Efficient credit policies in a housing debt crisis.
Eberly, Janice ; Krishnamurthy, Arvind
ABSTRACT Consumption, income, and home prices fell simultaneously
during the financial crisis, compounding recessionary conditions with
liquidity constraints and mortgage distress. We develop a framework to
guide government policy in response to crises in cases when government
may intervene to support distressed mortgages. Our results emphasize
three aspects of efficient mortgage modifications. First, when
households are constrained in their borrowing, government resources
should support household liquidity up-front. This implies modifying
loans to reduce payments during the crisis rather than reducing payments
over the life of the mortgage contract, such as via debt reduction.
Second, while governments will not find it efficient to directly write
down the debt of borrowers, in many cases it will be in the best
interest of lenders to do so, because reducing debt is an effective way
to reduce strategic default. Moreover, the lenders who bear the credit
default risk have a direct incentive to partially write down debt and
avoid a full loan loss due to default. Finally, a well-designed mortgage
contract should take these considerations into account, reducing
payments during recessions and reducing debt when home prices fall. We
propose an automatic stabilizer mortgage contract which does both by
converting mortgages into lower-rate adjustable-rate mortgages when
interest rates fall during a downturn--reducing payments and lowering
the present value of borrowers' debt.
**********
During the financial crisis and in its aftermath, those segments of
the economy most exposed to the accumulation of mortgage debt have
tended to fare the worst. Whether one measures the impact by industry
(construction), by geography (sand states), or by household (the most
indebted), the presence of greater mortgage debt has led to weaker
economic outcomes (see, for example, Mian and Sufi 2009 and Dynan 2012).
Moreover, research suggests that financial crises may be more severe or
may be associated with slower recoveries when accompanied by a housing
collapse (Reinhart and Rogoff 2009; Howard, Martin, and Wilson 2011; and
International Monetary Fund 2012).
These observations lead to an apparently natural macroeconomic
policy prescription: restoring stronger economic growth requires
reducing accumulated mortgage debt. In this paper, we consider this
proposal in an environment where debt is indeed potentially damaging to
the macroeconomy and where the government and private sector have a
range of possible policy interventions. We show that while debt
reduction can support economic recovery, other interventions can be more
efficient. We also show that whether debt reduction is financed by the
government or by lenders matters for both its efficacy and its
desirability. Hence, while the intuitive appeal of debt reduction is
clear, its policy efficiency is not always clear, and the argument is
more nuanced than the simple intuition.
Our results emphasize three aspects of efficient mortgage
modifications. First, when households are borrowing-constrained,
government support should provide liquidity up-front. This implies loan
modifications that reduce payments during the crisis, rather than using
government resources for debt reduction that reduces payments over the
life of the mortgage contract. The reasoning behind this result is
simple and robust. Consider choosing among a class of government support
programs, all of which transfer resources to a borrower, but which may
vary in the timing of transfers. Suppose the objective of the program is
to increase the current consumption of the borrower. For a
permanent-income household, only the present discounted value of the
government transfers matters for current consumption. But for a
liquidity-constrained household, for any given present discounted value
of transfers, programs that front-load transfers increase consumption by
strictly more. Thus, up-front payment reduction is a more efficient use
of government resources than debt reduction.
Second, while governments will not find it efficient to directly
write down borrower debt, in many cases it will be in the best interest
of lenders to do so. Reducing debt is effective in reducing strategic
default. Lenders, who bear the credit default risk, have a direct
incentive to partially write down debt and avoid greater loan losses due
to default. In cases where there are externalities from default that
will not be internalized by the lender, government policy can be
effective in providing incentives or systematic structures to lenders to
write down debt. Finally, a well-designed mortgage contract should take
these considerations into account ex ante, reducing payments during
recessions and reducing debt when home prices fall. We propose an
automatic stabilizer mortgage contract which does both by converting
mortgages into lower-rate adjustable-rate mortgages when interest rates
fall during a downturn--reducing payments and lowering the value of
borrowers' debt.
We begin with a simple environment with homeowners, lenders, and a
government. We start from the simplest case, namely one with perfect
information where all households are liquidity constrained. We then
layer on default, private information, heterogeneous default costs,
endogenous provision of private mortgage modifications by lenders, and
an equilibrium home price response.
Initially, homeowners may consider defaulting on their mortgages
because they are liquidity constrained (that is, cash-flow constrained)
or because their mortgages exceed the value of their homes (strategic
default), or because both considerations may be present. The government
has finite resources and maximizes utility in the planner's
problem. We initially consider a two-period model with exogenous home
prices and then allow for general equilibrium feedback. We ask,
"What type of intervention is most effective, taking into account
the government budget constraint and the program's effectiveness at
supporting the economy?" We consider a general class of
interventions that includes mortgage modifications, such as interest
rate reductions, payment deferral, and term extensions, as well as
mortgage refinancing and debt write-downs. We extend the model to
include default with known, uncertain, and unobserved default costs,
with dynamic default timing, and with lender renegotiation.
The model is abstract and simple by design, allowing us to focus on
the minimum features necessary to highlight these mechanisms in the
housing market. It omits many interesting and potentially relevant
features of the housing market and of the economy more generally. For
example, we generate a "crisis period" exogenously by
specifying lower income in one period to disrupt consumption smoothing
by households. We could, in principle, embed our housing model in a
general equilibrium framework that would derive lower income and
generate the scope for housing policy endogenously, as in the studies
done by Gauti Eggertson and Paul Krugman (2010), Robert Hall (2010),
Veronica Guerrieri and Guido Lorenzoni (2011), Emmanuel Farhi and Ivan
Weming (2013), and others. For example, in the work by Eggertson and
Krugman, the nominal values of debt and sticky prices, along with the
liquidity-constrained households that we include, cause output to be
determined by demand; hence there is scope for policy to improve
macroeconomic outcomes when the debt constraint binds and the nominal
interest rate is zero. Including our model in such a structure would
also allow us to examine how housing policy feeds back into the
macroeconomy from the housing market. While this would be an interesting
route to pursue, our focus is on distinguishing between various types of
housing market interventions, so the additional impact that may come
from the macroeconomic feedback is left for further work.
Here the crisis period is defined by low income, which constrains
consumption due to liquidity constraints. The household cannot borrow
against future income nor against housing equity in order to smooth
through the crisis. The government has a range of possible policy
interventions and a limited budget; we focus on policies related to
housing modifications, given the severity of the constraints and
defaults experienced there. For simplicity, we begin with a case without
default. The main result that comes from analyzing this case is that the
need for consumption smoothing favors transfers to liquidity-constrained
households during the crisis period. Optimally, such transfers will take
the form of a payment deferral, granting resources to the borrower in a
crisis period in return for repayment from the borrower in a noncrisis
period. We then add the potential for default and show that optimal
policies that concentrate transfers early in the crisis but require
repayment later may lead to defaults.
These results suggest that payment deferral policies alone (which
grant short-term reductions in home payments but are repaid with higher
loan balances later), may generate payments that rise too quickly and
generate defaults, suggesting that payment forgiveness to replace or
augment payment deferrals may be optimal. That is, government resources
should first be spent on payment forgiveness. Once the resource
allocation is exhausted, further modifications should take the form of
payment deferral. We also show that "debt overhang" concerns,
that is, the possibility that debt inhibits access to private credit and
reduces consumption, do not change our results. Even if loan
modifications such as principal reduction reduce debt overhang,
liquidity constraints can be directly and more efficiently addressed by
front-loaded policy interventions, rather than through a reduction in
contracted debt.
