Boom, bust, recovery: forensics of the Latvia crisis.
Blanchard, Olivier J. ; Griffiths, Mark ; Gruss, Bertrand 等
ABSTRACT
Latvia's boom, bust, and recovery provide a rare case study
for macroeconomists: an economy that responded to a balance-of-payments
crisis by maintaining its currency peg and adjusting through internal
devaluation and front-loaded consolidation. This paper lays down the
facts about Latvia's boom and bust and analyzes the policy response
and the mechanics of the adjustment through internal devaluation. While
Latvia's adjustment was very costly, with a large drop in output, a
big increase in unemployment, and substantial emigration, it was
eventually successful. The internal devaluation worked faster, though
quite differently, than what had been expected. Productivity increases,
rather than nominal wage cuts, drove much of the unit labor cost
reduction. These then led to an increase in profit margins, rather than
a decrease in prices, and to a surprisingly fast supply response. The
strong front-loaded adjustment did not prevent the recovery. The lessons
of the Latvian experience for other countries may however be limited,
since many of the elements of the eventual success appear to have been
due to factors largely specific to Latvia, factors that are not present
in southern euro countries, in particular.
**********
Latvia is a small country, with a population of only two million,
yet it has been an object of intense attention during the financial
crisis. In response to their country's own twin crises--in balance
of payments and banking--and against the recommendations of many
economists, the Latvian authorities decided to maintain their currency
peg and adjust through internal devaluation and front-loaded fiscal
austerity rather than devalue.
Five years later, the proponents of this approach see it as a clear
success. Its opponents see it, if not as a clear failure, at least as an
excessively painful adjustment. Witness the recent back-and-forth
between Latvia's prime minister, Valdis Dombrovskis, and Paul
Krugman:
Krugman famously said back in December 2008 that Latvia is the new
Argentina, it will inevitably go bankrupt, and now he has difficulty
apparently admitting he was wrong and so he tries to seek some problems
in how Latvia is recovering from the economic crisis [...] But I think
that the mere fact that for the last two years we are enjoying rapid
growth shows that it was probably the right strategy.
--Prime Minister Valdis Dombrovskis, March 15, 2013 (1)
The adulation over Latvia really tells us more about what the
European policy elite wants to believe than it does either about the
realities of Latvian experience or the fundamentals of macroeconomics.
[...] We're looking at a Depression-level slump, and five years
later only a partial bounce back; unemployment is down but still very
high, and the decline has a lot to do with emigration. It's not
what you'd call a triumphant success story.
--Paul Krugman, January 2, 2013 (2)
The main goal of this paper is to lay down the (often misstated)
facts about Latvia's adjustment. On its own, this would be a
fascinating story of boom, bust, and (at least partial) recovery. But
the story has wider relevance. Adjustment under a fixed exchange rate
and the speed of fiscal consolidation have been and remain central
issues in the euro debate, and Latvia is often used by one side or the
other as an example of what to do or not to do. We hope our paper
contributes toward moving this debate forward.
The basic and striking facts to be explained are illustrated in
figure 1. GDP increased by almost 90 percent from 2000Q1 to 2007Q4,
followed by a decrease of 25 percent from 2007Q4 to 2009Q3 and then a
recovery, as of 2013Q2, of 18 percent. Meanwhile, the unemployment rate
sketched a mirror image, decreasing from 14 percent in 2000Q1 to 6
percent in 2007Q4, then increasing to more than 21 percent by 2010Q1 and
then decreasing since then to 11.4 percent as of 2013Q2.
We focus in this paper on six aspects of the story. These six key
questions, and the answers we reached, may be summarized as follows. (3)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
First, What triggered the boom? The boom was triggered by a
combination of the country's EU accession, belief in convergence to
EU per capita incomes, cheap funds from foreign-owned banks, and
optimistic expectations. The boom was healthy at the start but, like
many booms, increasingly bubbly and unbalanced at the end.
Second, What ended the boom? The end came in two stages. First,
starting in 2007, a slowdown occurred due to rising inflation and loss
of competitiveness, as well as tightening credit that reflected
banks' increasing worries about their loan books. Then, at the end
of 2008, a collapse occurred due to the world financial crisis, leading
to a sudden stop, a credit crunch, a sharp drop in exports, and
increased uncertainty. Fiscal austerity came later, for the most part.
Third, What role did the sudden stop play in explaining the sharp
decline in output? Liquidity provided by foreign banks, the central
bank, and the Treasury reduced but did not eliminate the credit crunch.
The decline in output was larger than what one would expect a credit
crunch to trigger, however. Uncertainty after the sudden stop, together
with the option value of waiting, were probably major additional
factors.
Fourth, What was the role of fiscal consolidation ? Despite the
public debate, it is hard to blame fiscal austerity for the decrease in
output. Much of the fiscal adjustment was implemented after the main
fall in output. There is suggestive evidence that commitment to a clear
adjustment program-- backed by substantial international financial
support--increased confidence, as reflected in lower CDS spreads.
However, much of the decrease in borrowing rates for households and
firms was associated with the increased credibility of the peg and the
decrease in exchange rate risk. This may have been partly the indirect
result of fiscal consolidation through market perceptions that
consolidation would ensure debt sustainability and also that it might
make the disbursement of international support more likely.
Fifth, How did the internal devaluation work? It did work, but in
ways different from the textbook adjustment. Public wages decreased
sharply but with limited effects on private wages. Much of the
improvement in unit labor costs, especially in the tradable sector, came
from increases in productivity. This improvement in unit labor costs was
only partly transmitted to prices, leading to an increase in firms'
profit margins. That was followed in turn by an increase in exports (but
from the supply side more than the demand side, due to increased
profitability), which was followed in turn by an increase in internal
demand. On the supply side, part of the adjustment has happened through
emigration, an adjustment not dissimilar to what happens across U.S.
states.
Sixth, Has output returned to its full potential and unemployment
returned to the natural rate? They have not yet returned, but they may
not be very far from that point. There is no evidence that the natural
unemployment rate is any higher now than it was before the crisis. But
the evidence also shows that, given the market-friendly labor market
institutions, the natural rate was surprisingly high before the crisis:
probably around 10 percent or even higher. The difficulty is to pin down
exactly what the natural rate was before the crisis.
Having laid out the facts, we return to the central issue. Is the
Latvian adjustment a success story? In some ways, it clearly is a
success. From a macroeconomic viewpoint, the Latvian economy is nearly
back to where it was before the boom became unhealthy. While the
unemployment rate is still somewhat higher than the (too high) natural
rate, output is growing and the financial system is safer. Few other
European countries can claim the same.
