Disentangling the channels of the 2007-09 recession.
Stock, James H. ; Watson, Mark W.
IV. The Slow Recovery
On its face, the unusually slow recovery following the 2009Q2
trough seems inconsistent with the conclusion of the previous sections
that the macroeconomic dynamics of this recession are consistent with
those of prior recessions, simply with larger shocks. Indeed, during the
8 quarters following that trough, GDP grew by only 5.0 percent, compared
with an average of 9.2 percent after 8 quarters for the recessions from
1960 through 2001, and employment increased by only 0.6 percent,
compared with a 1960-2001 average of 4.0 percent. (20) The contrast
between the current slow recovery and the robust recoveries of 1960-82
is even more striking: those recessions averaged 8-quarter GDP growth of
11.0 percent and 8-quarter employment growth of 5.9 percent following
the trough. In this section we therefore take a closer look at the
extent to which the current slow recovery is or is not consistent with
historical experience.
Why has the recovery in employment since 2009Q2 been so much slower
than the 1960-82 recoveries? In the context of the DFM, employment
growth after a trough is the sum of four terms: trend employment growth,
the predicted cyclical common component (deviations from trend) given
the state of the economy at the trough, the prediction errors in the
cyclical common component, and the series-specific idiosyncratic errors.
Accordingly, the weakness of the recovery since 2009Q2 relative to, say,
that after 1982Q4 could arise from differences in underlying trends
(such as in demographics), differences in recovery paths after different
types of recessions (such as one induced by monetary policy versus one
following a financial crisis), differences in macroeconomic luck once
the recovery commenced, or peculiarities of employment unrelated to the
rest of the economy. Although the latter two terms might be of
historical interest, the former two shed more light on structural
differences between the two recoveries. In this section we therefore
focus on the first two of these terms--the trend and the predicted
cyclical common component--comparing their values in the post-2009Q2
recovery with their values in previous recoveries.
As in section III, the calculations here require a VAR for the
factors, which we estimate using four lags and the "old"
factors over the 19592007Q3 period. With this model held constant,
differences in the predicted cyclical component across recoveries
reflect differences in recovery paths implied by the shocks that
produced the recessions. This permits a decomposition of the slow pace
of the recovery after 2009Q2, relative to previous recoveries, into
changes in the trend plus changes in the predicted cyclical component.
IV.A. Different Shocks Imply Different Recovery Paths
Different structural shocks induce different macroeconomic
responses. For example, Bloom (2009) predicts a fast recovery after an
uncertainty shock (investment and consumption pick up as soon as the
uncertainty is resolved), whereas Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff
(2009) describe recoveries from financial crises as typically slow. In
terms of the factor model, the state of the economy at the trough is
summarized by the current and past values of the factors as of the
trough. Because the values of the shocks (and thus of the factors) vary
across recessions both in composition and in magnitude, the recovery
paths predicted by the DFM also vary across recessions.
Figure 4 plots actual quarterly employment growth, its common
component, and its predicted common component following each of the
eight post-1960 troughs. All series are expressed as deviations from
trend, so that a value of zero denotes employment growth at trend. The
predicted common component is computed using the values of the factors
through the trough date; that is, the predicted common component is the
forecast of the common component one would make standing at the trough,
given the historical values of the factors through the trough date and
the model parameters (because the DFM was estimated through 2007Q3, the
predicted components in figure 4 are in-sample for the first seven
recessions and pseudo-out-of-sample forecasts for 2009Q2). The
difference between actual employment growth and its common component is
the idiosyncratic disturbance ([e.sub.t] in equation 1). The difference
between the common component and the predicted common component arises
from the factor innovations ([eta], in equation 2) that occurred after
the trough.
Three features of figure 4 are noteworthy. First, there is
considerable heterogeneity across recessions in both the shape and the
magnitude of predicted recoveries of employment. By construction, the
sole source of this heterogeneity is differences in the state of the
economy, as measured by the factors, at the trough. Strong positive
employment growth is predicted following the 1982Q4 trough--employment
growth returns to trend only 3 quarters after the trough--whereas slow
employment growth is predicted following 1980Q3, 1991Q1, and 2009Q2.
Second, in most recessions the predicted values track the actual
common component. The main exception is the 1980Q3 recovery, which was
interrupted early on by the next recession.
Third, given the values of the factors in 2009Q2, the DFM predicts
6 quarters of subtrend employment growth following the 2009Q2 trough. In
fact, the DFM predicts a slower employment recovery from the 2009Q2
trough than actually occurred; that is, the current recovery in
employment is actually stronger than predicted. (21)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
IV.B. Decomposition of the post-2009Q2 Recovery into Trend and
Cyclical Components
We now turn to the decomposition of the post-1959 recoveries into
their trend and predicted cyclical components, where the latter are
computed as described in the previous subsection using the factors at
the trough. Table 9 summarizes the results for 8-quarter cumulative
post-trough growth of GDP, employment, and productivity.
Consistent with the trends plotted in figure 1, table 9 shows that
the trend component of predicted growth in GDP and employment falls over
time. Consistent with the cyclical components plotted in figure 4, there
is considerable variation in the predicted cyclical components, which
arises from variation in the composition and magnitude of the factors at
the trough. The predicted cyclical contributions to 8-quarter employment
growth range from +1.1 percentage points following the 1982Q4 trough to
-3.1 percentage points following the 2009Q2 trough.
The final rows of table 9 report the decomposition into trend and
cycle of the difference between the predicted 8-quarter growth following
2009Q2 and the corresponding averages for pre-1984 recoveries. Predicted
GDP growth emerging from 2009Q2 is 3.0 percentage points less than the
pre-1984 average; four-fifths of this gap (2.4 percentage points) is due
to differences in trend. Predicted employment growth is 6.0 percentage
points less than the pre-1984 average; of this gap, 2.7 percentage
points is attributed to differences in the cyclical components, whereas
most, 3.3 percentage points, is attributed to differences in trend
employment growth. The predicted cyclical component of productivity
growth in the post-2009Q2 recovery is unusually large, 6.3 percentage
points, although this predicted value is perhaps comparable to its
values in the recoveries after 1975Q1 and 1982Q4. The difference between
the trend components of productivity growth in the recovery after 2009Q2
and in the average for the pre-1984 recoveries is 0.5 percentage point;
that is, trend productivity growth in the post-2009Q2 episode is
slightly higher than its 1960-82 average. Most of the difference in
productivity growth between the post-2009Q2 recovery and the 1960-82
recoveries is attributed to differences in the cyclical component. (22)
IV.C. The Slowdown in Trend Labor Force Growth and Slow Recoveries
A striking result of the previous section is that the decline in
the trend component accounts for nearly all of the slowdown in GDP
growth, and for over half the slowdown in employment growth, in the
current recovery relative to the pre-1984 averages. Table 10 decomposes
the change in trend GDP growth from 1965 to 2005 into GDP per employee,
the employment-population ratio, the labor force participation rate, and
the growth of the labor force. As seen in the first panel of table 10,
the decline in the trend growth rate of GDP of 1.2 percentage points
from 1965 to 2005 is, in this accounting sense, almost entirely due to
declines in trend employment, which in turn is approximately equally due
to declines in growth of the employment-population ratio and in
population growth. In this accounting sense, the third panel of the
table shows that declines in the growth of the employment-population
ratio are in turn due to declines in the growth of the labor force
participation rate, which in turn are largely due to declines in the
growth rate of the female labor force participation rate. Figure 5
presents the estimated trends for the terms in the first panel in table
10 for the full 1959-2011 period.
Because the trend value of the unemployment rate is approximately
the same in the 1960s as in the early 2000s (after peaking in the early
1980s), understanding the decline in mean employment growth amounts to
understanding the decline in the growth of the labor force. (23) A
significant literature examines long-term labor force trends and links
them to two major demographic shifts (figure 6). (24) The first is the
historic increase in the female labor force participation rate from the
1960s through the 1990s and its subsequent plateau; see Claudia Goldin
(2006) for an extensive discussion. The second is the (smaller) decline
in the male labor force participation rate. Stephanie Aaronson and
others (2006) and Bruce Fallick and Jonathan Pingle (2008) attribute
this decline to a combination of changes in the age distribution of
workers and changing cohort labor force participation rates associated
with the aging of the baby-boom generation (also see Fallick,
Fleischman, and Pingle 2010). The main conclusion from this demographic
work is that, barring a new surge in female labor force participation or
a significant increase in the growth rate of the population, these
demographic factors point toward a further decline in trend growth of
employment and hours in the coming decades. Applying this demographic
view to recessions and recoveries suggests that future recessions with
historically typical cyclical behavior will have steeper declines and
slower recoveries in output and employment.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
V. Conclusions and Discussion
Three main substantive conclusions emerge from this work. First,
the recession of 2007-09 was the result of shocks that were larger
versions of shocks previously experienced, to which the economy
responded in a historically predictable way. Second, these shocks
emanated primarily, but not exclusively, from financial upheaval and
heightened uncertainty. Third, although the slow nature of the
subsequent recovery is partly due to the nature and magnitude of the
shocks that caused the recession, most of the slow recovery in
employment, and nearly all of that in output, is due to a secular
slowdown in trend labor force growth. This slowdown provides a simple
explanation for the jobless recoveries of the 2001 and 2007-09
recessions. To the extent that it derives (as the literature suggests)
from persistent demographic changes, recoveries from future recessions
can be expected to be "jobless" as well. To these substantive
conclusions we would add a fourth, methodological conclusion: that
ignoring these changing trends will impart low-frequency movements to
the errors, which seems likely to introduce subtle problems into
structural VAR analysis.
