The missing "one-offs": the hidden supply of high-achieving, low-income students.
Hoxby, Caroline ; Avery, Christopher
IV. C. College Enrollment and Progress toward a Degree
In this subsection, we demonstrate that, conditional on applying to
a specific college, high- and low-income students thereafter behave
similarly. There is no statistically significant difference in their
probability of enrolling or in their progress toward a degree.
To find the first of these results, we estimate a conditional logit
model in which the binary outcome is 1 for the college in which the
student initially enrolled and zero for all others. Importantly, we
limit the student's choice set to the colleges to which he or she
applied. So that the student's enrollment decision is compared to
those of students who applied to the same college, we include a fixed
effect for each college. We also include interactions between these
fixed effects and an indicator for a student's having high or low
income. We then test whether each college's high-income or
low-income interaction is statistically significantly different from
zero. Thus, we test, specifically, whether high- and low-income students
who apply to the same college are differentially likely to enroll in it.
We also estimate a variant of this model in which we include an
indicator variable for each number of colleges to which the student
applied: 1 college, 2 colleges, and so on up to 20 or more colleges.
This variant tests whether a high- and a low-income student who apply to
the same college and the same number of colleges are differentially
likely to enroll in the college in question.
Because so few high-income students apply to nonselective and
low-selectivity colleges, many of the high-income x college interactions
are dropped by the regression. Therefore, the effect of income on
enrolling in such colleges, conditional on having applied, is not
identified.
Note that the tests subsume colleges' admissions decisions.
That is, if we find that high- and low-income students are equally
likely to enroll in a college, conditional on having applied to it and
to the same number of colleges, they must be getting treated similarly
in the admissions process. Otherwise, they would enroll differentially
simply because they had been admitted differentially. (27) Moreover, if
we find that high- and low-income students are equally likely to enroll
in a college, conditional on having applied to it (regardless of the
number of colleges to which they applied), not only must they be treated
similarly in the admissions process, but they must also typically apply
to the same number of colleges. (28)
Table 5 shows the results from these estimations. The table is
organized by colleges' median test scores, with more selective
colleges closer to the top. We find that only very small shares of low-
and high-income enrollment probabilities (conditional on applying) are
statistically significantly different from one another at the 5 percent
level. For instance, low-income enrollment probabilities differ from
high-income enrollment probabilities in only 4 percent of the colleges
that have median scores at the 90th percentile or above. This is about
what one would expect from a test at the 5 percent level. The remaining
rows of the table contain similar results, all suggesting that low- and
high-income students do not enroll differentially, conditional on
applying. The results are very similar when the estimation includes an
indicator for each number of colleges to which a student applies.
Our test for differential progress toward a degree, conditional on
the school at which a student initially enrolled, is constructed in an
analogous way. The dependent variable is now the percentage of
coursework toward a 4-year degree that the student appears to have
completed as of June 2012. (29) A student who is making on-time progress
should have completed 100 percent of his or her coursework by then. We
estimate a fixed effect for every college so that students are compared
to others who enrolled in the same school. We interact the fixed effects
with high- and low-income indicators, and we test whether these
interactions are statistically significantly different. Again, the
effects for nonselective and low-selectivity colleges are not identified
because so few high-income students enroll in them.
The left-hand column of table 6, which is organized in much the
same way as table 5, shows the results from this estimation. For
selective colleges, we find that only very small shares of colleges have
statistically significant differences between the progress of their low-
and of their high-income students. For instance, low-income
students' progress toward a degree differs from high-income
students' progress toward a degree at only 5 percent of the
colleges that have median scores at the 90th percentile or above. This
is what one would expect from a test at the 5 percent level.
The right-hand column of table 6 reports results of reestimating
the model excluding low-income students who attend selective and magnet
high schools. The reestimation addresses the possibility that
achievement-typical students perform well in college because, although
poor, they attended high schools that offer unusually strong
preparation. (This is true of some but not most achievement-typical
students, as shown below.) We obtain very similar results.
There are two key takeaways from this subsection. First, the
application stage is where interesting differences appear in the
behavior of high-income high achievers and low-income high achievers. If
they apply to the same colleges, their educational paths are similar
afterward. Thus, interventions that could make low-income high
achievers' college careers look more like those of their
high-income counterparts must, as a logical matter, be focused on the
application stage or preparation for it. Second, the data do not suggest
that low-income students who currently fail to apply to selective
colleges and therefore fail to attend one would be rejected or would
perform badly if they were admitted and enrolled. Of course, we cannot
say that they would do just as well as the low-income students who do
apply. One would need to induce low-income students to apply to
substantially more selective schools and then estimate causal effects to
make such a claim. We do not attempt to do that in this paper. (30)
However, we are certainly not struck by evidence that low-income
students have poor outcomes when they apply to selective schools.
V. Factors That Predict a Student's Being Achievement-Typical
or Income-Typical
In this section, we use simple descriptive statistics to identify
some factors that predict whether a low-income student is
achievement-typical or income-typical. Our goal in this section is to
characterize the two types of low-income students sufficiently well that
we can build hypotheses about why they apply to colleges so differently.
Ex ante, our hypotheses fall into three broad categories:
(i) Despite the fact that both income-typical and
achievement-typical students have estimated family incomes in the bottom
quartile, income-typical students are actually socioeconomically
disadvantaged compared to achievement-typical students when we examine
their backgrounds more carefully. Given their greater disadvantage, they
cannot be expected to behave similarly.
(ii) Income-typical students are likely to be poorly informed about
college compared to achievement-typical students.
(iii) Income-typical students are making rational, well-informed
choices about college. Their utility from attending nonselective or less
selective colleges exceeds the utility they would derive from attending
more selective colleges.
We can look for evidence of hypotheses in categories (i) and (ii).
The hypothesis in category (iii) is inherently untestable, so it is
effectively the residual explanation if there is no evidence for other
hypotheses. Note that if hypothesis (iii) is the true one, students need
not get more utility from attending a nonselective college because it is
a good academic match for them. A student might attend a school that is
obviously a poor academic match because it enables him or her, say, to
look after his or her family. The student might derive sufficient
utility from doing this so that his or her college choice is utility
maximizing. Cultural and social factors that deter students from
applying would also fall under hypothesis (iii). For instance, a student
might feel that he or she would enjoy a better social life if he or she
attended school with people from a very similar background.
Table 7 reports statistics on several characteristics of the
families of high-achieving students that might reveal that
income-typical students are truly socioeconomically disadvantaged
relative to achievement-typical students. These statistics tend to go
the wrong way for hypotheses of type (i). Income-typical students have
slightly higher estimated family income than achievement-typical
students do. Their (admittedly very flawed) reports of parents'
education suggest that income-typical students' parents might have
0.7 years more of education than those of achievement-typical students.
Achievement-typical students are more likely to be black or Hispanic, so
they are presumably more, not less, likely to have experienced
discrimination or to expect to experience it in college.
Table 8 reports statistics on several neighborhood factors that are
useful for assessing hypotheses of both types (i) and (ii). A
person's neighbors reveal something about his or her own
socioeconomic disadvantage, but they also reveal something about the
information he or she is likely to encounter. The statistics show that
income-typical and achievement-typical students live in Census block
groups with very similar average family income. However,
achievement-typical students' block groups are less white, and more
black, Hispanic, and Asian than those of income-typical students.
Achievement-typical students also have more baccalaureate degree holders
in their block groups, both in absolute number (207 versus 144) and as a
share of adults (22.0 percent versus 16.8 percent). This last fact
suggests that income-typical students may be less likely to get advice
about college from a neighbor with a degree.
Table 9 compares the geography of income-typical and
achievement-typical students, and the contrast is striking. Sixty-five
percent of achievement-typical students live in the main city of an
urban area, whereas only 30 percent of income-typical students do. Even
within main city residents, achievement-typical students are much more
likely to live in a large urban area (one with population greater than
250,000). Indeed, 70 percent of the achievement-typical students come
from just 15 metropolitan areas (out of 334 nationwide): San Francisco,
Oakland, Los Angeles, San Diego, Dallas, Houston, Chicago, Cleveland,
Pittsburgh, Portland (Maine), Boston, Providence, New York,
Philadelphia, and Baltimore. (31)
Only 21 percent of achievement-typical students live in a nonurban
area (not necessarily rural, but a town rather than an urban-area
suburb). By contrast, 47 percent of income-typical students live in a
nonurban area. Put another way, income-typical students tend to be the
high achievers who live in counties that have a large number of high
achievers per 17-year-old (figure 7) but not a large number of achievers
in absolute terms (figure 6).
Using administrative data from the U.S. Department of Education,
table 10 compares the high schools attended by income-typical and
achievement typical students. These statistics should help us to assess
these students' academic disadvantages and the amount of
college-related information they might obtain at school.
Achievement-typical students are considerably more likely to attend a
school that is classified as a magnet school or an independent (as
opposed to religious) private school. These statistics certainly
understate the extent to which the achievement-typical students attend
high schools that admit students on the basis of exams or grades.
Chester Finn and Jessica Hockett (2012) find that only a small share of
such high schools are classified as magnet schools. (32) Spending per
pupil at achievement-typical students' public schools is higher,
but since facilities and staff costs are often higher in the urban areas
where they tend to live, it is unclear whether the higher spending
actually gives them an advantage. Pupil-teacher and pupil-counselor
ratios are fairly similar for achievement-typical and income-typical
students: 18.3 versus 17.2, and 328 versus 305.
Using survey data from the Schools and Staffing Surveys from 1987
to 2007 and data on previous cohorts from the College Board and ACT,
table 11 compares college-related factors at the high schools attended
by achievement-typical and income-typical students. (33) The first
striking statistic in the table is what a tiny share of low-income
students' teachers graduated from colleges that would be peer or
safety colleges for high-achieving students. Only 1.1 percent of
income-typical students' teachers attended peer colleges, and only
5.0 percent attended safety colleges. The shares are larger for
achievement-typical students teachers, but still not large: 2.9 percent
from peer colleges and 7.5 percent from safety colleges. Even
high-income students do not encounter many teachers with degrees from
very selective colleges.