Nevertheless, the adjustment involved a very large decrease in
output, a very large increase in unemployment, and substantial
emigration. The question is whether an alternative strategy could have
achieved a better outcome. Nobody can give a definitive answer. What can
be said is that the sharp fall in output was not primarily due to the
adjustment policies, that fiscal consolidation was associated with
higher credibility and did not prevent the recovery, and that the
internal devaluation worked surprisingly quickly.
I. On the Boom
I.A. Background
After being occupied by the Soviet Union following World War II,
Latvia became independent again in 1991. A small, middle-income country,
it has been a member of the European Union since 2004. In 2012, its
nominal GDP was 22 billion euros, its population was 2 million, and its
PPP GDP per capita was 62 percent of the average for the European
Union's 28 member nations.
Latvia has a very open economy. In 2012, trade openness, measured
by the ratio of exports to GDP, was 60 percent, with about 30 percent of
exports being re-exports. Financial openness is also high. In 2012, the
ratio of gross foreign liabilities to GDP stood at 135 percent, of which
about half were bank liabilities, and there are no capital controls. The
national currency, the lat, has been pegged at 1.42 euros per lat since
January 1, 2005, and Latvia joined the EU's exchange rate mechanism
(ERM II) on May 2, 2005. Before then, the lat was pegged to the
IMF's special drawing right (SDR) basket of currencies. Latvia
joined the eurozone in January 2014.
After the initial drop in output due to the transition in the early
1990s and a brief interruption due to the Russian crisis in the late
1990s, Latvia experienced very high growth until the global financial
crisis, 7.7 percent annually from 1996 to 2007. Based on the Penn
tables, PPP GDP per capita in 2005 dollars increased from $5,500 in 1993
to a peak of $14,800 in 2007, just before the crisis.
In general, Latvia has adopted "pro-market" institutions.
In the 2013 "Ease of doing business" survey conducted by the
World Bank, Latvia ranked 25th out of 183 countries.
I.B. The Boom
Given the country's low income per capita in the early 1990s,
its relatively strong governance institutions, and its proximity to
Western Europe, the potential for Latvia to catch up was clearly high.
The question is whether its high rate of growth before the crisis
reflected healthy catch-up growth or something more.
Before looking at the specifics, it is useful to establish a
benchmark. Using two variants of the Barro growth specification
(Schadler and others 2006, and Vamvakidis 2008), which includes not only
initial real income per capita, but also population growth, partner
country growth, and a number of institutional variables, we obtain the
following. Until 2000, average growth of PPP GDP per capita was 6.2
percent, close to what these panel regressions predict. From 2001 to
2004, however, average growth was 8.2 percent, which is 1 to 3
percentage points higher than the regression predicts, and from 2005 to
2007 it was 11.6 percent, which is 4 to 6 percentage points higher than
predicted. (4) This suggests that starting in the 2000s, and especially
from 2005 on, GDP growth in Latvia was higher than can be explained by
catch-up. It also suggests that the boom became increasingly cyclical
and, as will be seen, unhealthy.
With these results in mind, we start our story in 2000 and refer to
the period 2000-07 as "the boom." During that boom, average
annual growth was 8.8 percent. The unemployment rate dropped from 14
percent in 2000 to 6 percent, its lowest level, at end-2007. Despite the
peg, inflation rose to 10.1 percent in 2007 and to 15.3 percent in 2008,
the highest in the European Union.
Viewed from the demand side, the boom came primarily from a rise in
domestic demand. The ratio of private consumption to GDP (in constant
prices) increased from 62 to 72 percent, and the ratio of investment to
GDP (also in constant prices) from 22 to 36 percent. (5) The growth in
investment partly reflected a housing boom. Housing investment grew from
2 to 5 percent of GDP, with 40 percent of the increase in employment
during the period taking place in construction (of which housing
accounts for roughly one-third) and real estate. There were indeed good
reasons for Latvian households and firms to increase their consumption
and investment: the prospect of catch-up growth, the prospect of EU
membership, and, later, the prospect of joining the eurozone, the last a
goal that would be delayed by the crisis but has now (in January 2014)
taken place.
As a matter of arithmetic, the result of increasing consumption and
investment ratios was a steady deterioration in the current account
balance, with the ratio of the current account deficit to GDP increasing
from 5 percent of GDP in 2000 to peak at a very large 25 percent in
mid-2007.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Once decomposed between exports and imports, the ratio of exports
to GDP (in constant prices) remained roughly constant at 45 percent.
This is impressive, given the high growth of the denominator--GDP
growth--but might have been even higher were it not for supply
constraints, as production shifted to the domestic market where demand
was growing rapidly. On the other hand, the ratio of imports to GDP
(also in constant prices) increased from 51 percent to 71 percent. If we
think of imports as depending on domestic demand rather than on GDP, and
given that domestic demand increased much faster than GDP, a more
relevant statistic is the ratio of imports to domestic demand; (6) this
ratio went up from 49 percent to 58 percent. Thus, not only was domestic
demand very strong, but it was accompanied by a large shift toward
foreign goods, leading to an even larger deterioration in the current
account balance. (Figure 2 plots the evolution of exports, imports, and
the trade balance.) Part of the shift probably reflected the increasing
real exchange rate appreciation (more on this below). Part of it may
also have reflected a shift toward higher quality foreign products, an
issue that will become relevant later when looking at the current
account adjustment (see Bems and Di Giovanni 2013).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The current account deficit was easily financed, but with a
worsening in the composition of financing over time. Foreign direct
investment (FDI) increased from around 5 percent of GDP in 2000 to a
peak of about 8 percent in mid-2007 before tailing off, perhaps an
indication of worries about the persistence of the boom. However, even
by 2007 the stock of FDI remained relatively low, 20 percent of GDP (and
much of the FDI represented capital increases of foreign bank branches
and subsidiaries operating in Latvia, which generated further credit
expansion).
The rest of the financing was provided mainly by Swedish and other
Nordic parent banks to their Latvian subsidiaries. Banks'
liabilities to foreign banks rose from 6 percent of GDP in 2000 to
almost 54 percent in 2007.
Throughout the boom, interest rates were low. Figure 3 plots a
number of interest rates from 2004 onward. The 3-month money market rate
decreased in the early 2000s, as Latvia repegged from the SDR to the
euro, remaining around 4 percent until early 2007. Mortgage rates, which
capture well the evolution of private borrowing rates in general, in
Latvia remained below 6 percent (in euros) until 2007. Mortgage rates in
lats increased from 2007 on, reaching about 14 percent by the end of
2007, with the premium reflecting a growing perceived risk in the
exchange rate. But, given the increasing inflation, even real mortgage
rates issued in lats (constructing the real rate as the nominal rate
minus current CPI inflation) were roughly equal to zero from 2004
onward, and real mortgage rates in euros were increasingly negative.
Using wage or house price inflation, one finds that real interest rates
were even more negative.
