to find many quite normal periods
during which both the number of failures and the losses of creditors
were far more considerable than in 1873. The solvency of the banks was
at no time in question. The defects in the banking system which were
disclosed were in its organization... Moreover, the banks were in what
was for them a normal condition of strength at the time [p. 81].
Moreover, "few banks failed during the crisis or during the
subsequent months and years of depression. And of the failures which did
occur hardly any involved serious loss to the creditors" [Sprague,
p. 2].(10) Thus the model should allow panics to arise without any
unusual occurrences other than that real activity is depressed. Also,
some banks should be liquidated during the panic, but should be
liquidated with relatively little loss to depositors.
Second, the bulk of withdrawals during the panic were made by
agents with readily observable characteristics. In particular, James
[1978, 120] reports that variations in the loans and reserves of New
York banks were accounted for mainly by reductions in bankers'
deposits, with the decline in bankers' balances being "almost
equivalent to the decline in reserves." Since country banks were
augmenting their cash reserves, these types of withdrawals seem likely
to have been speculative.(11) Moreover, such withdrawals were rationed.
For instance, on September 24 the Chicago clearinghouse association
voted to recommend suspension of currency payments to country banks. The
Chicago banks that did so were ones with large deposits of country
banks, while "other banks,...having to deal with only city
depositors, have been paying all demands upon them." [Chicago
Tribune, 25 September 1873, quoted in Sprague, p. 66]. Thus banks did
take actions to restrict withdrawals with substantial speculative
components. At the same time, banks attempted to meet withdrawal demands
by agents with demonstrable liquidity needs. Sprague [p. 63-66] provides
examples of efforts of banks to meet (observably) urgent withdrawal
demands of local customers during suspensions. Noyes [1909, 195] goes
further, and suggests (for 1893, which he argues was unusually severe)
that "most of the banks cashed freely the checks of depositors
where it was shown that the cash was needed for personal or business
uses."(12) In short, it is consistent with observation to proceed
as though banks were able to distinguish between "speculative"
and other types of withdrawal demand, and that under appropriate
circumstances, reserve agents were able to ration payments on
bankers' deposits.(13)
Third, while the panic of 1873 appears to have originated in New
York itself, the magnitude of the panic derived from the reserve agent
roles of the seven New York banks. Sprague states:
Had all the New York banks been purely local institutions, with no
responsibilities to the rest of the country, there can be little doubt
that they would have been able to weather the storm without further
difficulty. But the most considerable withdrawals of currency which they
had to meet came from the out-of-town banks, and demands from that
quarter showed no signs of diminishing [p. 51]. Suspension of cash
payments occurred on September 24 in New York ,shortly thereafter
becoming general throughout the U.S. This suggests the necessity of
having a model in which panics occur because of the special position of
reserve agents in the banking system. (The discussion of the panics of
1893 and 1930-33 will make this even more apparent.) In particular, it
appears to be important to subject reserve agent banks to speculative
withdrawal demand by other banks.
The Panic of 1893
As was the case in 1930-33, the panic of 1893 had a distinct
geographic flavor to it. Again, as in 1873, the New York banks were in a
(historically) strong position with respect to reserve holding:
"they were far more amply provided with cash than has been
customary in periods of active business either before or since"
[Sprague, p. 153]. In fact, the reserve position of the banking system
as a whole was "reasonably satisfactory" [Sprague, p. 161]. In
addition, the period prior to the panic was one of general monetary
expansion [Sprague, pp. 158-9], and the months of July and August saw
large monetary increases [Sprague, p. 184]. Finally, "there is no
evidence that depositors had become distrustful of the banks"
[Sprague, p. 181]. Thus circumstances do not suggest that the panic was
caused either by monetary factors, or by the kinds of factors stressed
by Diamond and Dybvig or Chari and Jagannathan, for instance.
The sense in which the panic had a geographic aspect is as follows.
The major banking development in the years before 1893 was the expansion
of bankers' deposits with reserve agents. "During the two
years after July, 1890, these deposits by interior banks in the city
institutions had increased one-third; in New York, they had actually
doubled... It was a 'run' of depositors on these Western banks
which in 1893 precipitated the urgent demand for return of deposited
reserves from Eastern institutions" (Noyes [1909, 190]).
In fact, at the end of May 1893 cash reserves of New York banks
were high, and cash flows from interior banks were positive. But in the
three weeks ending on June 17 the reserves of New York banks fell 18
percent, and their surplus reserves fell nearly 65 percent. "The
withdrawal of money from New York was directly due to the failure and
suspension of large numbers of banks, both state and national, and of
private bankers in the West and South" [Sprague, p. 168]. The
problems of these banks were attributable to adverse real events
precipitating large numbers of mercantile failures: "These failures
exceeded both in number and in the amount of liabilities those which had
occurred in any other period of equal length in our history"
[Sprague, p. 169].
While the outflow of cash had yet to create difficulties for New
York banks, on June 15 mechanisms for issuing clearinghouse loan
certificates were established. Thus New York banks were anticipating
problems that might be caused by their reserve agents positions, even
though "no bank in the city was in difficulty" [Sprague, p.
170].
By July 8, the total loss of reserves of the New York banks was $40
million.(14) Nonetheless, this "serious strain had been met boldly
and successfully" [Sprague, p. 173]. However, "during the
third week of July a second wave of distrust of the banks spread over
the West and South" [Sprague, p. 175]. The outflows of funds from
New York occasioned by these regional problems then led the New York
banks to restrict cash payments. It is apparent, then, that this
restriction was due to the reserve agent role of the New York banks.
Further, suspension of payments in New York closely preceded nationwide
suspension.
Two final points of note are as follows. First, "in 1873
suspension was one of the initial causes interrupting the normal course
of business. In 1893 it was rather of the nature of a last straw adding
to the burdens resting on the business community" [Sprague, p.