The above three substantive conclusions are subject to a number of
caveats. First, although the evidence for the stability of the factor
loadings is relatively strong, it is difficult to draw inferences about
the stability of the factor VAR parameters with only 15 quarters of
post-2007Q3 data, particularly in the presence of evident
heteroskedasticity in the factor innovations. The tact that the current
recovery in employment has been stronger than predicted by the DFM given
the state of the economy at the trough could reflect the effectiveness
of the extraordinary monetary and fiscal policy measures taken during
the recession, or it could be an indication of parameter instability; we
are unable to distinguish between these two possibilities with the
current limited data.
Second, the structural DFM analysis using the method of external
instruments estimates shocks that are correlated with each other. The
ability to estimate this correlation, rather than needing to impose it
as an identifying restriction, is a strength of this methodology.
Finding sometimes-large correlations across different types of shocks
suggests that different identification strategies are estimating similar
features of the data, but interpreting them differently. This raises
broader challenges for the structural DFM and VAR literatures, which lie
beyond the scope of this analysis. Sorting out credible instrumental
variables methods for separately identifying liquidity shocks, market
risk shocks, exogenous wealth shocks, and uncertainty shocks constitutes
a large research agenda.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank John Driscoll, Lutz Kilian, Valerie Ramey,
Eric Swanson, Egon Zakrajsek, and Tao Zha for providing or helping us
construct their shock series and for comments. We also thank Alan
Blinder, Nick Bloom, Markus Brunnermeier, Marty Eichenbaum, Jon Faust,
Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Karel Mertens, Salil Mehta, Neil Shephard,
Chris Sims, Mike Woodford, Tom Zimmerman, and the editors for helpful
comments and discussions.
References
Aaronson, Stephanie, Bruce Fallick, Andrew Figura, Jonathan Pingle,
and William Wascher. 2006. "The Recent Decline in the Labor Force
Participation Rate and Its Implications for Potential Labor
Supply." BPEA, no. 1:69-154 (with discussion).
Adrian, Tobias, Paolo Colla, and Hyun Song Shin. Forthcoming.
"Which Financial Frictions? Parsing the Evidence from the Financial
Crisis of 2007-9." NBER Macroeconomics Annual.
Andrews, Donald W. K. 2003. "End-of-Sample Instability
Tests." Econometrica 71, no. 6: 1661-94.
Bachmann, Ruediger, Steffen Elstner, and Eric Sims. 2010.
"Uncertainty and Economic Activity: Evidence from Business Survey
Data." Working Paper no. 16143. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Bai, Jushan, and Serena Ng. 2002. "Determining the Number of
Factors in Approximate Factor Models." Econometrica 70: 191-221.
--. 2006. "Confidence Intervals for Diffusion Index Forecasts
and Inference for Factor-Augmented Regressions." Econometrica
74:1133-50.
Baker, Scott R., Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis. 2012.
"Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty." Stanford University.
Bank of Canada. 2011. Monetary Policy Report: October 2011. Ottawa.
Bassett, William F., Mary Beth Chosak, John C. Driscoll, and Egon
Zakrajsek. 2011. "Changes in Bank Lending Standards and the
Macroeconomy." Washington: Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Basu, Susanto, John Fernald, and Miles Kimball. 2006. "Are
Technology Improvements Contractionary?" American Economic Review
96, no. 5: 1418-48.
Bates, Brandon J., Mikkel Plagborg-Moller, James H. Stock, and Mark
W. Watson. 2012. "Consistent Factor Estimation in Dynamic Factor
Models with Structural Instability." Harvard University.
Baxter, Marianne B., and Robert G. King. 1999. "Measuring
Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time
Series." Review of Economics and Statistics 81, no. 4: 575-93.
Bekaert, Geert, Marie Hoerova, and Marco Lo Duca. 2010. "Risk,
Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy." Working Paper no. 16397.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Berger, David. 2011. "Countercyclical Restructuring and
Jobless Recoveries." Yale University.
Bernanke, Ben S., Jean Boivin, and Piotr Eliasz. 2005.
"Measuring the Effects of Monetary Policy: A Factor-Augmented
Vector Autoregressive (FAVAR) Approach." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 120: 387-422.
Bloom, Nicholas. 2009. "The Impact of Uncertainty
Shocks." Econometrica 77: 623-85.
Boivin, Jean, and Marc Giannoni. 2010. "DSGE Models in a
Data-Rich Environment." Working Paper no. 12772. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bordo, Michael D., and Joseph G. Haubrich. 2011. "Deep
Recessions, Fast Recoveries, and Financial Crises: Evidence from the
American Record." Rutgers University.
Campbell, John Y., Stefano Giglio, and Christopher Polk. 2010.
"Hard Times." Working Paper no. 16222. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Chetty, Raj. Forthcoming. "Bounds on Elasticities with
Optimization Frictions: A Synthesis of Micro and Macro Evidence on Labor
Supply." Econometrica.
Chetty, Raj, Adam Guren, Day Manoli, and Andrea Weber. Forthcoming.
"Does Indivisible Labor Explain the Difference between Micro and
Macro Elasticities? A Meta-Analysis of Extensive Margin
Elasticities." NBER Macroeconomics Annual.
Cochrane, John H., and Monica Piazzesi. 2002. "The Fed and
Interest Rates: A High-Frequency Identification." American Economic
Review 92: 90-95.
Eickmeier, Sandra, and Christina Ziegler. 2008. "How
Successful Are Dynamic Factor Models at Forecasting Output and
Inflation? A Meta-Analytic Approach." Journal of Forecasting 27,
no. 3: 237-65.
Fallick, Bruce, and Jonathan Pingle. 2008. "The Effect of
Population Aging on Aggregate Labor Supply in the United States."
In The Outlook for Labor Supply in the United States. Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston (with discussion).
Fallick, Bruce, Charles Fleischman, and Jonathan Pingle. 2010.
"The Effect of Population Aging on the Aggregate Labor
Market." In Labor in the New Economy, edited by Katharine G.
Abraham, James R. Spletzer, and Michael Harper. University of Chicago
Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Faust, Jon, Eric Swanson, and Jonathan Wright. 2004.
"Identifying VARs Based on High-Frequency Futures Data."
Journal of Monetary Economics 51, no. 6: 1107-31.
Fisher, Jonas D. M., and Ryan Peters. 2010. "Using Stock
Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks." The Economic
Journal 120: 414-36.
Friedman, Benjamin, and Kenneth Kuttner. 1993. "Why Does the
Paper-Bill Spread Predict Real Economic Activity?" In Business
Cycles, Indicators and Forecasting, edited by J. H. Stock and M. W.
Watson. University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Gali, Jordi. 1999. "Technology, Employment, and the Business
Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?"
American Economic Review 89: 249-71.
Giannone, Domenico, Michele Lenza, and Lucrezia Reichlin. 2012.
"Money, Credit, Monetary Policy and the Business Cycle in the Euro
Area." ECARES Working Paper no. 2012-008. Brussels: European Centre
for Advanced Research in Economics and Statistics.
Giannone, Domenico, Lucrezia Reichlin, and Luca Sala. 2004.
"Monetary Policy in Real Time." NBER Macroeconomics Annual
161-200.
Gilchrist, Simon, and Egon Zakrajsek. Forthcoming. "Credit
Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations." American Economic Review:
Gilchrist, Simon, V. Yankov, and Egon Zakrajsek. 2009. "Credit
Market Shocks and Economic Fluctuations: Evidence from Corporate Bond
and Stock Markets." Journal of Monetary Economics 56:471-93.
Goldin, Claudia. 2006. "The Quiet Revolution That Transformed
Women's Employment, Education, and Family." American Economic
Review 96, no. 2: 1-21.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2008. The Race between
Education and Technology. Harvard University Press.
Gurkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack, and Eric T. Swanson. 2005.
"Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? The Response of Asset Prices
to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements." International Journal
of Central Banking 1, no. 1: 55-93.