Associated with foreign financing through banks was very high
credit growth, which grew by end-2007 to almost 10 times its 2001 level,
an annual average growth rate of 33 percent in real terms. While the
ratio of private sector credit to GDP was less than 20 percent in 2000,
it reached almost 90 percent in 2007, higher than in other emerging
European economies, although still lower than the euro area average. The
proportion of loans denominated in foreign currency (initially mostly in
dollars, but by the end almost entirely in euros) also increased
steadily, rising from 50 percent in 2001 to more than 85 percent in
2007. (7)
There were few signs of overheating until 2005, consistent with the
notion that high growth until then reflected mostly potential growth.
Starting in 2006, however, signs of overheating became much clearer.
Wages and prices increased rapidly. As shown in figure 4, unit labor
costs (ULCs), normalized to 100 in 2000, reached 135 at the end of 2005,
164 at the end of 2006, 211 at the end of 2007, and 245 at the end of
2008. (8) The export price and the GDP deflator increased, although by
less, to reach around 200 at the end of 2008. (The smaller increase in
the GDP deflator than in the ULC implies a substantial increase in the
labor share, a point to which we shall return later.) The CPI also
increased, although by less than the GDP deflator, reflecting the large
share and the stable price of imported goods in the consumption basket.
The price per square meter of an apartment in Riga, a good index of
housing prices, quadrupled between early 2004 and early 2007, rising
from 400 to 1700 euros. (9) Thus, high inflation, increasing
overvaluation, a current account deficit of 25 percent of GDP, and
exploding housing prices all pointed to an increasingly unhealthy boom
and overheating. By 2007, output was likely well above potential.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Despite this, through 2007 the policy response was limited.
Although there were some increases in reserve requirements and a
broadening of the reserve base, monetary policy was run as a quasi
currency board, with the implication that the refinancing rate of the
Bank of Latvia followed the low ECB lending rate very closely.
A small fiscal headline deficit turned into a small headline
surplus in 2007. Was it the appropriate fiscal stance? This is where
hindsight comes heavily into play. As of 2007, the European
Commission's assessment was that Latvia's output was only
slightly above potential, so the output gap was perceived to be only
slightly positive. In hindsight, it has become clear that the output gap
was in fact larger, and thus the "cyclically adjusted" fiscal
balance was much worse. Fiscal policy was procyclical. The point is
illustrated in figure 5, which plots the cyclically adjusted balance for
each year from 2006 to 2009, using the output gap for that year
(calculated by the European Commission as of different dates).10 For
example, the adjusted balance estimated for 2004 was roughly similar
across calculation vintages, reflecting the fact that, both then and
now, the output gap was perceived as small. For 2007, however, the
adjusted balance, which was then perceived to be close to zero (as in
figure 5), is now estimated to have been a deficit of close to 3
percent. This reflects the current perception that what was seen then as
a small positive output gap (3 percent according to the European
Commission) is now estimated to have been a much larger one (12 percent
as of 2013).
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
In March 2007, the authorities introduced an "anti-inflation
plan." The main measures were balanced budget targets in 2007-08
and budget surpluses for 2009-10, the introduction of a capital gains
tax for real estate, and attempts to restrain bank lending (including
making loans exclusively on clients' legal incomes as opposed to
their stated incomes, making 10 percent first-installment payments
mandatory, and fixing a maximum loan-to-value ratio). However, it was
too little too late. (11)
In short, the anticipation of a large scope for catch-up growth,
together with cheap external financing, led to an initially healthy
boom. As time passed, the boom turned unhealthy, with overheating
leading to appreciation and large current account deficits, along with
lower credit quality and the balance sheet risks associated with foreign
exchange borrowing.
It is no great surprise that the government was reluctant to
acknowledge the changing nature of the boom and thus was unwilling to
slow it down dramatically. As late as mid-2006, government officials
argued that macroeconomic developments were largely benign: rapid growth
was essential for income convergence, inflation was due more to wage and
price convergence than to demand factors, and increased infrastructure
investment would prevent growth bottlenecks and enhance competition. In
the words of the then transport minister, it was time to "put the
pedal to the metal." (12) The financial regulator saw potential for
further credit growth, arguing that household debt ratios were low and
that the strong and liquid housing market provided adequate loan
collateral. The regulator regarded its responsibility to be one of
ensuring that individual banks had sufficient capital rather than one of
playing a macroprudential role. In contrast, the Bank of Latvia appeared
more concerned about overheating and the risks from high debt levels and
large currency and real estate exposures. Although it supported fiscal
tightening, aside from raising reserve requirements the Bank of Latvia
lacked the instruments to respond, given the quasi currency board and
the open capital account.
An interesting question, with obvious implications beyond Latvia,
is whether outside observers with no obvious political stake were
sounding the alarm bell more strongly than the Latvian authorities. The
answer, at least in the case of the IMF, is a qualified yes. In its 2005
annual review (the so-called Article IV review), the IMF pointed out
problems arising from rapid credit growth and domestic banks'
increasing reliance on nonresident deposits for funding. It viewed the
authorities' decision to remove limits on banks' open
positions in euros (because of the peg and the goal of euro adoption) as
premature. In 2006, the IMF renewed its warnings, recommending stronger
fiscal tightening and macroprudential measures to limit credit. In its
concluding statement for the 2007 Article IV mission, its warnings were
even more explicit.
The record of credit agencies was definitely mixed. Though they
lowered their outlooks, ratings agencies were slow to react with ratings
downgrades. For example, while Moody's recognized that rising
inflation and current account deficits posed risks, it cited as
mitigating factors the government's low debt ratio and stable
external funding of the financial system (long-term loans from parent
banks plus nonresident deposits, which it viewed as stable). Standard
& Poor's (S&P) kept its A-rating until May 2007 and then
kept its BBB+ until October 2008. Fitch kept an A-rating until August
2007 and then a BBB+ until October 2008. Moody's kept its A2 rating
until November 2008. S&P and Fitch did not lower their ratings to
BB+ (below investment grade) until February and April 2009,
respectively, while Moody's kept its investment grade rating
throughout.
II. On the Bust, Part 1: Fatigue and the Global Financial Crisis
The boom ended in two distinct phases. First there was a slowdown,
before the global financial crisis. Then came a collapse due to the
impact of the crisis, through a sudden stop of capital inflows, a credit
crunch, and a sharp drop in exports.
II.A. Fatigue and the Slowdown
Booms sometimes die a natural death. The stock adjustment process
that initially increased investment and durable consumption comes to an
end. Expectations of sustained fast growth turn out to be too optimistic
and are revised downward, leading to lower domestic demand. Credit
quality deteriorates, leading banks eventually to tighten credit.
Increasing wage and price inflation lead to increasing overvaluation and
reduced exports.