199]. Thus it is reasonable to view the problems of 1893 as occurring in
the context of (rather than being the cause of) depressed business
conditions.(15) Second, of the 158 national bank failures that occurred
in 1893, 153 were in the South and West (Noyes [1909, 193]). Thus
problems that caused bank liquidation were geographically confined to
certain regions.
The Panic of 1907
Some aspects of this panic that are challenging for existing models
are discussed by Smith [1984]. Hence it is sufficient to make a single
point about the reserve agent role of New York banks. The (partial)
suspension of cash payments in New York occurred on 16 October 1907.
Shipments of cash by New York city clearing-house banks to other states
in September 1907 were $23 million, and were $48 million in October. The
analogous numbers for 1906 were $27 million and $30 million,
respectively, while in 1908 the analogous numbers were $18 million and
$13 million.(16) Thus, as previously, suspension by money center banks
followed large demands for shipments of cash by interior banks. And,
"although there were runs on some banks in scattered parts of the
country due to local causes, loss of confidence was displayed less by
the public than by country banks" (Friedman-Schwartz [1963, 160]).
The Panics of 1930-33
As in 1893, the sequence of panics from October 1930 to March 1933
had distinctly regional aspects. Moreover, the transmission mechanism
for regional banking disturbances involved correspondent relations in an
integral way. This section establishes these facts, and attempts to
address the question: why was the experience of 1930-33 more severe than
that of earlier panics? Following Friedman and Schwartz, the suggested
answer is that money center banks were deterred from suspending payments
by the presence of the Federal Reserve System. As suggested by the model
of the following section, only such a suspension could prevent
insolvency of money center banks under the banking system in place.(17)
A number of authors have noted that the first banking crises of the
period (beginning in October-November 1930) had obvious regional
origins: "a crop of bank failures, particularly in Missouri,
Indiana, Illinois, Iowa, Arkansas, and North Carolina, led to widespread
attempts to convert demand and time deposits into currency... A
contagion of fear spread among depositors, starting from the
agricultural areas... But such contagion knows no geographical
limits" (Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 301]). In short, a panic with
regional origins was transmitted to money center banks.(18) Wicker
[1980] argues that the panic began with the failure of Caldwell and
Company, the largest southern investment banking firm, and that this
failure "led to the suspension within a two-week period of more
than 120 banks in four states" (Wicker [1980, 576]). Moreover,
Wicker argues that the failure of Caldwell and Company, and subsequent
related failures, was not due to the depression, but rather was an
exogenous shock (consistent with the modelling strategy employed below).
Finally, Wicker's argument suggests that a single shock was
responsible for the banking problems of an entire (four-state) region.
This is again consistent with the model developed below in which all the
agents in a given location are subject to the same disturbance.
Another aside relevant to the formulation of the model concerns two
additional facts about the panic of 1930. First the panic produced
"no discernible interest rate effects" (Wicker [1982, 47]).
This allows the model to follow Diamond and Dybvig in viewing rates of
return on investments as technologically determined. Such a formulation,
while not consistent with all observations from historical panics, is
also not inconsistent with all panic experiences. Second, the panic
produced relatively minor expenditure effects (Wicker [1982, 440-441]).
Thus it is not inappropriate to model the onset of a panic as a shock
which bank failures do not necessarily feed back on. This strategy is
adopted below.
The second crisis of the period at hand occurred in March 1931, and
then sustained difficulties began with a "renewed series of bank
failures...in the last quarter of 1932, mostly in the Midwest and Far
West" (Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 324]). Runs in particular
states occurred, leading to the declaration of state banking holidays in
Nevada, Iowa, Louisiana, and Michigan by 14 February 1933. Thus, as
previously, the onset of the panic had a regional nature. However, these
regional difficulties were transmitted generally by correspondent
banking relations, as described by Friedman and Schwartz:
While the holiday halted withdrawals in a given state, it
increased pressure elsewhere, because the banks that had been given
temporary relief withdrew funds from their correspondents in other
states in order to strengthen their position... The main burden of the
internal drain fell on New York city banks. Between February 1 and March
1, interior banks withdrew $760 million in balances they held with those
banks (leaving $900 million) [p. 325-6].
Finally, rumors of devaluation led to a demand by interior banks
for remittances in gold coin or gold certificates. "Mounting panic
at New York city banks on these accounts were reinforced in the first
few days of March by heavy withdrawals from savings banks and demand for
currency by interior banks" [Friedman and Schwartz, p. 326]. Thus,
as in earlier panics, withdrawals from New York by interior banks
continued to play a crucial role.
A national bank holiday was proclaimed on March 6. The severity of
banking problems in 1930-33 relative to earlier panics is summarized by
Friedman and Schwartz [p. 329]: "in none of the earlier episodes,
with the possible exception of the restriction (of payments) that began
in 1839 and continued until 1842, was there any extensive series of bank
failures after restriction occurred." The contrast with the
aftermath of the banking holiday is clear.
Why were the consequence of the panics of 1930-33 so much more
severe than those of earlier panics? Friedman and Schwartz argue that
the existence of the Federal Reserve System prevented a suspension of
cash payments:
We have already expressed the view that under the pre-Federal
Reserve banking system, the final months of 1930 would probably have
seen a restriction, of a kind that occurred in 1907, of convertibility
of deposits into currency... Restriction would almost certainly have
prevented the subsequent waves of bank failures that were destined to
come in 1931, 1932, and 1933 [p. 311].
Moreover, they argue [p. 311] that "the existence of the
Reserve System prevented concerted restriction." Thus the failure
to suspend cash payments was responsible for the severity of the banking
problems of 1930-33.(19)
The Free Banking Era (1837-1863)
Having emphasized issues related to the concentration of reserves
and the geographic contagion of regional banking difficulties, I now
consider briefly experiences during a period when reserves were less
concentrated, and when the banking system seemed less susceptible to
such contagion. While correspondent relations between interior and New
York banks were important even during this period (see Myers [1931, ch.
