Debt and incomplete financial markets: a case for nominal GDP targeting.
Sheedy, Kevin D.
IV. Quantitative Analysis of Optimal Monetary Policy
This section presents a quantitative analysis of the nature of the
optimal monetary policy characterized in section III.
IV.A. Calibration
Let T denote the length in years of one discrete time period in the
model. The numerical results presented here assume a quarterly frequency
(T= 1/4). The parameters of the model are [beta], [theta], [alpha],
[lambda], [eta], [mu], [epsilon], [xi], and [sigma]. As far as possible,
these parameters are set to match features of U.S. data. (14) The
baseline calibration targets and the implied parameter values are given
in table 1 and justified below.
Consider first the parameters [beta] and [theta] (equations 40 and
41 show that the choice of these parameters is equivalent to specifying
the patience parameters [[DELTA].sub.b] and [[DELTA].sub.s]). These
parameters are calibrated to match evidence on the average price and
quantity of household debt. The "price" of debt is the average
annual continuously compounded real interest rate r paid by households
for loans. As seen in equation 41, the steady-state growth-adjusted real
interest rate is related to [beta]. Let g denote the average annual real
growth rate of the economy. Given the length of the discrete time period
in the model, 1 + [bar.[rho]] = [e.sup.rT] and 1 + [bar.g] = [e.sup.gT].
Hence, using equation 41, [beta] can be set thus:
(66) [beta] = [e.sup.-(r-g)T].
From 1972 through 2011 there were average annual nominal interest
rates of 8.8 percent on 30-year mortgages, 10 percent on 4-year auto
loans, and 13.7 percent on 2-year personal loans, while the average
annual change in the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) price index
over the same period was 3.8 percent. The average credit-card interest
rate between 1995 and 2011 was 14 percent. For comparison, 30-year
Treasury bonds had an average yield of 7.7 percent over the periods
1977-2001 and 2006-11. The implied real interest rates are 4.2 percent
on Treasury bonds, 5 percent on mortgages, 6.2 percent on auto loans,
9.9 percent on personal loans, and 12 percent on credit cards. The
baseline real interest rate is set to the 5 percent rate on mortgages,
since these constitute the bulk of household debt. The sensitivity
analysis considers values of r from 4 percent up to 7 percent. Over the
period 1972-2011, used to calibrate the interest rate, the average
annual growth rate of real GDP per capita was 1.7 percent. Together with
the baseline real interest rate of 5 percent, this implies that [beta]
[approximately equal to] 0.992 using equation 66. Since many models used
for monetary policy analysis are typically calibrated assuming zero real
trend growth, for comparison the sensitivity analysis also considers
values of g between 0 percent and 2 percent.
The relevant quantity variable for debt is the ratio of gross
household debt to annual household income, denoted by D. This
corresponds to what is defined as the loans-to-GDP ratio [bar.l] in the
model (the empirical debt ratio being based on the amount borrowed
rather than the subsequent value of loans at maturity) after adjusting
for the length of one time period (T years), hence D = [bar.l]T. Using
the expression for [bar.l] in equation 42 and given a value of [beta],
the equation can be solved for the implied value of the debt service
ratio [theta]:
(67) [theta] = 2(1 - [beta])D/[beta]T.
Note that in the model, all GDP is consumed, so for consistency
between the data and the model's prediction for the debt-to-GDP
ratio, either the numerator of the ratio should be total gross debt (not
only household debt), or the denominator should be disposable personal
income or private consumption. Since the model is designed to represent
household borrowing, and because the implications of corporate and
government debt may be different, the latter approach is taken.
In the United States, as in a number of other countries, the ratio
of household debt to income has grown significantly in recent decades.
To focus on the implications of the levels of debt recently experienced,
the model is calibrated to match average debt ratios during the five
years from 2006 to 2010. The sensitivity analysis considers a wide range
of possible debt ratios from 0 percent up to 200 percent. Over the
period 2006-10, the average ratio of gross household debt to disposable
personal income was approximately 124 percent, while the ratio of debt
to private consumption was approximately 135 percent. Taking the average
of these numbers, the target chosen is a model-consistent debt-to-income
ratio of 130 percent, which implies (using equation 67) a debt service
ratio of [theta] [approximately equal to] 8.6 percent.
For the coefficient of relative risk aversion [alpha], the survey
evidence presented by Barsky and others (1997) suggests considerable
risk aversion, but most likely not in the high double-digit range for
the majority of individuals. Overall, the weight of evidence from this
and other studies suggests a coefficient of relative risk aversion above
one, but not significantly higher than 10. A conservative baseline value
of 5 is adopted, and the sensitivity analysis considers values from zero
up to 10.
One approach to calibrating the discount factor elasticity
parameter [lambda] (from equation 28) is to select a value on the basis
of its implications for the marginal propensity to consume from
financial wealth. Let m denote the increase in per-household (annual)
consumption of savers from a marginal increase in their financial
wealth. It can be shown that m, [lambda], and [beta] are related as
follows:
(68) [lambda] = 1 - mT/[beta].
Parker (1999) presents evidence to suggest that the marginal
propensity to consume from wealth lies between 4 and 5 percent (for a
survey of the literature on wealth and consumption, see Poterba 2000).
However, it is argued by Juster and others (2006) that the marginal
propensity to consume varies between different forms of wealth. They
find that the marginal propensity to consume is lowest for housing
wealth and larger for financial wealth. Given the focus on financial
wealth in this paper, the baseline calibration assumes m [approximately
equal to] 6 percent, which using equation 68 implies [lambda]
[approximately equal to] 0.993. The sensitivity analysis considers
marginal propensities to consume from 4 to 8 percent.
The range of available evidence on the Frisch elasticity of labor
supply [eta] is discussed by Hall (2009), who concludes that a value of
approximately 2/3 is reasonable. However, both real business cycle and
New Keynesian models have typically assumed Frisch elasticities
significantly larger than this, often as high as 4 (see King and Rebelo
1999; Rotemberg and Woodford 1997). The baseline calibration adopted
here uses a Frisch elasticity of 2, and the sensitivity analysis
considers a range of values for q from completely inelastic labor supply
up to 4. With the assumption (equation 43) on the differences between
the Frisch elasticities of borrowers and savers that ensures the wealth
distribution has no impact on the aggregate supply of labor, the
baseline calibration amounts to setting [[eta].sub.b] [approximately
equal to] 1.6 and [[eta].sub.s] [approximately equal to] 2.6.
The debt maturity parameter [mu] (which given [mu] = [gamma]/(1 +
[bar.n]) stands in for the parameter [gamma] specifying the sequence of
coupon payments) is set to match the average maturity of household debt
contracts. In the model, the average maturity of household debt is
related to the duration of the bond that is traded in incomplete
financial markets. Formally, duration [T.sub.m] refers to the average of
the maturities (in years) of each payment made by the bond weighted by
its contribution to the present value of the bond. Given the geometric
sequence of nominal coupon payments parameterized by [gamma], the bond
duration (in steady state) is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Let j denote the average annualized nominal interest rate on
household debt, with 1 + [bar.j] = [e.sup.jT]. In the optimal policy
analysis, the steady-state rate of inflation is zero ([bar.[pi]] = 0),
hence nominal GDP growth is [bar.n] = [bar.g], and so [mu] = [gamma]/ (1
+ [bar.g]). It follows that [gamma] and [mu] can be determined by
(69) [gamma] = [e.sup.jT] (1 - T/[T.sub.m]), and [mu] = [e.sup.-gt]
[gamma].
Doepke and Schneider (2006) present evidence on the average
duration of household nominal debt liabilities. Their analysis takes
account of refinancing and prepayment of loans. For the most recent year
in their data (2004), the duration lies between 5 and 6 years, and the
duration has not been less than 4 years over the entire period covered
by the study (1952-2004). This suggests a baseline duration of [T.sub.m]
[approximately equal to] 5 years, which using equation 69 implies [mu]
[approximately equal to] 0.967. The sensitivity analysis considers the
effects of having durations as short as one quarter (one-period debt)
and as long as 10 years.