We study the borrower's incentive to "strategically"
default in the crisis period. We find that in many cases borrowers will
choose to service an underwater mortgage. They do so for two reasons.
First, default involves deadweight costs which the borrower will try to
avoid. Second, when borrowers can choose when to default--either during
a crisis or later--they will value the option to delay default and
instead continue to service an underwater mortgage. In this context,
payment reduction will have a more beneficial effect than principal
reduction in supporting consumption. We also show that payment reduction
increases the incentive to delay a default and thus reduces foreclosures
in a crisis.
While government resources are best spent on payment reduction, a
lender may find it preferable to write down debt. Since lenders bear the
credit default risk, effectively they fully write down the loan (and
take back the collateral) if it defaults. Hence, renegotiating the loan,
including partially writing down debt to avoid strategic default, can be
in the lender's own best interest. However, lenders also tend to
delay in order to preserve the option value of waiting, since the loan
may "cure" without any intervention. Without liquidity
constraints, lenders concerned about strategic default would optimally
offer a debt reduction at the end of the period (defined as just prior
to default) in order to preserve option value but avoid costly default.
When there are externalities from default that will not be internalized
by the lender, government policy can still play a useful role, in this
case by providing lender incentives to write down debt.
Summarizing, our analysis of loan modifications produces two broad
results. First, with liquidity constraints, transfers to households
during the crisis period weakly dominate transfers at later dates and
hence are a more effective use of government resources. These initial
transfers could include temporary payment reductions, such as interest
rate reductions, payment deferrals, or term extensions. This result is
robust to including default, various forms of deadweight costs of
default, debt overhang, and the easing of credit constraints through
principal reduction. Generally, any policy that transfers resources
later can be replicated by an initial transfer of resources, although
the converse is not true. Second, principal reductions should be offered
by lenders and not by the government. Principal reductions can reduce
any deadweight costs due to strategic default. This conclusion is
independent of whether or not liquidity constraints are present. Lenders
have a private incentive to write down debt since they bear losses in
default, so writing down debt can increase the value of the loan to
lenders. With the potential for delay, however, lenders will find it
privately optimal to delay debt write-downs until just prior to default.
Allowing for endogenous price determination in the housing market
reinforces these results. We embed the consumption and policy choice
problem in an equilibrium model of housing, with rental housing demand
augmented by households defaulting on their mortgages and moving from
homeownership to rental. The key result from this section is that
foreclosures by liquidity-constrained households undermine home-purchase
demand and hence prices more than strategic defaults do. Any default
incurs the deadweight cost of default, so this (potentially large) cost
is the same regardless of the cause of the default. However,
liquidity-constrained households carry their constraint into the rental
market, which constrains their housing demand and puts further downward
pressure on home prices. Strategic defaulters, on the other hand, are
not in liquidity distress by definition and hence have greater demand
for housing than do the liquidity-constrained. For a policymaker
concerned about foreclosure externalities and home prices, distressed
foreclosures by liquidity-constrained households are more damaging.
Our results demonstrate that different types of ex post
interventions in home lending solve conceptually distinct problems. For
example, payment-reducing modifications, which steepen the profile of
payments through payment deferrals, temporary interest rate reductions,
or term extensions, address cash flow and liquidity constraints. Loan
principal reductions are inefficient at addressing cash flow issues,
because they backload payment reductions, but they are effective at
addressing the risk of strategic defaults in the later period (though
not the initial period) that lenders face.
These results on ex post modifications are suggestive of the ex
ante properties of loan contracts that would ameliorate the problems
that arise during a crisis with both borrowing constraints and declining
home prices. Specifically, a contract should allow for lower payments
when borrowing constraints bind and a reduction in loan obligations when
home prices fall to reduce the incentive for strategic default. Such a
contract fills the role of automatic stabilizers in the housing market
by responding to economic conditions. An automatic stabilizer mortgage
contract that includes a reset option--that is, that can be reset as a
lower-adjustable-rate mortgage during a crisis period--is consistent
with the ex ante security design problem. The cyclical movement of
interest rates is key to achieving the state-contingency: if the central
bank reduces rates during cyclical downturns and when home prices fall,
the reset option allows mortgage borrowers to reduce their payments in a
recession as well as their outstanding debt. This latter effect on debt
reduction occurs because a reduction in contract interest rates via a
reset option reduces the present value of the payment stream owed by the
borrower. This present value of payments, rather than a contracted face
amount of principal, is the critical variable that enters a strategic
default decision. Finally, since it relies on a reset option that is
quite similar to the standard refinancing option, such a contract is
also near the space of existing contracts with pricing expertise and
scale.
Various forms of home price insurance or indexing of contracts to
home prices have been proposed (for example, see Mian and Sufi 2014) to
address the problems posed by negative equity. These options also
implement the intent to avoid strategic default in a downturn. Some
contracts of this type have been implemented on a small scale, although
measuring home prices at the appropriate level of aggregation and
allowing for home improvements and maintenance incentives pose practical
challenges. Indexing to interest rates, as suggested in the stabilizing
contract, has the advantages of being observable and consistent and
preserving monetary policy effectiveness. Contracts with this feature
already exist and have been implemented and priced on a large scale.
Moreover, effectively indexing contracts to interest rates makes them
sensitive to a broader range of economic conditions than home prices
alone.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next
section lays out a basic two-period model in which a household takes on
a mortgage to finance both housing and nonhousing consumption. We then
shock the household's income in a crisis period and study the
optimal form of transfer that smooths household consumption, showing
that it takes the form of a mortgage payment deferral. In section II we
introduce the possibility that the household may default on the mortgage
at the final period because the mortgage is underwater (a strategic
default). Since payment deferral increases the incidence of strategic
default, the optimal mortgage modification includes more crisis-period
payment reduction and less deferral. In section III, we study the case
where the borrower may strategically default in the crisis period as
well as the final period. We find that borrowers may delay defaulting in
a crisis period because the option to delay is valuable. In this
context, our earlier results concerning the merits of payment reduction
over principal reduction are strengthened. In section IV, we study the
lender's incentives to modify mortgages. We show that lenders,
unlike the government, will find it efficient to reduce mortgage
principal, but only just before the borrower defaults. In section V, we
consider the question of why there were so few modifications in practice
during the recession, and show that one reason may be adverse selection.
With the possibility of private information, lenders will be concerned
that a given modification will only attract types of borrowers that
cause them to make negative profits. We show that this consideration can
cause the modification market to break down. In section VI, we embed our
model in a simple housing market equilibrium and show that the merits of
spending government resources on payment reduction rather than principal
reduction are strengthened by general equilibrium considerations. In
section VII, we turn to the ex ante contract design problem and suggest
that a mortgage contract that gives the borrower the right to reset the
mortgage rate into a variable-rate mortgage goes some way toward
implementing the optimal contract. Section VIII concludes.