6]), the ratio of bankers' deposits to individual deposits in New
York was less than one-third of its 1872 level in 1846, and less than
half its 1872 level in 1856 (Myers [1931, 119]). In fact, deposits of
country banks in New York in 1857 comprised only about one quarter of
total New York bank deposits (Myers [1931, 141]).(20)
As described by Rolnick and Weber [1983; 1984; 1985], regulations
on state banks favored holding a considerable portion of bank reserves
in the form of state bonds, which were placed on deposit with the
auditor or treasurer of the chartering state. Since banks in a given
state therefore often had similar portfolios, the banks in each state
often also experienced very similar shocks to the value of their assets.
Thus large numbers of banks in a given state might tend to experience
difficulties simultaneously. As shown by Rolnick and Weber [1985], there
were episodes when large numbers of state banks were forced to liquidate
simultaneously. In later periods regional liquidations of such large
magnitude were transmitted generally. However, Rolnick and Weber [1985]
demonstrate that many such episodes under free banking were
geographically confined, suggesting that contagion is not inherent to
all possible organizations of the banking structure.(21)
Two points relevant to the formulation of the model in the next
section might also be noted. First, because free banks within a given
state often had similar portfolios, all of the customers of a given bank
were affected by a similar set of disturbances. The model of the next
section adopts, as a simplification, a specification in which all the
depositors of any given (interior) bank experience the same shock. This
makes the incentives for the formation of correspondent banking
relations very obvious, without doing violence to reality in some
important instances.
Second, while some states had very poor experiences under free
banking, Rolnick and Weber [1985, 5] discuss some instances where there
were large scale bank liquidations that involved very little loss to
noteholders. The next section constructs a model where large scale
liquidation can occur, while all liquidated regional banks meet their
contractual obligations.
III. THE MODEL
The Model Without Correspondent Banking
The discussion above suggests that understanding the incentives for
correspondent banking relations to form, and the limitations placed on
such relations by legal restrictions, is important in understanding
panics, and perhaps more so than informational frictions. This section
develops a model closely related to those of Diamond and Dybvig [1983]
and Bhattacharya and Gale [1985], but which incorporates some of the
institutional features discussed in section II. It is demonstrated that
periodic suspensions are natural in such a context to prevent general
insolvency of the banking system. To emphasize that informational
frictions are inessential to the argument, the model assumes complete
information.
To begin, a version of the model with no correspondent banking
relations is considered. This version of the model is meant to capture
crudely certain features of the free banking period, and to illustrate
the incentives for formation of correspondent banking. As will be
obvious, with no correspondent links in place geographic contagion
cannot occur, and the model is specified in such a way that (absent
these links) liquidated banks always pay off their obligations "at
par."
The model has three periods with time indexed by t = 0, 1, 2, and
with the physical environment similar to that of Diamond and Dybvig.(22)
In particular, all agents are endowed at t = 0 with one unit of a single
good. One unit "invested" in a single "primary
asset" at t = 0 pays off one unit if the investment is liquidated
at t = 1, and R > 1 units if the investment is held until t = 2. This
primary asset and bank deposits are the only investment opportunities.
In addition to the agents just described (depositors), banks are
allowed to form. It is useful to think of banks and depositors as being
assigned at t = 0 to distinct "locations," which then remain
fixed. Thus agents are geographically immobile. There is assumed to be a
continuum of locations, contained in some interval S the non-negative
real line. Let s [Epsilon] S index locations. Each location has one
bank, and some (identical across locations) number of depositors, which
is arbitrary.
All banks and depositors are identical ex ante (i.e., as of t = 0),
and depositors are identical to those described by Diamond and Dybvig.
In particular, letting [c.sub.t] [is greater than or equal to] 0 denote the consumption of an arbitrary depositor at date t, depositors (as of t
= 0) have utility functions , with is a random variable realized at time
1, and which takes the same value for all depositors in location s. For
each s, [Phi](s) has the probability distribution (1) [Phi](s) = 0 with
probability p
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Phi](s) = 1 with probability 1-p. Thus, at this point, there is
no aggregate uncertainty. Finally, the realization of [Phi](s) publicly
observable.(23)
Banks behave as follows. Banks in location s take deposits (at
most) from depositors in location s. Inter-location asset trade is
precluded, as are interbank interactions.(24) Let [r.sub.t](s) denote
payments by banks in location s to depositors who withdraw at date t; t
= 1, 2. Then, since all depositors in location s are identical at t = 1,
clearly
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
In short, without correspondent banking there is no scope for these
banks to pool the risks implicit in the model.
It should be clear that panics cannot occur here if banks in
location s are permitted to suspend if [Phi](s) but there are withdrawal
demands at t = 1.(25) Also, a fraction p of banks will be liquidated at
t = 1, and will be liquidated "at par," i.e., they fulfill all
contractual obligations. Thus this banking system is very safe. It is
also very inefficient since the expected utility of depositors (as of t
= 0) is pU(1) + (1 - p)U(R).(26)
A Model With a Reserve Agent and no Aggregate Uncertainty
Suppose the government now designates a single bank as a
"reserve agent," which is the only bank allowed to hold
interbank deposits. This bank, then, plays the role of the seven New
York city reserve agents. The reserve agent, for simplicity, does not
hold individual deposits.