In Latvia the first signs of such fatigue appeared in 2006.
Consumer confidence peaked in 2006Q3, and business confidence peaked in
2007Q1. Then, starting in February 2007, worries about the exchange rate
peg led to a large jump in the Rigibor, the Latvian interbank rate,
relative to its Euribor counterpart, with the spread increasing from 0.5
percent to 6 percent within two months. By early 2007, credit standards
were being tightened, led by subsidiaries of Swedish banks. Borrowing
rates rose from around 7 percent at the start of the year to peak at
around 15 percent in November--although , as discussed earlier, real
interest rates declined because of the sharp increase in inflation.
Output peaked in 2007Q4.
Had there been no global financial crisis, Latvia might have gone
through a slump similar in nature to what happened in Portugal in the
early 2000s: weak foreign demand due to the overvaluation triggered by
the earlier boom and weak domestic demand, due in part to tighter
credit. (13) However, starting in 2008 this adjustment process was
overtaken by the effects of the world financial crisis.
II.B. The Global Financial Crisis and the Bust
As in other emerging markets, the global financial crisis affected
Latvia through two main channels: trade and financial. (14)
It is useful to look at the evolution of the different components
of GDP during the bust. Figure 6 shows the evolution of each component
of GDP from the peak in 2007Q4 to the trough in 2009Q3 as a percentage
of 2007Q4 GDP.
Over those eight quarters, GDP declined by 25 percent. Foreign
demand (X) accounted for 8 percent of the decrease. But much more
dramatic was the decrease in domestic demand (C+I+G), which declined by
43 percent of GDP! Fixed investment itself fell by more than half. This
decrease in domestic demand was partly offset in its effect on the
demand for domestic goods--and by implication in its effect on GDP--by a
decrease in imports (M) of 26 percent of GDP. (15) These numbers have a
clear implication: The bust was due in part to a decrease in foreign
demand, but much more so to a collapse in domestic demand.
Looking more closely, we start by examining foreign demand. Exports
started declining in 2008Q1, while world demand was still increasing,
before the global crisis. This decrease was probably due to the
increasing overvaluation noted earlier. But the major decline took place
during 2008Q4 and 2009Q1. During those two quarters, exports fell by 8
percent of GDP, clearly due to the global crisis.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Dynamic simulations, using an estimated export equation specifying
log exports as a function of the log of the partner countries' GDP
(using trade weights) and the real exchange rate, suggest that the
adjustment was faster than usual, but by 2009Q2 they were roughly in
line with what would have been predicted. (16)
How much of the decrease in output can be explained by the decrease
in foreign demand? About 30 percent of exports are re-exports. So a
decrease in exports of 8 percent of GDP implies a decrease in net
external demand of just over 5 percent. In our earlier BPEA paper on
emerging markets during the crisis (Blanchard, Das, and Faruqee 2010),
we found that an (unexpected) decrease in exports of 1 percent of GDP
led to a 1.5 percent (unexpected) decrease in GDP; applying that finding
to this case, we arrive at (5 x 1.5 =) 7.5 percent. Given the size of
the decrease in domestic demand (43 percent), it is clear that the
dominant factors must be found elsewhere, namely with the credit crunch
and the sudden stop, starting in 2008; fiscal policy did not play much
of a role until the middle of 2009. We discuss the sudden stop and
credit crunch as well as the role of fiscal policy in the next two
sections.
III. The Bust, Part 2: The Sudden Stop and the Credit Crunch
The relative simplicity of the Latvian financial system makes it
easier to trace the effects of the sudden stop.
Some background is in order. In 2008, Latvian subsidiaries of
Nordic banks accounted for 60 percent of total bank assets. (17) The
largest domestic bank, Parex, accounted for another 14 percent. Other
domestic banks accounted for the remaining 26 percent. The banks had
different business models. On the liability side, the Nordic
subsidiaries were financed 1/3 by resident deposits and 2/3 by their
parent banks. In contrast, Parex was financed in roughly equal
proportions by resident and nonresident deposits, most of the latter
from the recently independent eastern European nations (the CIS
countries). (18) Thus, funding for the Nordic banks depended very much
on the decisions of their parent banks, and funding for Parex depended
on the behavior of nonresident depositors and lenders from abroad.
As noted earlier, credit growth had already slowed before the
global crisis. New loans had peaked in 2006Q4 (and therefore before the
decrease in output), and real credit growth had slowed from 12 percent
(quarter on quarter) in 2006Q4 to being virtually flat one year later.
But the trigger for the financial crisis was a run on Parex in the wake
of the Lehman collapse.
Parex was exposed to high rollover risk. In addition to funding by
nonresident deposits, large syndicated loans, amounting to 16 percent of
its end-2008 liabilities, would be coming due in early 2009, and a
eurobond, accounting for another 4 percent of its liabilities, was
potentially callable, for example in the event of default on syndicated
loans. In contrast to the Nordic subsidiaries, Parex had no parent bank
and therefore no deep pockets. And under a currency board, there was, at
least in principle, no room for liquidity provision by Latvia's
central bank.
A "bank walk" started in late July 2008. Then, starting
in early October (a few weeks after the Lehman collapse), the walk
turned into a run. By the end of 2008, total deposits in Parex were down
by 34 percent relative to June. Various measures were taken by the
Latvian supervisory authority and by the government. A partial public
takeover in November was followed by full nationalization later in the
month. However, even this did not stop the run. Restrictions on deposit
withdrawals from Parex had to be imposed in early December 2008.
As nonresidents closed their accounts and converted them into
foreign currency or moved their money outside the country, the central
bank defended the peg. Reserves fell (ignoring valuation effects from
the depreciation of the euro and thus the lat). In the last three months
of 2008, the Bank of Latvia sold 1.15 billion [euro], or roughly one
quarter of its end-September reserves. Under a strict currency board,
there would have been no further central bank intervention, which would
have implied a decrease in the monetary base equal to the decrease in
reserves. However, there was strong pressure to provide funds to Parex.
This was eventually done, though indirectly. The government placed
Treasury bills and increased Treasury deposits at Parex (to one-third of
total deposits by end-2008), which in turn used the bills to obtain
financing from the central bank to fund deposit outflows. In turn,
international donors--at first a swap line from the Swedish and Danish
central banks, which served as a bridge to a subsequent IMF/EU/Nordic
program--replenished the reserves of the central bank.
Fortunately for Latvia's economy, the Nordic parent banks
absorbed losses by recapitalizing their subsidiaries and committing to
not cut funding to their subsidiaries, both implicitly at the start of
the program and more formally later on. Loans from these Latvian
subsidiaries to residents still declined, from a peak of 10.5 billion
lats in 2008Q4 to 8.1 billion lats at the end of 2011, but it was a
smooth decline, and it is likely that much of it could be explained by
lower credit demand rather than by the tighter credit supply alone.
