An analysis of import expansion policies.
Dinopoulos, Elias ; Kreinin, Mordechai E.
AN ANALYSIS OF IMPORT EXPANSION POLICIES
1. INTRODUCTION
Policy makers appear to display unlimited ingenuity in devising new
and ever more complex measures to influence international trade. No
sooner did the profession come to understand the economics of
trade-restricting devices, such as tariffs, quotas and voluntary export
restraints (VERs) (the discirminatory nature of VERs has been recently
noted and analyzed in Dinopoulos and Kreinin [1988; 1989]), then a new
policy instrument was introduced, christened by Bhagwati [1987] as
Voluntary Import Expansion (VIE).
In several recent instances the United States insisted that Japan
"voluntarily" expand its import of certain products, such as
semiconductors or beef, from the United States. While the VER restricts
the volume of trade below free-market equilibrium, the VIE would expand
the volume of trade beyond the equilibrium level. But both policies
depart from free-trade equilibrium, and both are discriminatory in
nature. A VER that limits Japanese auto exports to the U.S. favors
European suppliers who are excluded from the restriction: their thems
of trade improve and/or their volume of export expands. A VIE that
forces the Japanese to import a minimum amount of semiconductors from
the United States excludes European suppliers. A similar VIE on beef
imports would discriminate against Australian and Argentinian suppliers.
It constitutes a form of "export protectionism" (Bhagwati and
Irwin [1987]).
How might a government administer a VIE? In the case of
semiconductor imports by Japan, the possibilities are: a subsidy by the
Japanese government on imports from the U.S., or an
"instruction" to the large chip-using companies in Japan to
purchase more American chips. (1) Alternatively, the Japanese
government may buy U.S. chips for its own use, or it may favor American
suppliers in awarding contracts.
In the Fall of 1987 certain Japanese steel companies agreed (under
MITI pressure) to expand purchases of American coal, even though it
costs $A7 per ton more than Australian coal. And in January 1988 (1) an
instance of a VIE in the construction sector came to light. Japan had
been under American pressure to permit U.S. construction companies to
bid on large Japanese public works projects, like the Kansai airport
near Osaka and the Tokyo-Bay bridge. Such projects can amount to $70
billion in the next decade. In response, the Japanese government
proposed to permit joint foreign-Japanese companies to bid on these
projects, and give American companies preferential treatment in forming
such partnership.
This paper analyzes the economic effects of a VIE and, whenever
appropriate, compares it to an export subsidy. Whereas the export
subsidy is an instrument used by the exporting country, the VIE is a
policy instrument employed by the importing country.
Section II presents a comparison between the two instruments within
a two-country general equilibrium framework when the offer curves are
elastic. Section III addresses the question of the optimum VIE and
compares it to the optimum tariff. Section IV analyzes the case when
the offer curve of the VIE-administering country is enelastic. Another
key distinction between a VIE and an export subsidy is that the former
is discriminatory between different trading partners while the latter is
not. Section IV incorporates this feature by recasting the analysis in
a three-country general equilibrium framework. Section V states the
conclusions of the paper.
II. VIEW VERSUS EXPORT SUBSIDY: A TWO-COUNTRY ANALYSIS
(WITH ELASTIC OFFER CURVES)
In coventional trade geometry, an export subsidy (assumed, as
usual, to be financed by a lump-sum tax) is shown by an outward shift
(namely, an increase) of the offer curve of the subsidizing country. By
contrast, a graphical representation of a VIE is more complex, and is
displayed in Figure 1. Japan exports good X (which may be autos) to the
U.S. and imports good Y (which may be tree) from the U.S. OJ is
Japan's free-trade offer curve, and it intersects the U.S. offer
curve at point A. Japan's free-trade import level is OE. Assume
that under U.S. pressure Japan accepts a minimum import of OM, which is
greater than OE. (3) Then the segment of Japan's free-trade offer
curve below M' becomes irrelevant, and only M'J is the
relevant part. In other words, if the terms of trade (rays from the
origin) intersect the offer curve along segment M'J, that segment
is operational. If Japan's terms of trade deteriorate to a level
below the ray OM' (so that they intersect the free trade offer
curve along OM'), then the minimum import takes over and
Japan's offer curve becomes segment M'L. Thus, the entire
offer curve is JM'L with a kink at M'. However, segment
M'L does not continue indefinitely, because there is a limit to
Japan's supply of its exportables.