As a consequence of the kinds of legal restrictions discussed in
section I, the reserve agent is required to announce deposit contracts
satisfying the "sequential service constraint" of Diamond and
Dybvig. Thus the reserve agent announces, at t = 0, a pair ([r.sub.1],
[r.sub.2]), where [r.sub.t] is the amount paid (per unit deposited) to a
bank that withdraws from the reserve agent at t. The sequential service
constraint prevents [r.sub.1] from being contingent on the volume of
withdrawals at t = 1. The reserve agent, then, can make payments at t =
1 state contingent only by suspending cash payments. Regulators permit
suspension only when a failure to suspend will result in insolvency of
the reserve agent.(27)
Following Diamond and Dybvig, the reserve agent is a cooperative
entity that maximizes the expected utility of regional bank depositors
as of t = 0. (Alternatively, there could be some fixed finite number of
reserve agents, each serving large numbers of "country banks,"
that compete for interbank deposits.) Then, at t = 0, all banks will,
for risk sharing reasons familiar from Diamond and Dybvig, deposit all
of their funds with the reserve agent. At t = 1 bank s will withdraw all
its reserve agent deposits if [Phi](s) = 0, receiving [r.sub.1] per unit
deposited. The proceeds are divided in a pro rata manner among the
depositors of bank s. Hence per person consumption in location s is
[r.sub.1] if [Phi](s) = 0, and is [r.sub.2] if [Phi](s) = 1 (and there
is no "run").(28) Then ([r.sub.1], [r.sub.2]) is chosen to
maximize pU([r.sub.1]) + (1 - p) U([r.sub.2]) subject to the resource
balance condition (2) [r.sub.2] = R/(1-p) - R[p/(1 - p)][r.sub.1] and an
incentive compatibility condition (3) [r.sub.2] [is greater than or
equal to] [r.sub.1]. The incentive condition (3) has an interpretation
different from that in Diamond and Dybvig. In their paper (3) must be
satisfied since [Phi](s) is unobservable, and hence depositors must be
given an incentive to truthfully reveal their realization of [Phi].
Here, [Phi](s) is observable. However, the reserve agent cannot ration
withdrawals except via a (permitted) suspension of convertibility.
Equation (3) requires that suspensions be necessary only in the event of
a "run," or in other words, that banks with [Phi](s) = 1 find
it optimal (in the absence of a run) not to withdraw their funds from
the reserve agent at t = 1.
The solution to the problem of maximizing pU([r.sub.1]) +
(1-p)U([r.sub.2]) subject to the resource balance condition (2), denoted
, satisfies. Thus the values, satisfying and equation (2) solve the
reserve agents's problem. Clearly satisfies.(29) Thus the
introduction of a reserve agent improves the performance of the banking
system, and in fact, supports a Pareto optimal allocation of resources.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
"Runs"
As mentioned above, if local banks are permitted to suspend
convertibility under appropriate circumstances then local runs cannot
occur. Runs on the reserve agent are a possibility, although these can
be forestalled by appropriate suspensions as well. Runs on the reserve
agent here are of exactly the Diamond-Dybvig variety, but have a
somewhat different interpretation. In particular, runs occur only
because the reserve agent is prevented (by regulation) from restricting
time 1 withdrawals (except through suspensions), and hence are simply
consequences of the "sequential service constraint."
To see that runs on the reserve agent can occur, suppose that local
banks conjecture that a fraction f of all banks will withdraw at t = 1.
If f satisfies (4) then each bank has an incentive to withdraw from the
reserve agent at t = 1. Moreover, since , condition (4) is satisfied for
f sufficiently near one. Thus if f = 1, a run which is a self-fulfilling
prophecy occurs.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
As in Diamond and Dybvig, runs can be prevented if the reserve
agent suspends whenever time 1 withdrawal demand is too large. In
particular, if the reserve agent suspends whenever f (the fraction of
country banks withdrawing at t = 1) exceeds p, then only banks with
[Phi](s) = 0 will withdraw at t = 1, and runs do not occur. Notice that
suspension does not involve a failure by any banks to make payments to
individual depositors, but only involves a refusal by the reserve agent
to make shipments to country banks.
Of course if the reserve agent suspends whenever f > p, runs
will not occur and suspensions will never be observed. Thus this section
should be viewed as leading expositionally to the introduction of
aggregate uncertainty.
The Model With Aggregate Uncertainty
The model is now modified by adding aggregate uncertainty about the
demand for withdrawals at t = 1. Following Diamond and Dybvig, p in
equation (1) is now a random variable realized at t = 1. Realizations of
p are common knowledge. The distribution of p will be denoted G(p), with
associated (continuous) density function g(p). The function g(.) has
support [Mathematical Expression Omitted] contained in [0,1]. It is
assumed that [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Other aspects of the
environment are as described above.
Similarly, the behavior of banks and reserve agents, including the
regulations under which they operate, are essentially the same as
previously. To capture one feature of the National Banking System
described in section II, the reserve agent announces an interest rate
for first period withdrawals, [r.sub.1], that is not permitted to be
contingent on the state p or on total withdrawals at t = 1. Let f denote
the fraction of interbank deposits withdrawn at t = 1. Then the resource
balance condition (2) is replaced by (5) [r.sub.2](p,f) = R/(1 - p) -
R[f/(1 - p)][r.sub.1].
Finally, as a description of regulatory behavior, f = p unless
banks (the reserve agent, and hence banks in general) suspend
convertibility of deposits. Suspension is permitted if and only if a
failure to suspend results in insolvency of the reserve agent at t = 1.
Here insolvency involves an inability to pay all country banks who at
t=1 withdraw [r.sub.1] per unit deposited. Insolvency occurs if payments
at t = 1, f[r.sub.1], are such that [r.sub.2](p,f) < [r.sub.1], since
then all country banks have an incentive to withdraw at time 1. Hence a
suspension occurs whenever f [is greater than or equal to] [p.sup.*],
where [p.sup.*] satisfies (6) Thus total withdrawals at t = 1 are given
by f = min(p,[p.sup.*]), which should be viewed as a regulatory
restriction. (It is verified below that the set of p values requiring a
suspension is, in fact, an interval.) [p.sup.*] is a choice variable for
the reserve agent at t = 0.