Hall, Robert E. 2010. "Why Does the Economy Fall to Pieces
after a Financial Crisis?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 24:
3-20.
--. 2011. "The Long Slump." American Economic Review 101:
431-69.
--. 2012. "Quantifying the Forces Leading to the Collapse of
GDP alter the Financial Crisis." Stanford University.
Hamilton, James D. 1996. "This Is What Happened to the Oil
Price-Macroeconomy Relationship." Journal of Monetary Economics 38,
no. 2: 215-20.
--. 2003. "What Is an Oil Shock?" Journal of Econometrics
113: 363-98.
--. 2009. "Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of
2007-08." BPEA, no. 1: 215-83.
--. 2010. "Nonlinearities and the Macroeconomic Effects of Oil
Prices." Working Paper no. 16186. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Jorda, Oscar Moritz H. P. Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2011.
"When Credit Bites Back: Leverage, Business Cycles, and
Crises." Working Paper no. 17621. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Kilian, Lutz. 2008a. "Exogenous Oil Supply Shocks: How Big Are
They and How Much Do They Matter for the U.S. Economy?" Review of
Economics and Statistics 90, no. 2: 216-40.
--. 2008b. "The Economic Effect of Energy Price Shocks."
Journal of Economic Literature 46, no. 4: 871-909.
--. 2009. "Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: Disentangling
Demand and Supply Shocks in the Crude Oil Market." American
Economic Review 99, no. 3: 1053-69.
Kim, Chang-Jin, and Yungjo Eo. 2012. "Markov-Switching Models
with Evolving Regime-Specific Parameters: Are Post-War Booms and
Recessions All Alike?" University of Washington.
King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson. 2012. "Inflation and Unit
Labor Costs." Princeton University.
Lee, Jaewoo, Paul Rabanal, and Damiano Sandri. 2010. "U.S.
Consumption after the 2008 Crisis." IMF Staff Position Note no.
SPN/10/01. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Lettau, Martin, and Sydney C. Ludvigson. 2011. "Shocks and
Crashes." Working Paper no. 16996. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Mertens, Karel, and Morten O. Ravn. 2010. "Technology-Hours
Redux: Tax Changes and the Measurement of Technology Shocks."
Cornell University.
--. 2012. "The Dynamic Effects of Personal and Corporate
Income Tax Changes in the United States." Cornell University.
Mian, Atif, and Amir Sufi. 2011. "What Explains High
Unemployment? The Aggregate Demand Channel." University of Chicago
Booth School of Business.
Mishkin, Frederic S. 2010. "Over the Cliff: From the Subprime
to the Global Financial Crisis." Working Paper no. 16609.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Montiel Olea, Jose Luis, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 2012.
"Inference in Structural VARs with External Instruments."
Harvard University.
Parker, Jonathan. 2011. "On Measuring the Effects of Fiscal
Policy in Recessions." Journal of Economic Literature 49, no. 3:
703-18.
Ramey, Valerie A. 201 la. "Identifying Government Spending
Shocks: It's All in the Timing." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 126, no. 1: 1-50.
--. 2011b. "Can Government Purchases Stimulate the
Economy." Journal of Economic Literature 49, no. 3: 673-85.
Ramey, Valerie A., and Daniel J. Vine. 2010. "Oil,
Automobiles, and the U.S. Economy: How Much Have Things Really
Changed?" NBER Macroeconomics Annual 25: 333-67.
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Vincent R. Reinhart. 2010. "After the
Fall." In Macroeconomic Policy: Post-Crisis and Risks Ahead,
Proceedings of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 2010 Jackson Hole
Symposium.
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009. This Time is
Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University
Press.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. 1989. "Does Monetary
Policy Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz."
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 4: 121-70.
--. 2004. "A New Measure of Monetary Shocks: Derivation and
Implications." American Economic Review 94: 1055-84.
--. 2010. "The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates
Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks." American Economic Review
100: 763-801.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 1998. "Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a
VAR Make Sense?" International Economic Review 39:907-31.
Saez, Emmanuel, Joel Slemrod, and Seth H. Giertz. 2012. "The
Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A
Critical Review." Journal of Economic Literature 50, no. 1: 3-50.
Sahin, Aysegtil, Joseph Song, Giorgio Topa, and Giovanni L.
Violante. 2011. "Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market."
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1989. "Two Models of Measurements and the
Investment Accelerator." Journal of Political Economy 97:251-87.
Sargent, Thomas J., and Christopher A. Sims. 1977. "Business
Cycle Modeling without Pretending to Have Too Much A-Priori Economic
Theory." In New Methods in Business Cycle Research, edited by C.
Sims and others. Minneapolis, Minn.: Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis.
Sims, Christopher A., and Tao Zha. 2006. "Were There Regime
Switches in U.S. Monetary Policy?" American Economic Review 96, no.
1: 54-81.
Smets, Frank, and Raph Wouters. 2007. "Shocks and Frictions in
U.S. Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach." American Economic
Review 97, no. 3: 586-606.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 2008. "NBER Summer
Institute Minicourse 2008: What's New in Econometrics--Time Series,
Lecture 7: Structural VARs." Cambridge, Mass.: National Institute
for Economic Research. www.nber.org/ minicourse_2008.html.
--. 2009. "Forecasting in Dynamic Factor Models Subject to
Structural Instability." In The Methodology and Practice of
Econometrics: Festschrift in Honor of D. F. Hendry, edited by Neil
Shephard and Jennifer Castle. Oxford University Press.
--. 2011. "Dynamic Factor Models." In Oxford Handbook on
Economic Forecasting, edited by M. J. Clements and D. F. Hendry. Oxford
University Press.
Comments and discussion
COMMENT BY ALAN S. BLINDER James Stock and Mark Watson, as skilled
a pair of time-series econometricians as the profession boasts, ask in
this paper how the 2007-09 recession differed from other U.S. postwar
recessions. Their answer is provocative: not much, actually, it was just
bigger. They conclude that "the 2007-09 recession was the result of
one or more large shocks, that these shocks were simply larger versions
of ones that had been seen before, and that the response of
macroeconomic variables to these shocks was almost entirely in line with
historical experience."
Provocative? Yes. I must admit to being provoked. For starters,
virtually every previous postwar recession was caused by either tight
monetary policy, an oil shock, or both. (1) This one was not. Instead,
it appears to have been caused by the bursting of a gigantic home-price
bubble and an even more gigantic fixed-income bubble, which together led
to the near-collapse of a jerry-built financial system, causing massive
wealth destruction and severe impairment of the economy's
credit-granting mechanisms. It looks more like a Reinhart-Rogoff
recession, the first in U.S. postwar history, or better yet, a Minsky
recession. (2) Furthermore, the Federal Reserve quickly (in December
2008) encountered the zero lower bound (ZLB) on nominal interest rates,
forcing it to rely on a wide variety of "unconventional"
monetary policies. Finally, long-term unemployment soared to levels not
seen since the 1930s. In short, the years following 2007Q4 did not look
like your father's recession--more like your grandfather's (or
your great-grandfather's, if you are very young).
Let me start by reviewing why the conventional wisdom sees the
200709 recession and its aftermath as something different. Then I will
take up Stock and Watson's challenge to this wisdom.
THE CONVENTIONAL WISDOM The U.S. economy entered 2007 with
incredibly high leverage, virtually everywhere. Leverage is not
something new. But as recently as the last mega-recession, in 1982-83,
total debt in the United States was only about 150 percent of GDP. By
the end of 2007, it was about 350 percent of GDP. High leverage, of
course, spells high vulnerability to shocks. That vulnerability, in
turn, was exacerbated by a variety of complicated (and mostly
unregulated) financial linkages--through complex derivatives, a
variegated shadow banking system, and more--that created a house of
cards in the years leading up to the crisis. These novel financial
developments sound like "slope things" to me--aspects of the
economy that would likely change impulse response functions--as opposed
to "intercept things" that only change levels of variables.
This financial house of cards, by the way, was poorly understood, which
makes the standard assumption of rational expectations something between
dubious and ludicrous.
Yet more "slope things" relate to monetary policy. When
the Federal Reserve hit the ZLB in December 2008, that presumably
reduced the power of monetary policy. Certainly it ended the ability to
use the federal funds rate as a policy instrument, even though linear
equations in standard models call for the funds rate to go negative.
Stuck at the ZLB, the Federal Reserve turned to new, untested weapons
like emergency lending facilities, large-scale asset purchases, and
forward guidance--policies whose "multipliers" are mostly
unknown.
Finally, as mentioned, the share of long-term unemployment (spells
over 26 weeks) in total unemployment rose to over 45 percent, having
never before topped 26 percent in postwar history. Might all those
long-term unemployed people affect the responses of measured employment
and unemployment to stimulative policies?