Equilibrium Under Free Trade and a VIE:
In Figure 1, OJ and OUS are respectivel the free-trade offer curves
of Japan and the U.S. yielding terms of trade OA (not drawn) and OE
imports into Japan. The two trade indifference curves (TICs) tangent to
ray OA at the point A, the intersection of the two offer curves,
represent the welfare levels of the two countries under free trade. If
minimum imports of OM are accepted by Japan, then its offer curve become
JM'L with a kink at M', as explained earlier. It intersects
the U.S. free-trade offer curve at point V. The new equilibrium terms
of trade is ray OV, and U.S. welfare is represented by TIC
[W.sup.V.sub.US.] The U.S. terms of trade improves and that Japans
deteriorates relative to the free-trade position. The VIE improves U.S.
welfare relative to free trade, because the U.S. has moved along its
curve away from the origin, and welfare is an increasing function of the
distance along a free-trade offer curve from the origin. (4)
Quantity-Equivalent Subsidy
We next define U.S. export equivalent to the VIE as the subsidy
that would ensure the same quantity of U.S. exports as under the VIE,
namely quantity OM. With a free-trade policy followed by Japan, its
offer curve reverts to the original OM'J. The geometrical
expression of the U.S. export subsidy is given by a leftward shift
(increase) in the U.S. offer curve, so that it intersects the free-trade
Japanese offer curve at M'. For the sake of clarity it is not
drawn.
U.S. welfare under the subsidy is [W.sup.S.sub.US.] It is
definitely inferior to U.S. welfare under a VIE, [(W.sup.V.sub.US)],
because both the terms of trade and the volume of imports are lower.
Japan is better off with a U.S. export subsidy (at equilibrium
point M') than with a VIE (at V) because its terms of trade (price
of an equal quantity of Japan's imports) is higher.
Indeed the sole difference between equilibrium poins M' and V
(and points in between) is the division of the rents between the two
countries. If the U.S. "forces" Japan to impose a VIE,
equilibrium is at V and the U.S. gets the rents. Intuitively, the VIE
is equivalent to a Japanese import subsidy of the magnitude M'V, so
that the subsidy is a revenue transfer to the U.S. of that amount. In
the case of a U.S. export subsidy, the rent M'V accrues to Japan.
Price-Equivalent Subsidy
Under elastic offer curves the same results when equivalence is
defined as the export subsidy that generates the same domestic price
ratio in the U.S. as the VIE. This definition of equivalence is
appropriate when the objective of the U.S. government is to maintain a
given level of production in each sector. In Figure 1 the VIE-ridden
equilibrium is at V, and U.S. welfare is represented by
[W.sup.V.sub.US], the TIC tangent to the international and the U.S.
domestic price [beta]. A price-equivalent U.S. export subsidy is one
that would shift the U.S. offer curve leftward to intersect Japan's
offer curve at P. Point P is defined as the intersection of
Japan's free-trade offer curve (OJ) with the U.S.
income-consumption path (not drawn), which is negatively sloped when
both goods are normal. By the nature of the income-consumption path,
the tangent to the U.S. TIC at P has the slope [beta].
U.S. welfare under the price-equivalent subsidy is represented by
TIC [W.sup.S.US.] It is distinctly inferior to the VIE--ridden welfare,
because by moving from V to P along the income-consumption path, we are
transferring income from the U.S. to Japan. Conversely, Japan's
welfare is higher with a U.S. export subsidy (at P) than with a VIE (at
V).
III. THE OPTIMUM VIE (5)
Is there an optimal VIE; namely, one which would maximize U.S.
welfare? In Figure 2 we extend the U.S. offer curve to its inelastic portion (beyond point B). All points of intersection between M'L
and the inelastic portion of U.S. offer curve (such as point U)
represent unstable equilibria. In other words, if the U.S. mandates the
VIE, Japan will always choose a point on the elastic part of the
American offer curve. Hence, the final outcome will never settle on the
inelastic portion of the U.S. offer curve. This rules out a Japanese
export whih is a Gifften good in the U.S. Likewise, if M' lies in
its entirety above point B, a VIE-ridden equilibrium does not exist.
It follows that a VIE-ridden trade equilibrium can exist only on
the AB portion of the U.S. offer curve. The VIE which maximizes U.S.
welfare is OR; namely, the one which results in trade-equilibrium point
B, where the U.S. offer curve is of unitary elasticity. The trade
indifference curve [W.sup.V.sub.US] represents U.S. welfare under an
optimum VIE. Thus, the optimum VIE is defined strictly in terms of the
U.S. offer curve.
By contrast, the U.S. optimum tariff is defined in terms of
Japan's offer curve. It results in a U.S. trade indifference curve
[W.sup.t.sub.US] tangent to Japan's offer curve. It is obvious
from Figure 2 that the optimum VIEW and the optimum tariff cannot be
ranked.