Thus, in the end, continued funding by Nordic parent banks limited
the size of the sudden stop (or at least made it less
"sudden"), and the liquidity provided by the Treasury and the
central bank limited the size of the credit crunch. Still, in the year
preceding June 2009, the monetary base had decreased by one third, or
about 5 percent of GDP. This monetary tightening (linked to another
round of devaluation rumors and thus speculative attacks) and higher
perceived counterparty risk were reflected in an increase in the 3-month
money market rate, which went from 6.3 percent in September to 21
percent in June 2009. Borrowing rates for households and firms moved in
the same way, with much evidence of strong credit rationing (interest
rate data on new medium and large loans became unavailable).
Interestingly, rates on loans in euros increased by much less,
suggesting that investors were more worried about the risk of euro
depegging rather than about credit risk (see figure 7).
How large was the credit crunch's effect on activity? A number
of studies have looked at the effect on output of such credit supply
shifts, both in normal times and in crises. The studies that look at
periods of crisis give a range for the one-year response of output
growth to credit growth of 0.3 to 1.1. (19,20) This suggests the
following back-of-the-envelope computation: Loan growth from 2008Q3
(when loans peaked) to 2009Q3, in real terms, was around--5 percent,
compared to loan growth over the four quarters up to 2008Q3 of around 3
percent (already down from close to 50 percent 18 months earlier). The
parameters above suggest that this decrease in loan growth of 8 percent
may explain a decrease in domestic demand growth between 3 and 9
percent. (21) This is a large decline, but it is still substantially
less than the decrease in domestic demand of 27 percent over the same
period.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
So what else can explain the collapse in demand? By process of
elimination, the answer seems to be uncertainty and the option value of
waiting. Suggestive evidence is given by the behavior of car sales
during the period. As shown in figure 8, new car registrations,
normalized to be 100 in 2007, collapsed to 18 in January 2009 and fell
gradually during the year to reach one tenth of their 2007 levels by
January 2010. (22,23) Some of the decrease came from credit rationing:
Partly because of the general uncertainty, and partly because of legal
uncertainty about the ability of banks to repossess the collateral,
banks simply stopped offering car loans. But much of the precipitous
drop in car sales clearly came from the high uncertainty facing
consumers, be it about the peg, the soundness of the banking system, or
the size of the ongoing recession.
IV. On Adjustment Choices: Fiscal Consolidation
In early 2009, after the large decrease in output, what was needed
to return Latvia to health? Again, it is important to keep in mind the
two sources of the crisis: the natural (or unnatural) end of a boom, and
the later collapse due to the world financial crisis. The world
financial crisis had led to a sudden stop and a credit crunch, a large
drop in exports, and a resulting large decrease in output. Recovery of
the world economy would be needed to resolve the second source of the
crisis. Financial cleanup would be needed to repair the first.
It was clear, however, that even without the financial crisis,
Latvia would have needed a large macro adjustment. Latvia had been
operating above potential output before the crisis. The resulting
accumulated inflation had led to overvaluation, reflected in an
unusually large current account deficit. And while the fiscal deficit
had remained small, to return the fiscal deficit to balance at anything
close to potential output would require substantial consolidation.
Many economists recommended a nominal devaluation, with some
variations, and a steady but smooth fiscal adjustment. (The variations
included a one-time devaluation and then use of the ERM II bands, backed
by the potential support of ECB intervention, or even an accelerated
adoption of the euro). The argument in favor of devaluation was an old
one, namely that external devaluations solve a coordination problem and
are easier to achieve than internal devaluations: A nominal exchange
rate adjustment automatically coordinates real price and wage
adjustments. The argument in favor of a steady but smooth fiscal
adjustment was that the increase in the deficit was mostly due to the
crisis and would largely go away as output recovered, combined with the
point that the ratio of net debt to GDP, while it would likely increase
because of bank recapitalization costs and future budget deficits, was
still very low at end-2008, at less than 15 percent.
The Latvian government, and especially the Bank of Latvia, rejected
this advice, deciding instead to maintain the peg and proceed with
frontloaded consolidation. The authorities worried that depreciation
would lead to inflation, and that the increase in the real value of
foreign currency--denominated liabilities would lead to widespread
insolvencies. They saw a devaluation as inconsistent with the goal of
euro adoption, a goal delayed first by the boom (because of the induced
inflation) and then by the crisis. They believed that institutional
features (shallow financial markets, lack of offshore lats markets,
difficulties for speculators to borrow in lats) reduced the risk of a
speculative attack and made it more feasible to sustain the peg,
provided there was international financial support. They also believed
that only a strong fiscal consolidation would send the signal that the
government was committed to fiscal sustainability (see Aslund and
Dombrovskis 2011).
The European Union, the European Central Bank, and the Nordic
authorities supported that strategy, albeit for their own reasons,
including worries about contagion. While views within the IMF differed,
it is fair to say that the IMF was more skeptical about the choice to
maintain the peg but went along with the overall strategy.
The remainder of this section looks at the fiscal consolidation,
and the next section looks at the adjustment under the peg--the
so-called internal devaluation.
In 2008, the headline general government balance turned from a
small surplus to a large deficit of 3.4 percent of GDP (excluding bank
restructuring costs of around 4 percent of GDP), reflecting the large
decrease in activity. Little fiscal consolidation took place until 2009,
which is why in this study we did not focus on fiscal policy when
explaining the initial decline in output.
A revised 2009 budget, passed in December 2008, included measures
adding up to 7 percent of GDP--although some estimates suggest only 4
percent was actually implemented.24 In February 2009 the government
fell, and in March a new government was put in place, with the challenge
of implementing the fiscal consolidation that the previous government
had agreed to but been unable to deliver (and which in part had caused
its downfall). At the same time, the deepening recession was blowing the
deficit wide open.
In June 2009, after local government and European elections and
following long discussions with social partners and with the involvement
of the president, the new government announced a consolidation program,
with new measures adding up to 3.4 percent of GDP in 2009 (with a
full-year effect of 6.5 percent of GDP). The new measures included a
further 20 percent cut in the government wage bill (in the event, public
sector wages decreased by more than 20 percent over the following year),
controversial cuts to pensions (later ruled unconstitutional), and
reductions in personal income tax allowances, which made the personal
income tax less progressive. (25) Netting out expansionary measures
(such as increases in pensions and benefits embedded in earlier versions
of the 2009 budget, and the approval of additional spending of 1 percent
of GDP in social safety nets, as part of the program) and the likely
partial implementation of earlier measures, fiscal consolidation in 2009
is estimated to have been about 8 percent of GDP; of this amount, only
about 2 to 3 percent of GDP took effect in the first half of the year.