For all these reasons and more, there is a strong a priori case
that empirical models based on historical data might be expected to
perform poorly after 2007. Before we jump to that conclusion, however,
let us note several other factors pointing in the opposite direction,
which tend to support Stock and Watson's claim that this recession
wasn't different, just bigger.
Bubbles have burst before, although this one was the whopper. We
have also regularly witnessed deterioration in underwriting standards
and other signs of irrational exuberance in lending during past booms.
The financial zaniness of 2004-07 was not the first "Minsky
moment" in postwar U.S. history--though it looked more like a
Minsky quinquennium. Nor was what followed the Lehman Brothers
bankruptcy the first banking crisis. The sheer size of the 2007-09
recession was unprecedented: real GDP declined by nearly 5 percent; even
nominal GDP fell. The decline in employment (and the rise in
unemployment) also appeared to be unusually large, even given the
miserable GDP performance, and the bounceback of employment after the
trough seems unusually slow. But maybe these are all just exaggerated
versions of what we have experienced in past recessions: normal
reactions to shocks that, although abnormally large, are not
qualitatively different.
This last thought leads to a philosophical question that is, in
some sense, at the heart of Stock and Watson's analysis: When does
a quantitative change become so large that it becomes a qualitative
change? For example, the earth's tectonic plates are always moving,
but somehow, earthquakes are different. Years ago, Thomas Sargent (1982)
called our attention to the unusual behavior around "The Ends of
Four Big Inflations" in Central Europe in the 1920s. There is
certainly no apparent Phillips curve trade-off, and no
"stickiness," when the inflation rate drops by hundreds or
thousands of percentage points within a few months, as it did then. And
Robert Shiller (2008) has pointed out that the U.S. housing boom and
bust of the 2000s was unlike anything seen in the nation's history
dating back to 1890. So was the recent bubble sui generis, or just
"normal but bigger?" Stock and Watson implicitly argue for the
latter. I wonder.
And while we are thinking this way, is the bursting of a bubble a
"shock," as we conventionally use the term? After all, we all
knew with near certainty that the housing bubble was going to burst; the
only question was when. If so, did the e in the home-price equation
still have a mean of zero after, say, 2005? Indeed, were Christopher
Sims, who does not allow such words, not the other discussant of this
paper, I might be tempted to ask whether bubbles are exogenous or
endogenous variables.
THE STOCK-WATSON VIEW The essence of Stock and Watson's
econometric methodology is as follows. Back in ancient times, economists
used to estimate giant "structural" macroeconomic models that
could be used to derive reduced forms like
(1) Y = X[beta] + [epsilon],
where Y is a vector of "endogenous" variables explained
by the model, X is a vector of "exogenous" variables not
explained by the model, and [epsilon] is a vector of error terms, or
"shocks." One problem was that Y and X might be very long
vectors, making [beta] a truly gigantic matrix, with more parameters
than one can reliably estimate. The factor analysis approach is an
attempt to economize on parameters, starting from the observation that
one can always find a much smaller set of variables, Z, such that
(2) X[beta] = Z[GAMMA] + u,
where u is another error vector. How well equation 2 fits the data
is an empirical question whose answer will depend, among other things,
on the number of Z variables--the "factors." Using equation 2,
one can rewrite equation 1 as
(3) Y=Z[GAMMA]+[epsilon]*.
Whereas X (and thus [beta]) may be huge, Z (and thus [GAMMA]) will
be of manageable size. In Stock and Watson's particular
application, Z is only six-dimensional. The operational question is how
much information is lost in going from equation 1 to equation 3; that
is, how good an approximation equation 2 is.
This formalism is mathematically valid, of course, but let me point
to three weaknesses. The first is what I call the reification fallacy:
One tends to treat the [epsilon]s in either equation 1 or equation 3 as
actual things--"shocks"--when they are really deviations from
conditional expectations ("error terms"). To be sure, there
are such things as genuine unexpected shocks, like surprise movements in
oil prices or in monetary policy. But what economists typically call a
"consumption shock," for example, is just the error term in
the consumption equation; it expresses, among other things, our
inadequate understanding of consumer spending. This distinction is
highly relevant to the "was it just bigger?" question. For
example, when several 5- or 6-standard-deviation shocks are observed,
are those just unusually large error terms, or do they signify that
something virtually unprecedented happened? (3) I lean toward the
latter.
Second, although moving from equation 1 to equation 3 is
legitimate, both algebraically and statistically, the Zs and [GAMMA]s
cry out for interpretation. Often that interpretation is hard to give,
or simply not given. In the old days, the Xs in equation 1 had clearly
understandable names like "exports" or "government
purchases." So, for example, [TEXT NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] might
be interpreted as the multiplier effect of higher exports on real GDP.
In describing their factor analysis methodology, by contrast, Stock and
Watson write, "arbitrary normalization means that the individual
factors do not have a direct economic interpretation." I am, no
doubt, an old fuddy-duddy, but this strikes me as a drawback. If, in the
old methodology, our computations found that [partial
derivative]GDP/[partial derivative]exports was 10 or -1, we would know
immediately that something was wrong. We have no such intuition about
[partial derivative]GDP/[partial derivative][F.sub.1].
The third problem is obvious, but it is also important in the
context of deciding whether some phenomenon is "new" or just
"bigger." If something has not been experienced before, it
obviously will not be in a statistical model based on real data. For
example, oil shocks were nowhere to be found in pre-1973 macroeconomic
models, although James Hamilton (1983) later taught us that they should
have been there all along. How, then, can a purely statistical model--as
opposed to observation, common sense, or an economic model--tell us
whether some unusual development is "new" or just an unusually
large deviation from historic norms?
With all that said, Stock and Watson's factor analysis model
performs surprisingly well. For most of the major macroeconomic
variables, such as GDP, employment, and their main components, their
factor analysis model estimated on pre-2007Q4 data captures the
post-2007Q4 data amazingly well. (See many of the panels in their figure
2.) I was impressed. (4)
But who ever expressed the view that, say, consumption behaved
abnormally relative to its major determinants (disposable income,
wealth, and so forth) during this period? The Stock-Watson factor
analysis model misses badly more or less where events lead you to think
any model would. Home prices, bank lending, the federal funds rate, the
monetary base, and long-term unemployment are some examples (again from
their figure 2). I do not say this to criticize the authors; those
variables are awfully hard to "get right" during the recession
and its aftermath. But it does lead me back to the thought that the
2007-09 recession and subsequent recovery really were different, not
just bigger.
Perhaps the gentlemen protest too much.
REFERENCES FOR THE BLINDER COMMENT
Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson. 1997.
"Systematic Monetary Policy and the Effects of Oil Price
Shocks." BPEA, no. 1: 91-142.
Hamilton, James. 1983. "Oil and the Macroeconomy since World
War II." Journal of Political Economy (April): 228-48.
Minsky, Hyman P. 1992. "The Financial Instability
Hypothesis." Working Paper no. 74. Jerome Levy Economics Institute
of Bard College.
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009. This Time Is
Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University
Press.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1982. "The Ends of Four Big
Inflations." In Inflation: Causes and Effects, edited by Robert E.
Hall. University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Shiller, Robert J. 2008. The Subprime Solution. Princeton
University Press.
(1.) Among the many papers that could be cited, see Bernanke,
Gertler, and Watson (1997).
(2.) By a Reinhart-Rogoff recession I mean a recession caused or
prolonged by the harmful balance-sheet effects of a financial crisis
(Reinhart and Rogoff 2009); by a Minsky recession I mean a recession
caused by the (inevitable) bursting of an asset bubble after excessive
speculation (see, for example, Minsky 1992).
(3.) Stock and Watson's table 5 contains six shocks larger
than 5 standard deviations; three of them are larger than 8 standard
deviations.
(4.) Maybe more than I should have been. Some Panel members
suggested during the general discussion of the paper that one of the six
factors must have closely resembled real GDP.
COMMENT BY CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS This paper by James Stock and Mark
Watson is an exercise in descriptive statistics, attempting to provide
insight into what was surprising about the Great Recession compared with
historical statistical patterns. Economists are attempting to revise
their theories and empirical models to account for what happened in
2007-11, so this paper's systematic examination of what happened,
using a wide range of economic time series, is valuable.
The paper has two themes: some things about the Great Recession
were very different from historical patterns, and some were not. The
story it tells, with some qualifications, is that the Great Recession
was characterized by big "shocks" (forecast errors in a linear
model), but that those shocks fed through the dynamics of a linear model
much as one would have expected from historical patterns. The paper
identifies the recent phenomenon of "jobless" recoveries as
differing from historical patterns, but in a smoothly trending way that
was visible well before the Great Recession.