IV. INELASTIC JAPANESE OFFER CURVE
In what follows we divide the inelastic portion of Japan's
offer curve into two components: the negatively sloping part (range BC
in Figure 3) and the positively sloping part (CJ), that represents the
case of a U.S. export which is a Giften good in Japan. In accordance
with our earlier notations, assume that OE is the free-trade imports
into Japan and OM is the VIE-ridden imports. Under a VIE, Japan's
offer curve would become MTCSL.
If the U.S. offer curve intersects Japan's offer curve in
range BS then the analysis in Section II holds, because the VIE
equilibrium would occur along SL. If the intersection occurs along ST,
the VIE constraint is not binding. Finally, should the U.S. offer curve
intersect Japan's free-trade offer curve in range TJ (the Giffen
good range), then the VIE-ridden equilibrium is in range TM. In that
latter case, the U.S. offer curve must cross Japan's offer curve
from below; otherwise, the free-trade equilibrium would not be stable.
With a U.S. offer curve OUS, free-trade equilibrium is at A, and
the VIE-ridden equilibrium is at V. The alternative of a U.S. subsidy
cannot generate the maximum imports of OM, as the subsidy-enhanced U.S.
offer curve would cut Japan's free-trade offer curve below point A.
An export subsidy reduces the price of the U.S. exportable, and it being
a Giffen good in Japan, the quantity demanded declines rather than
rises. Thus, in order to meet the minimum import objective OM the U.S.
must impose a tariff that would shift its offer curve in a way that it
passes through point T.
Japan is better off under a VIE than under a U.S. tariff. To
obtain the same amount of imports, it needs to export more under a
tariff (MT [is greater than] MV). By similar reasoning, the U.S. is
better off under a tariff.
V. VIE VERSUS EXPORT SUBSIDY IN A THREE-COUNTRY FRAMEWORK
Because the VIE is an inherently discriminatory device, while the
export subsidy is not, we need to compare the two instruments in a
three-country framework, which can capture discriminatory practices. We
do this for one trade pattern, namely, where the U.S. imports from
Europe and Japan. Analysis of alternative trade patterns yields similar
results and is available from the first author upon request. The
analysis is confined to elastic offer curves and to quantity
equivalence.
In Figure 4 OUS is the U.S. free-trade offer curve, while OE and OJ
are the offer curves of Europe (the third country) and Japan,
respectively. They are added up to O(E+J) by summing the quantities
traded by the two countries with the U.S. along each terms of trade line
(ray from origin) (see Dinopoulos-Kreinin [1989]). The free-trade
equilibrium is at F with terms of trade OF. The welfare level of the
three countries is represented by the three TICs (not shown) tangent to
OF at its points of intersection with the three offer curves.
Japan's imports from the U.S. is OA.
We now introduce a VIE for Japan, where Japan increases its imports
from OA to OM. Its offer curve becomes JM'LB, with a kink in
M' (as in Section II). To derive the new (E+J) offer curve we take
the following steps: (a) For all terms of trade rays steeper than
OM', the (E+J) offer curve is unchanged, so the segment above point
K remains intact. (b) For points below K we add up, for each terms of
trade, the quantities traded by Japan along M'B (fixed imports,
variable exports) with those traded by Europe along its free-trade offer
curve. That yields the segment below K of the new (E+J) offer curve.
Note that the segment below point L represents a reversal of
Europe's trade pattern. Point L is the intersection of MB with a
terms-of-trade ray representing the autarky price for Europe and Japan.
The intersection of the new offer curve LK(E+J) with OUS yields the new
trade equilibrium at point V. If it occurs at terms of trade steeper
than OK, then the VIE constraint is not binding. If it occurs at a
point below L, then the trade pattern is reversed. Hence, our interest
is confined to range KL.
In our diagram, the new equilibrium is at V with terms of trade OV.
The U.S. welfare is represented by [W.sup.V./.sub.US]; it is higher than
its free-trade welfare. Europe's welfare declines from its
free-trade position as we move down its free-trade offer curve and its
terms of trade deteriorate. Japan's welfare worsens relative to
free-trade (to a TIC passing through C) and its terms of trade
deteriorate.
A U.S. export subsidy (non-discriminatory) which would yield the
same Japanese imports from the U.S. as under the VIE (OM), would shift
the U.S. offer curve to the left, such that it would pass through point
K. The resulting terms of trade intersects Japan's free-trade
offer curve at M', so that Japan's imports would be OM. U.S.
welfare under an export subsidy is represented by the TIC
[W.sup.S./.sub.US], passing through K but not tangent to OK.