I. Basic Model
Households derive utility from housing and other consumption goods
according to the consumption aggregate, [C.sub.t]:
(1) [C.sub.t] [equivalent to] [([c.sup.h.sub.t].sup.[alpha]]
[([c.sub.t].sup.(1-[alpha])]
where [c.sup.h.sub.t] is consumption of housing services and
[c.sub.t] is consumption of non-housing goods. The household maximizes
linear utility over two periods
(2) U = [C.sub.1] + [C.sub.2],
where we have set the discount factor to 1, since it plays no role
in the analysis.
At date 0, that is, a date just prior to date 1, the household
purchases a home and takes out a mortgage loan. At the date 0 planning
date, the household expects to receive income of [bar.y] at both dates.
For now, there is no uncertainty. Income is allocated to nonhousing
consumption and to paying interest on a mortgage loan to finance housing
consumption. A home of size [c.sup.h] costs [P.sub.0] and is worth
[P.sub.2] at date 2. In the basic model, [P.sub.2] is non-stochastic.
(Later we will introduce home price and income uncertainty; for now, we
take these as given and known to the household.) The home price
[P.sub.0] satisfies the asset pricing equation,
(3) [P.sub.0] = r[c.sup.h] + r[c.sup.h] + [P.sub.2],
where r is defined as the per-period user cost of housing. That is,
if an agent purchases a home for [P.sub.0] and sells it in two periods
for [P.sub.2], the net cost over the two periods is 2r[c.sup.h] (=
[P.sub.0] - [P.sub.2)].
To finance the initial [P.sub.0] outlay, the household takes on a
mortgage loan. A lender provides [P.sub.0] funds to purchase the house
in return for interest payments of [l.sub.1] and [l.sub.2] and a
principal repayment of D. For the lender to break even, repayments must
cover the initial loan:
(4) [l.sub.1] + [l.sub.2] + D = [P.sub.0],
where we have set the lender's discount rate to 1, as well.
Given choices of ([l.sub.1], [l.sub.2], D), nonhousing consumption is
(5) [c.sub.1] = [bar.y] - [l.sub.1] and, [c.sub.2] - [bar.y] +
[P.sub.2] - D - [l.sub.2].
The household chooses ([l.sub.1], [l.sub.2], D) to maximize (2).
It is straightforward to derive the result that a
consumption-smoothing household maximizes utility by setting
(6) [l.sub.1] = [l.sub.2] - [alpha][bar.y] and, D = [P.sub.2].
That is, interest payments on the housing loan are [alpha][bar.y],
and the principal repayment is made by selling the home for [P.sub.2].
These choices result in consumption
(7) [c.sup.h.sub.t] = [alpha][bar.y]/r and, [c.sub.t] = (1 -
[alpha])[bar.y].
Note that with Cobb-Douglas preferences, the expenditure shares on
housing and nonhousing consumption are [alpha] and 1 - [alpha]. Since
the effective user cost of housing, r, is constant over both periods,
the household equalizes consumption over both dates. (1)
I.A. Crisis
A "crisis" occurs in the model by allowing an
unanticipated negative income shock to hit this household, so that
income at date 1 is instead [y.sub.1] < [bar.y], leaving income at
date 2 unchanged. There are two ways the household can adjust to this
shock. It can default on the mortgage, reduce housing consumption, and
increase nonhousing consumption. (2) Alternatively, it can borrow from
date 2, reducing future consumption and increasing current consumption.
We first study the second option and assume that the household does not
default on its mortgage (we will consider default in the next sections).
If the household does not default, it will consume too little of
nonhousing services at date 1, both because permanent income is lower
and also because the household cannot smooth nonhousing consumption by
borrowing against future income, so that
(8) [c.sub.1] < [c.sub.2].
That is, if the household could borrow freely at an interest rate
of zero, it would increase date 1 consumption and reduce date 2
consumption.
A household with other assets, or one with equity in its home, can
borrow to achieve this optimum consumption path. We instead will focus
on a liquidity-constrained household. This household has no other
assets, little to no equity in the home, and is unable to borrow against
future income. (3) Hence this household can only adjust its nonhousing
consumption beyond the liquidity constraint by defaulting on its
mortgage, since it cannot borrow against future income or consume from
other assets or home equity. (4) If it does not default, then date 1
consumption is constrained by the precommitted mortgage payment.
Let us suppose that a government has Z dollars that it can spend to
increase household utility. The scope for government intervention arises
in this setting directly because of the liquidity constraint, as in
Eggertson and Krugman (2010) and Guerreri and Lorenzoni (2011), or due
to other nominal rigidities, as in Farhi and Werning (2013) and others.
It could also be reinforced by an aggregate demand shortfall,
consumption externalities, other credit market frictions, or other
considerations. We do not model these explicitly, since our focus is on
the housing market (although we allow for additional considerations in
the next sections). Hence, the government's budget allocation may
result from its intention to ease liquidity constraints in period 1, or
similarly, as a way of implementing countercyclical macroeconomic
policies, since date 1 is the "crisis" period in the model.
Suppose the government chooses transfers to households ([t.sub.1],
[t.sub.2)] in the first and second period, respectively, that satisfy
the budget constraint (5)
(9) [t.sub.1] + [t.sub.2] = Z.
Various choices of [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2] can be mapped into
standard types of loan modifications. For example, setting [t.sub.1]
> 0 and [t.sub.2] = 0 in our notation corresponds to a pure
"payment reduction" loan modification, which temporarily
reduces loan payments, for example through a temporary interest rate
reduction. A "payment deferral" program offsets the initial
payment reduction with future payment increases, setting [t.sub.1] >
0 and [t.sub.2] < 0, for example through a maturity extension or loan
forbearance. A program with [t.sub.1] = [t.sub.2] > 0, so that
payment reductions are equally spread over time, corresponds to a
fixed-rate loan refinancing (since loan payments are lowered uniformly)
and to principal reduction, that is, a reduction in the loan principal
that results in reduced interest and principal payments at each date.
With these transfers, the household's budget set is now
augmented by a transfer in period 1 to help overcome the liquidity
constraint and a second transfer at date 2, resulting in household
consumption of
(10) [c.sub.1] = [y.sub.1] - [alpha][bar.y] + [t.sub.1], [c.sub.2]
= [bar.y] - [alpha][bar.y] + [t.sub.2].
Here we consider only policies related to modifying the mortgage;
in the next section, we add default so that policies are more directly
tied to mortgage payments. The planner maximizes household utility
(11) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
subject to equations 9 and 10. Note that since we are considering
the case where the household does not default and hence does not
reoptimize housing consumption, the consumption values [c.sup.h.sub.1],
[c.sup.h.sub.2] = [alpha][bar.y]/r, are invariant to the choice of
[t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2].