That there were big shocks is clear, and it is interesting to see
when they occurred and in which variables. The downward bend in trend
employment growth that the authors find looks statistically convincing,
and the paper informally suggests plausible reasons for it. The case for
the linear dynamics having been stable is less convincing to me,
however, and there are aspects of the data's behavior that have
been unusual and that are not captured in pre-2008 economic models or in
the models that this paper fits to the data.
The biggest statistical surprise in the recession was the size of
the forecast errors in the linear model, both during the 2008Q4 crash
and to some extent preceding it. The paper does not actually display any
such forecast errors, but table 5 shows estimated surprise components of
11 variables, constructed from the authors' dynamic factor model.
It would be easier to interpret the results if these were actual
forecast errors in the variables listed at the top of the table, but as
the paper's figure 2 shows, the variables are fairly close to the
same thing as their "common components," so the table comes
fairly close to showing us forecast errors in these variables. The
errors are scaled by the standard deviation of forecast errors over
1960-2007Q3, so those larger than 4 in absolute value--in productivity,
housing starts, oil prices, the VIX, and the TED spread--are extremely
unusual by historical standards. If the disturbances were normally
distributed, even those larger than 3 would be unlikely to have occurred
in the historical sample, but the data are not normal. Three-sigma
errors occurred fairly often in the sample, but four-sigma and larger
errors did not. In fact, all the series with over-four-sigma errors had
no disturbances of that magnitude in the sample period. (These
conclusions are all based on data related to table 5, extending it to
earlier periods, that the authors made available to me.)
That there were large unforeseen changes in economic time series in
this period is, of course, not news. It is good to have the size of the
surprise quantified, however, and to observe where the surprises
concentrate: Except for the 2008Q4 productivity shock (about which more
below), each of these extremely large surprises was in a variable
related to housing or financial markets. That these variables showed
large unexpected changes is again not news, but their size relative to
historical norms is worth noting.
Perhaps more unexpected is that for GDR consumption, and investment
there were large disturbances, but they were not larger than had been
seen during the 1960s and 1970s. This raises an interesting question
that the paper does not explore: did the large shocks in financial
variables feed through into large predicted changes in the nonfinancial
variables, and did those effects lead to more accurate forecasts?
My curiosity aroused, I used monthly data from the authors'
database on the 3-month Treasury bill rate, the 3-month London
Eurodollar deposit rate, and logs of industrial production, employment,
oil prices, and the personal consumption expenditures deflator to
estimate a vector autoregression (VAR) on data from 1971 through
September 2007. (I used 13 lags and an improper prior shrinking toward
persistent behavior of the data.) If, as seems likely to me, the
paper's six factors can be well approximated by linear combinations
of current and lagged values of these six variables, one can use the VAR
to gain insight into how the paper's model works.
The VAR confirms that the Eurodollar rate (which, combined with the
Treasury bill rate, can reproduce a version of the TED spread) has
substantial power in explaining industrial production over medium to
long horizons. When the Eurodollar rate is excluded from the VAR,
forecasts conditioned on data through September 2008 (although still
with coefficients estimated through September 2007) are considerably
worse. The Eurodollar rate variable allows the VAR to underestimate the
decline in output and employment through mid-2009 by substantially less.
As can be seen from my figures 1 and 2, however, the VAR residuals
contrast with the findings reported in the paper's table 5 in some
respects. One is that the very large forecast errors are spread evenly
across variables in the VAR, not concentrated as in the authors'
model in its one financial-stress variable LIBOR. This could happen
because the VAR does not include as rich a set of financial variables,
but in my view it is more likely a reflection of the difference in time
units. What happened to output, employment, and the PCE deflator in
September 2008 was extremely large and sudden by historical standards.
The suddenness is partly smoothed away by the use of quarterly rather
than monthly data. The large positive shock to productivity shown in the
paper's table 5 probably reflects the complicated and rapid changes
in output and labor markets during this period. No positive shock to
productivity shows up in the VAR residuals, and the authors in a
personal communication to me showed that the positive shock occurs only
in the projection of productivity on the factors, not in the
productivity series itself. Most of the surprises in table 5 correspond
well with sharp movements in the series labeling the columns, but not
this one.
Many of the monthly series show VAR residuals that are both large
and oscillating in sign during the final 3 months of 2008 and the first
half of 2009. During this period the large shocks were not simply
feeding through the usual dynamics. The usual dynamics were producing
large error after large error. After this period, however, the residuals
return to a size commensurate with historical norms. My conclusion is
that the notion that the crisis consisted merely of large shocks feeding
through the usual dynamics is somewhat misleading. The usual dynamics
did not explain what was going on for several months around the peak of
the crisis. During that period existing linear models may have been
unhelpful. But after that period, starting from a new, depressed
economic state but with the financial markets stabilized, models fitted
to history began tracking reasonably well again.
My figure 1 brings out another point that is implicit in the
paper's methods but could be further emphasized. The historical
data before the end of 2007 already showed clear evidence that large
outliers and sustained periods of unusually high or low volatility are
recurring phenomena. All the statistical tests that the paper applies
carefully avoid assuming normality of residuals or even constant
variances, sacrificing power because the stronger assumptions would be
clearly counterfactual. If one is looking for what the standard
macroeconomic models have been missing, this is a good place to start.
We should be modeling the evolution of volatility and its potential
interaction with mean dynamics, not treating these phenomena as
"nuisance parameters" to be worked around. Our statistical
descriptive models should go beyond linear models, in other words, and
our theoretical models should be required to provide interpretations for
the results. The interaction of financial market malfunction with the
macroeconomy may be a good part of what generates the outliers and
time-varying volatility that we observe.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The authors were among the first to point out the value of interest
rate spread variables in forecasting. In their seminal 2002 paper they
included a number of spread variables, but not the TED spread or a
Eurodollar rate. In this recent crisis the Eurodollar rate has done
particularly well in after-the-fact forecasting models, as it measures
distress in interbank lending, which was central in this crisis. It was
useful before the crisis as well, as otherwise models estimated through
late 2007 would not have detected its effects. But the fact that it
plays a prominent role in the paper's model does reflect what
economists have already learned about the deficiencies in precrisis
models. Measures of financial distress are important, and we have been
sifting through candidates for measuring them better. Financial
institutions and regulations are continually changing, however, so that
the markets where we need to look for measures of stress will probably
continue to shift. This suggests a reason for caution in interpreting
this paper's results as showing big shocks feeding through stable
dynamics.
My conclusions about the substance of the paper's results are
that it is correct to point to the continuing usefulness of models
fitted to historical data in the wake of the crisis, but that to suggest
that this means the crisis was "just large shocks" is
misleading. Linear model dynamics did not work well during the peak of
the crisis, and linear models turn a blind eye to what should be one of
our most important scientific tasks, that of understanding recurrent
instances of high volatility in macroeconomic and financial time series.
I turn now to some comments on the paper's methods. The paper
uses the principal-component dynamic factor model setup that the authors
developed and have used before. The approach requires stationary data,
and economic data are not stationary. Accordingly, the authors prefilter
all series to make each one plausibly stationary, first-differencing
real variables and second-differencing prices. My view of the
econometric literature on cointegration is that its complicated
prescriptions for frequentist inference--which would be totally
impractical for the model of this paper--are misguided. But the
literature begins from an important observation: when cointegration may
be present, simply getting rid of nonstationarity by differencing
individual series so that they are all stationary throws away vast
amounts of information and may distort inference. That is why the VAR
that I used above to interpret the paper's results was estimated in
levels, allowing the model dynamics to account for any nonstationarity.
In addition to this differencing, the paper removes
"trend" through another layer of filtering, then applies
factor analysis to the residuals from these two layers of preprocessing.
Any inference that is carried out ignores uncertainty about the
prefiltering and about the factors themselves. As mentioned above, all
the statistical tests are in a form that, in a large enough sample,
would be robust to nonnormality. Because of these layers of data
processing and of the authors' reluctance to present an explicit
model of nonnormality and time-varying volatility, it would not be
reasonable to ask them for error bands around the statistics they
develop. Perhaps most important, their plots of out-of-sample forecast
and actual values of employment growth (figure 4 in the paper) are
presented only as point forecasts. One can see that the model, in most
but not all recessions, gets the overall growth rate of employment about
right, but there are errors, and no standard exists by which to judge
whether these errors are big or small. This is one main reason that I
prefer to work with an explicit probability model of the data, which
becomes testable because it attaches uncertainty measures to its
forecasts.
The preprocessing also raises some doubts about the result that
jobless recoveries are explained by a downward bend in the trend rate of
growth of employment. Because the trend is estimated with a two-sided
filter that uses data for several years ahead of the current date, the
precrisis trend could actually be affected by crisis-period data.