There are two main strategies for calibrating the price elasticity
of demand [epsilon]. The direct approach draws on studies estimating
consumer responses to price differences within narrow consumption
categories. A price elasticity of approximately 3 is typical of
estimates at the retail level (see, for example, Nevo 2001), while
estimates of consumer substitution across broad consumption categories
suggest much lower price elasticities, typically lower than one
(Blundell, Pashardes, and Weber 1993). Indirect approaches estimate the
price elasticity based on the implied markup 1/([epsilon] - 1), or as
part of the estimation of a DSGE model. Rotemberg and Woodford (1997)
estimate an elasticity of approximately 7.9 and point out this is
consistent with markups in the range of 10 to 20 percent. Since it is
the price elasticity of demand that directly matters for the welfare
consequences of inflation rather than its implications for markups as
such, the direct approach is preferred here and the baseline value of
[epsilon] is set to 3. A range of values is considered in the
sensitivity analysis, from the theoretical minimum elasticity of 1 up to
10.
The production function is given in equation 32. If e denotes the
elasticity of aggregate output with respect to hours, then the
elasticity [xi], of real marginal cost with respect to output can be
obtained from e using [xi] = (1 - e)/e. A conventional value of e
[approximately equal to] 2/3 is adopted for the baseline calibration
(this would be the labor share in a model with perfect competition),
which implies [xi] [approximately equal to] 0.5. An important
implication of [xi], is the strength of real rigidities, which are
absent in the special case of a linear production function ([xi] - 0).
The sensitivity analysis considers values of [xi] between 0 and 1.
In the model, [sigma] is the probability of not changing price in a
given time period. The probability distribution of survival times for
newly set prices is (1 - [sigma])[[sigma].sup.l], and hence the expected
duration of a price spell [T.sub.p] (in years) is [T.sub.p] =
T[[summation].sup.infinity].sub.l=1] l(1 - [sigma])[[sigma].sup.l] =
T/(1 - [sigma]). With data on [T.sub.p], the parameter [sigma] can be
inferred from:
(70) [sigma] = 1 - T/[T.sub.p].
Following Nakamura and Steinsson (2008), the baseline duration of a
price spell is taken to be 8 months ([T.sub.p] [approximately equal to]
8/12), implying [sigma] [approximately equal to] 0.625. The sensitivity
analysis considers average durations from 3 to 15 months.
IV.B. Results
Consider an economy hit by an unexpected permanent fall in
potential output. Flow should monetary policy react? In the basic New
Keynesian model with sticky prices but either complete financial markets
or a representative household, the optimal monetary policy response to a
total-factor-productivity shock is to keep inflation on target and allow
actual output to fall in line with the loss of potential output. Using
the baseline calibration from table 1 and the solution (equations 63-65)
to the optimal monetary policy problem, figure 1 shows the impulse
responses of the debt-to-GDP gap [[??].sub.t], inflation [[pi].sub.t],
the output gap [[??].sub.t], and the bond yield [j.sub.t] under the
optimal monetary policy and under a policy of strict inflation targeting
for the 30 years following a 10 percent fall in potential output.
With strict inflation targeting, the debt-to-GDP gap rises in line
with the fall in output (10 percent) because the denominator of the
debt-to-GDP ratio falls while the numerator is unchanged. The effects of
this shock on the wealth distribution and hence on consumption are long
lasting. The serial correlation of the debt gap is equal to [lambda]
[approximately equal to] 0.993, implying an average duration of
approximately 36 years. Intuitively, with a marginal propensity to
consume from financial wealth of 6 percent per year, consumption
smoothing leads to persistence in the wealth distribution for far longer
than typical business-cycle frequencies. Strict inflation targeting does
ensure that the output gap is completely stabilized (the "divine
coincidence"), and with no change in real interest rates or
inflation, bond yields are completely unaffected.
The optimal monetary policy response is in complete contrast to
strict inflation targeting. Optimal policy allows inflation to rise,
which stabilizes nominal GDP over time in spite of the fall in real GDP.
This helps to stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio, moving the economy closer
to the outcome with complete financial markets where borrowers would be
insured against the shock and the value of debt liabilities would
automatically move in line with income. The rise in the debt-to-GDP gap
is very small (around 1 percent) compared to strict inflation targeting
(10 percent). The rise in inflation is very persistent, lasting around
two decades. The higher inflation called for is significant, but not
dramatic: for the first two years, it is around 2-3 percentage points
higher (at an annualized rate), for the next decade around 1-2 percent
higher, and for the decade after that, around 0-1 percent higher. The
serial correlation of inflation is due almost entirely to the
autoregressive root [mu] [approximately equal to] 0.967 (the other
autoregressive root is x [approximately equal to] 0.29, and the
moving-average root is 0.41, which are much smaller and not far from
canceling out as a common factor). The average duration of inflation is
approximately 7 years, which is longer than typical business-cycle
frequencies. Inflation that is spread out over time is still effective
in reducing the debt-to-GDP ratio because debt liabilities have a long
average maturity. It is also significantly less costly in terms of
relative-price distortions to have inflation spread out over a longer
time than the typical durations of stickiness of individual prices: this
is the inflation-smoothing argument that drives the optimality of the
autoregressive root [mu].
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The rise in inflation does affect the output gap for the first one
or two years, but this is short-lived because the duration of the real
effects of monetary policy through the traditional price-stickiness
channel is brief compared to the relevant time scale of decades for the
other variables. The effect is also quantitatively small because
inflation is highly persistent, the rise in expected inflation closely
following the rise in actual inflation, so the Phillips curve implies
little impact on the output gap. Finally, nominal bond yields show a
persistent increase. It might seem surprising that yields do not fall as
monetary policy is loosened, but the bonds in question are long-term
bonds, and the effect on inflation expectations is dominant (there is a
small fall in real interest rates because the rise in bond yields is
less than what is implied by the higher expected inflation, but there is
no significant "financial repression" effect).
The term [chi] from equation 64 provides a precise measure of the
relative importance of risk sharing versus inflation stabilization under
the optimal monetary policy (the response of the debt gap is a multiple
1 - [chi] of what it would be under strict inflation targeting, while
the response of inflation is a multiple [chi] of what it would need to
be to support full risk sharing). The baseline calibration leads to a
policy weight [chi] on debt gap stabilization of approximately 89
percent and a policy weight 1 - [chi] on inflation stabilization of 11
percent.
The baseline calibration thus implies that addressing the problem
of incomplete financial markets is quantitatively the main focus of
optimal monetary policy rather than other objectives such as inflation
stabilization. What explains this, and how sensitive is this conclusion
to the particular calibration targets? Consider the exercise of varying
each calibration target individually over the ranges discussed in
section IV. A, holding all other targets constant. For each new target,
the implied parameters are recalculated and the new policy weight [chi]
is obtained. Figure 2 plots the values of [chi] (the optimal policy
weight on risk sharing) obtained for each target.
As can be seen in figure 2, over the range of reasonable average
real GDP growth rates and real interest rates there is almost no effect
on the optimal policy weight. The results are most sensitive to the
calibration targets for the average debt-to-GDP ratio and the
coefficient of relative risk aversion. The average debt-to-GDP ratio
proxies for the parameter [theta], which is related to the difference in
patience between borrowers and savers. It is not surprising that an
economy with less debt in relation to income has less of a concern with
the incompleteness of financial markets, because in such a case the
impact of shocks is felt more evenly by borrowers and savers. In the
limiting case of a representative-household economy, the average
debt-to-GDP ratio tends to zero, and the degree of completeness of
financial markets becomes irrelevant. Risk sharing receives more than
half the weight in the optimal policy as long as the calibration target
for the average debt-to-GDP ratio is not below 50 percent.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
It is also not surprising that the results are sensitive to the
coefficient of relative risk aversion. Since the only use for complete
financial markets in the model is risk sharing, if households were
risk-neutral then there would be no loss from these markets being
absent, as long as saving and borrowing remained possible in incomplete
financial markets. The baseline coefficient of relative risk aversion is
higher than the typical value of 2 found in many macroeconomic models
(although that number is usually relevant for intertemporal substitution
in those models, not for attitudes to risk), but it is low compared to
the values often assumed in finance models that seek to match risk
premia. The optimal policy weight on risk sharing exceeds 0.5 if the
coefficient of relative risk aversion exceeds 1.3, so lower degrees of
risk aversion do not necessarily overturn the conclusions of this paper.