Income-typical students attend high schools where just 1.6 students
in a typical previous cohort applied to one of the 10 most selective
colleges in the United States. (34) In contrast, 7.6 students applied to
these colleges in a typical previous cohort of achievement-typical
students' schools. Thus, compared to an income-typical student, an
achievement-typical student would be much more likely to vicariously
experience the process of applying to a very selective college, through
an upperclassman. In addition, only 3.8 percent (including the student)
of the average income-typical student's high school class, compared
with 11.2 percent of the average achievement-typical student's
class, are high achievers themselves. Since income-typical
students' high schools are, on average, less than two-thirds the
size of achievement-typical students' high schools, these low
percentages translate into very little school-based contact with other
high achievers. The low percentages also suggest that their counselors
are unaccustomed to advising students who have opportunities to attend
selective colleges.
Of course, one might gather and advise a critical mass of high
achievers outside of the high school setting, but the bottom rows of
table 11 show that even this is difficult for income-typical students.
The radius needed to gather 50 high achievers is 37.3 miles for the
average income-typical student, but only 12.2 miles for the average
achievement-typical student. Since a college access program cannot
expect to get participation from every qualified student in the area it
covers, the radii shown suggest that most income-typical students cannot
be reached by programs that require a critical mass of high achievers to
operate at efficient scale.
VI. Thought Experiments: Interventions That Might Inform
Income-Typical Students
In this section we consider a few interventions that might affect
how informed income-typical students are about their college-going
opportunities. We do this because, as shown in the previous section, the
data evince no support for hypothesis i (that income-typical students
are actually more disadvantaged than achievement-typical ones) so that
we are left with hypotheses ii (students are poorly informed) and iii
(students are well informed and utility-maximizing). One way to assess
hypothesis ii is to consider what information actually reaches or could
reach income-typical students. After all, they are low-income high
achievers who are apparently desirable applicants. Why should they not,
for instance, become informed by their counselors or by traditional
college recruitment methods?
VI.A. Traditional Interventions
Colleges often send admissions staff to high schools to recruit
high-achieving students. Therefore, consider a thought experiment in
which any student who attends a high school that contains at least 20
high-achieving students will have contact with some college admissions
staff. (We chose a cutoff of 20 because it is expensive in time and
money for admissions staff to visit high schools in which they cannot
fill at least a classroom with potential applicants.) If this experiment
occurred, 92 percent of high-income high achievers and 66 percent of
achievement-typical students would have contact with admissions staff,
but only 17 percent of income-typical students would have such contact.
Of course, admissions staff can hold evening or weekend events that
students from multiple high schools can attend. Thus, we should also
consider what would happen if admissions staff visited every location in
the United States where they could gather at least 20 high-achieving
students from a 10-mile radius. Such visits would ensure that 94 percent
of high-income high achievers and 73 percent of achievement-typical
students could meet with admissions staff. But such visits would allow
only 21 percent of income-typical students to meet admissions staff.
Clearly, admissions staff visiting students is unlikely to be an
effective method of informing income-typical students. What about
students visiting colleges? As another thought experiment, consider what
would happen if every high-achieving student visited colleges if he or
she could reach five peer colleges by traveling 2,000 miles or less.
Then 75 percent of high-income high achievers and 71 percent of
achievement-typical students would do a college "tour." Only
22 percent of income-typical students would.
In fact, remembering that 70 percent of achievement-typical
students are drawn from only 15 urban areas, we note that many of these
students need not travel out of town at all to visit one or more
selective colleges. Without needing anything other than a subway pass, a
New York City student could easily visit Columbia University, Barnard
College, New York University, Cooper Union, and at least six other
colleges ranked at least "very competitive" by Barron's.
A student living in Boston, Chicago, Los Angeles, Philadelphia, or the
San Francisco Bay area would also be spoiled for choice. Even a student
from Portland, Maine--an area that might have seemed out of place on our
list of 15 urban areas--has Bates, Bowdoin, Colby, and Dartmouth (all
very selective institutions) within a modest radius. In fact, we know
from colleges' own published materials and communications with
their authors that many colleges make great efforts to seek out
low-income students from their metropolitan areas. These strategies,
although probably successful, fall somewhat under the heading of
"searching under the lamppost." That is, many colleges look
for low-income students where the college is instead of looking for
low-income students where the students are.
We have already seen that income-typical students are very unlikely
to encounter a teacher, counselor, or neighbor who attended a selective
college himself or herself. Furthermore, income-typical students'
counselors (each of whom typically manages a roster of hundreds of
students) cannot be expected to develop expertise about very selective
colleges, given the rarity with which they are called upon to advise
high achievers. Indeed, at College Board sessions attended by the
authors, several counselors reported that when the rare student in their
school was qualified to attend very selective colleges, they told him to
guide himself or herself by gathering information on the Internet
because they themselves lacked expertise. This is despite the fact that
counselors who attend College Board sessions are probably more
sophisticated and informed than the average counselor.
The logic that makes admissions staff visits ineffective with
income-typical students works similarly for after-school or weekend
college mentoring programs: programs with sustainable costs are unlikely
to reach income-typical students. Of course, college mentoring programs
do exist in areas where income-typical students live, but the typical
program focuses on motivating students merely to attend college--not on
the decisions faced by high-achieving students with many college
opportunities. The typical program also does not provide much advice on
negotiating the multilayered application process that very selective
colleges use.
What about mailing brochures with a specialized letter to students
who live in ZIP codes where most families are poor? This strategy might
work in the very largest urban areas, particularly if they are densely
populated, but it cannot work well outside them. The United States
Postal Service defines ZIP codes with the goal of making mail delivery
efficient, not with the goal of identifying families with similar
incomes. In a place like Manhattan, a ZIP code might be physically small
enough to contain families with fairly uniform socioeconomics. In
smaller cities and rural areas, though, the typical ZIP code contains
families with diverse incomes, ensuring that mail campaigns targeted to
high-poverty ZIP codes systematically fail to reach most low-income
students.
VI.B. Novel Interventions
What, then, are some interventions that might inform income-typical
students about college and that might overcome the challenge of serving
high achievers who are geographically dispersed? First, a college has
many more alumni than admissions staff, and alumni are much more broadly
distributed geographically than admissions staff. For instance, the
anonymous private, very selective university studied by Jonathan Meer
and Harvey Rosen (2012) has at least one alumnus or alumna in nearly
every U.S. county. (35) Presumably, colleges could give their alumni the
names of local students who appear on the search lists of students who
are likely qualified for admission. Such alumni-based information
interventions could potentially overcome the lack of geographic
concentration among income-typical students. The main challenges for
such interventions would seem to be the need to coordinate and inform
alumni. It would be problematic, for instance, if alumni knew very
little about their college's current curriculum or financial aid
policies.
Income-typical students are intelligent and able to absorb written
material. Thus, other interventions that might affect them would be
purely informational ones, whether distributed by mail, online, or
through social media. To be effective, however, such interventions must
be much better targeted to low-income students than a campaign based on
ZIP codes. Also, they cannot simply replicate the content that students
already receive in the form of numerous college brochures. The two most
obvious deficiencies of these brochures are that they are generic rather
than customized to a student's situation (for instance, the
student's family finances), and that they have a boosterism that
may make it difficult for students to derive information from them.
Taking these points to heart, we test several interventions in Hoxby and
Sarah Turner (2013) that have the potential to identify causal effects
of giving low-income students information about their college-going
opportunities.
VI.C. Recruiting Athletes versus Recruiting Low-Income High
Achievers
Colleges seem able to identify and recruit students who are top
athletes. (36) Should they therefore be able to identify and recruit the
vast majority of low-income high achievers? Our analysis suggests that
not only is the answer no, but that athletes are the exception that
proves the rule.
Regardless of how dispersed they are, it is easy for colleges to
identify top athletes. Any top athlete who participates in an individual
sport can be easily found on lists of state finalists, often as early as
the 10th grade. Most recruited athletes who play team sports also
generate statistics (such as rushing yards) that are readily available,
or play for a team that participates in state competitions. Even
athletes who play only a team sport and whose home team is mediocre can
be readily identified by the coaches of the top state teams with whom
they compete: "John Smith from High School X is a great running
back, even though his team has a mediocre record." (37)
Our conversations with college athletic directors suggest that they
use simple, traditional recruiting methods to find athletes. The same
methods would not work with low-income high achievers. Again, we
emphasize that the data and analytics used in this paper are not
available to colleges.
VII. Conclusions
We have demonstrated that the majority of high-achieving,
low-income students do not apply to any selective colleges despite
apparently being well qualified for admission. These income-typical
students exhibit behavior that is typical of students of their income
rather than typical of students of their achievement. There are,
however, high-achieving, low-income students who apply to college in
much the same way as their high-income counterparts. These
achievement-typical students also enroll and persist in college like
their high-income counterparts.
There are several plausible explanations for income-typical
students' behavior:
(i) they cannot afford to attend peer institutions;
(ii) they are actually more disadvantaged than achievement-typical
students and therefore behave differently;
(iii) they would fail to be admitted to peer institutions or would
fail to thrive at them, were they to apply;
(iv) they are poorly informed about their college-going
opportunities;
(v) they have cultural, social, or family issues that make them
unwilling to apply to peer institutions, even if they are confident of
being admitted and succeeding academically.
We believe we have eliminated explanations (i) and (ii). What is
especially striking is that income-typical students pay more to attend
less selective colleges than they would pay to attend peer institutions.
Our evidence also does not support explanation (iii) since we find
that--if they apply--low-income high achievers enroll and persist at the
same rates as high-income students with the same test scores.
Nevertheless, we cannot definitively test explanation (iii) in this
paper. We are mainly left with explanations (iv) and (v), both of which
are compatible with the fact that income-typical students are fairly
isolated. Hoxby and Turner (2013) rigorously test explanations (iii) and
(iv), leaving (v) as the residual explanation.
In this paper we have demonstrated that achievement-typical
students not only come disproportionately from the central cities of
large urban areas but are likely to attend selective, magnet, or other
feeder high schools. A majority of achievement-typical students are
drawn from only 15 urban areas, each of which has at least one and often
several selective colleges. We show that traditional recruiting methods
are likely to work better in large, dense urban areas and in the
immediate vicinity of the college itself. Probably unintentionally,
colleges end up looking for low-income students where the college is,
instead of looking for low-income students where the students are. Thus,
they recruit the low-income students "under the lamppost" but
fail to identify the vast majority of others. We speculate that
admissions staff believe that the supply of low-income high achievers is
inelastic for two reasons. Many of these students are not on the radar
screen because they do not apply. Also, staff spend much of their time
informing students who attend high schools that are already so
"tapped out" that their efforts merely shift students among
colleges but fail to expand the number of low-income, high-achieving
applicants.