The complexity of the dynamic factor model structure could in
principle be providing better forecasts and more accurate modeling of
the macroeconomy. This paper does not provide any direct evidence on
whether this approach is an advancement over one that would directly
model the time-series behavior of, say, a dozen major standard aggregate
series, explaining the remaining 150 or so as functions of these central
aggregates. My reading of the previous literature on these methods is
that it does not provide evidence on this point either. This matters,
because the task of explicit probability modeling is much harder if it
requires extraction of unobservable factors from hundreds of series.
I have not commented on the paper's attempts to give
behavioral interpretations to its factors by correlating them with
external variables. I find
this exercise completely unconvincing. The external variables have
themselves in most instances been constructed by modeling macroeconomic
aggregates, many of which are included in the factor model or have close
analogues in it. The intuitive interpretation of this procedure is
similar to that underlying the projections of individual variables on
factors that generated the results in table 5. Some variable or group of
variables to which one can give a name is regressed on the factors, and
the resulting linear combination of factors is given a name. That may
help in interpreting the six nameless factors, but it is in no sense
"structural" estimation. The authors do not even provide a
structural model of the data within which these estimates would be valid
estimates of something structural.
The paper represents hard work and has produced much food for
thought. Like most good empirical work, it required making decisions
about how to analyze and present data (that is, "assumptions")
that provide plenty of targets for critics. But despite my having taken
aim at some of these targets, I hope the paper will stimulate more work
along this line.
REFERENCE FOR THE SIMS COMMENT
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 2002. "Macroeconomic
Forecasting Using Diffusion Indexes." Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics 20, no. 2: 147-62.
GENERAL DISCUSSION William Brainard noted that the authors'
conclusions depended heavily on how they distinguished between changes
in structure and shocks. That distinction, in turn, depended on how they
detrend and how they weight the roughly 200 time-series variables. Their
estimate of a variable's trend was approximately the same as its
average rate of change over a centered window of plus or minus 30
quarters. If a shock is large and persistent, as arguably some were in
the 2007-09 recession, this procedure may improperly allocate a
significant fraction of a shock to the trend. Brainard cited as an
example the case of housing starts, which were relatively steady at a
high level until the bubble burst, declined rapidly starting in 2005,
and have remained low ever since. When the authors' detrending
procedure is used, much of the large drop in housing starts is likely to
appear as a decrease in trend. The dramatic drop in starts does not
average out; the shocks in the window covering 2007-09 go in one
direction. The same danger of confounding trend and cycle, Brainard
continued, arises in the case of employment growth, where the authors
attribute most of the recent slow recovery to a slowdown in trend
employment growth.
Brainard also reasoned that the results could be sensitive to the
authors' use of unweighted percentage changes for the real
variables. As a consequence, their results could reflect large
percentage changes in variables that are relatively unimportant to
aggregate output, while underweighting variables that are more important
but have smaller percentage changes. Principal component analysis, which
the authors use to compute the factors, is not scale independent,
Brainard noted. He wondered what the results would have been if the
authors had weighted changes by their importance to the overall economy
or had conducted their analysis in levels.
Finally, the authors' finding that the structural dynamics of
the pre-2007 recessions matched those of the most recent one puzzled
Brainard, since the most recent recession was so deep and the current
levels of variables like housing starts and unemployment are so
different from what was observed during previous recoveries. In the case
of housing starts, the authors' scatter-plot makes clear that the
errors using the dynamic factor model are autocorrelated, which is
inconsistent with the model's assumptions. Brainard suggested that
such autocorrelation of errors might explain similar discrepancies
between the observed levels of other variables and the predicted levels
implied by the authors' model.
Refet Gurkaynak observed that after every big macroeconomic event,
economists feel pressure from the public and policymakers to look at
that event as something entirely new and unique and to forget all
lessons from previous experience and research. He saw this paper as an
important counter to that kind of thinking, because it showed that
economists have accumulated some wisdom over the years that remains
relevant from event to event and could be used to give policy advice
even in the face of new challenges.
Gurkaynak was troubled, however, by the fact that a large financial
shock was driving the results of the authors' model for the recent
recession. He interpreted financial asset prices as forward-looking
information aggregators, which measure whatever is missing in the rest
of the economic model. The fact that the model required a large
financial shock to explain the Great Recession data meant that there are
probably important variables that were observable over the period
leading up to and during the recession but are omitted from the model
and instead show up indirectly as the large financial shock.
Olivier Blanchard argued that it is in the nature of dynamic factor
models to explain aggregate variables fairly well, because many of the
series are closely related to each other and therefore highly
correlated. For example, some of the authors' series might be
different components of industrial production, which the industrial
production index, an aggregate of these, will explain quite well.
Blanchard did not take the fit of the linear model as evidence that
structural relationships in the economy were truly linear. On the
contrary, he thought Stock and Watson did not provide a way to test
empirically for nonlinear relationships, but he felt confident that such
relationships exist. The effect of the interest rate on debt dynamics,
for example, depends on whether the national debt is 50 percent of GDP
or 100 percent, as the recent European experience shows. The effect of a
1-percentage-point drop in the rate of GDP growth on loan performance,
as another example, depends on whether the GDP growth rate starts out at
4 percent or at 1 percent. Blanchard suspected that coming up with
appropriate ways to measure these relationships would be hard but could
be done.
Martin Baily said that given the unusual nature and size of the
shocks that had provoked the Great Recession, he was surprised by the
extent to which Stock and Watson found the shape of the recession and
subsequent recovery to match that of previous recessions and recoveries.
The recent recession had featured a strong inventory cycle, as had
previous ones, for example. And a financial accelerator effect appeared
to have depressed investment, again as in previous recessions.
What Baily found most puzzling was the performance of the labor
market, which he thought had suffered more initially and recovered more
slowly than in previous recessions even after accounting for demographic
changes. He was therefore surprised that the dynamic factor model was
able to match employment data in the recession and recovery as well as
it did. Baily thought that cross-country data might shed some light on
the poor U.S. labor market performance. He noted that patterns in GDP
growth and employment growth varied widely across countries during and
after the Great Recession. Germany and the United Kingdom both suffered
larger drops in GDP but experienced smaller declines in employment than
the United States. Spain, on the other hand, experienced a similar drop
in GDP as the United States but an even larger employment decline. The
other aspect of the Spanish economy that paralleled the U.S. experience
was its large housing boom and subsequent collapse of residential
construction. That parallel led Baily to wonder whether the exceptional
labor market decline in both countries could be traced to the collapse
in housing construction. The theory might explain why Stock and
Watson's model could explain the collapse in employment, since
their analysis includes housing market data.
Frederic Mishkin, like Blanchard, thought that modeling nonlinear
features of the business cycle was very hard but worth further study.
The literature has long noted the existence of financial disruptions and
financial accelerators as important factors in recessions, he said, but
these phenomena had not been incorporated in the dynamic stochastic
general equilibrium models used for policy analysis. He wished
especially that models could better incorporate the extreme
nonlinearities that are constantly present in the financial sector and
worsen during recessions. Some of these nonlinearities could even
independently help trigger recessions, as he thought was true of
Enron's crash in late 2001 and the recession that soon followed.
For the most recent recession, he saw the crash of Lehman Brothers as an
important source of nonlinearity.
Robert Hall described a related exercise he had recently carried
out to examine the causes of the recession. Using a dynamic, nonlinear
macroeconomic model, he computed the paths that two driving
forces--financial friction and deleveraging--must have taken to explain
the pattern of unemployment and investment observed during the downturn.
He found that financial friction was a large and persistent factor in
explaining unemployment and investment, whereas deleveraging was an
important factor early on but diminished in importance quickly. The same
exercise would have been easy to carry out for earlier business cycles
using the same model, the only difference being that the movements of
the variables would have been smaller. That the same model and driving
forces could explain patterns of unemployment and investment across
different recessions was unsurprising, since they did so by design.
Because Hall saw Stock and Watson's exercise as similar to his
own, he found their results mostly unsurprising, with the possible
exception that they could explain a large number of time series well
using a much smaller number of factors. However, he understood it to be
a well-known feature of dynamic factor models that only a few factors
could explain the movement of many variables.
Linda Tesar wondered how well the authors' model could explain
imports and exports, since both dropped significantly during the
recession even though the exchange rate changed little. She also
suggested that another test of the model might be to test how well it
fits the data in other countries.
Justin Wolfers thought the authors had neglected to highlight one
of the most striking findings of the paper, namely, that numerous
variables that had previously been identified by macroeconomists as
exogenous instruments were in fact highly correlated with each other. In
one of their tables, for example, the fiscal shock identified by
Christina Romer and David Romer in 2010 exhibited a -0.8 correlation
with the monetary policy shock identified by the same authors in 2004.