These measures and others introduced in subsequent budgets implied a
further adjustment of 5.4 percent of GDP in 2010 and 2.3 percent in
2011.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The evolution of headline deficits and of "cyclically
adjusted" fiscal balances (our motivation for using quote marks
will be clear below) from 2008 on is illustrated in figure 9. We plot
three series: the change in the headline deficit, the change in the
cyclically adjusted deficit including bank restructuring costs, and the
change in the cyclically adjusted deficit excluding bank restructuring
costs. (26)
Two aspects of the figure are particularly striking. The first is
the increase in the headline deficit in 2009; but given the very large
decline in output, this corresponded to a reduction in the cyclically
adjusted deficit. The second is the small decrease in the cyclically
adjusted deficit in 2009, computed excluding bank restructuring costs
(which affected the budget primarily in 2008): 1.4 percent versus the
bottom-up 8 percent number given earlier, based on government measures
taken in 2009. This points to the difficulties in measuring cyclically
adjusted deficits under such conditions--and thus the extreme care that
must be exercised in quantitative exercises. The problem in this case is
not so much the measurement of the size of the output gap, which we
discussed earlier; so long as measures of potential output move smoothly
from year to year, changes in the fiscal position are not very much
affected by potential output measurements.
The problem comes from two sources. First, the elasticity of
various budget items to activity. For example, the adjustment for the
output gap can be misleading if some taxes depend on domestic demand,
and domestic demand and output move very differently (as they did in
2009, with domestic demand contracting much more than output). Di Comite
and others (2012) conclude that correcting for the right elasticities
implies up to 3 to 4 percent of GDP in 2009 more consolidation than the
1.4 percent reported in the figure. Second, and going the other way,
there are measures that are neither cyclical nor explicit but that still
affect the budget: In the case of Latvia, for example, Di Comite and
others show that indexation of public wages to past inflation and
noncyclical social benefits may have led to higher expenditures,
subtracting 2 percent from the bottom-up number reported above.
In any case, the numbers imply a substantial fiscal consolidation,
with much of the adjustment starting in the second half of 2009 and
continuing through 2010 and 2011. Determining its effects on output with
any certainty is impossible. Surely it is unwise to argue, as some have
done, that the return to growth from 2009Q4 onward was due to the
expansionary effects of fiscal consolidation. Many other factors were at
play. As we have seen, much of the earlier sharp decrease in domestic
demand was likely due to uncertainty and the option of waiting. It is
likely that, as uncertainty decreased, the economy would have recovered,
independently of the path of fiscal policy.
One of the channels through which fiscal consolidations can have
limited adverse effects on activity, and even sometimes lead to an
increase in output, is through decreases in interest rates. The
announcement of a credible consolidation program may lead investors to
decrease the risk premium, leading in turn to an increase in demand that
may partly or fully offset the direct contractionary effects of
consolidation. And it is indeed the case that during that time in
Latvia, there was a dramatic decrease in interest rates. As was shown in
figure 3, the 3-month money market rate went from a high of 21 percent
in June 2009 to 11 percent in September 2009 and down to 3 percent by
February 2010.
Can this decrease be attributed to fiscal consolidation? Two
arguments suggest that the answer is probably no, or at least that it
cannot be attributed directly.
Five-year credit default swap (CDS) spreads on Latvian public debt,
which had increased from 800 at the start of 2009 to 1200 after the fall
of the government, indeed fell to 700 by the end of April, when the new
government was installed, and then fell to 500 by the end of September,
reflecting increasing confidence about fiscal sustainability. (27) But
there appears to be little relation between the evolution of these
spreads and the rates relevant to private borrowers, such as the 3-month
money market rate and the mortgage rates. The decrease in the 3-month
rate was almost fully accounted for by the decrease in the spread
between lat rates and euro rates, suggesting a decrease in exchange rate
risk rather than fiscal risk. And, indeed, there were good reasons for
investors to believe that the peg would be maintained. Despite intense
debates until June about the pros and cons of a devaluation, the
government reiterated its commitment, and by July both the European
Union and the IMF had agreed to disburse funds, removing one major
source of uncertainty about the ability of the government and the
central bank to keep the peg.
In short, it may well be that a credible fiscal plan was part of
what made the overall program credible, and, together with other
measures, restored confidence in the peg and led to the drop in interest
rates. But even if this was the case, the effect was indirect. What
cannot be established is whether major front loading was needed for
credibility. Whatever the case, the fact is that fiscal consolidation
coincided with growth, although from a very low starting point.
V. On Adjustment Choices: The Internal Devaluation
Before the global crisis, Latvia had been running very high current
account deficits. This partly reflected output that was above potential
and correspondingly high imports, and in part reflected overvaluation.
With the global crisis came a dramatic improvement in the current
account.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
While exports further decreased, domestic demand collapsed, leading
to a collapse in imports. During 2009, the "urrent account actually
swung into surplus (although part of this reflected the recording of
foreign bank loan losses as positive investment income).
This surplus was hardly good news, however. It was likely that with
the return of output to potential--whatever the precise value of
potential output was (a subject that will be discussed later)--the
current account deficit would reappear. To maintain a balanced current
account as growth came back, there would be a need for a real
depreciation. Estimates varied, but it was generally believed that a
significant real depreciation was needed. While many argued that a
devaluation of the lat was the best solution, the authorities
emphatically rejected this approach. They decided instead to adjust
through an internal devaluation, an adjustment of nominal prices and
wages, rather than adjusting the nominal exchange rate.
So how did it work?
V.A. The Evolution of Unit Labor Costs
Figure 10 shows what happened to unit labor costs (ULCs), measured
as the ratio of compensation of employees to output. It plots cumulative
changes in ULCs and its two components, productivity and wages, for the
economy as a whole, from 2008Q3 on. (The decomposition of ULCs between
productivity and wages requires the use of an employment series. As
explained in the appendix, because of a break in the official employment
series, we instead use "occupied posts," that is, the number
of employees as reported by firms.)
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
The evolutions are quite striking. The adjustment of ULCs was fast
and substantial. By the end of 2009, ULCs had declined by close to 25
percent, and they have remained roughly stable since. While wage cuts
played a role initially, much of the reduction in ULCs today reflects
productivity improvements rather than wage cuts.
For competitiveness, however, what matters is the evolution of ULCs
in the tradable sector. The 20 percent decrease in public sector wages
mentioned earlier may have been essential for the fiscal adjustment, but
it was of no direct relevance to competitiveness, so in figure 11 we
plot the evolution of the same three variables, but only for
manufacturing--the best proxy sector we have for tradables. Again the
picture reveals a substantial and fast adjustment, but this time with
much less of a decline in wages: Wages in manufacturing barely fell
initially, and then increased. The adjustment has come mostly from an
increase in productivity.