Even if we knew for certain that income-typical students behaved as
they do because they are poorly informed (as opposed to being deterred
by cultural factors), we would not attribute blame to colleges,
counselors, or the students themselves. Income-typical students are
insufficiently geographically concentrated to be reached,
cost-effectively, by traditional methods of informing students about
their college opportunities. Their high school counselors cannot be
expected to develop expertise about selective colleges when doing so is
rarely relevant to their duties, which require them to advise hundreds
of students on myriad issues. Low-income high achievers are not
necessarily less enterprising than their high-income counterparts; they
simply do not have parents or counselors who ensure that they know
something about peer institutions.
Our results suggest that interventions likely to affect low-income
high achievers' college-going behavior will be ones that do not
depend, for their efficacy, on the students being concentrated in a
limited number of schools or small geographic areas.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS For inspiration, generous help with data, and
numerous useful suggestions, we thank the College Board and ACT. These
two organizations' dedication to providing students with
well-informed college application advice is the reason that this
research exists. We have been especially helped by Connie Betterton,
Michael Matthews, Anne Sturvenant, Ryan Williams, and Robert Ziomek. For
important comments and suggestions we thank Sarah Turner, Amanda
Pallais, Eric Bettinger, Scott Carrell, Charles Clotfelter, Susan
Dynarski, Bridget Long, Parag Pathak, Bruce Sacerdote, Douglas Staiger,
Jacob Vigdor, and the editors.
References
Avery, Christopher, and Caroline Hoxby. 2004. "Do and Should
Financial Aid Packages Affect Students' College Choices?" In
College Choices: The Economics of Where to Go, When to Go, and How to
Pay For It, edited by C. Hoxby. University of Chicago Press.
Avery, Christopher, and Sarah Turner. 2009. "Aid and
Application Awareness." Harvard Kennedy School and University of
Virginia.
Avery, Christopher, Mark Glickman, Caroline Hoxby, and Andrew
Metrick. 2013. "A Revealed Preference Ranking of American Colleges
and Universities." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 128 (1):
425-467.
Avery, Christopher, Caroline Hoxby, Clement Jackson, Kaitlin Burek,
Glenn Pope, and Mridula Raman. 2006. "Cost Should Be No Barrier: An
Evaluation of the First Year of Harvard's Financial Aid
Initiative." Working Paper no. 12029. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Bowen, William, Matthew Chingos, and Michael McPherson. 2009.
Crossing the Finish Line: Completing College at America's Public
Universities. Princeton University Press.
Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 2005. "Would the Elimination
of Affirmative Action Affect Highly Qualified Minority Applicants?
Evidence from California and Texas." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 58, no. 3: 416-34.
Dillon, Eleanor, and Jeffrey Smith. 2012. "Determinants of
Mismatch between Student Ability and College Quality." University
of Michigan.
Finn, Chester, and Jessica Hockett, 2012. Shiny Needles in the
Education Haystack: America's Academically-Selective Public High
Schools. Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press.
Freeberg, Norman. 1988. "Accuracy of Student Reported
Information." College Board Report no. 88-5.
professionals.collegeboard.com/profdownload/pdf/ RR%2088-5.PDF.
Hill, Catherine, Gordon Winston, and Stephanie Boyd. 2005.
"Affordability: Family Incomes and Net Prices at Highly Selective
Private Colleges and Universities." Journal of Human Resources 40,
no. 4:769-90.
Hoxby, Caroline. 2009. "The Changing Selectivity of American
Colleges and Universities." Journal of Economic Perspectives 23,
no. 4:95-118.
Hoxby, Caroline, and Sarah Turner. 2013. "Expanding College
Opportunities for Low-Income, High-Achieving Students." SIEPR
Discussion Paper no. 12014. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Institute for
Economic Policy Research.
Meer, Jonathan, and Harvey Rosen. 2012. "Does Generosity Beget
Generosity? Alumni Giving and Undergraduate Financial Aid." Working
Paper no. w17861. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Pallais, Amanda. 2009. "Small Differences That Matter:
Mistakes in Applying to College." Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
U.S. Department of Education. Institute of Education Sciences,
National Center for Education Statistics. 2009. The Common Core of Data.
Electronic data for the 2008-09 school year. Downloaded from
http://nces.ed.gov/ccd/pubschuniv.asp.
U.S. Department of Education. Institute of Education Sciences.
National Center for Education Statistics. 2009. Private School Universe
Survey. Electronic data for the 2008-09 school year. Downloaded from
http://nces.ed.gov/surveys/pss/ pssdata.asp.
Comments and Discussion
COMMENT BY AMANDA PALLAIS
This paper by Caroline Hoxby and Christopher Avery provides a
comprehensive analysis of the differences in college application
patterns between high-achieving students of differing family incomes. It
finds that high-achieving, low-income students apply to substantially
different sets of colleges than do their higher-income peers. Over half
of the low-income group send SAT or ACT test scores to at least one
nonselective college and do not send scores to any college with a median
test score within 15 percentiles of their own score. Only 8 percent send
scores to a portfolio containing at least one "match" college,
one "safety" college, and no nonselective college.
This paper is not the first to note that low-income students apply
to different sets of colleges than high-income students (see, for
example, Spies 2001, Bowen and others 2005, and Pallais and Turner
2006). However, it is distinguished by its comprehensiveness and the
sheer amount of data that allow the authors to fully characterize the
application choices of high-achieving students. The paper starts with
data on everyone in the high school class of 2008 who took either the
ACT or the SAT I. Then it links these students to the colleges they sent
scores to, to data on their high schools, and to data on their census
block and zip code, as well as to information on whether and where they
ultimately enrolled in college and whether they had completed a 4-year
degree by 2012.
After showing the differences in application patterns between high-
and low-income high achievers, the paper considers the characteristics
both of those low-income students whose application behavior is similar
to high-income students' (what the authors call
"achievement-typical" students) and of those who do not apply
to selective institutions ("income-typical" students).
Achievement-typical students are more likely to come from schools and
neighborhoods where they could more easily obtain information about
colleges (for example, because they are more likely to have teachers who
attended selective colleges and friends from earlier cohorts who applied
to selective colleges). The paper suggests that many low-income,
high-achieving students would actually benefit from attending selective
colleges but do not apply, because unlike high-income students, they do
not have specific relevant information (for example, about the range of
colleges available, colleges' true costs, or the relevant benefits
of attending specific colleges).
A closely related explanation for low-income high achievers'
distinct application choices is that applying to college or for
financial aid is prohibitively difficult for some. For example, they may
be less likely to have parents or guidance counselors who can assist
them with the application process. This explanation also implies that
low-income high-achievers might benefit from attending selective
colleges but are failing to apply. However, if the applications
themselves are preventing these students from attending selective
colleges, simply providing more information without also assisting them
in filling out the applications (or simplifying the application process)
will not be effective. In the rest of this comment, I summarize some of
the existing literature on these two explanations as they relate to
low-income students in general, not just high-achievers. (1) This
relatively new literature provides many examples in which giving high
school students information about colleges or assistance with completing
applications affects whether and where students attend college.
A recent paper by Hoxby and Sarah Turner (2013) presents the
results of a randomized experiment with several different treatments. In
one treatment, they sent high-achieving, low-income students information
on colleges' actual net cost. (2) They found that this induced
students to apply to more colleges and raised the likelihood both of
their applying to a selective college and of their being admitted. (The
point estimate also implies that this intervention increased the
probability that students attended a selective college, but it is not
statistically significant.) Another randomized treatment sent students
information about suggested application strategies, college graduation
rates, and application deadlines. Additionally, it sent students a copy
of the Common Application (a standardized application used by many
colleges), perhaps making it easier to apply. This treatment also
induced students to send more applications and led to their being
admitted to more-selective colleges. As a result of this treatment,
students attended more-selective colleges.
Hoxby and Turner (2013) also provide evidence that application fees
present a barrier to attending selective colleges for high-achieving,
low-income students. Although low-income students can obtain fee
waivers, the process requires additional paperwork. Randomly selected
students in another treatment received fee waiver coupons in the mail
and information on where the coupons could be used. Low-income students
in this treatment also sent more applications, were admitted to
more-selective colleges, and attended more-selective colleges than a
randomly selected control group.
Eric Bettinger and others (2012) provide evidence that another
aspect of the college application process, the Free Application for
Federal Student Aid (FAFSA), is a barrier to low-income students
attending college in general. In this project, H&R Block completed
the FAFSA for randomly selected students. These students were
significantly more likely to attend college than a control group. In
contrast, students who received individualized financial aid information
and were encouraged to complete the FAFSA on their own were not more
likely to attend college than the control group.
Pallais (2012) shows that a small decrease in the cost of sending
standardized test scores to colleges can induce low-income students to
attend more-selective colleges. Before the fall of 1997, ACT allowed
students to send three score reports to colleges for free and charged $6
for each additional score report. Thereafter ACT allowed students to
send four score reports for free, with the same marginal cost for
additional reports. Before the change, 82 percent of students sent
exactly three score reports, while only 3 percent sent four. Afterward,
only 10 percent of students sent three score reports, while 74 percent
sent four. Both high- and low-income students sent more score reports as
a result of the cost change, widened the range of colleges they sent
scores to, and sent score reports both to more-selective and to less
selective colleges than they would have otherwise. However, only
low-income students ended up actually attending more-selective colleges
as a result. It could have been the actual decrease in the cost of the
fourth score report that led students to change their behavior: perhaps
the $6 was a financial barrier to applying to colleges for low-income
students. Alternatively, students could have viewed the number of free
score reports as information about the optimal number of score reports
to send, interpreting the provision of three (or four) free score
reports as reflecting ACT's informed judgment that sending three
(or four) score reports was optimal.