[Mathematical Expreession Omitted]
It remains to describe what transpires in the event of a suspension
(p > [p.sup.*]) at t = 1. If the reserve agent suspends, then it
makes payments of [r.sub.1] per unit deposited until the fraction of
banks that have withdrawn equals [p.sup.*]. Any additional banks wishing
to withdraw thereafter are unable to do so, so that the "sequential
service constraint" remains in effect. Country banks that wish to
withdraw at t = 1 are assigned an arbitrary position "in line"
so that, conditional on p, the probability of a country bank making a
desired withdrawal at t = 1 is min[([p.sup.*]/p), 1]. Since
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] [by (7), (8), and f =
min(p,[p.sub.*])] country banks that experience [Phi](s) = 1 make
withdrawals from the reserve agent only at t = 2.
Reserve Agent Behavior
For given values of [r.sub.1] and [p.sup.*] [satisfying (6)], let
[c.sub.t](p) denote the date t consumption of a representative
depositor. Then (7) and (8.a) [c.sub.2](p) = R/(1-p) -
R[p/(1-p)][r.sub.1]; p [is less than or equal to] [p.sup.*] (8.b)
[c.sub.2](p) = R/(1-p) - R[[p.sup.*]/(1-p)][r.sub.1]; p [is greater than
or equal to] [p.sup.*] Equation (7) is the sequential service
constraint, with suspensions occurring whenever p > [p.sup.*], and
(8) is the resource balance condition [using f = min (p,[p.sup.*])].(30)
Finally, incentive compatibility requires that (9), of course, satisfies
(9) with equality.) Equation (9) requires that country banks with
[Phi](s) = 1 find it optimal not to withdraw at t = 1 if convertibility
has not been suspended.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
As before, the reserve agent is a cooperative entity, which chooses
[r.sub.1] and [p.sup.*] to solve the problem subject to equations (8)
and (9). In addition, (10) R/(1-[p.sup.*]) - R[[p.sup.*]/(1 -
[p.sup.*])][r.sub.1] [is greater than or equal to] [r.sub.1] with
equality unless [p.sup.*] = p [bar], and subject to (11) (12)
1/[p.sup.*] [is greater than or equal to] [r.sub.1] [is greater than or
equal to] 0. The solution to this problem gives equilibrium values of
[r.sub.1] and [p.sup.*].
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Equilibrium Suspensions of Convertibility
If , partial suspensions of convertibility occur with positive
probability (since). Thus suspensions occur whenever enough locations
experience "bad" realizations ("local
liquidations"), which is exactly the geographic transmission of
disturbances. Moreover, suspensions can occur even if there are no
demands for liquidity by depositors in the reserve agent's
location. Thus, given the organization of the banking system, periodic
suspensions are to be expected so long as.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
It is therefore of interest to provide conditions implying that.
One (although by no means the only) set of sufficient conditions for
this is now stated. PROPOSITION: The solution to the problem (P) sets
[r.sub.1] > 1. In addition, if and (13), then REMARKS: The assumption
that cU [double prime](c)/U [prime](c) < - 1 implies U [prime](1)
> RU [prime](R). This, in turn, implies that (13) will hold if p
[bar] is sufficiently close to one.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
The proof of the proposition is straightforward but tedious, and is
therefore omitted here. A complete proof appears in Smith [1987], which
is available from the author on request. Notice that (recalling the
remark) the proposition asserts that periodic suspensions will be
observed if p can assume a large enough range of values. The probability
of a suspension at any date is, of course, 1-G([p.sup.*]).(32)
IV. CONCLUSIONS
Traditional explanations of bank panics, such as those offered by
Sprague [1910], Hepburn [1915], and Myers [1931; 1970] emphasize the
role of the organization of the banking system in allowing panics to
occur. The analysis in the previous section shows that existing models
of bank liquidity provision that follow Diamond and Dybvig [1983] can
easily be modified to incorporate organizational features of the banking
system. When these are introduced, such models can readily explain
observed panics without relying on informational asymmetries or multiple
equilibria. This fact is important not just because it demonstrates that
traditional explanations of panics can be formalized. It also raises the
possibility, which is important from a policy perspective, that a
reorganization of the banking system is a cheaper way of reducing the
possibility of bank panics than are deposit insurance schemes (with
their attendant adverse incentives for bank lending behavior). A
formalization of this intuition must be left as a topic for future
research, however.
In addition, the analysis offers some warnings against equating "safety" of the banking system with "efficiency" of
the banking system. This point was illustrated specifically in the
context of free banking, but is of course more general. For instance, a
common policy prescription for increasing the stability of the banking
system into the 1930s was the prohibition (or limitation) of interest
payments on deposits, and especially on interbank deposits. According to
Hepburn [1915, 318]," all the Comptrollers of the Currency down to
and including Knox recommended the prohibition of interest upon deposits
by reserve banks." As is easily verified, if restrictions on
deposit rates are interpreted as ceilings on the value of [r.sub.1],
effective interest rate ceilings will reduce the probability of
suspension. Thus the model suggests that this action would have rendered
the banking system less prone to suspension. Of course such an action
also would have reduced the (ex ante) expected utility of depositors, so
that again safer banking systems need not be the same thing as more
efficient banking systems.
In addition to formalizing the traditional explanations of panics
described above, the model also confirms some arguments about the
differences between the panics of 1930-33 and earlier panics. As an
example, Friedman and Schwartz [1963] argue that the presence of the
Federal Reserve System in 1930-33 prevented (early) suspension by the
New York banks, which made the panic of 1933 much more severe than
earlier panics. To the extent that the first part of their argument is
correct, the model confirms their conclusion. If the reserve agent
chooses [r.sub.1] and [p.sup.*] to solve the problem (P) in section III,
and then is inhibited from suspending ex post if p > [p.sup.*], the
result is that [r.sub.2](p,f) < [r.sub.1] will hold. There will be
consequent general demand for withdrawals from the reserve agent, which
will be left insolvent.