The next most important calibration target is the price elasticity
of demand. A higher price elasticity increases the welfare costs of
inflation. Welfare ultimately depends on quantities, not prices, but the
price elasticity determines how much quantities are distorted by
dispersion of relative prices. To reduce the optimal policy weight on
the debt gap below one-half it is necessary to assume price elasticities
in excess of 10. Such values would be outside the range typical in IO
and microeconomic studies of demand, with 10 itself being at the high
end of the range of values used in most macroeconomic models. The
typical value of 6 often found in New Keynesian models only reduces
[chi] to approximately 71 percent.
The results are largely insensitive to the marginal propensity to
consume from financial wealth, which is used to determine the parameter
[lambda] in the specification of the endogenous discount factors. The
Frisch elasticity of labor supply has a fairly small but not
insignificant effect on the results, with the optimal policy weight on
risk sharing increasing with the Frisch elasticity. A higher elasticity
increases the welfare costs of shocks to wealth distribution by
distorting the labor supply decisions of different households, as well
as making it easier for monetary policy to influence the real value of
debt by changing the ex-ante real interest rate in addition to
inflation. An elastic labor supply does mean that inflation fluctuations
lead to output gap fluctuations, which increases the importance of
targeting inflation, but the first two effects turn out to be more
important quantitatively.
The results are somewhat more sensitive to the average duration of
a price spell and the elasticity of real marginal cost with respect to
output. The first of these determines the importance of nominal price
rigidities. Greater nominal rigidity leads to more dispersion of
relative prices from a given amount of inflation, and thus reduces the
optimal policy weight on the debt gap. A higher output elasticity of
marginal cost implies that the production function has greater
curvature, so a given dispersion of output levels across otherwise
identical firms represents a more inefficient allocation of resources.
However, considering the range of reasonable values for the duration of
price stickiness does not reduce [chi] below 65 percent, and the range
of marginal cost elasticities does not lead to any [chi] value below 80
percent.
The effects of the calibration target for the average duration of
household debt are more subtle. It might be expected that the longer the
maturity of household debt, the higher the optimal policy weight on risk
sharing. This is because longer-term debt allows inflation to be spread
out further over time, reducing the welfare costs of the inflation, yet
still having an effect on the real value of debt. However, the
sensitivity analysis shows that the optimal policy weight is a
non-monotonic function of debt maturity: either very short-term or
long-term debt maturities lead to high values of [chi], while debt of
around 1.5 years maturity has the lowest value of [chi] (approximately
75 percent).
This apparent puzzle is resolved by recalling that there are two
ways monetary policy can affect risk sharing: inflation to change the
ex-post real return on nominal debt, and changes in the ex-ante real
interest rate ("financial repression"). As has been discussed,
the first method is effective at a lower cost for long debt maturities.
When labor supply is inelastic, the second method is not available, and
the value of [chi] is then indeed a strictly increasing function of debt
maturity (with the value of [chi] falling to 15 percent for the
shortest-maturity debt). When the ex-ante real interest rate method is
available, it is most effective compared to the first method (taking
account of the costs in terms of inflation and output gap fluctuations)
when debt maturities are short.
Finally, it is possible to calculate the magnitude of the losses
from following a policy of strict inflation targeting rather than the
optimal policy described above. With strict inflation targeting,
equation 55 shows that the innovation to the debt gap is given by the
negative of the shock [p.sub.t], with the effect on the debt gap in
subsequent periods being -[lambda] [p.sub.t], -[[DELTA].sup.2]
[p.sub.t], and so on. The welfare loss (as an equivalent percentage of
GDP) from strict inflation targeting according to the loss function
(equation 56) is therefore equal to [p.sup.2.sub.t] multiplied by the
coefficient of [[??].sup.2.sub.t] in equation 56 divided by (1 -
[beta][[lambda].sup.2]).
Using the baseline calibration, a 1-percent shock to the debt gap
results in a total loss equivalent to 0.023 percent of one year's
GDP, a 5-percent shock results in a 0.58-percent GDP loss, and a
10-percent shock results in a 2.3-percent loss. These losses are not
inconsiderable for large shocks, but are negligible for small shocks.
With a higher relative risk aversion of 10, the losses from the
1-percent, 5-percent, and 10-percent shocks would be 0.078 percent, 2.0
percent, and 7.8 percent of GDP, respectively. The expected loss per
year is obtained by averaging these over the probability distribution of
[p.sub.t], shocks occurring during a year, which can be derived from the
stochastic process for
real GDP using equation 55. Even though losses from large shocks are
significant, fortunately the U.S. economy only rarely experiences shocks
of the order of magnitude seen during the financial crisis. Using the
2.1-percent standard deviation of annual real GDP growth over the period
1972-2011 suggests that the average annual loss from strict inflation
targeting would lie in the range 0.1-0.3 percent of GDP.
If the average welfare loss from the lack of risk sharing under
strict inflation targeting is so small, how is it possible that concerns
over risk sharing receive such a high weight relative to inflation
stabilization in the optimal monetary policy? The small expected loss
might suggest that there should be little willingness to pay to obtain
insurance. However, note that the optimal policy only deviates
significantly from inflation targeting when large shocks occur (figure 1
is drawn for a 10-percent shock to potential output). The inflation
fluctuations called for in a typical year are around five times smaller
than those shown in figure 1 and would likely involve (annualized)
inflation being not much more than 0.4 percent from its average, for
which the welfare losses are vanishingly small.
This means it is possible to put a high weight on replicating
complete financial markets even when the expected gains from risk
sharing are small because, unlike an insurance premium, a non-negligible
cost of inflation fluctuations is incurred only when large shocks occur,
which is also when the gains from risk sharing are large. Combined with
inflation smoothing to keep down the welfare losses from relative-price
distortions when nominal debt has a long average maturity, this means
the benefits of greater risk sharing from a long-term nominal GDP target
can outweigh the costs even without assuming double-digit coefficients
of relative risk aversion.
V. Conclusion
This paper has shown how a monetary policy of nominal GDP targeting
facilitates efficient risk sharing in incomplete financial markets where
contracts are denominated in terms of money. In an environment where
risk derives from uncertainty about future real GDP, strict inflation
targeting would lead to a very uneven distribution of risk, with
leveraged borrowers' consumption highly exposed to any unexpected
change in their incomes when monetary policy prevented any adjustment of
the real value of their liabilities. Strict inflation targeting does
provide savers with a risk-free real return, but fundamentally, the
economy lacks any technology that delivers risk-free real returns, so
the safety of savers' portfolios is simply the flip side of
borrowers' leverage and high levels of risk. Absent any changes in
the physical investment technology available to the economy, aggregate
risk cannot be annihilated, only redistributed.
That leaves the question of whether the distribution of risk is
efficient. The combination of incomplete markets and strict inflation
targeting implies a particularly inefficient distribution of risk when
households are risk averse. If complete financial markets were
available, borrowers would issue state-contingent debt where the
contractual repayment was lower in a recession and higher in a boom.
These securities would resemble equity shares in GDP, and they would
have the effect of reducing the leverage of borrowers and hence
distributing risk more evenly. In the absence of such financial markets,
in particular because of the inability of households to sell such
securities, a monetary policy of nominal GDP targeting could effectively
replicate complete financial markets even when only noncontingent
nominal debt was available. Nominal GDP targeting operates by
stabilizing the debt-to-GDP ratio. With financial contracts specifying
liabilities fixed in terms of money, a policy that stabilizes the
monetary value of real incomes ensures that borrowers are not forced to
bear too much aggregate risk, converting nominal debt into real equity.