Sarena Goodman (2012) and George Bulman (2013) show that inducing
students to take a college entrance exam changes their college
matriculation outcomes. Goodman (2012) analyzes the effect of mandates
in some states that require all high school juniors to take the ACT. She
finds that these mandates increased the number of students who took the
ACT and did so disproportionately for low-income students. The mandates
did not change the overall college attendance rate in these states but
did substantially increase the number of students attending selective
colleges (which are much more likely to require standardized test
scores). Bulman (2013) examines the effect of opening an SAT testing
center at a student's own high school. Having such a testing center
allows students to take the SAT at their own high school rather than
travel to other local schools. He finds that opening such a center
increased the probability that a given student took the SAT and the
probability that he or she attended a selective college. Both these
effects were larger for students attending schools in low-income areas.
Finally, Scott Carrell and Bruce Sacerdote (2012) show that helping
high school students navigate the college application process can induce
these students to attend college. Their paper presents the results of a
randomized intervention targeted at high school students in the winter
of their senior year. Eligible students were identified by their
guidance counselors as those who were "on the margin" of
applying to college: they had expressed interest in applying to college
but had made little or no progress in applying. Treated students were
chosen at random from this pool. They had their application fees, SAT
fees, and ACT fees paid for them and received in-person mentoring by a
Dartmouth student. Dartmouth students also helped the students sign up
for the SAT or the ACT if they had not already done so, complete essays,
complete and file applications, request transcripts and recommendation
letters, and start the FAFSA. The mentors sometimes also provided advice
on how many and which colleges the students should apply to. Finally,
students in the treatment group received $100 for completing their
applications. This intervention substantially increased 4-year college
going among female students, but not among men. (3) The intervention
also seemed to have larger effects at more-disadvantaged high schools.
An important question is whether inducing low-income students to
attend college and to attend more-selective colleges actually benefits
them. It is hard to answer this question fully without knowing more
about students' utility functions or the information they have when
making college decisions. However, Hoxby and Avery's paper provides
evidence that low-income students actually pay less on average to attend
very selective colleges than they would to attend less selective
colleges. Moreover, research suggests that low-income students receive
particularly high returns from attending college in general (Card 1995)
and from attending more-selective colleges (Dale and Krueger 2002,
Saavedra 2008). Hoxby and Avery show that low-income students who attend
highly selective colleges have graduation rates similar to those of
high-income students attending these colleges; thus, low-income students
appear to be successful in these selective colleges. Of the studies
described above, those that followed the students who were induced by
the interventions to attend college or to attend more-selective colleges
(Hoxby and Turner 2013, Bettinger and others 2012, Sacerdote and Carrell
2012, and Bulman 2013) all find that these students have high
persistence in college. Thus, it seems likely that many low-income
students who do not already do so would benefit from attending college
and attending more-selective colleges.
REFERENCES FOR THE PALLAIS COMMENT
Bettinger, Eric P., Bridget Terry Long, Philip Oreopoulos, and Lisa
Sanbonmatsu. 2012. "The Role of Application Assistance and
Information in College Decisions: Results from the H&R Block FAFSA
Experiment." Quarterly Journal of Economics 1277, no. 3: 1205-42.
Bowen, William G., Martin A. Kurzweil, and Eugene M. Tobin. 2005.
Equity and Excellence in American Higher Education. University of
Virginia Press.
Bulman, George. 2013. "The Effect of Access to College
Assessments on Enrollment and Attainment." Working paper. Stanford
University.
Card, D. 1995. "Using Geographic Variation in College
Proximity to Estimate the Return to Schooling." In Aspects of
Labour Market Behavior: Essays in Honour of John Vanderkamp, edited by
L. N. Christofides, E. K. Grant, and R. Swidinsky. University of Toronto
Press.
Carrell, Scott E., and Bruce Sacerdote. 2012. "Late
Interventions Matter Too: The Case of College Coaching in New
Hampshire." Working Paper no. 19031. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Dale, Stacy Berg, and Alan B. Krueger. 2002. "Estimating the
Payoff to Attending a More Selective College: An Application of
Selection on Observables and Unobservables." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 117, no. 4: 1491-1527.
Ellwood, D. T., and T. J. Kane. 2000. "Who Is Getting a
College Education: Family Background and the Growing Gaps in
Enrollment." In Securing the Future: Investing in Children from
Birth to College, edited by Sheldon Danziger and Jane Waldfogel. New
York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Goodman, Sarena. 2012. "Learning from the Test: Raising
Selective College Enrollment by Providing Information." Working
paper. Columbia University and University of California, Berkeley.
Hoxby, Caroline M., and Sarah Turner. 2013 "Expanding College
Opportunities for High-Achieving, Low Income Students." SIEPR
Discussion Paper no. 12-014. Stanford Institute for Economic Policy
Research.
Pallais, Amanda. 2011. "Essays in Labor Economics." Ph.D.
dissertation. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
--. 2012. "Small Differences That Matter: Mistakes in Applying
to College." Working paper. Harvard University.
Pallais, Amanda, and Sarah Turner. 2006. "Opportunities for
Low Income Students at Top Colleges and Universities: Policy Initiatives
and the Distribution of Students." National Tax Journal 59, no. 2:
357-86.
Saavedra, Juan E. 2008. "The Returns to College Quality: A
Regression Discontinuity Analysis." Working paper. Harvard
University.
Spies, Richard R. 2001. "The Effect of Rising Costs on College
Choice: The Fourth and Final in a Series of Studies on This
Subject." Princeton University Research Report Series no. 117.
Princeton University.
(1.) Throughout the ability distribution, low-income students apply
to less selective colleges than their higher-income peers (Pallais 2011)
and, conditional on high school performance, are less likely to attend
any college (for example, Ellwood and Kane 2000). However, the
application barriers that high-achieving students face may be different
from those faced by lower-achieving students.
(2.) As the paper documents, students' net cost of attendance
after financial aid often differs substantially from colleges'
sticker prices, particularly at selective colleges.
(3.) It was not only the $100 payment that increased college going:
students receiving the whole intervention experienced large increases in
college going relative to a randomly selected group who received only
the $100 incentive.
COMMENT BY PARAG A. PATHAK
This paper by Caroline Hoxby and Christopher Avery provides
convincing evidence of the following fact: a large number of
high-achieving, low-income students systematically do not apply to
selective colleges or universities. The authors identify two major
classes of low-income college applicants. "Income-typical"
applicants apply to schools in much the same pattern as do other
students in their local area and to no schools whose median scores are
similar to their own. "Achievement-typical" applicants apply
to schools in much the same pattern as do high-income high achievers,
who are mostly from urban areas or have exposure to selective colleges.
One noteworthy feature of the low-income, high achieving students in
their sample is that most are not underrepresented minorities. The paper
nicely illustrates the importance of descriptive empirical work and the
value of a nationally representative data set.
There are some important parallels between this paper and existing
work on selective K-12 institutions in the United States. Atila
Abdulkadiroglu, Joshua Angrist, and Pathak (2012) study exam high
schools, including Boston Latin School and New York City's
Stuyvesant High School and Bronx High School of Science. In both Boston
and New York, roughly two-thirds of exam school students are eligible
for a free or subsidized lunch, an indicator of poverty. Moreover,
students enrolled in an exam school are between 1.3 and 1.5 standard
deviations ahead of their public school peers on baseline standardized
tests. Thus, they are low-income high achievers, but they are a few
years away from applying to college.
The barriers to application for these schools seem, if anything,
lower than the barriers faced by low-income, high-achieving students
when they apply to college. For instance, the schools in both cities
have long histories, they are widely known, and admission requires
completing a common application on a standardized timeline. To gauge the
extent to which applicants do not apply to a selective exam school in
Boston for seventh grade, I estimate linear probability models of
application and offers for students, controlling for their baseline test
scores and demographics. By comparing the offer probability with the
application probability, it is possible to measure the extent to which
students who seem likely to obtain an offer at a school are likely to
apply.
My table 1 reports the estimates by decile of predicted offer. An
important fact shown in the table is that a large fraction of students
who would almost certainly be offered admission to one of Boston's
exam schools do not apply. Only 75.8 percent of students in the top
decile submit an application, even though applicants in this group would
be very likely to obtain an offer given their baseline test scores and
demographics. That is, for this highest achieving, mostly low-income
population, there is roughly a one-quarter gap in the fraction of
students who apply to an exam school among those who are most likely to
be given an offer. Seen in this light, it is perhaps no longer that
surprising that for the more complicated process of applying to a
selective college or university, many students who would almost surely
be admitted do not apply.
Given the fact that Hoxby and Avery uncover, a natural question is
whether it reflects a market failure, which would rationalize some form
of policy intervention. There are many aspects to this question, and in
what follows I will only touch on a few. First, this paper and other
work by Hoxby (2009) provides evidence that more selective colleges
provide more student-oriented resources than less selective colleges, a
trend that has increased dramatically in the last two decades (see, for
example, figure 2 in Hoxby 2009). This fact, together with the likely
scenario that attendance at a selective college will cost low-income
students less, because of the college's own financial aid and other
scholarship opportunities, seems to suggest that applicants are making
suboptimal decisions. Moreover, the evidence that Hoxby and Avery
marshal about the tendency of achievement-typical students to come from
major urban areas or magnet or independent private schools seems to
imply that the income-typical applicants lack adequate information about
college, so that reducing application costs (broadly defined) seems
likely to boost demand from this population.
There has been progress in making it easier for students to
exercise their choice options for K-12 education. In districts that
allow a choice of schools to attend, through either open enrollment
plans or charters, there has been a recent push toward standard
application timelines and common, online application systems. Cities
like Denver and New Orleans have recently adopted single-offer
coordinated charter and district school admissions schemes, and new
assignment mechanisms that make it safe for participants to rank schools
truthfully have become increasingly widespread (see, for example,
Abdulkadiroglu, Pathak, and Roth 2009, Pathak 2011, Pathak and Sonmez
2008, 2013). The goal of these reforms is to increase access to
high-quality educational options for students. Unlike college
admissions, many of these reforms involve changes within existing
centralized institutions. However, it seems that decision aids,
informational cues, and further guidance would be beneficial in either a
decentralized college admissions system or a centralized assignment
mechanism.
Second, a perhaps more difficult issue for policy is related to the
fact that college admissions is an assignment market. It is possible
that low-income, high-achieving students benefit from selective colleges
and universities. However, if there are slot constraints at schools,
reforms in favor of low-income students would involve a reallocation
between these students and other students. Therefore, it seems
especially important to investigate whether low-income students benefit
more or less from selective education than other students. This may be
so either because their fallback options are not as good, or because a
selective school education creates social externalities.