Wolfers noted that if labor economists somehow discovered that the
typical instruments for educational attainment--quarter of birth,
Vietnam draft lottery number, and distance to college, for example--were
in fact highly correlated, they would regard the finding as enormously
destructive to most of what modern labor microeconomics had achieved. He
wondered, then, what this correlation of supposedly instrumental
variables meant for macroeconomics. Wolfers also found it puzzling that
the authors' factors seemed to explain GDP and some other macro
time series too well given the margin of error with which those series
are measured.
John Driscoll offered a possible insight into why one of the
series, commercial and industrial loan volume, fit less well than some
others. Early in a recession, business loans often rise before
eventually falling, because firms are using previously unused parts of
credit lines that had been approved before the recession started. The
recent recession featured a particularly large run-up and a subsequent
crash in commercial and industrial loans. One could observe this effect
more directly by examining measures of unused loan commitments from
banks' call reports, which fell at the start of the recession as
businesses used up their available credit.
Valerie Ramey suggested a caveat to the authors' finding that
an oil shock was an important contributor to the start of the recession.
Previous research had found that the effects of oil price shocks on the
U.S. economy had declined since the mid-1980s. However, in a 2010 paper,
she and Daniel Vine had found that the appearance of a structural shift
in the effect of oil shocks could be traced to the removal of price
controls on oil after the 1970s, which had caused severe misallocation.
With price controls absent, an increase in the price of oil in 2008
ought to have had a smaller effect on the economy than a comparable
shock in the 1970s.
Ramey also commented on the difficulty of separating shocks from
long-run trends, noting that the latter may actually help drive what we
think of as the business cycle. In unpublished work, using a standard
real business cycle model, she had modeled the effects of an anticipated
change in the growth rate of the labor force and found that decreases in
that rate in the 1930s had led to decreased productivity and investment.
Similarly, John Maynard Keynes and Alvin Hansen had suggested that the
cutoff of immigration in the 1920s, which slowed labor force growth, was
a factor in the Great Depression. Ramey had also found that, in the
1940s, an increase in the labor force growth rate led to increased
productivity and investment even without a World War II shock in the
model.
Christopher Carroll thought the paper was helpful for focusing
economists' attention on the shocks that had led to the recession.
However, he thought the most credible method of calculating the
recession-causing shocks might be to use a model that was published just
before the recession. David Wilcox reported that several of his
colleagues, Hess Chung, Jean-Phillipe Laforte, David Reifschneider, and
John Williams, had completed an exercise similar to the one Carroll had
suggested; their paper was forthcoming in the Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking. Before the Great Recession, using the 2007 version of the
Federal Reserve's main macroeconometric model, the FRB/US model,
Reifschneider and Williams had found that the likelihood of a multiyear
zero-lower-bound event was so low as to be practically a statistical
impossibility. The forthcoming paper uses a range of other models and
considers a wider spectrum of sources of uncertainty. With those
adjustments, recent events are seen as less remotely improbable, but
still relatively unlikely. On this basis, Wilcox was surprised that
Stock and Watson's paper seemed to suggest that their model could
account for basic features of the recession.
To Ricardo Reis, the fit of the model to the post-2007Q4 data was
useful for demonstrating that over the course of the recent recession
and recovery, the six-factor model was not missing a major seventh
factor. Reis highlighted a footnote in the paper in which the authors
specify the algebraic manipulations they used to estimate the
post-2007Q4 factors and to compute the common component of the
macroeconomic time series in the post-2007Q4 period. There they explain
that they use principal component analysis to find the six linear
combinations of the series that best account for the data over the
1959-2007Q3 period. These linear combinations are described by the
factor loadings matrix, [??] (59-07). The six factors are then estimated
for the post-2007Q4 period by applying the transpose of the factor
loadings matrix to post-2007Q4 data for the macroeconomic series.
Finally, the factor loadings matrix is applied to the six estimated
factors to predict the same series in the post-2007Q4 period. The key
point for Reis was that, with this methodology, the post-2007Q4 factors
are "old" in the sense that they are based on the pre-2007Q4
linear combinations of the series. As the footnote explained, if there
were a new factor, the space spanned by the factors would change, so the
new factor would not be spanned by the post-2007Q4 estimated factors.
Reis likened this process to a much simpler exercise: Imagine being
given data on durable goods output and nondurable goods output for a
number of years. These two series sum to total goods output. Then
suppose one is given total goods output for the next few years and asked
to predict durable goods output and nondurable goods output during that
period. The strength of the prediction will depend on how well one is
able to capture the relationship among durable goods, nondurable goods,
and total output over the period for which data on all three series are
available, and whether this relationship continues to hold in the period
over which the prediction is made.
Reis drew from the authors' analysis a much weaker claim than
some other panelists had suggested. The exercise did not, he argued,
imply that the world did not change in 2007. The six factors may have
undergone larger innovations than in past decades, or become more
stochastically volatile, but such changes would still be consistent with
the authors' finding, so long as no new type of shock had emerged.
Reis saw the authors' "no new shock" finding as
consistent with theorizing by other economists trying to explain the
sources of the financial crisis. That work often focuses on just one or
two types of structural shocks--such as preference shocks, technology
shocks, or monetary policy shocks--and abstracts away other aspects of
the economy. Thanks to Stock and Watson's work, Reis thought, these
researchers could rest assured that they are not ignoring some
unidentified "animal spirit" or other type of shock that could
undermine their models.
Finally, following on Wolfers' point, Reis thought that the
correlations between variables that had previously been identified as
instrumental show that economists have limited understanding of what
structural shocks are driving the factor innovations in Stock and
Watson's model.
Wendy Edelberg noted that, at the trough of the recession, if
policy-makers had been able to predict the path of GDP growth over the
next few years, they presumably would have enacted different policies.
She wondered, then, whether the authors' analysis shed any light on
what policy-makers should have done during the recession.
Christopher Sims highlighted the fact that Stock and Watson's
results were driven, in part, by large deviations from historical norms
in the interest rate and in monetary aggregates. He thought it was
misleading to acknowledge these large historical deviations but ignore
the fact that, in their absence, other macroeconomic variables would
have behaved very differently. He saw Stock and Watson's inability
to predict what would have happened in the absence of significant policy
intervention as a limitation of their analysis.
Sims analogized the issue to tracking the temperature in one's
kitchen from day to day. On a typical day, the temperature rises while
dinner is cooking and then falls. Suppose one day a fire started while
dinner was being prepared and a fire extinguisher was used to put the
fire out. The time path of temperature in the kitchen would look
relatively normal, but it would be incorrect to say nothing unusual had
happened, because had the fire extinguisher not been used, the
temperature in the kitchen would have developed very differently that
evening.
Michael Kiley characterized the authors' work as a tracking
exercise rather than a prediction exercise. He did not find it
surprising that their factors were able to track macroeconomic
aggregates well. He saw their principal component analysis as
identifying an "economic activity" factor, which, much like
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago's National Activity Index,
could track GDP well using a linear combination of other macroeconomic
time series. Applying Okun's Law, one could also use the same
factor to track the unemployment rate fairly well.
Kiley thought the authors were correct to identify the financial
shock as an important driver of the recession, and correct to say that,
conditional on the large shock to financial prices, the macrodynamics
that followed were not so surprising. However, their model did not
incorporate a rich enough picture of the financial system to determine
whether the forces that created or amplified the large financial shock
were surprising or unusual or nonlinear. The panic related to
mortgage-backed securities and the collapse of three investment funds
held by the French bank BNP Paribas, for example, were unusual events
that seemed to have induced large movements in financial markets but
were not captured by Stock and Watson's model.
Responding to the discussion, James Stock agreed with Brainard that
his and Watson's detrending method may not always distinguish well
between shocks and trends, especially near the end of certain data
series. He and Watson had run sensitivity checks that gave them
confidence in their results, but they thought that more work needed to
be done in identifying trends in macroeconomic series and that
researchers would do well to study trend identification more closely.
Replying to Wolfers, Stock felt that macroeconomists' work on
finding exogenous instruments was very constructive and well worth
continuing. He did not view the correlations between instruments as a
setback but rather as a source of new questions to pursue.
Stock also thought that Reis's interpretation of his and
Watson's findings was essentially correct. To further clarify, he
explained that, in the post-2007Q4 period, there did not appear to be
any new factor driving correlation across the idiosyncratic errors in
their model. And in linear algebraic terms, the space spanned by the
factors also spanned the innovations in time series over the course of
the recession. This seemed reasonable to Stock since the shocks driving
the crisis, such as financial and uncertainty shocks, had occurred
before on smaller scales.
Replying to Sims, Stock conceded that the results reflected only
the net effect of financial shocks and countervailing policy
interventions, measured on a quarterly basis. He and Watson had hoped to
be able to examine these shocks at a finer level, but data limitations
had prevented this.