While the model is far too simple to apply to the recent financial
crises and deep recessions experienced by a number of economies, one
policy implication does resonate with the predicament of several
economies faced with high levels of debt combined with stagnant or
falling GDPs. Nominal GDP targeting is equivalent to a countercyclical
price level, so the model suggests that higher inflation can be optimal
in recessions. In other words, while each component of the word
"stagflation"--"stagnation" and
"inflation"--is bad in itself, if stagnation cannot
immediately be remedied, some inflation might be a good idea to
compensate for the inefficiency of incomplete financial markets. And
even if policymakers were reluctant to abandon inflation targeting, the
model does suggest that they would have the strongest incentives to
avoid deflation during recessions (a procyclical price level). Deflation
would raise the real value of debt, which combined with falling real
incomes would be the very opposite of the risk sharing stressed in this
paper, and even worse than an unchanging inflation rate.
It is important to stress that the policy implications of the model
in recessions are matched by equal and opposite prescriptions during an
expansion. Thus, it is not just that optimal monetary policy tolerates
higher inflation in a recession--it also requires lower inflation or
even deflation during a period of high growth. Pursuing higher inflation
in recessions without following a symmetrical policy during an expansion
is both inefficient and jeopardizes an environment of low inflation on
average. Therefore, the model also argues that more should be done by
central banks to "take away the punch bowl" during a boom,
even were inflation to be stable.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am grateful to Carlos Carvalho, Wouter den Haan,
Monique Ebell, Cosmin Ilut, John Knowles, Greg Mankiw, Albert Marcet,
Matthias Paustian, George Selgin, the editors, and my discussants for
helpful suggestions and comments. The paper has also benefited from the
comments of Brookings Panel participants and seminar participants at
Banque de France, University of Cambridge, CERGE-EI, Ecole
Polytechnique, University of Lausanne, University of Maryland, National
Bank of Serbia, National University of Singapore, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, University of Oxford, PUC-Rio, Sao Paulo School of
Economics, University of Southampton, University of St. Andrews,
University of Warwick, the Anglo-French-Italian Macroeconomics Workshop,
Birmingham Econometrics and Macroeconomics Conference, Centre for
Economic Performance Annual Conference, Econometric Society North
American Summer Meeting, EEA Annual Congress, ESSET, ESSIM, Joint French
Macro workshop, LACEA, LBS-CEPR conference "Developments in
Macroeconomics and Finance," London Macroeconomics Workshop,
Midwest Macro Meeting, and NBER Summer Institute in Monetary Economics.
I have no relevant material or financial interests to declare regarding
the content of this paper.
References
Abel, Andrew B. 1990. "Asset Prices under Habit Formation and
Catching Up with the Joneses." American Economic Review 80, no. 2:
38-42 (May).
Allen, Franklin, Elena Carletti, and Douglas Gale. 2011.
"Money, Financial Stability and Efficiency." Working Paper.
New York University.
Andres, Javier, Oscar Arce, and Carlos Thomas. 2010. "Banking
Competition, Collateral Constraints and Optimal Monetary Policy."
Working Paper no. 1001, Bank of Spain.
Attanasio, Orazio, and Steven J. Davis. 1996. "Relative Wage
Movements and the Distribution of Consumption." Journal of
Political Economy 104, no. 6: 1227-62 (December).
Bach, G.L., and James B. Stephenson. 1974. "Inflation and the
Redistribution of Wealth." Review of Economics and Statistics 56,
no. 1: 1-13 (February).
Bailey, Samuel. 1837. Money and Its Vicissitudes in Value. London:
Effingham Wilson.
Barro, Robert J. 1979. "On the Determination of the Public
Debt." Journal of Political Economy 87, no. 5: 940-971 (October).
Barsky, Robert B., F. Thomas Juster, Miles S. Kimball, and Matthew
D. Shapiro. 1997. "Preference Parameters and Behavioral
Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement
Study." Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, no. 2: 537-79 (May).
Bean, Charles R. 1983. "Targeting Nominal Income: An
Appraisal." Economic Journal 93: 806-19 (December).
Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S.
Posen. 1999. Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International
Experience. Princeton University Press.
Blundell, Richard, Panos Pashardes, and Guglielmo Weber. 1993.
"What Do We Learn about Consumer Demand Patterns from Micro
Data?" American Economic Review 83, no. 3: 570-97 (June).
Bohn, Henning. 1988. "Why Do We Have Nominal Government
Debt?" Journal of Monetary Economics 21, no. 1: 127-40 (January).
Calvo, Guillermo A. 1983. "Staggered Prices in a
Utility-Maximizing Framework." Journal of Monetary Economics 12,
no. 3: 383-98 (September).
Chari, V. V., Lawrence J. Christiano, and Patick J. Kehoe. 1991.
"Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Some Recent Results."
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 23, no. 3(2): 519-39 (August).
Chari, V. V., and Patick J. Kehoe. 1999. "Optimal Fiscal and
Monetary Policy." In Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 1C,
edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford. Elsevier.
Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gall, and Mark Gertler. 1999. "The
Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective." Journal
of Economic Literature 37, no. 4: 1661-1707 (December).
Cochrane, John H. 1991. "A Simple Test of Consumption
Insurance." Journal of Political Economy 99, no. 5: 957-76
(October).
Cohen, Alma, and Liran Einav. 2007. "Estimating Risk
Preferences from Deductible Choice." American Economic Review 97,
no. 3: 745-88 (June).
Cooley, Thomas F., and Lee E. Ohanian. 1991. "The Cyclical
Behavior of Prices." Journal of Monetary Economics 28, no. 1: 25-60
(August).
Cukierman, Alex, Ken Lennan. and F. Papadia. 1985.
"Inflation-Induced Redistributions via Monetary Assets in Five
European Countries: 1974-1982." In Economic Policy and National
Accounting in Inflationary Conditions, edited by J. Mortensen (Volume 2
of Studies in Banking and Finance). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Curdia, Vasco, and Michael Woodford. 2009. "Credit Frictions
and Optimal Monetary Policy." Working Paper. Columbia University.
De Fiore, Fiorella, Pedro Teles, and Oreste Tristani. 2011.
"Monetary Policy and the Financing of Firms." American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3, no. 4: 112-42 (October).
Doepke, Matthias, and Martin Schneider. 2006. "Inflation and
the Redistribution of Nominal Wealth." Journal of Political Economy
114, no. 6: 1069-97 (December).
Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Paul Krugman. 2012. "Debt,
Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo
Approach." Quarterly Journal of Economics 127, no. 3: 1469-1513.
Garriga, Carlos, Finn E. Kydland, and Roman Sustek. 2013.
"Mortgages and Monetary Policy." Discussion paper 2013-6.
London: Centre for Macroeconomics.
Ghent, Andra C. 2011. "Securitization and Mortgage
Renegotiation: Evidence from the Great Depression." Review of
Financial Studies 24, no. 6: 1814-47.
Guerrieri, Veronica, and Guido Lorenzoni. 2011. "Credit
Crises, Precautionary Saving, and the Liquidity Trap." Working
Paper no. 17583. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Hall, Robert E. 2009. "Reconciling Cyclical Movements in the
Marginal Value of Time and the Marginal Product of Labor." Journal
of Political Economy 117, no. 2: 281-323 (April).
Hall, Robert E., and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1994. "Nominal Income
Targeting." In Monetary Policy, edited by N.G. Mankiw. University
of Chicago Press.
Hayashi, Fumio, Joseph Altonji, and Laurence Kotlikoff. 1996.
"Risk-Sharing between and within Families." Econometrica 64,
no. 2: 261-94 (March).
Iacoviello, Matteo. 2005. "House Prices, Borrowing
Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle." American
Economic Review 95, no. 3: 739-64 (June).
Juster, F. Thomas, Joseph P. Lupton, James P. Smith, and Frank
Stafford. (2006), "The Decline in Household Saving and the Wealth
Effect." Review of Economics and Statistics 88, no. 1: 20-27
(February).