We can rewrite the planner's problem thus:
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where
(13) v([c.sub.t]) [equivalent to] [([alpha][bar.y]/r).sup.[alpha]]
[([c.sub.t]).sup.1-[alpha]]
and we note that v (*) is concave. This problem provides the
minimal incentive to support household consumption, as it focuses only
on the liquidity constraint of a single household and does not take into
account aggregate demand externalities that may be present in a crisis,
as emphasized by other authors.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 illustrates the solution for nonhousing consumption for Z
= 0. The vertical axis graphs [c.sub.2], while the horizontal axis
graphs [c.sub.1]. The initial point A after the shock has [c.sub.2] >
[c.sub.1]. The bold diagonal line traces out the set of points that
satisfy the budget constraint, [t.sub.1] + [t.sub.2] = 0 (that is, Z =
0). The optimum calls for full consumption smoothing, which is to set
[t.sub.1] > 0 and [t.sub.2] < 0 until [c.sub.1] = [c.sub.2] (the
dotted 45-degree line) at point B.
As Z rises, the bold diagonal line shifts outward, but for any
given Z we see that payment deferral ([t.sub.1] > 0, [t.sub.2] <
0) is better than payment reduction ([t.sub.1] > 0, [t.sub.2] = 0)
because it allows higher transfers in the first period, which is in turn
better than principal reduction ([t.sub.1] > 0, [t.sub.2] > 0),
where transfers continue beyond the crisis period. This finding is
consistent with general results in public finance showing that transfers
into liquidity-constrained states enhance utility, since the marginal
utility of consumption is high in those states. A reduction in mortgage
principal does not transfer liquid assets into those states since the
household is by definition liquidity-constrained and cannot borrow
against its higher wealth. The increase in wealth is implemented by a
stream of lower mortgage payments over the life of the loan, which is
likely to extend well beyond the crisis period. Hence, gathering those
benefits together into a front-loaded transfer is more effective. We
highlight this result in this simplest setting because it is robust
throughout as we add additional features to the model: transfers in the
initial crisis period at least weakly dominate policies that transfer
resources later.
We have described the solution ([t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2]) as the
solution to the planning problem. However, there is nothing in our setup
thus far that precludes the private sector from offering a loan
modification. If private lenders could offer contracts with [t.sub.1]
> 0, [t.sub.2] < 0 they would find it profitable to do so. This
would correspond to loan refinancing with term extension, for example,
which might be desirable to households by reducing payments immediately
but also profitable for lenders over the life of the loan. Nonetheless,
there are several reasons why policy may still be desirable. While we
have not modeled a government's preference for countercyclical
policy, private lenders might not offer the socially optimal amount of
modifications if there are credit market frictions, consumption
externalities, or an aggregate demand shortfall. Hence, it may be
optimal for the government to offer or subsidize modifications in
addition to available private sector contracts. Moreover, later we will
show that with asymmetric information, the market in private contracts
may collapse due to adverse selection, which provides further scope for
policy intervention.
II. Optimal Decisions and Default Risk at Date 2
Without default, the best transfer policy is to reduce payments as
much as possible in the crisis period in order to support consumption.
Given the government's budget constraint, a policy that reduces
mortgage payments in the crisis period and defers the payments until
date 2 is the most cost effective; that is, for a given budget, it
allows the most payment reduction during the crisis. However, in
practice such loans may induce default by front-loading the benefits and
back-loading the costs of the program to households. Households,
especially those with underwater mortgages, may use the payment deferral
and then subsequently default on the loan. In this section, we study the
case where agents can reoptimize and possibly default at date 2,
allowing us to examine how policy interventions at date 1 affect
subsequent date 2 default. In section III, we consider the case where
agents can reoptimize and default at either date 1 or date 2, so that
there is a timing element in the default decision.
II.A. Stochastic Home Price, Date 2 Decisions, and Default
Suppose that at the start of date 2 before the household consumes
or makes interest payments on debt, the home price [P.sub.2] changes.
Agents then have the opportunity to reoptimize their consumption and
borrowing choices, possibly defaulting on their mortgage loan. The home
price change is unanticipated from the date 0 perspective. We analyze
decisions at date 2, taking previous decisions as given.
At the start of date 2, prior to any interest payments or default
decisions, a household has wealth of
(14) [bar.y] + [P.sub.2] - D + [t.sub.2].
If [P.sub.2] - D + [t.sub.2] [not equal to] 0, the household will
want to rebalance consumption. For example, if P2 - D + t2 > 0, the
household will want to increase housing and nonhousing consumption given
that its wealth is greater than the initially expected amount of
[bar.y]. We suppose that at date 2 the household can readily sell the
home, repay any debts, and be left with [bar.y] + [P.sub.2] - D +
[t.sub.2]. The household uses these resources to purchase (or rent) a
home for one period. Given Cobb-Douglas preferences and a one-period
user cost of housing of r, it is straightforward to show that utility
over date 2 consumption is linear in wealth,
(15) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [psi] is the marginal value of a dollar at date 2 and will be
a constant throughout the analysis. It a household defaults on its
mortgage, it loses the home, which was the collateral for the loan, and
loses any equity in the home. Since the household still requires housing
services, it enters the rental market to replace the lost housing
services. The household also suffers a default cost, which may represent
restricted access to credit markets, benefits of homeownership or
neighborhoods, match-specific benefits of the home, and so on. Thus, in
default the household's wealth becomes
(16) [bar.y] - [theta],
where [theta] is a deadweight cost of default. Note that the
household also loses the date 2 home-related transfer of [t.sub.2]. The
household utility from this wealth is ([bar.y] - [theta])[psi]. The
household defaults if
(17) [bar.y] - [theta] > [bar.y] + [P.sub.2] - D + [t.sub.2],
so that wealth after defaulting exceeds wealth of continuing to
service the mortgage.
Define the equity in the home ([P.sub.2] - D) plus the default cost
as
(18) [phi] [equivalent to] [P.sub.2] + [theta] - D,
which represents the total cost of default to the household. Then
the default condition is expressed by the inequality
(19) [phi] < -[t.sub.2],
which determines whether the household defaults on its mortgage and
incurs the deadweight cost of default. Otherwise the household continues
to service the mortgage.
II.B. Optimal Date 1 Loan Modification with Date 2 Default Risk
We now solve for the optimal loan modification, accounting for the
possibility that some borrowers will default on their loans. Our
principal conclusion is that the payment reductions and deferrals still
dominate principal reductions. Moreover, since default risk increases
under payment deferral, because borrowers have to pay back more in the
future, government resources are best spent first providing payment
relief and only then shifting to payment deferral.
Suppose that [phi], which measures the incentive to default, is a
random variable that is realized at date 2. For example, realizations of
[P.sub.2] may vary across homeowners, leading to different realizations
of [phi]. Moreover, suppose the possibility that home prices are
uncertain only becomes apparent to borrowers and lenders at date 1. That
is, continue to assume that this uncertainty is unanticipated at the
date 0 stage, so that the date 0 loan contract is signed under the
presumption that home prices are certain.
Default risk affects the planner's decisions over ([t.sub.1],
[t.sub.2)] because the planner has to account for the possibility that
setting [t.sub.2] < 0 (or requiring date 2 payments for borrowers)
may induce default. Denote the CDF of [phi] as F([phi]). Since borrowers
default when [phi] < -[t.sub.2], for any given [t.sub.2] we have
F(-[t.sub.2]) borrowers defaulting on loans. We will assume the
interesting case where ([t.sub.1], [t.sub.2)] are such that it is
advantageous for every liquidity-constrained borrower to take the
modification contract, but a fraction F(-[t.sub.2]) strategically
default on their loans in the second period.