What can explain this increase in productivity? Without question it
was associated initially with labor shedding: Employment decreased in
nearly all sectors, an outcome reflected in the large increase in
unemployment. This raised the issue of whether the productivity
improvement would be long lasting or whether it reflected something
temporary, for example credit constraints forcing firms to take
decisions they might reverse when credit improved. Events have shown
that the latter does not appear to have been the case. Productivity
gains have indeed remained, as figure 11 shows for manufacturing.
Looking across subsectors within manufacturing, we find that
productivity continued increasing even in subsectors where employment
growth has resumed.
The question has been raised whether this increase in productivity
reflects composition effects, namely that the decrease in employment was
particularly pronounced for low-productivity sectors, or for
low-productivity firms, or for low-productivity workers. (28) Any such
composition effect would lead to an overestimation of the true increase
in productivity and therefore to an underestimation of the true decrease
in wages. To examine sectoral composition effects, we constructed a
fixed-weight wage series for the whole economy, using fixed employment
shares for 110 NACE subsectors at the two-digit level; (29) we found a
less than 2 percent difference in the increase in the two series since
2008. To examine skill level composition effects, we looked at the
relative employment of workers with only primary education. At a given
unemployment rate (so comparing the unemployment rate in 2004 to the
unemployment rate today), these workers' share in employment has
indeed declined, from roughly 13 percent to 9 percent. Using the wage
differential between them and other workers, this implies that skill
composition effects may have led to an increase in the average wage of
about 3 percent, again a small number.
This suggests that decreases in private sector wages have indeed
been limited and that productivity increases have been genuine. That may
be because tight credit constraints forced firms--and limited employment
protection allowed them--to reduce some X-inefficiency built up in the
boom. Or it may be, as Paul Krugman has argued, that underlying
productivity growth was high and the increase in productivity was simply
a return to the trend--if so, an option relevant for Latvia and other
Baltic countries but much less so for southern periphery euro countries.
Before the adjustment started, one of the main worries was that
large nominal wage cuts would be needed, and judging from the evidence
from other advanced countries, that it would be a slow and difficult
process at best (as it has indeed proven to be in euro countries on the
southern periphery). The increase in productivity made this a less
central worry, since all else being equal, smaller nominal wage cuts
were needed. In fact, smaller nominal wage cuts were achieved.
Still, the large divergence between productivity and wages raises
the question: Why were productivity gains not matched by wage increases?
Clearly, the large increase in the unemployment rate, weaker unions, and
limited employment protection must have all played a central role. Also
playing a central role must have been the large decrease in public
sector wages, which was part of the 2009 fiscal adjustment. (30) Other
factors, specific to Latvia, were also likely at play, although they are
impossible to quantify. One is the earlier boom: Latvians probably knew
that the earlier large wage increases were excessive. Looking at the
Baltic and euro periphery countries, Joon Shik Kang and Jay Shambaugh
(2013) find that countries that had greater wage increases during the
boom (since 2000) had greater wage decreases later. Another factor
likely at play was the still-recent history of Latvia, including its
painful transition to a market economy in the early 1990s and the sense
of national unity in the face of its Russian neighbor. Yet another
likely factor was the determination to integrate more closely with
Europe and join the eurozone.
V. B. From Unit Labor Costs to Prices
One would have expected the decrease in ULCs to be reflected in
lower export prices and thus higher competitiveness. The story is more
complicated, however.
Figure 12 shows the evolution of manufacturing ULCs (used as a
proxy for the ULCs in the export sector) since 2000. It also shows the
corresponding evolution in export prices and a partner country price
index (constructed as a weighted average of partner country import
prices, using Latvian 2009-11 export shares as weights). Export prices
did decline in 2009, but they generally moved in line with partner
country prices--which themselves declined because of the global crisis.
Indeed, the proportional decline in Latvia's export prices was
equal to the proportional decline in the partner country price index.
Thus, ULCs may have played a role, but it was a limited one. Since then,
export prices have recovered, while ULCs have remained low. This
suggests that Latvian exporters are largely price takers, with the
implication that the decrease in ULCs has led more to an increase in
profit margins than to lower prices in the export sector. (31,32)
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
The same general picture extends to the GDP deflator. As we saw
earlier in figure 4, the GDP deflator initially declined less than ULCs
and is now higher than it was in 2008. (33) Put another way, the
adjustment has come with a large drop in the labor share (recall that
the labor share can be expressed as the ratio of the ULC to the GDP
deflator). This is shown in figure 13, which plots the labor share both
for the economy as a whole and for manufacturing alone, starting in
2000.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
For the economy as a whole, the labor share has fallen from 58
percent at the peak to 46 percent. For manufacturing, the share has gone
from 64 percent to 45 percent. Figures 4 and 12 make clear that this is
largely the mirror image of what had happened during the late part of
the boom. Wages had increased faster than the GDP deflator, and the
labor share had steadily increased. The adjustment has undone this
increase--in the case of manufacturing, it has more than undone it.
In short: The adjustment of ULCs and prices was surprisingly fast.
And in contrast to expectations and the textbook adjustment, it came
largely from productivity increases and has been reflected more in
larger profit margins rather than in lower prices.
V.C. External and Internal Demand
Increases in profit margins typically lead to a supply response,
but it is generally believed that this response is slow. Exports,
however, increased quickly, and have increased by more than 40 percent
since the output trough in 2009Q3. This increase is remarkable given
that it was achieved during a period of weak foreign demand growth: The
GDP of partner countries has increased since 2009Q3 by only 11 percent.
Indeed, after falling slightly during the crisis, Latvia's export
market share has increased from 0.07 percent to 0.08 percent, higher
than it was before the crisis--a large increase for a small country.
This suggests that the increase in profit margins and better credit
conditions allowed existing firms to expand their production and exports
and new firms to enter export markets, although we have no solid
microeconomic evidence on this point (see Benkovskis 2012 and Vanags
2013).
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
Turning to the overall increase in demand, figure 14 shows the
evolution of the different components of GDP since the trough, as ratios
to 2009Q3 GDP. (Figure 14 corresponds to figure 6, which shows the
evolution from peak to trough.) It shows a recovery driven by foreign
demand: The increase in exports is actually larger than the increase in
GDP, a contribution of 23 percent versus an 18 percent GDP increase.
These two numbers imply that the contribution of domestic demand
for domestic goods has actually been negative, specifically -5 percent
of GDP. Domestic demand itself has been reasonably strong, with
increases in consumption and investment accounting for 13 percent and 6
percent of GDP, respectively. But imports have increased by a surprising
24 percent of GDP. If one removes that part of imports that is
re-exported (about one-third of exports), the remaining increase in
imports is still 17 percent of GDP (24 percent minus 0.3 times 23
percent), and therefore nearly equal to the increase in domestic
demand--a surprisingly large increase. Part of the explanation must be a
rebound from the exaggerated import collapse of 2009. Another, more
intriguing explanation is the reversal of a phenomenon analyzed by
Rudolfs Bems and Julian Di Giovanni (2013), who, based on supermarket
data during the bust, found that consumption had shifted toward lower
quality and lower priced goods, which tended to be domestic goods. As
income recovered, the reverse of this effect may have taken place.