Finally, the analysis suggests some questions that must be left as
topics for future investigation. First, it has been common to argue that
the Canadian banking system avoided the recurrent panics observed in the
U.S. because Canadian banks were able to branch freely. (Such an
argument appears in Myers [1931; 1970].) Interestingly, deposit interest
rates paid by Canadian banks tended to display very little variation
over long periods. An interesting question is whether unlimited
branching alone (without significantly state contingent deposit rates)
can account for the superior stability of Canadian banks. A second
question, also raised by the differing experiences of Canada and the
United States, concerns the relative costs and benefits (taking into
account the possibility of panics) of having large banks with a national
system of branches that are imperfectly competitive versus having small
banks that behave competitively. A natural topic for investigation would
be to derive conditions under which the superior stability properties of
the former system would outweigh the costs of its associated
distortions.
(1)Examples of literature offering this kind of explanation of panics
include Sprague [1910] and Myers [1931; 1970]. Hepburn [1915, 314]
describes this argument without either endorsing or disputing it.
(2)Examples of such theories include those of Bental, Eckstein, and
Peled [1985], Chari and Jagannathan [1984], Gorton [1985], Jacklin
[1983], Smith [1984], and Waldo [1985]. (3)And in the related models of
Chari and Jagannathan [1984], Bental, Eckstein and Peled [1985], and
Jacklin [1983]. (4)"Speculative" withdrawal demand is defined
here and throughout as withdrawal demand that occurs (only) because
those seeking to withdraw are speculating about the ability of a
particular bank (or the banking system) to maintain payments. (5)It
should be mentioned that some models (e.g., Gorton [1985]) emphasize
private information by banks about their own asset position in
explaining panics and suspensions. However, as Rolnick banks [1987]
demonstrates, such a position would be difficult to defend as a
practical matter, since rates of interest on passbook accounts conveyed
substantial information about the riskiness of bank portfolios. (6)An
explanation for the differences between Canadian and U.S. banking
history that is not considered here (suggested to me by Tom Courchene)
is that Canadian banks were able to issue notes freely, and to use them
in meeting withdrawal demand. This argument, while different from that
considered here, would suggest that the susceptibility of a banking
system to panics depends heavily on legal specifications regarding how
depositors can demand payment. Interestingly, in Canada (with unlimited
branching) the number of branch offices closed during 1930-33, as a
percentage of total offices, was roughly equal to the percentage of U.S.
banks that failed during the same period. This suggests a similar
stimulus, but a very different response in the two economies. For an
argument that the difference was due to the kinds of branching
restrictions discussed in the text, see White [1984]. (7)This figure is
from Sprague [1910]. As pointed out to me by David Laidler,
Sprague's calculations deduct clearing-house exchanges from
individual deposits. (8)Quoted by Sprague [1910, p. 97]. Incidentally,
it is common in more modern studies to question the practical
significance of usury laws and to suggest that their provisions were
easily evaded. However, the conclusion of the clearing-house report is
consistent with the fact that the rate of interest on interbank deposits
paid by New York banks "remained remarkably stable at 2 percent per
annum..." over the entire 1888-1907 period (James [1978, 263]).
James [p. 265] reiterates this point: "in spite of substantial
general downward pressure on interest rates in the 1890s, the rate on
bankers' balances remained virtually fixed at 2 percent with some
short-lived deviations." James attributes this to
"competition," but does not state why competition would imply
constant rates on interbank deposits in the face of significant
movements in other rates. In fact, it appears that these interest rates
were not used to "protect or augment" the resources of New
York banks according to circumstances. Whether this is for the reason
cited in the text or not would seem to require a careful study of the
determination of interest rates on bankers' balances. I am aware of
no such study, and such a study is clearly beyond the scope of this
paper. However, since models following Diamond and Dybvig generally
assume that interest rates could not be made sufficiently state
contingent, it seems useful to explore the implications of taking the
claim in the clearinghouse report seriously. (9)The ratio of cash
holdings to individual deposits for national banks as a whole was higher
in 1873 than in all but three subsequent years before 1910 (National
Monetary Commission [1910, Table 12]). (It should be noted, however,
that these figures do not include the holding of national bank notes by
these banks.) It is true that this ratio was lower in 1873 than it had
been in previous years, but even so Sprague argues that "the cash
foundation of the credit structure had not been seriously weakened"
[1910, 10]. Also, it might be noted that the seven largest New York
reserve agents had a somewhat weaker reserve position than did the other
New York national banks. How important this fact might have been is hard
to know, since the New York Clearinghouse members pooled their reserves
during the panic. (10)See also Gorton [1986], who concludes that
depositors generally did not experience any unusual losses during the
panics that occurred under the National Banking System. (11)In
particular, in the face of declining deposits, the cash reserves of
country banks rose by $3,000,000, which constituted an 8 percent
increase. It might be argued that these banks increased their cash
reserves in anticipation of further runs, so that this behavior was
precautionary rather than "speculative." Two comments are in
order. First, the cash reserves of country banks rose, and did not
decline again until the end of the panic. If country bank behavior was
precautionary, apparently these banks systematically over-predicted
withdrawal demand (in other panics as well). Second, in view of the
detailed information on the status of the various regional banks
available in Sprague, it seems likely that reserve agent banks could
have gathered considerable information on which of their correspondents
were likely to be run. Whether they favored such correspondents is not
discussed in any literature that I am familiar with, but again the
possibility of rationing speculative withdrawal demand is raised.