A planner with Z dollars to spend solves thus:
(20) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The first line is the utility of the constrained borrowers with
high default costs (that is, high [phi]) who take the modification and
do not default. The second line is the utility of the constrained
borrowers who will default.
The government budget constraint requires (6)
(21) Z - [t.sub.2] [1 - F (-[t.sub.2])] - [t.sub.1] = 0.
A fraction 1 - F (-[t.sub.2]) of borrowers make the repayment of
-[t.sub.2]. This repayment plus the Z dollars must cover the initial
payment of [t.sub.1].
Denote [mu] as the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint.
The first-order condition with respect to [t.sub.1] gives
(22) v'([y.sub.1] - [alpha][bar.y] + [t.sub.1]) = [mu],
and with respect to [t.sub.2] gives
(23) [1 - F (-[t.sub.2])] [PSI] = [mu]{[1 - F (-[t.sub.2])] +
[t.sub.2] f([t.sub.2])}.
Combining, we find
(24) v'[(l - [alpha]) [bar.y] + [t.sub.2]] [[PSI].sup.1] = 1 +
[t.sub.2]f([t.sub.2])/1 - F (-[t.sub.2]).
The solution is easy to illustrate pictorially. Figure 2 graphs
first and second period nonhousing consumption for various values of
government transfers. The curves AB and AC in figure 2 illustrate the
set of all transfers that satisfy the government's budget
constraint. The key point is that this set is a "curve" for
[t.sub.1] > Z. Starting from point A, where transfers are zero, along
the dashed curve, as [t.sub.1] exceeds Z, -[t.sub.2] must become
negative to satisfy the budget constraint. However, with negative date 2
transfers, a fraction of borrowers will default, and increasingly so as
[t.sub.2] becomes more negative; this induces curvature in the
government's budget set. We also graph the isoquants for the
liquidity-constrained high-default-cost household. Taking only this
household into account, we see that at the optimum point B, the planner
sets [t.sub.1] > 0 and [t.sub.2] < 0. Accounting for the utility
of the household that defaults increases [t.sub.1] further since this
household places weight only on the date 1 transfer. As Z rises, the
dashed (AB) curve shifts out to the AC curve, and at the tangency point
C, the transfer [t.sub.1] becomes larger, while the required repayment
[t.sub.2] falls. Thus the contract calls for payment reduction and
payment deferral, with more reduction available as Z rises. (Later, we
allow for the default cost [phi] to be unobserved to the policymaker and
lender, so that adverse selection is an issue.)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The fact that the budget set becomes a curve when we allow for
default underlies many of the results about the desirability of date 1
transfers. If the government promises future resource transfers to
households but there is a recession or crisis today, households will
want to pull those resources forward and consume more now. Liquidity
constraints may bind and prevent them from doing so at all. Even if
credit markets are available to do so, so that households could borrow
from the future to consume today, the interest rate at which they could
borrow has to allow for the possibility of default. So it is more
expensive for households to rely on credit markets than to receive the
equivalent payment reduction today. The curved budget line reflects the
possibility of default and means that consumption bundles that could be
achieved with transfers today ([t.sub.1] > 0) are not available if
the government instead transfers resources in the future ([t.sub.2] >
0).
II.C. Principal Reduction with Default Risk
Above we considered the case where [t.sub.1] > 0 and [t.sub.2]
< 0. In the case of principal reduction, both [t.sub.1] and [t.sub.2]
are positive. In particular, since [t.sub.2] > 0, the planner
transfers resources to the household and the budget constraint becomes
(25) Z - [t.sub.2] - [t.sub.1] = 0.
Suppose we solve the planning problem subject to the above budget
constraint and restrict attention to solutions where [t.sub.1] and
[t.sub.2] are non-negative. Figure 3 illustrates the solution. The
shaded area illustrates the set of all points such that [t.sub.1] +
[t.sub.2] = Z, [t.sub.1] > 0, and [t.sub.2] > 0. It is clear that
the solution is a corner: set [t.sub.1] - Z and [t.sub.2] - 0 (point A
in the figure). This implies that principal reduction (in which
[t.sub.2] > 0) is not optimal, since the solution goes to the corner
where the transfers are front-loaded, that is, for payment reduction
focused in period 1. This occurs despite the fact that our problem
allows for strategic default with default costs and that borrowers
default less if [t.sub.2] > 0. For high enough Z, the transfer to
date 1 is sufficient to ensure full consumption smoothing, and hence
there is no need for further transfers.
In this setting, principal reduction is never optimal, even though
default is costly and is accounted for by the planner, because the
alternative of directly transferring the same resources to households in
the first period raises utility more. It is optimal for the planner to
use this strategy until the liquidity constraint no longer binds and
consumption is completely smoothed. Until that occurs, principal
reduction is suboptimal compared with payment deferral or reduction, and
thereafter no policy intervention is needed to address liquidity
constraints.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
II.D. Principal Reduction to Alleviate Debt Overhang
The debt overhang from underwater mortgages is an additional
macroeconomic consideration, since continuing to make mortgage payments
prevents households from rebalancing their spending toward other forms
of consumption, as emphasized by Karen Dynan (2012). Hence, in addition
to reducing default, principal write-downs may also ease a debt overhang
problem by easing a borrower's date 1 credit constraint. If the
government would prefer to increase date 1 consumption, easing the
credit constraint could be desirable. Does this change the calculus of
government interventions to ease the liquidity constraint; that is, does
debt overhang suggest that principal reduction is valuable over and
above elimination of deadweight loss?
The answer is no. Suppose at date 1 the government offers a loan
modification of [t.sub.2] > 0, [t.sub.1] - 0, to reduce principal by
[t.sub.2]. (We structure the modification in this way to be clear that
any increase in date 1 resources comes from easing the debt overhang and
not from a direct government transfer at date 1.) Consider private
lender transactions ([[tau].sub.1], [[tau].sub.2]) that at least break
even for the lenders, that is, (7)
(26) -[[tau].sub.2] (1 - F(-[[tau].sub.2])) - [[tau].sub.1] = 0.
In figure 3, we represent the principal reduction of Z by moving
from the zero transfer allocation to point B. The dashed curve in figure
3 represents the set of trades, ([[tau].sub.1], [[tau].sub.2]), that a
private sector lender will make that allows the lender to break even.
These trades allow agents to borrow against the future transfer Z in
order to smooth consumption, solving the liquidity constraint problem at
date 1. Again, the critical thing to note is that the borrowing
constraint becomes a curve. Starting from point B, the household will
trade to point C, which achieves less utility than point A. That is, the
household will choose to borrow the Z back to increase date 1
consumption. However, since some borrowers default, the interest rate on
the private loan will exceed 1, so that the government would do better
by offering the transfer of Z at date 1, that is, a payment reduction
rather than a principal reduction, to reach point A.
This is a general point: even if principal reduction is
sufficiently generous to overcome individual borrowing constraints,
direct payouts to borrowers are more efficient since the government
avoids the default costs associated with borrowing against home equity.
(8)
The key insight underlying these results is the constraint
affecting date 1 consumption. Even if credit markets exist to transfer
date 2 resources into date 1 consumption, default risk makes this
approach more expensive than a direct date 1 transfer to households.