V.D. Balance Sheet Effects, Investment, and Consumption
During the boom, as loans were increasingly being set in foreign
currency, a growing worry (expressed, for example, in a number of IMF
reports) was that the eventual adjustment would lead to strong adverse
balance sheet effects. It is estimated that as of 2008, foreign exchange
exposure amounted to 25 percent of GDP for consumers and 44 percent of
GDP for firms. (Both the public sector--government and central bank
consolidated--and banks had a small positive net foreign exchange
position.) A back-of-the-envelope computation suggested that, for
example, a 20 percent real devaluation, whether achieved through
external or internal devaluation, would reduce the net worth of
consumers by 5 percent of GDP and the net worth of firms by 8.8
percent--holding GDP constant. (34) Balance sheet effects could also
come from declines in housing prices. Although only 25 percent of
households had mortgages, a large decline in housing prices would lead
to an increase in the number of households underwater. Mortgages in
Latvia are full recourse and are often backed by the personal guarantees
of family members. These adjustments could lead to large wealth effects
and a large increase in the proportion of nonperforming loans,
preventing the recovery (again, a worry that has proven to be relevant
in a number of euro periphery countries).
What, then, actually happened? Again, the script has deviated
somewhat from the feared scenario and from the textbook. The fact that
the adjustment has mostly taken the form of productivity increases
rather than wage decreases has limited the increase in the ratio of
nominal debt to wages. The fact that prices have adjusted less than
wages have implies that balance sheet effects have affected firms less
than households. Housing prices, however, fell by half between 2008Q1
and 2010Q1 (private estimates suggest the decrease may have been as
large as 70 percent).
The result of this has been an increase in nonperforming loans
(NPLs), though the increase has been one the banks have been able to
manage. Firms' NPLs peaked at 22 percent of loans in early 2010,
and as of mid-2013 were down to 8.5 percent. Households' NPLs
stabilized for some time at a high 20 percent, but have now decreased to
14.1 percent. There has been a substantial restructuring of loans: about
1/3 of the end-2009 stock of loans was restructured between 2010Q1 and
2013Q2. Cumulative write-offs during that period amounted to 7 percent
of the end-2009 stock of loans. By June 2013, 10 percent of the stock of
loans was still in the work-out process, 14 percent in the case of loans
to households.
Despite the still high NPLs, the banking system is in decent shape
and is profitable again. As of June 2013, Latvian banks reported a
capital adequacy ratio of 18.6 percent, up from 11 percent at end-2007
and 14.6 percent at end-2009, and 71 percent of NPLs were provisioned.
Parex no longer exists; it was recapitalized through a conversion of the
Treasury deposits into equity and subordinated debt in May 2009 and then
split into a "good bank/bad bank" in August 2010. Core assets
and some non-core performing assets were transferred to a new bank,
Citadele Bank. Remaining assets and liabilities were put in a
special-purpose vehicle in March 2012. Except for Parex and a small
public bank, MLB, the banking system received no public help. (35)
VI. Is Most of the Adjustment Complete?
Have the macro and financial adjustments been achieved? On the one
hand, output has increased by 18 percent since the trough, the current
account and the fiscal accounts are roughly in balance, and the
financial system seems to be in decent shape. On the other hand, output
is still 11 percent below its peak. Unemployment is still around 12
percent. And the country's population is 7.7 percent lower than it
was at the beginning of 2008, reflecting a net emigration of 5.7 percent
of the population over the period. (36)
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
This raises at least two issues. How far is unemployment from the
natural rate? And how should one think about emigration as part of the
adjustment process? We examine these two issues next, in reverse order.
VI.A. Emigration
Although we have not focused on emigration up to this point, it has
played an important role in the adjustment (see Hazans 2007, 2011, and
2013). Figure 15 illustrates the numbers for net emigration since 2000.
It makes clear that Latvian emigration long predates the crisis. The
average net emigration rate was 0.5 percent from 2000 to 2007. The rate
increased to an average 1.3 percent from 2008 to 2011, but by 2012 it
had returned roughly to its precrisis average. Given the low income per
capita, and the fact that Latvia is part of the Schengen agreement on
the free circulation of persons within the European Union, such steady
emigration is easily explained. Nevertheless, the crisis clearly led to
a temporarily higher emigration rate. (37)
What was the effect on unemployment? Two crude back-of-the-envelope
computations give plausible upper and lower bounds. We can compute
excess emigration as the increase in emigration in 2008-11 over the
normal emigration trend, and thus as a cumulative 3.3 percent over four
years. If we assume that, had they stayed, all the emigrants of working
age would have remained unemployed, and given a ratio of the labor force
to population of about 50 percent, the unemployment rate would be about
6 percent higher. Alternatively, if we assume that only those emigrants
who were unemployed at the time of emigration had remained unemployed,
but that the unemployment rate among emigrants was 3 1/2 times higher
than among non-emigrants, the unemployment rate would be about 3
percentage points higher.
The question, in either case, is whether this emigration reflects
in some sense a failure of the adjustment program. In the United States,
migration rather than unemployment is the major margin of adjustment to
state-specific shocks (Blanchard and Katz 1992, with an update and
extensions by Dao, Furceri, and Loungani 2013). These adjustments are
typically regarded as good, indeed as the main reason why the United
States functions well as a common currency area: If there are jobs in
other states, and if moving costs are low, it is better for workers to
move to those jobs than to remain unemployed.
Is the answer different for a small country than for a U.S. state?
Some economic aspects are different: Some of the costs of running a
country are fixed costs, and thus may not be easy to support with a
smaller population. In the United States, many of those costs are picked
up by the federal government (although, as we have seen for Detroit, the
remaining fixed costs per capita may make it difficult for a state or a
city to function). This is not the case for a country, which must, for
example, finance its defense budget alone. Political aspects may also be
relevant, and a country may care more about the size of its population
than does a U.S. state.
In that respect, an important question is who the emigrants are and
whether they may return home. The evidence suggests that in Latvia the
emigrants during the crisis were slightly younger and slightly more
educated than the average population (Hazans 2011). And according to a
survey of the relatives of emigrants, only 20 percent of those who left
during the crisis reported an intention of coming back within 5
years--although this rate is higher among more-educated than among
less-educated emigrants. The largely permanent departure of the younger
and more educated workers may indeed be costly for those who stay.