An interesting discussion of some of these issues in the context of
the panic of 1907 appears in Laughlin [1912, 55-6]. (12)According to
Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 163], the panic of 1893 was more severe
than that of 1907, of which they argue "payroll difficulties
apparently were less conspicuous than in 1893, for banks generally
supplied their customers' requirements for this purpose in one way
or another." This is despite the fact that New York banks suspended
again to prevent a drain of reserves to interior banks
[Friedman-Schwartz, p. 160]. (13)An alternative strategy, suggested to
me by Edward Prescott, would be to have banks observe depositor
characteristics at some cost. A costly state verification model of bank
panics (with banks doing the verification) would be an interesting topic
for future research. (14)Parenthetically, Sprague states that country
banks increased their cash reserves during May and June, just as they
did in the panic of 1873 [1910, 173]. This serves to emphasize that,
during panics, country banks drew only on their deposits with reserve
agents. This is further validation of the abstraction from the holding
of reserves by country banks in the model below. (15)This is not to say
that the panic did not accentuate these conditions. See Sprague [1910,
200], for a discussion of some of its consequences. (16)These figures
are from Statistics for the United States, 1867-1909, Table 18.
(17)Parenthetically, state banks continued to hold reserves in the form
of deposits with New York, as they had under the National Banking System
(Kent [1963, 48]). Other aspects of the panics of 1930-33 that mirror
earlier panics are discussed by Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 167, 311].
(18)Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 311] argue that New York banks began to
be affected almost immediately. They suggest, for instance, that the
Bank of the United States might have been able to reopen (as the
Knickerbocker Trust did in 1908) had the New York banks suspended
payments in 1930. (19)While suspensions could have occurred as they did
earlier, Friedman and Schwartz [1963, 311] offer some arguments as to
why incentives to suspend were attenuated by the presence of the Federal
Reserve System. (20)While several factors are important in explaining
why relations with New York banks were generally less important during
this period, regulations concerning how reserves could be held likely
played a significant part. While some states allowed interbank balances
in New York to count as reserves by the 1850s (James [1978, 97]),
regulations about how interbank balances could be counted against
reserve requirements were less favorable to the concentration of
reserves in New York than they were to be under the National Banking
System. That regulations allowing deposits in New York to count as
reserves were important in concentrating bankers' balances there is
supported by Myers's [1931, 109] discussion of Vermont banks in the
1850s. This again emphasizes the importance of institutional features of
the banking system. (21)Two comments are in order. First, the episodes
examined by Rolnick and Weber [1985] involved shocks affecting the value
of bank assets, whereas in the model below, shocks affect the liquidity
preference of depositors. However, as will be clear, shocks to liquidity
preference affect the value of bank portfolios in a way that would seem
to capture the general phenomenon discussed by Rolnick and Weber. Also,
it would be easy to allow both for liquidity preference shocks and
shocks to bank portfolios in the model, although this would not alter
the basic point.
Second, while there was a systemic panic in 1857, this was not the
result of geographic contagion of the type discussed in the panics of
1893 or 1930-33. The panic originated in New York (Myers [1931, 142]),
although interestingly, "the drawing down of country balances
marked the beginning of the strain" (Myers [1931, 143]). (22)It
would be straightforward to embed the model in an overlapping
generations setting. This would allow the arrangements described to be
repeated over time, with suspensions occurring periodically. Since such
an extension is fairly trivial, for ease of exposition only a
"one-shot" version of the model is considered. (23)The
assumption that all depositors in location s experience the same shock
merits some comment. While inessential to the analysis, this assumption
permits all liquidated banks (in this section) to pay off obligations
"at par." It is also the simplest way of illustrating the
incentives for the formation of interbank relations. Of course it is
possible to relax this assumption at the cost of some complication. One
way of relaxing this assumption would be to make the model more closely
resemble that of Bhattacharya and Gale [1985]. (24)Interbank relations
are, of course, ruled out only for the purposes of this section.
Interlocation asset trading (that does not occur through banks) is ruled
out for two reasons. First, as is the case in Diamond and Dybvig and
related literature, the role for banks hinges on the absence of share
markets in which claims to capital in process can be traded. (On this
point see Jacklin [1983]). Second, a natural question about real world
arrangements would be: if legal restrictions inhibited banks from
creating optimal risk sharing arrangements, why weren't other
financial markets used to accomplish this objective? A natural answer is
that legal restrictions inhibited the formation of nationally integrated
asset markets in general (Davis [1965, 381-3]). Thus the assumption in
the text is a natural one. (25)In practice, suspensions and subsequent
resumptions were common by interior banks in periods of stringency. Thus
this does not appear to be an overly strong assumption. (26)Thus
depositors are indifferent between deposits and direct investment in the
primary asset. This indifference could be remedied by having direct
investments by individuals be subject to some risk of theft, for
example. It will also disappear when correspondent relations are
allowed. (27)Legally banks could suspend only by ceasing discounting
operations under normal circumstances. During panics suspensions were
sometimes sanctioned by some states, and were "tolerated in the
rest" (Friedman-Schwartz [1963, 161]). Of course banks did not
cease operations during these episodes (other than the bank holiday of
1933). For a discussion of official encouragement of suspension by
states in the panic of 1907, see Andrew [1908]. (28)It goes without
saying that this "contract" between local banks and depositors
in optimal, given the behavior of the reserve agent. In particular, the
only other feasible contracts between local banks and depositors either
induce depositors with [Phi](s) = 1 to withdraw at t = 1, or randomize payments among depositors. No contracts with these features can be
optimal (29)This result and both follow from the assumption that cU
[double prime](c)/U [prime] (c) < -1, as in Diamond and Dybvig.