Hence, even with default risk, we again find that transfers in the
initial crisis period at least weakly dominate policies that transfer
resources later. Government resources to reduce principal are better
spent in engaging lenders to renegotiate mortgage loans than in engaging
them to write down loans directly. (9)
III. Optimal Date 1 Decisions and Default Timing
The economic environment during a crisis is explicitly dynamic,
however, so borrowers, lenders, and policymakers have to decide not only
what to do, but when to do it. These considerations can be quite
important, since conditions may change unpredictably over time.
Therefore, we now study the case where the borrower can take action at
either date 1 or date 2, and information becomes available along the
way. In the last section, we restricted the borrower to default only at
date 2 in order to keep our analysis simple and establish the intuition
for the default decision. Timing makes the problem more interesting and
adds some potentially surprising results about delay.
The problem is somewhat more complex to study, but it does not
change our conclusions on the benefits of payment reduction/deferral
over principal reduction. Government resources spent on principal
reduction for a borrower who remains current on his mortgage still has
lower consumption benefits than a payment reduction that increases the
borrower's liquidity because of the liquidity constraint. Moreover,
comparing equivalent payment and principal reductions, the payment
reduction increases the borrower's incentive to remain current on
his mortgage and thus reduces default in addition to increasing
consumption. This is again due to the liquidity constraint, whereby the
borrower places a high value on continuing to service a mortgage that
has been modified to reduce current payments. Additionally, the analysis
turns up a somewhat surprising result: borrowers who are underwater on a
mortgage will typically continue to service it, because delaying the
decision to default is a valuable option. Hence, borrowers need not be
irrational or excessively optimistic when they continue to make payments
on an underwater loan.
Suppose that at date I borrowers have information
[E.sub.[phi]][equivalent to][E.sub.t=1][[phi]] (that is, their mortgage
at date 1 is underwater). Given this information, we analyze the
borrower's decision at date 1, accounting for how the date 1
decision affects the date 2 decision we analyzed in the previous
section. If the borrower chooses not to default at date 1, then utility
at date 1 is
(27) [([alpha][bar.y]/r).sup.[alpha]] [([y.sub.1] + [t.sub.1] -
[alpha][bar.y]).sup.1-[alpha]].
If the household defaults at date 1, it can reoptimize its
consumption plan to rebalance housing and nonhousing consumption,
yielding a utility of
(28) [y.sub.1]([([alpha]/r).sup.[alpha]]) = [y.sub.1][PSI], where
[PSI] [equivalent to] [([alpha]/r).sup.[alpha]][(1 -
[alpha]).sup.1-[alpha]].
However, if the household defaults at date 1, it loses any value in
the home as well as the option to delay default until date 2. Under
default at date 1, date 2 wealth becomes [bar.y] - [theta], yielding a
date 2 utility of
(29)([bar.y] - [theta]) [PSI].
With no default at date 1, utility at date 2 is
(30) {[bar.y] + E[max ([P.sub.2] + [t.sub.2] - D, -
[theta])]}[PSI].
Hence, comparing values with and without a date 1 default, the
default at date 1 occurs if
(31) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Rewriting, we obtain the condition under which default occurs at
date 1 as
(32) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Figure 4 graphs the left- and right-hand side of (32) as a function
of E[phi], which measures the degree to which a homeowner has equity
([P.sub.2] - D) (plus the default cost), or the inverse of
"underwaterness." The gray curve graphs the value of the
option to keep making mortgage payments and delaying default, on the
right-hand side of equation 32. This value is uniformly positive,
although low for low values of E[phi]. The dashed line is the benefit of
defaulting, on the left-hand side of equation 32. This value is
independent of E[phi]. For low values of E[phi]), the household chooses
to default at date 1.
The borrower chooses to default when the benefit of defaulting (the
bold line) exceeds the benefit of delay (the gray line), given his level
of equity and default cost. In option terms, underwater borrowers have a
call option on keeping the home, which is extinguished by default. Thus
the choice to make the mortgage payment at date 1 is not just about
whether the loan is underwater; it is a question of whether the cost of
making this payment covers the value of the call option. When liquidity
constraints are tight, the cost of making the payment is highest; this
determines the height of the horizontal bold line in Figure 4. When the
borrower is underwater, the value of the call option is lowest, as shown
in the gray line, which rises as the household's equity in the home
rises. (10) The intersection of the dashed and gray lines, at point A,
determines the value of E[phi], or the degree of being underwater, that
triggers default. This characterization is also consistent with the
"double-trigger" model of default, as in Christopher Foote,
Kristopher Gerardi, and Paul Willen (2008) and John Campbell and Joao
Cocco (2014), for example: underwater, liquidity-constrained homeowners
are the most likely to default.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
We can now consider policy in this richer setting and revisit the
planning problem of choosing ([t.sub.1], [t.sub.2]). A borrower with
E[phi], to the right of point A--called the threshold E[[phi].sup.A] in
figure 4--continues to pay his mortgage, allowing nonhousing consumption
to adjust with the income shortfall. Note that for points just to the
right of E[[phi].sup.A], the borrower is underwater on the mortgage. We
can rewrite the condition for no default as
(33) E[[P.sub.2]] - D [greater than or equal to] E[[phi].sup.A] -
[theta],
where we note that E[[phi].sup.A] < 0. Borrowers continue to
service an underwater mortgage at date 1 both because of the deadweight
cost of default, [theta] > 0, and because of the value of the option
to delay a default decision, E[[phi].sup.A] < 0.
For the underwater borrower who continues to service his mortgage,
the problem is the same as we have analyzed in the previous section. The
optimal transfer sets [t.sub.1] > 0 and [t.sub.2] < 0 to support
date 1 consumption. However, when default is a possibility, the
government may choose to set transfers and intervene to prevent
defaults, avoiding foreclosure externalities and further deterioration
in the housing market. We examine these effects and potential
equilibrium feedback in more detail in the next section, but begin by
examining the effect of transfers on defaults here.
Borrowers with E[phi] considerably below E[[phi].sup.A] will
default independent of any transfers. Consequently, these are cases
where the transfers generate no economic benefits, so we set these cases
aside. For borrowers with [phi] near but just below E[[phi].sup.A],
transfers affect default incentives in interesting ways. Increasing
[t.sub.1] shifts down the benefit to defaulting (dashed line) at all
values of E[phi] to the thin horizontal line. Hence the trigger value
falls from point A to point C; the household will be more deeply
underwater before defaulting. Increasing [t.sub.2] increases the cost of
defaulting, shifting up the solid gray curve to the dashed gray curve,
and the trigger value falls from point A to point B. Note that this
latter effect is strongest at higher values of E[phi], on the right-hand
side of figure 4. However, this is the region for which default is
dominated; the default option is out of the money. Hence, positive date
2 transfers move equity values most when households are least likely to
default. This point can be seen clearly analytically. The derivative of
the left-hand side of equation 32 with respect to [t.sub.1] is
(34) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The derivative of the right-hand side of equation 32 with respect
to [t.sub.2] is
(35) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Thus a dollar increase in [t.sub.1] always decreases the benefit of
defaulting at date 1 more than a dollar increase in [t.sub.2]. The
difference in these effects increases as E[phi] falls, that is, as the
mortgage is more underwater. Hence, the more underwater the loan is, the
more effective an initial payment reduction is at avoiding default,
relative to an equivalent transfer received at date 2. (11) The date I
transfer supports consumption and reduces default, reinforcing our
finding that date 1 transfers are more effective than flat or
back-loaded transfers. Initially, this was clear with a date 1 liquidity
constraint, but the same result obtains with date 2 default and now with
the possibility of date 1 default and default timing on strategic
default.