Relatively few studies address these questions. Mark Hoekstra
(2009) documents earnings effects from attending a flagship state
university. Stacy Dale and Alan Krueger (2002, 2011) present
"selection-adjusted" evidence on the returns to selective
education and find some effects of attending a selective college for
students from disadvantaged family backgrounds (as measured by parental
education or income). However, identifying the causal effect of
selective colleges is a challenging issue. In particular, it seems hard
to describe a data generating process under which all selection bias
operates through the set of schools one applies to, as in Dale and
Krueger's research design. Perhaps just as important, if it were
possible to encourage low-income high-achievers to attend selective
schools, the relevant margin is probably the switch from a local
community college to a lower-end selective college, which may not be the
effect identified by Dale and Krueger. On the other hand, the evidence
from selective secondary schools seems to point to little benefit to
selective education (Bui and others 2011, Abdulkadiroglu and others
2012, Clark 2010). Without a doubt, additional research is needed to
measure the benefits of selective education. The additional work by
Hoxby and Turner (2013), foreshadowed in this paper, will likely provide
valuable evidence on this challenging empirical question.
Finally, the stylized facts documented by Hoxby and Avery indicate
another rationale for intervention, one related to issues of equity. Of
course, whether equity should be seen as a rationale for policy
intervention depends on the objective functions of colleges, and of
society more generally. These points are being brought forward in recent
policy debates. For example, a possible response to court challenges of
affirmative action is the adoption of broader income-based criteria.
Here again an important precedent at the K-12 level seems worth noting.
The 2007 Supreme Court ruling in Parents Involved in Community Schools
v. Seattle School District No. 1 has been widely seen as outlawing the
use of racial preferences in K-12 school admissions. A number of
districts throughout the country are experimenting with a redefinition
of diversity. For instance, Chicago Public Schools has established a
"tier system" for its nine selective high schools. Each census
tract in Chicago is given a socioeconomic status score based on median
family income, educational attainment, the percentage of single-parent
households, the percentage of residents who are homeowners, the
percentage that speak a language other than English, and average school
performance. At each selective school, 30 percent of seats are reserved
to be assigned on the basis of admissions test scores only, and the
remaining 70 percent are assigned according to admission test scores
within tier. It seems a good bet that school systems will continue to
experiment with like-minded policies that seek to redefine diversity for
higher education. If so, an encouraging aspect of Hoxby and Avery's
finding is that low-income, high-achieving students are plentiful, and
if Hoxby and Avery can find them, others might be able to as well.
REFERENCES FOR THE PATHAK COMMENT
Abdulkadiroglu, Atila, Parag A. Pathak, and Alvin E. Roth. 2009.
"Strategy-proofness versus Efficiency in Matching with
Indifferences: Redesigning the NYC High School Match." American
Economic Review 99, no. 5: 1954-78.
Abdulkadiroglu, Atila, Joshua D. Angrist, and Parag A. Pathak.
2012. "The Elite Illusion: Achievement Effects at Boston and New
York Exam Schools." IZA Discussion Paper no. 6790. Bonn, Germany:
Institute for the Study of Labor. (Also forthcoming in Econometrica.)
Bui, Sa A., Steven G. Craig, and Scott A. Imberman. 2011. "Is
Gifted Education a Bright Idea? Assessing the Impact of Gifted and
Talented Programs on Achievement." Working Paper no. 17089.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (May).
Clark, Damon. 2010. "Selective Schools and Academic
Achievement." B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy:
Advances 10, no. 1: article 9.
Dale, Stacy Berg, and Alan B. Krueger. 2002. "Estimating the
Payoff of Attending a More Selective College: An Application of
Selection on Observables and Unobservables." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 107, no. 4:1491-1527.
--.2011. "Estimating the Return to College Selectivity over
the Career Using Administrative Earnings Data." Working Paper no.
17159. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (June).
Hoekstra, Mark. 2009. "The Effect of Attending the Flagship
State University on Earnings: A Discontinuity-Based Approach."
Review of Economics and Statistics 91, no. 4: 717-24.
Hoxby, Caroline. 2009. "The Changing Selectivity of American
Colleges." Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, no. 4:95-118.
Hoxby, Caroline, and Sarah Turner. 2013. "Expanding
Opportunities for High-Achieving, Low Income Students." SIEPR
Discussion Paper no. 12-014. Stanford Institute for Economic Policy
Research.
Pathak, Parag A. 2011. "The Mechanism Design Approach to
Student Assignment." Annual Review of Economics 3:513-36.
Pathak, Parag A., and Tayfun Sonmez. 2008. "Leveling the
Playing Field: Sincere and Sophisticated Players in the Boston
Mechanism." American Economic Review 98, no. 4: 1636-52.
--. 2013. "School Admissions Reform in Chicago and England:
Comparing Mechanisms by Their Vulnerability to Manipulation."
American Economic Review 103, no. 1: 80-106.
Table 1. Probability of Sixth-Graders Applying to a Boston Exam
School, by Decile of Predicted Probability of Receiving an Offer
Predicted probability
Decile p of receiving an offer (a) Probability p of applying
1 0.021 0.085
2 0.042 0.111
3 0.068 0.141
4 0.105 0.178
5 0.160 0.226
6 0.237 0.286
7 0.357 0.361
8 0.520 0.460
9 0.726 0.583
10 0.927 0.758
Source: Author's calculations using data from Abdulkadiroglu,
Angrist, and Pathak (2012).
(a.) Predictions are based on baseline test scores and the following:
interactions of application year x baseline decile for both math and
English; race: sex; and whether the student is eligible for the free
school lunch program. Students classified as having limited English
proficiency or as in special education are excluded.
GENERAL DISCUSSION
Donald Kohn wondered what incentives selective colleges have to
find and admit high-performing low-income students. Noting that most
available diversity statistics measure racial and ethnic diversity and
not income diversity, Kohn speculated that admissions officers have less
of an incentive to search out high-performing, low-income students who
are not members of historically disfavored racial and ethnic groups. He
also asked, given the recent drop in male college application and
completion rates, whether the missing high-performing, low-income
students were predominantly male.
Justin Wolfers mentioned that he had written an op-ed with Betsey
Stevenson describing Hoxby and Avery's results, which had led the
president of the University of Michigan to inquire about the results and
how the university might utilize them. That indicated that at least one
selective university was interested in improving its recruitment of
high-performing low-income students.
Benjamin Friedman observed that the geographic distribution of the
"missing" high-performing, low-income students in the
authors' data appeared to be correlated with current political
patterns in the United States: relatively larger numbers of such
students tend to be found in the "red" (Republican-leaning)
states. He thought this correlation might offer some clues for
understanding why these students were "missing."
Robert Gordon questioned the assumption in the discussion thus far
that improving the situation of high-performing, low-income students
would yield a net gain to society. A student who is admitted to and
attends Harvard instead of a Chicago community college almost surely
reaps a lifetime benefit, but that student displaces another student
from attending Harvard, who then attends a slightly less prestigious
school. That displaced student in turn displaces another student at that
school, and so on. The sum of these displaced students' lost
utilities, Gordon argued, should be taken into account in any net social
welfare calculation. Gordon further noted that the shares of black and
Hispanic students among the population of high-performing, low-income
students are lower than their shares in the overall population.
Raquel Fernandez wondered how much additional financial aid is
being allocated to high-performing, low-income students and what that
might imply for colleges' incentive to admit them. She also asked
whether it would it be possible for a high school student's
performance information to be automatically made available to selective
colleges when the student takes a standardized test.
Citing his own experience as a parent of high school students,
Michael Klein proposed that the largest component of the cost of
applying to any given college might be the cost of making a campus
visit. He wondered how many students attend a college that they had not
first visited, and how many high-performing, low-income students are
prevented from attending colleges appropriate to their ability by the
cost of visiting.
Betsey Stevenson suggested that family issues may help explain why
some high-performing, low-income students do not go to the most
competitive colleges. For instance, firstborn children might have
responsibilities for younger siblings that prevent them from going away
to college. In terms of the things over which colleges have more
influence, she argued that it might be the perceived, not the actual,
cost of a selective college that is deterring applications: many
low-income applicants might be poorly informed about the true cost of
attending college.
Gary Burtless cited a possible adverse consequence of increasing
the number of high-performing, low-income applicants to elite colleges.
He recalled reviewing a recent book by Charles Murray that showed that
in the 1940s, students at elite universities scored only slightly
better, on average, on standardized tests than students at a cross
section of Pennsylvania universities. Given that elite universities now
accept high-performing students almost exclusively, the distribution of
high-performing, low-income students by selectivity of their college is
roughly the same today in as the 1940s, but the distribution of other
high-performing students has become significantly more concentrated. If
that trend were to continue so that all high-performing students ended
up attending elite colleges, it would contribute to what Murray saw as
an increasing divide between the elite and the rest in society.
Supporting Burtless's point, Gordon noted that until roughly 1960,
the majority of Harvard students were from college preparatory schools,
but from then on more public high school graduates than college prep
graduates attended.
Alexandre Mas observed that colleges generally do a better job of
recruiting high-achieving athletes than of recruiting high academic
achievers. Could colleges use their athletic recruitment policies as a
model for recruiting more high-performing, low-income students? Laurence
Ball added that it was absurd to imagine that there are students capable
of playing intercollegiate basketball at UCLA or Duke but not applying
there and ending up at local community colleges instead.
Ricardo Reis asked how the authors reconciled their finding of
large benefits from attending an elite college with those of other
studies, such as by Parag Pathak, that find little value added from
attending an elite high school. Reis noted that students can apply to
elite schools at any of three different levels: high school,
undergraduate, or graduate school. But the differences in family income
among attendees of elite high schools are less pronounced than those for
attendees of undergraduate colleges, and applicants to graduate schools
are less tied to their city or state of origin. This suggested to Reis
that, of the three levels, only for undergraduate college is geography
the binding constraint on elite school attendance for high-performing
low-income students.
Willaim Brainard agreed with Stevenson that students face important
information constraints in deciding which college to apply to. Even many
Yale faculty members and administrators, he reported, cannot accurately
state the current cost of a year's tuition at Yale. Brainard
suspected that many high-performing students do not apply to elite
colleges because they think, mistakenly, that they have a negligible
chance of being admitted, or if admitted, being able to afford the cost.