King, Robert G., and Sergio T. Rebelo. 1999. "Resuscitating
Real Business Cycles." In Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. IB,
edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford. Elsevier.
Koenig, Evan F. 2013. "Like a Good Neighbor: Monetary Policy,
Financial Stability, and the Distribution of Risk." International
Journal of Central Banking 9, no. 2: 57-82 (June).
Lee, Jae Won. 2010. "Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous
Households and Imperfect Risk-Sharing." Working Paper. New
Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University.
Lustig, Hanno, Christopher Sleet, and Sevin Yeltekin. 2008.
"Fiscal Hedging with Nominal Assets." Journal of Monetary
Economics 55, no. 4: 710-27 (May).
Meade, James E. 1978. "The Meaning of 'Internal
Balance.'" Economic Journal 88: 423-35 (September).
Nakamura, Emi, and Jon Steinsson. 2008. "Five Facts about
Prices: A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 123, no. 4: 1415-64 (November).
Nelson, Julie A. 1994. "On Testing for Full Insurance Using
Consumer Expenditure Survey Data." Journal of Political Economy
102, no. 2: 384-94 (April).
Nevo, Aviv. 2001. "Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat
Cereal Industry." Econometrica 69, no. 2: 307-42 (March).
Parker. Jonathan A. 1999. "Spendthrift in America? On Two
Decades of Decline in the U.S. Saving Rate." NBER Macroeconomics
Annual 14: 317-70.
Persson, Torsten, and Lars E.O. Svensson. 1989. "Exchange Rate
Variability and Asset Trade." Journal of Monetary Economics 23, no.
3: 485-509 (May).
Pescatori, Andrea. 2007. "Incomplete Markets and
Households' Exposure to Interest Rate and Inflation Risk:
Implications for the Monetary Policy Maker." Working Paper 07-09,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Piskorski, Tomasz, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig. 2010.
"Securitization and Distressed Loan Renegotiation: Evidence from
the Subprime Mortgage Crisis." Journal of Financial Economics 97,
no. 3: 369-97 (September).
Poterba, James M. 2000. "Stock Market Wealth and
Consumption." Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 2: 99-118
(Spring).
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1997. "An
Optimization-Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary
Policy." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12: 297-346.
Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe. 2004. "Optimal
Fiscal and Monetary Policy under Sticky Prices." Journal of
Economic Theory 114, no. 2: 198-230 (February).
Selgin, George. 1995. "The "Productivity Norm"
versus Zero Inflation in the History of Economic Thought." History
of Political Economy 27, no. 4: 705-35 (Winter).
--. 1997. "Less than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level
in a Growing Economy." Hobart Paper no. 132, Institute of Economic
Affairs.
Sheedy, Kevin. 2014. "Debt and Incomplete Financial Markets: A
Case for Nominal GDP Targeting." CEPR Discussion Paper no. DP9843
(available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2444864).
Shiller, Robert J. 1993. "Macro Markets: Creating Institutions
for Managing Society's Largest Economic Risks." Oxford
University Press.
--. 1997. "Public Resistance to Indexation: A Puzzle."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1: 159-228.
Siu, Henry E. 2004. "Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy with
Sticky Prices." Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 3: 575-607
(April).
Sumner, Scott. 2012. "The Case for Nominal GDP
Targeting." Working Paper. Fairfax, Va.: Mercatus Center, George
Mason University.
Uzawa, Hitofumi. 1968. "Time Preference, the Consumption
Function, and Optimum Asset Holdings." In Value, Capital and
Growth: Papers in Honor of Sir John Hicks, edited by J.N. Wolfe.
Chicago: Aldine.
Vlieghe, Gertjan W. 2010. "Imperfect Credit Markets:
Implications for Monetary Policy." Working Paper no. 385, Bank of
England.
White, Michelle J. 2009. "Bankruptcy: Past Puzzles, Recent
Reforms, and the Mortgage Crisis." American Law and Economics
Review 11, no. 1: 1-23.
Woodford, Michael. 2001. "Fiscal Requirements for Price
Stability." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33, no. 3: 669-728
(August).
--. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary
Policy. Princeton University Press.
Comments and Discussion
COMMENT BY
JAMES BULLARD (1)
Modern rationales for monetary stabilization policy rely mainly on
the sticky price friction. Sticky prices are thought to prevent the
market solution from being fully optimal and therefore suggest a role
for monetary policy intervention. Generally speaking, leading renditions
of this idea lead to the monetary policy advice that prices should be
stabilized along a price level path. In this fascinating paper, Kevin
Sheedy studies an alternative rationale for monetary stabilization
policy. In the alternative, the friction is nonstate contingent nominal
contracting (NSCNC), and it is this defect of credit markets that keeps
the market solution from being fully optimal. The monetary policy advice
associated with this rationale is somewhat different from that
associated with sticky prices. Rather than keeping prices stable along a
price level path, the advice calls for deliberate movements in the price
level in order to offset shocks to the growth rate of national
income--countercyclical price level movements.
Sheedy has laid out considerable intuition for the alternative
rationale. I would go so far as to say that he has set the standard for
future analyses in this area. The paper includes valuable commentary on
an extensive related literature, and it includes a calibrated model with
both sticky price and NSCNC frictions included. In the calibrated case,
the more important of the two frictions is associated with nonstate
contingent nominal contracting.
Is it surprising that the NSCNC friction can be more important from
a policymaking perspective than the sticky price friction? Perhaps not.
According to Atif Mian and Amir Sufi (2011), the ratio of household debt
to GDP in the United States was about 1.15 before debt rose in the
2000s, when it ballooned to 1.65 or more. In today's dollars, the
latter ratio would mean about $19.5 to $28 trillion in debt, comprising
mostly mortgage debt. Improper functioning in these markets might be
quite costly for the economy, so it is certainly plausible that the
nonstate contingent nominal contracting friction could be quite
important.
My discussion is organized around three questions. First, given
that some may view the model here as somewhat special, would these
results hold in a model with many more heterogeneous participants
interacting in a large private credit market? Based on a general
equilibrium life cycle model with many period lives, the tentative
answer seems to be yes, so that Sheedy's results may have more
general applicability than it might first appear. The second question
is: What are some of the key issues on which future research in this
area may wish to focus? And finally, what does this paper have to say in
framing the ongoing global monetary policy debate on the wisdom of
nominal GDP targeting?
IS THE MODEL SPECIAL? The Sheedy model has two types of households:
relatively patient and relatively impatient. Since there are just two
types of agents interacting in a credit market, there is only one set of
marginal conditions that requires "repair." The policymaker
has just one tool, the price level, which in certain circumstances
neatly fixes the marginal conditions. A natural question is whether
these results would carry over to a more realistic environment with more
heterogeneity in the private credit market. My tentative answer is that
the results do carry over to a somewhat different class of models with a
greater degree of heterogeneity, and therefore that the Sheedy results
have greater applicability than may be initially apparent.
One way to investigate this is to consider a stripped-down,
endowment general equilibrium life-cycle economy. (2) In order to stress
that business cycle questions can be addressed with such a model, I will
use a "quarterly" specification, with households living 241
periods. One interpretation would be that households enter economic life
around age 20, die around age 80, and are most productive in the middle
period, around age 50. (3) To this standard framework we can add the key
assumption made by Sheedy, namely that loans are dispersed and repaid in
the unit of account--that is, in nominal terms--and are not contingent
on income realizations. This is the NSCNC friction. Agents in the
economy I am describing are endowed with an identical productivity
profile over their lifetime. This productivity profile begins at zero,
rises to a peak at the middle period of life, and then declines to zero,
exhibiting perfect symmetry. Agents can sell the productivity units they
have in the labor market at a competitive wage.
Such a model, which is very standard in textbooks, produces very
uneven income over the life cycle. People near the beginning or end of
the life cycle earn little or no labor income, while those in the middle
of life earn a lot. If the productivity profile were exactly triangular,
then 50 percent of the households would earn 75 percent of the income.