The option approach also illustrates the role of uncertainty, which
raises the option value of waiting, or in terms of figure 4, shifts up
the gray curve. The slanted straight line gives the payoff value under
certainty (when [phi] is known); greater uncertainty shifts the gray
curve up relative to the slanted line. Higher home price uncertainty is
therefore associated with fewer defaults at date 1, as homeowners have a
greater option value of waiting for home prices to rise. This
illustrates the subtlety of arguments about the effect of uncertainty on
the economy. Putting a floor under home prices (reducing the mass in the
left tail) would reduce defaults, but reducing uncertainty, or trading
off a floor with a commensurate ceiling on home prices, could increase
defaults. (12)
Finally, we note that a borrower who does not experience an income
shock, [y.sub.1] = [bar.y], never defaults at date 1. The left-hand side
of equation 32 is zero in this case, because there is no benefit to
reoptimizing date 1 consumption. Moreover, the right-hand side is
strictly positive. Even in the case where c is expected to be negative,
there is a positive value to waiting and exercising the option to
strategically default at date 2, so that it is never optimal to default
at date 1. This cleanly illustrates the intuition for strategic delay by
unconstrained households.
We conclude from this analysis that payment reductions at date 1
are more effective than flat or back-loaded transfers in supporting
consumption and preventing default at date I. Principal reductions at
date 2 are most effective in preventing strategic default at date 2.
This finding reinforces our earlier results for liquidity-constrained
households. There, the binding liquidity constraint made it clear that
for macroeconomic consumption purposes, date 1 transfers are the most
effective use of government budget resources. Allowing for future
default modified this finding: date I payments coupled with repayment at
date 2 can induce default at date 2. Hence, payments should be flatter
but still front-loaded. A flat or back-loaded transfer schedule is
always dominated by date 1 payments until the liquidity constraint is
fully relaxed. (13) With default and an option value of delay, we still
obtain that policy transfers in the initial crisis period dominate
policies that transfer resources later.
IV. Lender-Initiated Loan Modifications
We have shown that government resources aimed at supporting
consumption and reducing default are better spent on payment reduction
than on principal reduction. Because lenders directly bear the credit
default risk, however, their incentives differ from the
government's. Unlike the government, lenders may find it efficient
to write down principal, because partially writing down principal may be
cost effective compared to a default on the entire loan. We show that a
lender's incentives to do so are highest when the borrower is
underwater on his mortgage and the strategic default risk is therefore
highest. Moreover, as with the borrower, when the lender can time a
principal write-down, the lender will choose to delay doing so until the
time that a borrower is about to default on the mortgage loan.
IV.A. Date 2 Principal Reduction
We first consider the lender's incentives at date 2 and then
work backward to the dynamic problem at date 1. First consider a
borrower whose home price exceeds the mortgage amount less the
deadweight cost of default at the start of date 2. This borrower is
expected to repay, and hence the lender receives the loan amount, D,
plus the interest payment on the loan of [rc.sup.h]. On the other hand,
a borrower with ([phi]) < 0 at the start of date 2 will be expected
to default on his debt. In that case, the lender receives the home,
which is worth [P.sub.2], and which the lender can rent out to receive
[rc.sup.h]. Denote [V.sub.2] ([P.sub.2], D) as the value of the mortgage
loan to a lender conditional on a given price [P.sub.2] and debt level
D. Then,
(36) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figure 5 graphs [V.sub.2] (x) as a function of [P.sub.2] for two
levels of debt, D and D' (where D' < D). The comparison
illustrates that when [P.sub.2] < D - [theta] (that is, [phi] <
0), the lender can increase the value of its loan by reducing D to
D'. (14) This occurs because [theta] is a deadweight cost of
default. If the borrower defaults on his loan, the lender only collects
[P.sub.2]. However, the borrower's value of keeping the loan and
not defaulting is [P.sub.2] + [theta]. Thus, the lender can offer to
write down the principal to D' < D and still increase the value
of its loan. (15) Formally, the lender renegotiation solves
(37) [max.sub.D'<D] [V.sub.2] ([P.sub.2], D'),
with solution D' = [P.sub.2] + [theta] for [P.sub.2] < D -
[theta].
We have identified a situation where principal reduction leads to
better date 2 outcomes. Importantly, no government resources are
required to implement the principal reduction, which is privately
optimal since the lender benefits from avoiding default. As we point out
later, though, the government may play an important role in encouraging
and coordinating the renegotiation (for example, by standardizing the
structure of modifications).
IV.B. Date 7 Principal Reduction
Now we move the lender's valuation forward to consider a
possible principal reduction at date 1, where lenders (and borrowers)
observe E[phi]. If E[phi] is to the left of point A on figure 4, then
borrowers will immediately default. In this case, the analysis of lender
incentives is the same as just discussed. The lender will choose to
immediately write down principal to [P.sub.1] + [theta]. Consider next
the case where E[phi] is to the right of point A, but still below zero.
In this case, borrowers will not default. Interestingly, lenders will
also choose not to write down principal immediately. As in the previous
section, this effect can be understood in terms of an American option,
though here from the lender's perspective. By waiting until t = 2
the lender can make the reduction contingent on the realization of
future prices, and specifically on whether or not [P.sub.2] is below or
above D - [phi]. By writing down principal, the lender extinguishes the
option to write down later, and it is not optimal to exercise the option
early. Formally, an early write-down has the lender maximizing:
(38) [max.sub.D'<D] E[[V.sub.2]([P.sub.2],
D')|[P.sub.1]].
The lender loses value in doing so because [max.sub.D,<D]
E[[V.sub.2]([P.sub.2], D')|[P.sub.1]] < [max.sub.D,<D]
[V.sub.2]([P.sub.2], D')|[P.sub.1]], by Jensen's inequality.
This delay effect is reinforced by any government transfer that
decreases the incentive for default in figure 4, and hence reduces the
incentive for a private lender renegotiation. Hence, a government
write-down makes a private write-down less likely. (16)
In practice, there may be costs in waiting. It may take time to
process the contractual requirements of reducing loan principal. Prices
may move discretely and the borrower might default before the lender is
able to implement the reduction. Such considerations may lead the lender
to reduce principal preemptively, although the value of delay will
always be balanced against those considerations.
While it is inefficient for the government to write down principal,
there may be circumstances where the government will prefer the lender
to immediately write down principal. For example, a householder may be
the best match for a home he is already living in and continue to
service an underwater mortgage, restricting his nonhousing consumption
and depressing economic activity in the crisis period. If the lender
were to write down principal at date 1, the borrower would be less
constrained and thus increase his nonhousing consumption at date 1,
which may have macroeconomic benefits. Our analysis shows that in order
to incentivize lenders to write down principal early, the lender must
receive a transfer equal to the value of the option to delay the
write-down. That is, the government must "purchase" the option
to delay the write-down from the lender in order to trigger an immediate
write-down.