Bradford DeLong observed that the number of undergraduate students
at Harvard has roughly tripled since the end of the 19th century, from
about 500 then to about 1,600 currently. But the number of qualified
individuals who might want to attend Harvard has increased by a factor
of at least 10 over the same period. The result has been a substantial
increase in selectivity, which means that a student's best strategy
is to submit many applications and hope for a good draw from what has
become largely a random selection process.
David Romer noted that many colleges like to have students from all
50 states. He wondered how well these colleges do at finding
high-achieving students from small states who do not attend high schools
with large numbers of high achievers.
Responding to the discussion, Caroline Hoxby remarked that
selective colleges today are quite eager to diversify their student
bodies by recruiting more low-income students--so eager that some,
regrettably, have been willing to lower their admission standards to do
so. These colleges would much prefer to find low-income students who
meet their standards and can do the academic work, because such students
are less likely to fail to keep up or to become segregated in the easier
majors. The problem, Hoxby said, is not in locating high achievers and
sending them information: colleges can easily buy lists of high-scoring
students from the College Board and ACT; indeed, college applicants
today are inundated with brochures, catalogs, application forms, and the
like--to say nothing of the vast amount of information now available
through the Internet. Part of the problem is that most students have
great difficulty navigating this sea of information without help from
more knowledgeable people, and such people tend to be scarce in the
homes, schools, and neighborhoods of low-income students.
Once a high-achieving, low-income student has applied to a
selective college, Hoxby continued, the college will likely make every
effort to recruit him or her--offering all-expense-paid visits, for
example, or even sending admissions staff to the student's home.
But many high-achieving, low-income students, precisely because they
lack adequate guidance about the opportunities available to them, never
apply. Hence they remain invisible to the selective colleges that are so
assiduously looking for them.
Hoxby also addressed the question of whether admitting more
low-income students to highly selective colleges simply displaces other
students to slightly less selective colleges, thus negating any net
social gain. She noted that before the financial crisis, several of the
nation's most selective colleges, including Harvard and Stanford,
had made plans to expand their freshman classes. Princeton actually did
so. In principle, then, the displacement problem could--and may yet--be
avoided. A concern, however, has been that higher-income students would
end up taking most of the new slots. Thus, the paper's finding that
many more low-income high achievers are out there than had been widely
believed should encourage these schools to proceed with their
expansions.
More broadly, Hoxby thought it a mistake to view college admissions
as a zero-sum game in which selective colleges have a fixed quantity of
resources to allocate among a fixed number of successful applicants.
That might be the case in the short run, she said, but the long run
presents a very different picture. Selective colleges seldom recoup
their operational costs from tuition and other upfront revenue--even
most of their higher-income students pay no more than about half the
true cost of their education. Rather, the books for a given graduating
class balance only decades later, as donations from successful--and
grateful--alumni flow in. Hoxby added that although in the short run a
college might lose more, because of financial aid, on its low-income
students than on the average student, often it is the low-income
students, mindful of the enormous difference the college has made in
their lives, who become the most loyal and generous alumni.
Finally, Hoxby argued that although streamlining the college
application process was surely part of the solution, it might
inadvisable if by "streamlining" one means reducing the amount
of information collected. After all, the aid package that a low-income
applicant to a highly selective college receives can be worth nearly
half a million dollars. Just as a bank considering a $500,000 small
business loan will require extensive information about the
borrower's business plan, so it is only reasonable for a college to
scrutinize each financial aid applicant carefully, to decide whether he
or she is a good investment.
Christopher Avery added, replying to Donald Kohn, that colleges are
in fact facing strong pressure to admit more low-income students. One
source of that pressure, he said, was the increasing availability of
rankings of colleges by their percentage of students who are eligible
for Pell grants.
Replying to a point in Amanda Pallais's comment, Avery agreed
that it was important for low-income high achievers to apply to many
selective colleges rather than a few, because although the average aid
package at such colleges is generous, the distribution of aid offers is
fairly wide. He also agreed with Pallais that even though the cost of
applying to a college is typically negligible relative to the potential
long-run benefits of attending, it nevertheless seems to be a behavioral
sticking point for many students. That underlined for him the importance
of fee waivers for low-income applicants.
CAROLINE HOXBY
Stanford University
CHRISTOPHER AVERY
Harvard Kennedy School
(1.) Hereafter, "low-income" and "high-income"
mean, respectively, the bottom and top quartiles of the income
distribution of families with a child who is a high school senior.
"High-achieving" refers to a student who scores at or above
the 90th percentile on the ACT comprehensive or the SAT I (math and
verbal) and who has a high school grade point average of A- or above.
This is approximately 4 percent of U.S. high school students. When we
say "selective college" in a generic way, we refer to colleges
and universities that are in the categories from "Very Competitive
Plus" to "Most Competitive" in Barron's Profiles of
American Colleges. There were 236 such colleges in the 2008 edition.
Together, these colleges have enrollments equal to 2.8 times the number
of students who scored at or above the 90th percentile on the ACT or the
SAT I. Later in the paper, we are much more specific about
colleges' selectivity: we define schools that are
"reach," "peer," and "safety" for an
individual student, based on a comparison between that student's
college aptitude test scores and the median aptitude test scores of
students enrolled at the school.
(2.) Note that such a student's out-of-pocket costs (including
loans), in absolute terms, peak at private colleges of middling to low
selectivity. This is because these colleges have little in the way of
endowment with which to subsidize low-income students and receive no
funding from their state government (as public colleges do) with which
to subsidize students. Moreover, the most selective colleges spend
substantially more on each student's education than is paid by even
those students who receive no financial aid (Hoxby, 2009). Thus, when a
low-income student attends a very selective college, he or she gets not
only financial aid but also the subsidy received by every student there.
(3.) In order to guarantee low-income students that they are at no
disadvantage in admissions, many colleges maintain "Chinese
Walls" between their admissions and financial aid offices.
Consequently, many schools can only precisely identify low-income
students once they have been admitted. However, admissions officers
target recruiting by analyzing applicants' essays, their
teachers' letters of recommendation, their parents' education,
and their attendance at an "underresourced" high school.
(4.) Even highly endowed colleges cannot afford to have their
admissions staff personally visit many more than 100 high schools a
year, and there were more than 20,000 public and more than 8,000 private
high schools nationwide in the school year relevant to our study.
(5.) Colleges routinely purchase "search files" from the
College Board and ACT that contain names and addresses of students whose
test scores fall in certain ranges (and who agree to be
"searched"). The colleges can then purchase marketing
information on which ZIP codes have low median incomes. The materials
they send to students in such ZIP codes typically include, in addition
to their usual brochures, a letter describing their financial aid and
other programs that support low-income students.
(6.) These schools are informally known as "feeders."
Feeder schools are often selective schools (schools that admit students
on the basis of exams or similar criteria), magnet schools, or schools
that enroll a subpopulation of low-income students despite having most
of their students drawn from high-income, highly educated families.
(7.) Since the vast majority of college mentoring programs rely on
students to self-select into their activities, it is unclear whether
they identify students who would otherwise be unknown to colleges or
merely serve as a channel for students to identify themselves as good
college prospects.
(8.) This practice is controversial. Since the organization may
merely be moving low-income students to colleges that pay from colleges
that do not, some admissions staff suspect that poaching (not expansion
of the pool of low-income applicants) is the reason that the
organization can fulfill the guarantees. They suspect that some very
selective colleges are able to look good at the expense of others, with
little net change in the lives of low-income students. Another
controversial aspect is that low-income students who allow themselves to
be funneled by the organization do not get to consider the full range of
admissions offers they could obtain.
(9.) In this paragraph, we draw upon personal communications
between the authors and many college admissions staff, including those
who attend the conferences of the College Board, the Consortium for
Financing Higher Education, and the Association of Black Admissions and
Financial Aid Officers of the Ivy League and Sister Schools
(ABAFAOILSS).
(10.) Much of the data we use are available only to researchers.
Moreover, the analytics involved are far beyond the capacity of the
institutional research groups of even the best endowed colleges. We have
worked for almost a decade to build the database and analysis that
support this paper.
(11.) The cutoff is 1300 for combined mathematics and verbal
("Critical Reading") scores on the SAT. The cutoff is 29 for
the ACT composite score.
(12.) We also considered excluding students who had taken no
subject tests, since some selective colleges require them. (Subject
tests include SAT II tests, Advanced Placement tests, and International
Baccalaureate tests.) However, we dropped this criterion for a few
reasons. First, many selective colleges do not require subject tests or
make admissions offers conditional on a student taking subject tests and
passing them. Second, among SAT I takers, few students were excluded by
this criterion. Third, ACT comprehensive takers usually take subject
tests offered by the College Board or International Baccalaureate. When
we attempt to match students between these data sources, errors occur so
that at least some of the exclusions are false.
We match students between the ACT comprehensive and the SAT I to
ensure that we do not double-count high-achieving students. However,
this match is easier than matching the ACT comprehensive takers to
College Board subject tests, which students often take as sophomores or
juniors in high school.
(13.) Approximately 2,400,000 students per cohort take a College
Board test, and approximately 933,000 students per cohort take the ACT.
(14.) Since we require microdata to create the relevant
distribution, our source for this information is the American Community
Survey 2008.
(15.) We obtain these numbers by counting the number of high
achievers whose estimated family income puts them in the bottom quartile
of family income. We subtract a number corresponding to our false
positive rate and add a number corresponding to our false negative rate.
There are two reasons why this procedure gives us a range rather than an
exact number. First, many high achievers appear in both the College
Board and ACT data. We cannot definitively eliminate all of the
duplicates because their names, addresses, and birthdates often do not
exactly match in the two data sets. Eliminating all possible duplicates
pushes us toward the lower bound. Second, although our false positive
rate is robust to the aid data we use, our false negative rate is not.
This is because the false negatives are low-income students who come
from block groups where only a small percentage of families have low
incomes. Our aid data from such block groups are fairly sparse, and we
are therefore not confident about whether we can extrapolate the false
negative rate to areas that appear similar but where we have never
observed a false negative. Extrapolating pushes us toward the upper
bound.