All of these cohorts will wish to use the credit market to smooth
consumption relative to income.
A second key assumption in the Sheedy paper is that there is an
aggregate shock, and that this shock is the only source of uncertainty.
(4) Let us think of this as a Markov process for the aggregate gross
rate of real wage growth, which can take on values of high, medium, or
low with equal probability and where the medium value is the average of
the three possibilities. Real national income is then the real wage
multiplied by the sum of the productivity endowments. Therefore, the
growth rate of real wages is also the growth rate of real output. The
policymaker completely controls the price level, which is just a unit of
account in this model. (5) An important within-period timing protocol is
embedded: (i) nature chooses the growth rate, (ii) the policymaker
chooses a price level, and (iii) households make decisions to consume
and save. This timing protocol is what allows the policymaker to
potentially offset incoming shocks.
The model I have described is simple, but it is interesting in
light of what Sheedy teaches us about the effects of the NSCNC friction.
The version I have described has 241 households, all credit market
users, each with a different level of asset holding depending on their
position in the life cycle. To calculate the full stochastic
equilibrium, one has to keep track of the distribution of asset holdings
over time, a fact that has made models in this class less intensively
studied than their representative agent cousins. Yet Sheedy's key
insights apply to this model as well, even though there are now many
more agents and the policymaker still only has one tool, the price
level.
Consider a nonstochastic balanced-growth path of the model I have
described, in which the economy simply grows at the average rate
forever. Assume also that the policymaker "gets out of the
way" and simply sets the price level to unity every period. On this
balanced growth path, consumption is exactly equalized across the
cohorts living at a point in time. The real interest rate is exactly
equal to the real output growth rate. (6) The private credit market
completely solves the point-in-time income inequality problem. Sheedy
provides some excellent intuition for results like this, which fuel the
findings later: The exact consumption equality across cohorts living at
a given date means all households have an "equity share" in
the economy. That is, despite their very uneven incomes at a point in
time, they all consume an equal fraction of national income available at
that date. Equity share contracts are known to be optimal when
preferences are homothetic, as they are in the economy I have described.
In the stochastic case, the main idea is to replicate this equity share
outcome.
COUNTERCYCLICAL PRICE LEVEL MOVEMENTS. In the stochastic case, the
NSCNC friction means that markets are incomplete. Households are not
allowed to contract based on actual realized returns. There is no
default or renegotiation--loans must be repaid. However, because of the
timing protocol, the policymaker can potentially provide
state-contingent movements in the price level after observing the shock
each period, and therefore restore the complete credit markets outcome.
The nature of this policy involves countercyclical price-level
movements. A period associated with a high real growth shock is also a
period with a lower-than-normal price level, and conversely, low growth
is associated with a higher-than-normal price level. This policy
restores complete markets because, in the economy I have described, each
cohort living at date t would consume the same amount, and this amount
would be higher or lower according to whether the growth rate was
particularly high or low at that date. In this sense, Sheedy's
results may have important applications in a wide class of life-cycle
economies, probably the most important class of heterogeneous agent
economies in macroeconomics.
The countercyclical price-level policy seems very different from
one focused on not allowing the price level to deviate far from a
price-level path. We might think of the price-level targeting policy
here as maintaining P (t) equal to unity at all times. (7) As Sheedy
stresses in the paper, such a policy would be inappropriate given the
NSCNC friction.
DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH. The Sheedy model has little to say
about average inflation rates. This is important, since nominal GDP
targeting is sometimes casually discussed in a way that suggests a
rationalization for higher average inflation. The Sheedy model calls for
higher-than-average inflation at certain points in time, notably in bad
times, but also calls for lower-than-average inflation in good times,
leaving the average rate of inflation unchanged in the long run.
It is sometimes asserted in discussions of nominal GDP targeting
that one can simply target nominal GDP and not worry about the
decomposition between real output and the price level. I do not see much
support for this view in the logic behind the Sheedy analysis. (8) The
typical statement might be that the policymaker could target a nominal
GDP aggregate gross growth rate, perhaps without knowing the exact value
of the average real growth rate of the economy. This indeed succeeds in
obtaining the counter-cyclical price-level movements necessary under the
NSCNC friction to complete the credit market. But it does not succeed in
maintaining the average rate of inflation at a desirable level for the
economy. In particular, such an approach would suggest that the balanced
growth path with a gross real growth rate of 1.02 and a gross inflation
rate of 1.02 was equally as desirable as the balanced growth path with
1.00 and 1.04, respectively. Yet this would only be true if there were
no welfare costs of inflation in the model.
The literature on the welfare cost of inflation is well established
and argues for lower average inflation as opposed to higher values, all
else equal. The Sheedy model does not provide any reason to choose the
higher average inflation value. It only provides a reason to generate
higher-than-average inflation in response to certain shocks and
lower-than-average inflation in response to other shocks. I conclude
from this that proper implementation of the Sheedy nominal GDP targeting
strategy would require knowledge of the average real growth rate for the
economy. One would have to know when real growth was "below
normal" or "above normal" in order to know when to
generate the required price-level movement to maintain complete credit
markets. If the policymaker did not know the average growth rate of the
economy and targeted only a nominal GDP growth rate, the policymaker
could end up with an average inflation rate considerably different from
the desired level. This could undo all the good done by the complete
credit markets policy.
I think further research on the trade-off between the benefits of
targeting a pure nominal quantity and the costs of inadvertently
generating higher-than-desirable inflation could be a fruitful area of
future research. I caution potential researchers, however: The
literature on the welfare costs of inflation tends to find that the
welfare losses from higher average inflation are much larger than the
welfare gains reported in Sheedy's paper from improved monetary
stabilization policy.
Many have argued that the NSCNC friction is not as compelling as it
may first appear. This is because we do observe default in actual
economies, and because of this there is a certain state-contingency in
actual contracting that is assumed away in models like Sheedy's.
Research along the lines of Sheedy's that could make better contact
with the issue of default could provide helpful insight. More subtly,
the mere threat of default can radically shape equilibrium outcomes,
even in models where no default occurs in equilibrium. For an example of
how endogenous debt constraints change one's view of potential
equilibria in a life cycle setting like the one described above, see
Costas Azariadis and Luisa Lambertini (2003). More research in this area
would be desirable as well, especially if it could shed more and sharper
light on the likely importance or unimportance of what seems to be
non-state-contingent contracting in actual economies.
Finally, Sheedy's model has no money demand, treating the role
of money only as a unit of account. What Sheedy is advocating is a
policy that focuses on completing the credit market and ignores
households that are holding money balances as a large fraction of their
wealth. The people who are in this latter situation may be hurt
economically by a monetary policy sharply focused on credit markets. In
the United States, some estimates suggest 10 to 15 percent of the
population is unbanked, and another 10 to 15 percent may be nearly
unbanked. These households tend to be poor and to use cash intensively,
and they may be shut out of credit markets. Research on models that
include this group may provide a better balance in assessing the best
role for monetary policy.
This paper has considerable potential to sharpen the ongoing debate
on nominal GDP targeting, an idea that has not often had an explicit
modem macroeconomic model behind it. Those interested in studying
nominal GDP targeting can proceed from the Sheedy model and study the
many additional issues that could arise if policymakers adopted the idea
of countercyclical price-level movements as optimal monetary policy.
Others can investigate the extent to which NSCNC may or may not be as
important a friction as it appears to be, perhaps because of the way
credit default is conceptualized and modeled. Both types of research
would likely improve our understanding of the NSCNC friction and
monetary policy's role in alleviating it.
REFERENCES FOR THE BULLARD COMMENT
Azariadis, Costas, and Luisa Lambertini. 2003. "Endogenous
Debt Constraints in Life Cycle Economies." Review of Economic
Studies 70, no. 3: 1-27.
Koenig, Evan. 2013. "Like a Good Neighbor: Monetary Policy,
Financial Stability, and the Distribution of Risk." International
Journal of Central Banking 9: 57-82.