The cost of this option is [max.sub.D,<D] [V.sub.2]([P.sub.2],
D')|[P.sub.1]] - [max.sub.D,<D] E[[V.sub.2]([P.sub.2],
D')|[P.sub.1]] > 0. In general, the value of this option will be
less than the dollar amount of any principal write-down, so incentives
for private writedowns may be effective even when the government does
not write down the loan itself.
The last two sections of this paper demonstrate that delay can be
desirable to both borrowers and lenders, who see default as
extinguishing a valuable option to wait and possibly avoid costly
foreclosure. The government may still intervene if it values the
externalities associated with foreclosure or constrained consumption
more than private agents do, and hence would prefer to move more quickly
to address inefficient servicer delays, information problems, and
capacity constraints. None of these actions involves principal
reductions paid for by the government. (17)
V. An Adverse Selection Explanation for Lack of Modifications
In practice, lenders were not active in doing mortgage
modifications, especially during the early period in the financial
crisis. Later, lenders began to offer principal reductions as part of
loan modifications; this was especially true of specialty servicers.
Lenders identified other considerations, including reputational effects
and incentives affecting a lender's whole portfolio of loans,
rather than just individual borrowers. For loans not held on balance
sheet by lenders, servicer incentives and capacity may also have
reinforced delay and timing discreteness.
Our theoretical findings are consistent with the empirical work of
Manuel Adelino, Kris Gerardi, and Paul Willen (2013), who document the
reluctance of servicers to renegotiate mortgages and emphasize the
presence of uncertainty arising from the risk of re-default and the
"self-curing" of mortgage delinquencies. Other authors address
administrative and structural frictions to loan renegotiation and
recommend legal and policy changes to reduce them; for example,
Christopher Mayer, Edward Morrison, and Tomasz Piskorski (2009) and John
Geanakoplous and Susan Koniak (2011). The efficacy of these proposals is
outside our present scope, although the challenges faced by servicers
and the administrative structure of mortgages also point to the
desirability of ex ante reforms (which we discuss in section VII) as
opposed to ex post renegotiations.
In this section, we demonstrate one force arising naturally in our
model that causes lenders to choose not to offer modifications. One
disadvantage of intervening in a crisis is that participating in a
modification program may create selection problems. For example, a
classic problem in lending is that the borrowers most eager to take out
a loan are those least likely to pay it back. That problem can also
arise in mortgage modifications, and it can cause beneficial private
modifications to collapse. To show this, we consider a setting in which
the market unravels due to adverse selection.
Returning to our model with unknown default costs from section
II.A, suppose now that [phi] is the private information of the
borrowers. In addition, suppose that 1 - [lambda] fraction of the
households are liquidity constrained as described, but [lambda] fraction
are unconstrained. For these unconstrained households [y.sub.1] =
[bar.y], so that they do not have to cut back on consumption at date 1
and have no need to borrow from future income.
Let us focus on a modification program with [t.sub.1] > 0 and
[t.sub.2] < 0, where v' ([y.sub.1] - [alpha][bar.y] + [t.sub.1])
> [PSI]. That is, the terms of this program are such that all
liquidity-constrained households find it beneficial to participate in
the program. On the other hand, among unconstrained households, only
those with low default costs, [phi] - [t.sub.2], will take the loan. For
this household, the modification, or consumption loan, is a free
transfer of [t.sub.1] since the household does not intend to repay the
loan. For a high-default-cost household that is unconstrained, the loan
is not useful; it does not increase utility because consumption is
already smooth across periods and the terms of trade in the loan imply
an interest rate above one. Then, within the population of households
that accept modifications, the fraction of defaulters [F.sup.A] is
(39) [F.sup.A](-[t.sub.2]) = [lambda]F(-[t.sub.2]) + (1 -
[lambda])F(-[t.sub.2])/[lambda]F(-[t.sub.2]) + (1 - [lambda]) > F
(-[t.sub.2]).
The break-even condition under which a lender would offer the loan
requires that
(40). Z - [t.sub.2](1 - [F.sup.A](-[t.sub.2])) - [t.sub.1] = 0.
Hence, the larger the fraction of defaulters, [F.sup.A], the
smaller the initial transfer to support consumption, [t.sub.1], can be,
for any given [t.sub.2]. As the share of unconstrained households
([lambda]) rises, [F.sup.A](-[t.sub.2]) goes to one, and the effective
interest required for a lender not to lose money goes to infinity. In
other words, the unconstrained strategic defaulters drive up the cost of
the modification for liquidity-constrained borrowers. At higher interest
rates, the liquidity-constrained borrowers also self-select: only
low-default-cost households take the loan, so the fraction of defaulters
in the population goes toward one. For sufficiently high [lambda], the
modification market breaks down for standard "lemons market"
reasons: the only contract offered is [t.sub.1] = [t.sub.2] = 0.
We can again write a planning problem to derive the optimal
([t.sub.1], [t.sub.2]). The solution calls for [t.sub.1] > 0 and
[t.sub.2] < 0. following the same logic as the previous case. As
[lambda] rises, there are more strategic defaulters in the pool, and the
solution requires a smaller initial transfer [t.sub.1].
Can the private market reproduce this outcome? Suppose that
modifications are offered by the private sector rather than by a
government and that there is competition among lenders. Consider two
lenders engaged in Bertrand competition. Fix a modification contract
([t.sub.1], [t.sub.2]) such that the lenders each break even. Now
suppose that one of the lenders offers a contract
[[??].sub.1] = [t.sub.1] - [[epsilon].sub.1], with [[??].sub.2] =
[t.sub.2]/[t.sub.1] [[??].sub.1] + [[epsilon].sub.2] for positive and
small [[epsilon].sub.1], [[epsilon].sub.2].
The second contract involves a smaller date 1 loan, but also a
smaller interest rate on the loan. The contract is not attractive to
unconstrained borrowers because they will not repay, and hence care only
about the size of the modification and not the effective interest rate.
But we can always choose [[epsilon].sub.1] and [[epsilon].sub.2] such
that the liquidity-constrained borrowers prefer the second contract over
the first contract. That is, the interest-rate savings,
[[epsilon].sub.2], can be chosen to be large enough to compensate for
the reduction in loan size, [[epsilon].sub.1], to make this contract
preferred by liquidity-constrained borrowers. In this case, the second
contract is a profitable deviation by a lender. But as a result, the
initial lender loses money, since this lender is left with a population
of unconstrained strategic defaulters; he will therefore lose [t.sub.1].
The first lender will then have to match the second lender and reduce
[t.sub.1], but this offer will also be undercut. Equilibrium can unravel
in the sense elaborated on by Michael Rothschild and Joseph Stiglitz
(1976).
This logic provides two insights. First, it offers one reason why
modifications were not offered more widely. Competition and the fear of
receiving an adverse pool of borrowers likely limited lender
modifications. Only in clear cases where the lender could exclude likely
strategic defaulters through screens and filters could a modification
proceed. (18) Second, it offers a rationale for a standard
government-supported modification contract. That is, if the government
supported and subsidized a standardized contract for all modifications,
then the unraveling problem disappears.