(16.) We do not attempt to correct these data for biases because we
do not have verified data on parents' education that we could use
to estimate the errors accurately. This is in contrast to family
incomes, where we do have a source of verified data (the CSS Profile).
(17.) "Underrepresented minority" is the term of art in
college admissions. Notably, it excludes Asians.
(18.) That is, the size and scope of municipalities, school
districts, and other jurisdictions are far less consistent than those of
counties.
(19.) Experts also advise students to look at the high school grade
point average that is typical of a college's students. However,
such grade-based categories are not terribly relevant to high-achieving
students because selective colleges vary so much more on the basis of
college aptitude test scores than on the basis of high school grades.
(20.) State flagship universities are something of a special case.
On the one hand, they vary widely in selectivity. On the other hand,
even flagships with low overall selectivity can create opportunities
(formal or informal) for their highest-aptitude students to get an
education oriented to students with their level of achievement. These
opportunities may include research jobs and taking courses primarily
intended for doctoral students.
(21.) As noted above, a student may often apply to a nonselective
college without sending scores, although a good number of students send
scores to them for apparently no reason (the first few sends are free)
or for placement purposes (that is, to avoid being placed in lower-level
or even remedial courses). If we match students to their enrollment
records in the National Student Clearinghouse, we can add to their set
of applications any nonselective school in which they enrolled without
sending scores. This does not change the figures much, although it does
systemically raise the bar for nonselective applications. We do add
applications in this way for the analysis in the second half of this
section, but it makes too little difference here to be worthwhile,
especially as we would then have to show figures for a sample of the
students, rather than the population of them.
(22.) For instance, consider a student whose own scores put him or
her at the 94th percentile. In order to apply to a reach school, he or
she would need to apply to a school whose median student scored at the
99th percentile. There are no such schools--or at least no schools that
admit to having such a high median score.
(23.) We do not treat the sending of no scores as equivalent to
applying to no selective institution. The reason is that a student may
send no scores because he or she takes both the SAT and the ACT and
prefers to send the scores from only one of the two tests. Since we
cannot definitively match students across the two data sources (see note
15), we cannot assume that no-score-sending corresponds to no selective
applications.
(24.) We considered estimating a rank-ordered logit model (Beggs,
Cardell, and Hausman 1981), on the assumption that the order in which
the student sent scores to colleges indicates the rank order of his or
her preference among them. (All colleges to which no application is sent
are assumed to generate net utility below the bottom-ranked college.) If
we do this, the rank-ordered logit generates fairly similar results, in
part because many students do not send scores to more than a few
colleges. However, the order of score sending might be a poor proxy for
some students' preference orderings because they choose a first
batch of colleges to receive their scores before they know what those
scores are. Once they learn their scores, they choose a second batch of
colleges to receive their scores. At application time, they presumably
prefer the second batch to the first.
(25.) That is, we do not assume that the response of a student to
mismatch is symmetric around his or her own test score. A student may
only slightly like being at a reach school, for instance, but strongly
dislike being at a safety school.
(26.) In Avery and Hoxby (2004), we found much smaller differences
in the behavior of low- and high-income students, but all the students
we sampled attended high schools that were at least somewhat reliable
feeders. As we will show, the low-income students we sampled were thus
very disproportionately what we call "achievement-typical"
students who do behave fairly similarly to high-income students.
(27.) We can interact additional student characteristics that might
affect admission for instance, race and ethnicity--with colleges'
fixed effects. This effectively "soaks up" each college's
preferential admissions standards. However, such a specification does
not change the estimated coefficients of interest to a noticeable
extent, and it makes interpretation slightly harder.
(28.) This is a somewhat subtle test of whether the
achievement-typical students have total application portfolios like
those of high-income high achievers.
(29.) We do not consider progress toward a 2-year degree because
virtually none of the high-achieving students reported that a 2-year
degree was their educational goal in the descriptive questionnaires that
accompany the ACT and SAT I tests.
(30.) Hoxby and Turner (2013) implement exactly the causal test
needed by inducing income-typical students to apply to substantially
more selective institutions. That study finds no evidence that the
students thus induced fail to be admitted at normal rates, fail to
attain normal grades, or fail to persist at normal levels.
(31.) There were 334 metropolitan statistical areas and primary
metropolitan statistical areas in the 2000 Census of Population.
(32.) Finn and Hockett found most of the selective high schools in
their study by word of mouth and by contacting all high schools that
were so dissimilar to other schools in their district that they seemed
likely to practice selective admissions. Interestingly, many school
districts deemphasize the existence of their selective high schools,
which can be controversial. This perhaps explains why there was no
reasonably accurate list of them before Finn and Hockett (2012).
(33.) We use all of the Schools and Staffing surveys in an attempt
to pick up as many high schools as possible, but we nevertheless end up
with teacher data for only 34 percent of the high-achieving students we
study. We use the survey weights to create statistics that should be
nationally representative. For the statistics based on previous cohorts,
we use the actual previous cohorts from the College Board but must
assume that our one previous cohort from the ACT was representative of
the whole previous decade.
(34.) Arguably, focusing on these colleges overstates the extent of
previous cohorts' sophistication about college applications. These
colleges are the most likely to show up in odd strategies like applying
to one nonselective institution and to Harvard.
(35.) Meet and Rosen generously computed the relevant statistics
for us.
(36.) Many readers of previous drafts have asked us to compare
athletes and low-income high achievers, which we are glad to do because
the comparison is telling. However, there is no evidence that colleges
actually identify and recruit most students who have the potential to
perform very well in college sports. Our readers tend to assume that
this is true, but colleges might, in fact, neglect to recruit many
talented athletes.
(37.) Of course, colleges will likely not identify a student who is
a potentially top athlete but only in a team sport and who plays on a
weak team that competes only with other weak teams. But arguably that
student cannot develop his or her potential in any case.
Table 1. College Costs and Resources, by Selectivity of College (a)
Dollars per year
Out-of-pocket Comprehensive Average
cost for student cost (cost instructional
at 20th %ile of before expenditure
Selectivity family income financial aid) per student
Most competitive 6,754 45,540 27,001
Highly
competitive plus 13,755 38,603 13,732
Highly competitive 17,437 35,811 12,163
Very competitive
plus 15,977 31,591 9,605
Very competitive 23,813 29,173 8,300
Competitive plus 23,552 27,436 6,970
Competitive 19,400 24,166 6,542
Less competitive 26,335 26,262 5,359
Some or no
selectivity,
4-year 18,981 16,638 5,119
Private 2-year 14,852 17,822 6,796
Public 2-year 7,573 10,543 4,991
For-profit 2-year 18,486 21,456 3,257
Sources: Barron's Profiles of American Colleges and authors'
calculations using the colleges' own net cost calculators and data
from the Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS),
National Center for Education Statistics.
(a.) All costs include tuition and room and board. Out-of-pocket
costs include loans. At the very competitive level and above, the net
cost data were gathered by the authors for the 2009-10 school year.
For all other institutions, net cost estimates are based on the
institution's published net cost calculator for the year closest to
2009-10, but never later than 2011-12. These published net costs are
then reduced to approximate 2009-10 levels using the institution's
own figures for room and board and tuition net of aid, from WEDS, for
the relevant years. Instructional expenditure data are from IPEDS.
Table 2. College Assessment Results of High-Achieving Students, by
Family Income (a)
Average SAT or ACT percentile score
Income quartile among high-achieving students
First (bottom) 94.1
Second 94.3
Third 94.8
Fourth 95.7
Source: Authors' calculations using data from the ACT, the College
Board, WEDS, and other sources described in the text (hereafter
referred to as the "combined data set").
(a.) High-achieving students are students in 12th grade who have an
ACT comprehensive or SAT I (math plus verbal) score at or above the
90th percentile and a high school grade point average of A- or above.
Table 3. Conditional Logit Regressions Explaining High-Achieving
Students' College Applications (a)
Low-income High-income
Factor students students
College is a peer school (b) 1.015 76.214 ***
College is a safety school (c) 3.009 *** 14.895 ***
College is nonselective 0.748 *** 1.6e-9 ***
Tuition before discount (thousands of
dollars) 0.865 *** 1.176 ***
Average tuition discount (percent) 1.091 ** 0.925 **
Could live at family home (college is <10
miles away) 4.942 *** 0.810 ***
Could go home often (college is <120 miles
away) 1.556 *** 1.185 ***
Distance in miles to college 0.996 0.998
Square of (distance in miles/1,000) 1.056 ** 1.283 ***
College is in-state 2.595 *** 1.206 ***
College is private 0.838 *** 1.002
College is for-profit 0.834 *** 0.012 ***
Highest degree offered is 2-year 0.925 ** 0.009 ***
College is a university 0.997 0.567 ***
College is a liberal arts college 0.717 *** 0.973 *
Source: Authors' regressions using the combined data set described in
the text.
(a.) Results of a conditional logit estimation in which the dependent
variable is an indicator equal to 1 if a high-achieving student
applies to the college and zero otherwise. Coefficients are expressed
as odds ratios, so that a coefficient greater than 1 means that an
increase in the covariate is associated with an increase in the
probability that the student applies to a college with the indicated
factor, all other covariates held constant. High-achieving students
are defined as in table 2. Low- and high-income students are those
from families in the bottom and top quartiles of the family income
distribution, respectively. Asterisks indicate statistical
significance at the * 10 percent, ** 5 percent, or *** 1 percent
level.
(b.) The absolute value of the difference between the college's
median test score and the student's own is within 5 percentiles.
(c.) The college's median score is 5 to 15 percentiles below the
student's own
Table 4. Conditional Logit Regressions Explaining Income-Typical and
Achievement-Typical Students' College Applications (a)
Low-income students
Income- Achievement- High-income
Factor typical (b) typical (c) students
College is a peer school 7.21e-8 *** 87.808 *** 76.214 ***
College is a safety school 2.142 *** 19.817 *** 14.895 ***
College is nonselective 0.795 *** 1.04e-8 *** 1.6e-9 ***
Tuition before discount
(thousands of dollars) 0.973 *** 1.004 1.176 ***
Average tuition discount
(percent) 1.000 1.020 * 0.925 **
Could live at family home
(college is <10 miles
away) 5.140 *** 1.477 *** 0.810 ***
Could go home often
(college is <120 miles
away) 1.972 *** 1.436 *** 1.185 ***
Distance in miles to
college 0.999 0.999 0.998
Square of (distance in
miles/1,000) 1.042 * 1.448 *** 1.283 ***
College is in-state 4.891 *** 7.455 *** 1.206 ***
College is private 0.662 *** 0.296 *** 1.002
College is for-profit 0.806 *** 0.001 *** 0.012 ***
Highest degree offered is
2-year 0.855 *** 0.016 *** 0.009 ***
College is a university 0.956 ** 0.861 *** 0.567 ***
College is a liberal arts
college 0.515 *** 0.167 *** 0.973 *
Source: Authors' regressions using the combined data set described in
the text.