Mian, Atif, and Amir Sufi. 2011. "House Prices, Home
Equity-Based Borrowing, and the U.S. Household Leverage Crisis."
American Economic Review 101, no. 5: 2132-56.
Sheedy, Kevin. 2013. "Debt and Incomplete Markets: A Case for
Nominal GDP Targeting." Discussion Paper no. 1209, Centre for
Economic Performance, May.
(1.) Any views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect
the views of others on the Federal Open Market Committee. I appreciate
the valuable comments I have received on these remarks from the editors.
(2.) See Sheedy (2013) for a three-period overlapping-generations
version of this paper.
(3.) I have in mind a model with a long list of simplifying
assumptions: identical within-cohort agents, no population growth;
inelastic labor supply; time-separable log preferences; no discounting;
no capital; no default; flexible prices; no borrowing constraints; and
no government other than the central bank.
(4.) In models like the one I am describing, it is also popular to
include idiosyncratic uncertainty, but that is not necessary for the
argument presented in the Sheedy paper.
(5.) For a two-period example along this line, see Koenig (2013).
(6.) This is due to the symmetric endowment pattern combined with
other simplifying assumptions.
(7.) Assuming a net inflation target of zero.
(8.) The total real output in the economy at a date t would be the
real wage multiplied by the sum of endowments, and the latter would
cancel in this expression.
COMMENT BY
IVAN WERNING (1)
This paper by Kevin Sheedy argues that risk sharing should be an
important goal in the conduct of monetary policy. It makes two distinct
contributions in this direction. First, it presents a tractable model in
which inflation affects risk sharing, applying this to derive
implications for monetary policy. Nominal GDP targeting is shown to
achieve optimal risk sharing in incomplete market settings with flexible
prices. Second, it pits the new risk sharing goal for monetary policy
against the traditional stabilization role. For a calibrated New
Keynesian economy featuring sticky prices, the paper finds that
significant weight should be placed on the risk sharing goal, affecting
the reaction to technology shocks.
These ideas are important, and the effort to push standard
representative-agent macroeconomic models to incorporate heterogeneous
agents is laudable and, here, accomplished very elegantly. The paper
helps create a bridge between the monetary policy literature, typically
divorced of risk-sharing considerations, with a literature focusing on
risk sharing that is typically divorced of monetary and nominal
considerations.
Sheedy definitely succeeds at making one think about risk sharing
and monetary policy in a more systematic way. As a discussant, I found
little to disagree with within the confines of the paper's setting.
However, I do believe that a few important elements are missing and that
they need to be incorporated to assess the appropriateness of risk
sharing as a goal for monetary policy.
I will begin by restating the main idea of risk sharing with
flexible prices in a simple static model. I then incorporate
heterogeneous risk exposures and idiosyncratic uncertainty, two features
that I believe are crucial to any discussion of risk sharing. These may
weaken the case for nominal GDP targeting in particular, although not
necessarily for inflation-induced risk sharing in general. Finally, I
briefly touch on elements that may affect the trade-off between risk
sharing and stabilization. I conclude that, rather than being competing
goals, risk sharing and stabilization may be complementary ones.
RISK SHARING AND NOMINAL GDP TARGETING. Let me reduce the argument
for inflation-induced risk sharing and nominal GDP targeting to its bare
essentials, within a static risk-sharing model.
Two agents, B (borrowers) and S (savers), have a common utility
function u(c). Income is distributed proportionally, with [y.sub.B] =
[[psi].sub.B]Y and [y.sub.s] = [[psi].sub.S]Y, assuming that
[[psi].sub.B] > [[psi].sub.S].
Let us assume, momentarily, that a conditional transfer T(Y) is
available. The planning problem is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[lambda].sub.B] and [[lambda].sub.S] are Pareto weights.
From now on I specialize to equal weights [[lambda].sub.B] =
[[lambda].sub.S] = 1, since nothing of interest is lost by doing so.
The expectation above is taken over aggregate income K However, the
maximization can be performed for each realization of aggregate income
Y,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The optimum equalizes consumption by setting
(1) T(Y) = [[psi].sub.B] - [[psi].sub.S] / 2 Y.
One can implement this optimal state-contingent transfer using
nominal debt, D, and a state-contingent price level, P(s), satisfying
T(Y) = D / P(Y),
or substituting using our solution (equation 1),
Y x P(Y) = 2 / [[psi].sub.B] - [[psi].sub.S] D,
a constant value for nominal spending. Optimal policy can be
characterized as targeting nominal GDP.
HETEROGENEOUS EXPOSURE TO AGGREGATE RISK. Following the paper, I
assumed above that individual income moves in proportion with aggregate
income--the elasticity of individual income with respect to aggregate
income is unity. Consider instead
[y.sub.B] = [[phi].sub.B] (Y),
[y.sub.S] = Y - [[phi].sub.B] (Y),
for some function [[phi].sub.B] (*). The elasticity of the
borrower's income to aggregate income may now depart from one. By
the same arguments I obtain
T(Y) = [[phi].sub.B] (Y) - [1/2] Y.
This shows that, in general, T(Y) is no longer proportional to
aggregate income Y. As long as T(Y) does not change signs, I can
implement the transfers by T(s) = D/P(s) for some P(s) > 0. Let us
assume this is the case. By implication, it is no longer the case that
nominal spending Y x P(Y) is constant. Instead,
([[phi].sub.B] (Y) - 1/2 Y) P(Y) = D.
For example, if the income of borrowers is more responsive to
aggregate income, so that the elasticity of [[phi].sub.B] (Y) is greater
than one, then the price level P(Y) should also have an elasticity
greater than one in absolute value. That is, the price level should be
more responsive than nominal GDP targeting.
IDIOSYNCRATIC UNCERTAINTY. The paper abstracts from idiosyncratic
income risk. This is unfortunate, because it is well appreciated that
the uncertainty households face trumps aggregate uncertainty.
To incorporate idiosyncratic uncertainty, let us assume
[y.sub.Bi] = [[epsilon].sub.Bi] and [y.sub.Si] =
[[epsilon].sub.Si]Y,
where [[epsilon].sub.Bi] and [[epsilon].sub.Si], are idiosyncratic
realizations for individual i within each respective group. The case
without idiosyncratic uncertainty is now a special case where Var
[[epsilon]] = 0. One important example of [epsilon] may be a
specification that captures unemployment risk, with [epsilon] = 0 when
the agent is unemployed.
The planning problem is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The first-order condition is
(2) [E.sub.[epsilon]] [u'([[epsilon].sub.B] Y - T(Y))|s] =
[E.sub.[epsilon]] [u'([[epsilon].sub.S]Y + T(Y))|Y],
which equalizes average marginal utility after each realization of
aggregate income Y. As before, as long as T(Y) does not change signs we
can implement the transfers by T(s) = D/P(s) for some P(s) > 0. Let
us assume this is the case.
I want to investigate whether
(3) T(s) = [tau]Y (s)
for some [tau]. For this purpose, it is helpful to assume a
homogeneous utility function u(c) = [c.sup.1-[sigma]]/(1 - [sigma]).
Substituting the guess (equation 3) into equation 2, one finds that
validating the guess requires
[E.sub.[epsilon]] [([[epsilon].sub.B] - [tau]).sup.-[sigma]] | Y] =
[E.sub.[epsilon]] [[([[epsilon].sub.S] + [tau]).sup.-[sigma]] | Y]
to hold for some fixed [tau] for all realizations of Y This is not
generally possible, except in the special case where [[epsilon].sub.B]
and [[epsilon].sub.S] are independent of Y. There is a large empirical
literature documenting the fact that idiosyncratic uncertainty varies
over the business cycle. When idiosyncratic shocks are not independent
of aggregate ones, the optimal policy for P(Y) will not target nominal
GDP.
IS INFLATION THE RIGHT TOOL? Idiosyncratic uncertainty also
highlights how imperfect inflation--or any tool that depends only on
aggregates and does not condition on idiosyncratic shocks--is for
risk-sharing purposes. Other policies, such as progressive taxes or
unemployment insurance benefits, do provide insurance against
idiosyncratic uncertainty.