In Figure 4 the U.S. terms of trade are worse under an export
subsidy (OK) than under a VIE (OV). (6) Thus, the U.S. welfare is
higher under a VIE. On the other hand, Japan and Europe are better off
with U.S. export subsidy than a VIE. Under a U.S. subsidy, their
welfare is represented by the TICs tangent to OK at points M' and
I, respectively. This is the same outcome as in the two-country case.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
In a two-country world, the VIE-subsidy comparison depends on the
division of the rents between the two countries. With a
Japan-administered VIE the U.S. captures the rent, while under a U.S.
export subsidy Japan receives the rent. Hence, the U.S. is better off
with a Japanese VIE and Japan is better off with a U.S. subsidy.
Introduction of an inelastic U.S. offer curve shows that the optimum VIE
for the U.S. is one which results in a trade-equilibrium point where the
U.S. offer curve is of unitary elasticity. It cannot be ranked relative
to the optimum tariff. Stability considerations rule out a solution
along the inelastic portion of the U.S. offer curve.
With an inelastic Japanese offer curve we can obtain a Giffen good
in Japan. Under these circumstances no U.S. subsidy can help attain the
required minimum import. Instead, the U.S. would have to levy a tariff
to reach this goal. Japan is better off under a VIE than a U.S. tariff,
while the reverse is true for the U.S. Introduction of a third country
does not affect the welfare ranking under the two policies. Under
elastic offer curves and independently of the pattern of trade, the U.S.
is better off under a Japanese VIE than under a U.S. export subsidy;
Japan is better off under a U.S. export subsidy than under a VIE. The
third country's welfare is higher under the policy which improves
its terms of trade, and that depends on the pattern of trade.
As a final point, it might be mentioned that if the VIE is designed
to offset an initial Japanese trade barrier, then it is conceivable that
both countries will be better off because the VIE might offset the
initial distortion.
(1) See the Wall Street Journal, 21 September 1988, p. 12.
(2) See the Wall Street Journal, 13 January 1988, p. 4.
(3) It is possible that a VIE can be expressed as a percentage of
the current level of imports. In this case the shape of the VIE-ridden
offer curve changes but the results of the paper hold.
(4) An equivalent equilibrium would ensue if Japan introduced a
trade subsidy which would shift its offer curve outward, such that it
would pass through point V.
(5) We are grateful to Peter Neary for inspiring this section.
(6) This property always holds as long as the VIE constraint is
binding and there are no multiple trade equilibria for the U.S.
REFERENCES
Bergsten, C. Fred, Kimberly A. Elliott, Jeffrey J. Schott and Wendy
E. Takacs. Auction Quotas and United States Trade Policy, Washington,
D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1987.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. "VERs, Quid Pro Quo DFI and VIEs:
Political-Economy-Theoretic Analysis." International Economic
Journal. Spring 1987, 1-14.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. and Douglas Irwin. "The Return of the
Reciprocitarians: U.S. Trade Policy Today." The World Economy,
September 1987, 109-30.
Brecher, Richard A. and Jagdish N. Bhagwati. "Voluntary
Export Restrictions Versus Import Restrictions: A Welfare-Theoretic
Comparison," in Essays in Honour of W.M. Corden, edited by H.
Kierzkowski. Basil Blackwell: Oxford, 1987,.
Dinopoulos, Elias and Mordechai E. Kreinin. "Effects of the
U.S.-Japan Auto VER on European Prices and on U.S. Welfare."
Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1988, 484-91.
Dinopoulos, Elias and Mordechai E. Kreinin. "Import Quotas and VERs: A Comparative Analysis in a Three-Country Framework."
Journal of International Economics, February 1989, 169-78.
Kreinin, Mordechai e. and Elias Dinopoulos. "Alternative
Quotas and VER Allocation Schemes--A Welfare Comparison." mimeo,
University of Florida, 1988.
Meade, James E. A Geometry of International Trade. London: Allen
and Irwin, 1952
Vanek, Jaroslav. International Trade: Theory and Economic Policy.
Homewood, Ill.: R.D. Irwin, Inc., 1962.
During the final phases of this paper the second author was a
visiting professor at Monash University, Melbourne, Australia. An
earlier version of the paper was presented at the 62nd Annual Western
Economic Association International Conference in Vancouver, B.C.,
Canada, July 1987; Monash University, Melbourne, Australia, October
1987; and the Seventh Annual Conference on International Trade Theory,
University of Western Ontario, Canada, April 1988. The authors would
like to thank Jagdish Bhagwati, Steven Matusz, Peter Neary, and Joe
Stone for useful comments and suggests. This paper has benefited
greatly from thoughtful comments and excellent suggestions by an
anonymous referee.