(a.) Results of a conditional logit regression in which the dependent
variable is an indicator equal to I if a high-achieving student
applies to the college and zero otherwise. Coefficients are expressed
as odds ratios, so that a coefficient greater than 1 means that an
increase in the covariate is associated with an increase in the
probability that the student applies to a college with the indicated
characteristic, all other covariates held constant. The coefficients
for high-income students are repeated from table 3 for ease of
comparison. High-achieving students are defined as in table 2.
Low-and high-income students are those from families in the bottom
and top quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Asterisks indicate statistical significance at the * 10 percent,
** 5 percent, or *** 1 percent level.
(b.) Those who apply to no school whose median score is within 15
percentiles of their own and apply to at least one nonselective
school.
(c.) Those who apply to at least one peer college, at least one
safety college with a median score not more than 15 percentiles lower
than their own, and no nonselective colleges.
Table 5. Estimates Showing Whether High-Achieving, Low-and High-
Income Applicants Have Different Probabilities of Enrolling in
Selective Colleges (a)
Percent of colleges where low-
and high-income students'
probabilities of enrolling
(conditional on application) are
statistically significantly
different at the 5 percent level
Base
specification
plus indicator
variables for
number of
Base applications
College's median test score specification (b) sent (c)
[greater than or equal to] 90th
percentile 4 5
[greater than or equal to] 80th
but <90th percentile 5 5
[greater than or equal to] 70th
but <80th percentile 4 5
[greater than or equal to] 60th
but <70th percentile 3 4
[greater than or equal to] 50th
but <60th percentile 6 5
<50th but college is selective Not identified (d)
College is nonselective Not identified
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) Results of a conditional logit estimation in which the dependent
variable is an indicator equal to I if a high-achieving student
enrolls in a particular postsecondary institution and zero otherwise.
Each student's choice set is the set of colleges to which he or she
applied. High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
(b.) The only independent variables are indicators for each college
interacted with an indicator for whether the student is high- or
low-income.
(c.) Indicator variables for whether the student applied to 1
college, 2 colleges, and so on up to 20 or more colleges are added to
the specification in the previous column.
(d.) Results are not identified for low-selectivity and nonselective
colleges because too few high-income students apply to such colleges.
Table 6. Estimates of Whether Low-and High-Income Students Have
Different Probabilities of Persisting at a Selective College,
Conditional on Having Enrolled (a)
Percent of colleges where
low- and high-income students'
shares of credits earned toward
a degree (conditional on
enrollment) are statistically
significantly different at the 5
percent level
Excluding
students from
selective and
magnet high
Base schools (c)
College's median test score specification (b)
[greater than or equal to] 90th
percentile 5 4
[greater than or equal to] 80th
but <90th percentile 4 5
[greater than or equal to] 70th
but <80th percentile 4 5
[greater than or equal to] 60th
but <70th percentile 5 5
[greater than or equal to] 50th
but <60th percentile 4 4
<50th but college is selective Not identified (d)
College is nonselective Not identified
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) Results of an ordinary least squares regression in which the
dependent variable is the share of credits toward a baccalaureate
degree earned by a student by June 2012. Students who do not enroll
in a postsec ondary institution are not included in the regression.
High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
(b.) The only independent variables are indicators for each college
interacted with an indicator for whether the student is high- or
low-income.
(c.) Same specification as in the previous column, but students who
attended high schools classified as magnet schools or that select
incoming students on the basis of test scores or grades are excluded.
(d.) Results are not identified for low-selectivity and nonselective
colleges because too few high-income students apply to such colleges.
Table 7. Socioeconomic Characteristics of High-Achieving Students (a)
Low-income students
High-income Achievement- Income
Characteristic students typical typical
Annual family income
(dollars) (b) 157,569 30,475 32,418
Parents' education (years) (c) 18.7 16.0 16.7
Race or ethnicity (d)
(percent of total)
White 74.8 45.1 79.5
Black 2.1 5.2 2.9
Hispanic 5.6 12.6 6.0
Asian 20.5 31.8 7.3
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Achievement-typical and income-typical students are defined as in
table 4.
(b.) Estimated as described in section II.
(c.) Highest level of education attained by either parent, as
reported by the student. Such self-reporting of parental education is
unreliable because students may be more likely not to report if their
parents' educational attainment is low.
(d.) Self-reported.
Table 8. Socioeconomic Characteristics of the Neighborhoods of
High-Achieving Students (a)
Low-income students
High-income Achievement- Income
Characteristic (b) students typical typical
Annual family income (dollars) 123,684 32,142 31,767
Adjusted gross income
(dollars) (c) 121,448 41.358 37,652
Residents with a B.A. degree
Number 863 207
Percent of all adults 66.7 22.0 16.8
Race or ethnicity (percent of
total)
White 86.7 58.2 77.1
Black 2.6 12.8 10.1
Hispanic 4.1 16.9 8.7
Asian 9.2 8.5 2.2
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Achievement-typical and income-typical students are defined as in
table 4.
(b.) Neighborhoods are census block groups except where noted
otherwise.
(c.) Neighborhood is the ZIP code.
Table 9. Types of Communities Where High-Achieving Students
Reside (a)
Percent
Low-income students
High-income Achievement- Income
Community type students typical typical
Main city, urban area with
population > 250,000 17 26 8
Main city, urban area with
population 100,000-250,000 14 21 13
Main city, urban area with
population < 100,000 48 18 9
Suburb, urban area with
population > 250,000 8 9 9
Suburb, urban area with
population 100,000-250,000 0 2 2
Suburb, urban area with
population < 100,000 0 4 12
Town, near an urban area 0 5 12
Town, far from an urban area 5 7 13
Rural, near an urban area 6 4 10
Rural, far from an urban area 0 5 10
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Achievement-typical and income-typical students are defined as in
table 4.
Table 10. Characteristics of High Schools Attended by High-Achieving
Students (a)
Low-income students
High-income Achievement- Income
Characteristic students typical typical
Number of students per cohort 333 330 241
Type of school (percent of
total)
Regular public school 66 73 86
Magnet school 4 11 0
Independent private school 16 7 3
Catholic or other religious
school 15 9 11
Spending per pupil (dollars;
public schools only) 15,558 12,975 10,701
Pupil-teacher ratio 16.8 18.3 17.2
Pupil-counselor ratio (public
schools only) 307 328 305
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Achievement-typical and income-typical students are defined as in
table 4.
Table 11. College-Related Characteristics of High Schools Attended
by High-Achieving Students (a)
Low-income students
High-income Achievement- Income
Characteristic students typical typical
Percent of teachers who
graduated from a peer
college (b) 8.9 2.9 1.1
Percent of teachers who
graduated from a safety
college (c) 14.4 7.5 5.0
Number in a typical previous
cohort who applied to top 10
U.S. colleges (d) 12.9 7.6 1.6
Number in a typical previous
cohort who were admitted to
a top 10 U.S. college (d) 12.3 7.4 1.5
Number in a typical previous
cohort who enrolled at a top
10 U.S. college (d) 12.3 7.4 1.5
Percent of cohort who are high
achievers 17.1 11.2 3.8
Radius to gather 20 high
achievers (miles) 2.6 7.7 19.3
Radius to gather 50 high
achievers (miles) 4.1 12.2 37.3
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data set described
in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2. Low- and
high-income students are those from families in the bottom and top
quartiles of the family income distribution, respectively.
Achievement-typical and income-typical students are defined as in
table 4.
(b.) A peer college is one where the college's median test score is
within 5 percentiles of the score of the average high achiever
attending the high school.
(c.) A safety college is one where the college's median test score is
between 5 and 15 percentiles below that of the average high achiever
attending the high school.
(d.) Average over the last 10 years.
Figure 2. High-Achieving Students, by Family Income Quartile (a)
1st quartile (17.0%)
2nd quartile (22.0%)
3rd quartile (27.0%)
4th quartile (34.0%)
Source: 2008 American Community Survey and authors' calculations
using the combined data set described in the text.
(a.) High-achieving students are defined as in table 2.
Note: Table made from pie chart.
Figure 3. High-Achieving Students, by Parents'
Educational Attainment (a)
High school diploma 3.2%
Some college or trade school 7.4%
Associate's degree 4.2%
Bachelor's degree 27.9%
Some graduate school 6.0%
Graduate degree 50.7%
Grades 8 or below 0.2%
Grades 9-11 0.4%
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data
set described in the text.
(a.) Parents' educational attainment is the highest level
attained by either parent. Percentages are of those
high-achieving students (defined as in table 2) who took
a College Board test and answered the question
about parents' education (61 percent of high achievers
declined to answer; the ACT questionnaire does not include
a similar question).
Note: Table made from pie chart.
Figure 4. High-Achieving Students, by Race and Ethnicity (a)
Mixed 2.6%
Native American 0.4%
Asian 15.0%
Black, non-Hispanic 1.5%
Hispanic 4.7
White, non-Hispanic 75.8%
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data
set described in the text.
a. Percentages are of those high-achieving students
(defined as in table 2) who took an ACT or a College
Board test and answered the question about their race
or ethnicity (2.1 percent of high achievers declined to
answer).
Note: Table made from pie chart.
Figure 5. High-Achieving, Low-Income Students,
by Race and Ethnicity (a)
Mixed 1.4%
Native American 0.7%
Asian 15.2%
Black, non-Hispanic 5.7%
Hispanic 7.6%
White, non-Hispanic 69.4%
Source: Authors' calculations using the combined data
set described in the text.
a. Percentages are of those high-achieving students
(defined as in table 2) from bottom-quartile-income
families who took an ACT or a College Board test and
answered the question about their race or ethnicity
(2.1 percent of all high achievers declined to answer).
Note: Table made from pie chart.