Equally relevant, the paper assumes that borrowers take on debt
that is no-contingent and free of risk. However, as the recent crisis
reminds us, both secured and unsecured consumer credit is not risk-free,
and borrowers default on both forms of debt, providing a form of state
contingency that is tailored to idiosyncratic conditions.
Overall, for these reasons, inflation is a relatively coarse tool
for dealing with the uncertainty that households face. It may be argued,
however, that once other available instruments are exhausted, there
remains a residual role to be played by inflation. Knowing just how
significant that role should be is crucial if one is going to have
monetary policy deviate from its traditional role.
(1.) My views were enriched by exchanges with Adrien Auclert and
Matt Rognlie.
GENERAL DISCUSSION Robert Shimer asked an empirical question: how
tightly is the consumption decline during a recession linked to an
individual's debt load? He thought the individuals who experienced
the largest declines in consumption might have no debt load on account
of their nonparticipation in credit markets. Shimer thought that
smoothing out inflation would not be very effective at helping this
group of people. It seemed to him that in principle this was something
one could address using existing data.
He also agreed with discussant Ivan Werning that using inflation
alone in the model is not going to work. As he understood the model,
even the optimal rate of inflation was still not going to have better
than a second-order benefit. If it turned out that the modeling was far
off because of incomplete risk sharing, one could imagine achieving a
first-order benefit from inflation. But which way it goes is going to
depend on how consumption declines during recessions or is related to
debt holdings, and Shimer acknowledged that he did not know how that
works.
Johannes Wieland asked the author to clarify the trade-off between
inflation targeting and nominal GDP targeting. He wondered if it would
be better to target inflation volatility instead of GDP.
Gerald Cohen found the concept of a natural rate of debt to GDP to
be rather frightening. He said he had not been able to find a
theoretical justification for any particular ratio of debt to GDP. Ever
since 2008, people have been talking about the economy needing to be
deleveraged, but Cohen said that whenever he asked others what the
optimal ratio of debt to GDP would be, they could only wave their hands
or, in his view, invent a number. People once talked about a ratio of
130 percent, but looking in retrospect today most people think that
number is too high, and now a common figure is 90 percent. Cohen's
feeling was that if one is going to target an optimal ratio one ought to
have a good theory behind it.
Justin Wolfers wondered why financial incompleteness existed at
all. He speculated that when people obtained a mortgage they might often
wonder why it was that the real value of the payoffs would be allowed to
decline over the course of the mortgage. After all, one could simply
write a debt contract in real terms, and if half the mortgage industry
began to do that the rest would certainly follow suit.
Kevin Sheedy responded to the comments made during this brief
discussion. First, he pointed out that he used a 10 percent fall in
potential output in his paper--certainly a huge shock but a reasonable
size relative to people's expectations of the trends prior to the
financial crisis. And when he did, he found that such a shock led to
only a 2-percentage-point increase in inflation over a decade. Since a
shock of that magnitude is rare, Sheedy suggested that there would be
little impact on inflation volatility. In his view, then, during a
"great moderation" period there would not be any tension
between targeting nominal GDP and targeting inflation. So the policy of
nominal GDP targeting would be a good one when the economy needed it,
when it was hit with really big real shocks, and when the need was not
there one would not have to tolerate a lot of inflation volatility. This
is key to explaining why the weight on risk sharing is so high.
Additionally, Sheedy noted, with long-term debt contracts inflation
is smoothed out over time, so there is less relative price distortion
and less aggregate volatility. So although the benefits of the policy
may be small when one considers other factors, such as idiosyncratic
risk, the costs of achieving the policy would also be relatively small.
Lastly, he agreed with some discussants that financial market frictions
might be entirely removed at some point in the future, but he did not
believe that would occur soon. Given the prevalence of nominal debt
contracts, he believed the case for nominal GDP targeting was still
strong.
KEVIN D. SHEEDY
London School of Economics
(1.) In addition to the theoretical case, the more practical merits
of implementing inflation targeting are discussed by Bemanke and others
(1999).
(2.) Persson and Svensson (1989) is an early example of a model--in
the context of an international portfolio allocation problem--where it
is important how monetary policy affects the risk characteristics of
nominal debt.
(3.) There is also a literature that emphasizes the impact of
monetary policy on the financial positions of firms or entrepreneurs in
an economy with incomplete financial markets. De Fiore, Teles, and
Tristani (2011) study a flexible-price economy where there is a costly
state verification problem for entrepreneurs who issue short-term
nominal bonds. Andres, Arce, and Thomas (2010) consider entrepreneurs
facing a binding collateral constraint who issue short-term nominal
bonds with an endogenously determined interest rate spread. Vlieghe
(2010) also has entrepreneurs facing a collateral constraint, and even
though they issue real bonds, monetary policy still has real effects on
the wealth distribution because prices are sticky, so incomes are
endogenous.
(4.) This point is made by Lustig, Sleet, and Yeltekin (2008) in
the context of government debt.
(5.) Woodford (2001) uses this modeling device to study long-term
government debt. See Garriga, Kydland, and Sustek (2013) for a richer
model of mortgage contracts.
(6.) The wage-bill subsidy is a standard assumption which ensures
the economy's steady state is not distorted (Woodford 2003). A
balanced-budget rule is assumed to avoid any interactions between fiscal
policy and financial markets.
(7.) Online appendixes for this volume may be found at the
Brookings Papers website, www.brookings.edu/bpea, under "Past
Editions."
(8.) Note that the natural debt-to-GDP ratio is not independent of
monetary policy when monetary policy is able to affect real GDP growth.
(9.) The assumption (equation 43) on the Frisch elasticities of
borrowers and savers ensures that the level of output with flexible
prices is independent of the wealth distribution, and thus the
completeness of financial markets, up to a first-order approximation.
The general case is taken up in an earlier working paper (Sheedy 2014).
(10.) If the assumption in equation 43 is relaxed then the debt gap
[[??].sub.t] will appear in the Phillips curve. The consequences of this
are taken up in an earlier working paper (Sheedy 2014), but they are not
found to be quantitatively important.
(11.) This is because the model has the feature that the marginal
propensities to consume from financial wealth are the same for borrowers
and savers up to a first-order approximation.
(12.) With both short-term and long-term bonds satisfying the
expectations theory of interest rates [j.sub.t] = (1 -
[beta][mu])[[SIGMA].sup.[infinity].sub.l=0]
[([beta][mu]).sup.l][E.sub.t][i.sub.t+l] where [i.sub.t] is the
short-term interest rate, then the usual ex-ante Fisher equation
[i.sub.t] = [[rho].sub.t] + [SIGMA] + [E.sub.t],[[pi].sub.t+1] would
hold.
(13.) Time consistency issues and the discretionary policy
equilibrium are studied in an earlier working paper (Sheedy 2014).
(14.) All the data referred to below were obtained from Federal
Reserve Economic Data (http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2).
Table 1. Baseline Calibration: Targets and Parameter Values
Calibration targets (a)
Real GDP growth g 1.7%
Real interest rate r 5%
Debt-to-GDP ratio D 130%
Coefficient of relative risk
aversion
Marginal propensity to consume m 6%
Frisch elasticity of labor
supply
Average duration of debt [T.sub.m] 5
Price elasticity of demand
Marginal cost elasticity w.r.t.
output
Average duration of price [T.sub.p] 8/12
stickiness
Implied parameter values (b)
Discount factor [beta] 0.992
Debt service ratio [theta] 8.6%
[alpha] 5
Discount factor elasticity [lambda] 0.993
[eta] 2
Debt maturity parameter [mu] 0.967
[epsilon] 3
[xi] 0.5
Calvo pricing parameter [sigma] 0.625
Sources: See discussion in section IV.A.
(a.) The calibration targets are specified in annual time units;
the parameter values assume a quarterly model (T = 1/4).
(b.) The parameters are derived from the calibration targets
using equations 66-70.