(30)In other words, the bank in location s pays its depositors [r.sub.1]
at t = 1 if if [Phi](s) = 0 and if it receives funds from the reserve
agent. The latter event occurs with probability min[[p.sup.*]/p, 1]. If
[Phi](s) = 1, the bank in locations withraws from the reserve at t = 2,
and pays depositors [r.sub.2](p,f). Again giveen the actions of the
reserve agent, this is an optimal contract between local banks and
depositors for the reasons stated in footnote 28. (31)The fact that
[r.sub.1] > 1 implies that [c.sub.2](p) is decreasing in p. Hence if
(9) holds with equality for [p.sup.*] it is violated for all p >
[p.sup.*]. Thus suspension of convertibility is required for all p >
[p.sup.*]. This validates the assertion above that suspensions must
occur whenever f [Epsilon] [[p.sup.*], p [bar]]. (32)A natural modelling
question would involve analyzing the consequences of introducing deposit
insurance or a "lender of last resort" into this economy. This
exercise is not undertaken here, since the focus of this paper is on
understanding historical panics. During the episodes discussed in
section II there was, of course, no (federal) government deposit
insurance scheme in effect. There was a lender of last resort during
1930-33, but the failure of the Federal Reserve System to function
effectively in this regard is well known.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
REFERENCES
Andrew, A. Piatt. "Substitutes for Cash in the Panic of
1907." Quarterly Journal of Economic, August 1908, 497-516.
Bhattacharya, Sudipto and Douglas Gale. "Preference Shocks,
Liquidity, and Central Bank Policy." Manuscript, University of
Pennsylvania, 1985.
Bental, Benjamin, Zvi Eckstein and Dan Peled. "Banking
Instability and International Capital Flows: Are Government Regulations
Desirable?" Manuscript, Tel Aviv University, 1985. Chari, V. V. and
Ravi Jagannathan. "Banking Panics, Information, and Rational
Expectations Equilibrium." Manuscript, Northwestern University,
1984.
Davis, Lance E. "The Investment Market, 1870-1914: The
Evolution of a National Market." Journal of Economic History,
September 1965, 355-99.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Phillip Dybvig. "Bank Runs, Deposit
Insurance, and Liquidity." Journal of Political Economy, June 1983,
191-206.
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the
United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Gorton, Gary. "Bank Suspension of Convertibility." Journal of
Monetary Economics, March 1985, 177-93.
______. "Bank Panics and Business Cycles." Manuscript,
University of Pennsylvania, 1986. Hammond, Bray. Banks and Politics in
America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957. Hepburn, A.
Barton. A History of Currency in the United States. New York: Macmillan,
1915. Jacklin, Charles J. "Information and the Choice Between
Deposit and Equity Contracts." Manuscript, 1983.
James, John A. Money and Capital Markets in Postbellum America.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978. Kareken, John and Neil
Wallace. "Deposit Insurance and Bank Regulation: A Partial
Equilibrium Exposition." Journal of Business, July 1978, 412-38.
Kent, Raymond P. "Dual Banking Between the Two World
Wars," in Banking and Monetary Studies, edited by Deane Carson.
Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, 1963, 43-63.
Kostak, William M. "The Analysis of Financial Crises: A
Comparison of the Banking Panics of 1907 and 1930-33." Senior
Honors Thesis, Carnegie-Mellon University, 1986.
Laughlin, J. Laurence. Banking Reform. Chicago: Blakely Printing
Co., 1912. Myers, Margaret G. The New York Money Market, vol. I. New
York: Columbia University Press, 1931.
______. A Financial History of the United States. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1970. National Monetary Commission.
Statistics for the United States, 1867-1909, compiled by A. Piatt
Andrew. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1910.
Noyes, Alexander D. Forty Years of American Finance. New York:
G.P. Putnam, 1909.
Rolnick, Arthur J. "The Benefits of Bank Deposit Rate
Ceilings: New Evidence on Bank Rates and Risk in the 1920s."
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Summer 1987, 2-18.
Rolnick, Arthur J. and Warren E. Weber. "New Evidence on the
Free Banking Era." America Economic Review, December 1983, 1080-91.
______. "The Causes of Free Banking Failures: A Detailed
Examination." Journal of Monetary Economics, November 1984, 267-91.
______. "Inherent Instability in Banking: The Free Banking
Experience." Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1985.
Smith, Bruce D. "Private Information, Deposit Interest Rates, and
the "Stability" of the Banking System." Journal of
Monetary Economics, November 1984 293-317.
______. "Bank Panics, Suspensions, and Geography: Some Notes
on the "Contagion of Fear" in Banking." Manuscript,
University of Western Ontario, 1987.
Sprague, O.M.W.A History of Crises Under the National Banking
System. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1910. Waldo,
Douglas G. "Bank Runs, the Deposit-Currency Ratio and the Interest
Rate." Journal of Monetary Economics, May 1985, 268-77.
White, Eugene N. "A Reinterpretation of the Banking Crisis of
1930." Journal of Economic History, March 1984, 119-38.
Wicker, Elmus. "A Reconsideration of the Causes of the
Banking Panic of 1930." Journal of Economic History, September
1980, 571-83.
______. "Interest Rate and Expenditure Effects of the Banking
Panic of 1930." Explorations in Economic History, October 1982,
435-45.
BRUCE D. SMITH, Cornell University and Rochester Center for
Economic Research. In writing this paper I have benefitted from
duscissions with, and the assistance of, Charles Calomiris, Edward
Prescott, Richard Sylla, and Warren Weber. I would especially like to
thank William Kostak for conversations that more or less directly led to
the writing of the paper. Also, I would like to thank Sudipto
Bhattacharya, Phillip Dybvig, Scott Freeman, David Laidler, Arthur
Rolnick, Richard Sweeney, Eugene White, and two anonymous referees for
their detailed comments on earlier draft. In addition, I have benefitted
from the comments of seminar participants at the Bank of Canada, the
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the University of California at
Santa Barbara, the University of Western Ontario, and the University of
Wisconsin, as well as participants in sessions at the American Finance
Association meetings and the conference "Approaches to the Business
Cycle" held at McGill University. Finally, this paper was done in
part while I was a visitor at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
which is thanked for its support. I alone am responsible for the
contents, however.