Finally, Stock acknowledged that linear models like theirs were
subject to substantial limitations and that nonlinearities could well be
driving some patterns in the data. However, not all nonlinearities
present problems; some should and do translate into shocks in their
model. The zero lower bound, for example, is a nonlinear constraint that
prevents the interest rate from falling below zero. In their framework
this constraint translates into a contractionary monetary policy shock
during the latter part of the Great Recession. However, nonlinearities
that cannot be captured by shocks are not handled well by their model.
JAMES H. STOCK
Harvard University
MARK W. WATSON
princeton University
(1.) The view that financial recessions and recoveries are
different from "normal" recessions has been articulated most
notably by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009); see also Reinhart and Reinhart
(2010), Hall (2010), Mishkin (2010), Bank of Canada (2011), and Jorda,
Schularick, and Taylor (2011).
(2.) Various reasons have been proposed for why this recovery is
exceptional, including the deleveraging that followed the financial
crisis (for example, Mian and Sufi 2011), regional or industry job
mismatch (for example, Sahin and others 2011), changes in labor
management practices (for example, Berger 2011), and monetary policy
rendered ineffective because of the zero lower bound.
(3.) Online appendixes and replication files for the papers in this
volume may be accessed on the Brookings Papers website,
www.brookings.edu/about/projects/bpea, under "Past Editions."
They are also accessible at Mark Watson's personal website at
Princeton University, www.princeton.edu/~mwatson/.
(4.) Equations 1 and 2 are the static form of the DFM, so called
because the factors F, enter with no leads or lags in equation 1. For a
discussion of the relationship between the dynamic and the static forms
of the DFM, see Stock and Watson (2011).
(5.) Endpoints are handled by truncating the kernel and
renormalizing the truncated weights to add to 1. This approach has the
desirable feature that it makes no assumption about reversion to the
local mean, in contrast to the mean reversion imposed by the standard
approach of using a stationary time-series model to pad the series with
forecasts and backcasts. We alternatively computed the local means using
a Baxter-King (1999) highpass filter with a pass band of periods with
[less than or equal to] 200 quarters, and using the trend implied by a
"local level" model (the sum of independent random walk and
white noise with a ratio of disturbance standard deviations of 0.025),
and obtained similar results. The weights for these different filters
are given in the online appendix.
(6.) Our procedure produces a smooth but not necessarily monotonic
trend. Kim and Eo (2012) model the trend decline in the growth rate of
GDP as a single Markov switching break and estimate a decline of 0.7
percentage point over this period, less than our estimate of 1.2
percentage points. If the trend is in fact smoothly declining, one would
expect their step-function approximation to estimate a smaller average
decline than our local mean.
(7.) Specifically, let [[??].sub.t] denote the vector of 132
disaggregated time series used to estimate the factors, and let [??]
denote their corresponding factor loadings. These factor loadings are
estimated by principal components using data on [[??].sub.t] over
1959Q1-2007Q3 (modified for some series having missing observations; see
the online appendix). Denote the resulting estimates of [??] by
[[??].sup.59-07], normalized so that [[??].sup.59-07],
[[??].sup.59-07]=I. The estimated "old" factors are computed
using [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], ..., 2011Q2.
The values of [[??].sub.t] post-2007Q4 are those of the "old"
factors in the sense that they are based on the pre-2007Q4 linear
combinations of [[??].sub.t]. The factor loadings for the remaining 68
series (the high-level aggregates) are obtained by regressing each
series on [[??].sup.59-07.sub.t] using data through 2007Q3; these
estimates, combined with [[??].sup.59-07] yield the estimated
"old" factor loadings, [[??].sup.59-07]. The vector of common
components of the full vector of time series associated with these
"old" factors and "old" factor loadings is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
(8.) The assumption that the factors and DFMs can be estimated with
no breaks over the 1959Q1-2007Q3 period is only partially consistent
with the empirical evidence. On the side of stability, in Stock and
Watson (2009) we use a similar data set and find that the space spanned
by the full-sample (no-break) factors spans the space of the factors
estimated using pre- and post-1984 subsamples; against this, there we
also find breaks in some factor loadings in 1984Q1. These apparently
contradictory findings can be reconciled by the property of DFMs that
the space spanned by the factors can be estimated consistently even if
there is instability in A (Stock and Watson 2002, 2009, Bates and others
2012). These findings suggest that, in the present analysis, we can
ignore the 1984Q1 break when estimating the factors; however, tests of
coefficient stability might be sensitive to whether the comparison
sample includes pre-1984Q1 data. We therefore consider a DFM with a
break in 1984Q1 as a sensitivity check. Additional sensitivity checks,
with breaks in 1984Q1, are reported in the online appendix.
(9.) The Bai-Ng (2002) [IC.sub.P1] and [IC.sub.P2] criteria select
either three or four factors, depending on the sample period, whereas
their [IC.sub.P3] criterion selected 12 factors. The scree plot (the
plot of the ordered eigenvalues of the sample covariance matrix of
[X.sub.t] drops sharply to four or five factors and then declines
slowly.
(10.) Using the notation of footnote 7, let [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] be the prediction error using the
"old" model and factors. The subsample [R.sup.2] for series i
is computed as [R.sup.2] = 1-([[summation].sub.t]
[[??].sup.2.sub.it])/([[summation].sub.t] [X.sup.2.sub.it]) where the
sums are computed over the column subsample.
(11.) Giannone, Lenza. and Reichlin (2012) examine the stability of
the relationship between various types of loans and macroeconomic
indicators in the euro zone during and after the crisis, relative to a
precrisis benchmark: they find no surprising behavior of loans to
nonfinancial corporations, conditional on aggregate activity, although
there are departures from historical patterns for household loans.
(12.) The negative quarterly [R.sup.2]s for output per hour reflect
a timing mismatch, and 4-quarter growth in productivity is well
predicted. The predicted values for average hourly earnings growth
change from procyclical to countercyclical in the mid-1980s, and the
negative [R.sup.2] reflects this apparent instability in the factor
loadings in 1984, not something special to the 2007-09 recession.
(13.) The Andrews (2003) test is based on an analogue of the usual
(homoskedasticity-only) Chow break-test statistic, with a p value that
is computed by subsampling.
(14.) Rewrite the factor VAR (equation 1) as [F.sub.t] =
[??](L)[F.sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t], so, from equation 2, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the contribution of the past
factors and [LAMBDA][[eta].sub.t], is the innovation in the common
component. The innovations in table 5 are the residuals from a four-lag
VAR estimated using the "old" factors over 1959-2011Q2.
(15.) The approach to structural VAR identification laid out here,
including the estimator in the just-identified case, was originally
presented in Stock and Watson (2008). This approach was also developed
independently in Mertens and Ravn (2012), of which we became aware after
presenting the conference draft of this paper. The idea of using
constructed exogenous shocks (what we call external instruments) as
instruments in structural VARs dates at least to Hamilton (2003); also
see Kilian (2008a, 2008b).
(16.) Other candidate instruments include the market announcement
movements of Cochrane and Piazzesi (2002) and Faust, Swanson, and Wright
(2004).
(17.) Lee, Rabanal, and Sandri (2010) take the uncertainty shock to
be the innovation to the VIX.
(18.) In the notation of equations 3 and 5, the factor component
due to the jth structural shock is
A[PHI][(L).sup.-1][H.sub.j][[epsilon].sub.jt]. The [R.sup.2] of the jth
variable with respect to the jth shock is thus computed as [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], where [[??]'.sub.i] is the ith row of
[??].
(19.) Again, to be clear, these statements concern correlations
among the shock series estimated using the instruments, not correlations
among the underlying instruments themselves. For example, whereas the
correlation between the shock estimated using the Fisher-Peters (2010)
spending instrument and the shock estimated using the Romer-Romer (2010)
tax instrument is -0.93, the correlation between the Fisher-Peters and
the Romer-Romer instruments themselves is only -0.06.
(20.) These averages exclude the recovery that began in 1980Q3
because the next recession started within the 8-quarter window of these
calculations.
(21.) Allowing for a break in [PHI](L) in 1984Q1 produces somewhat
faster predicted recoveries before 1984 and somewhat slower ones after
1984; for details see the online appendix.
(22.) The online appendix reports results for five- and
seven-factor models. The only notable departure from the results
reported in this paper for the six-factor model is that the five- and
seven-factor models predict a stronger post-2009Q2 recovery, so they
attribute even more of the gap between that recovery and the 1960-82
recoveries to the slowdown in trend growth.
(23.) Two pieces of evidence suggest that the observed decline in
employment growth is not an artifact of long-term mismeasurement. First,
trend growth in employment measured by the household survey exhibits the
same pattern as that in the establishment survey, with a decline from
2.1 percent annually in 1970 to 1.0 percent annually in 2000; this
1.l-percentage-point decline is close to the 1.4-percentage-point
decline in the establishment survey (see the online appendix). Second,
the small net trend in GDP per worker (from the establishment survey)
matches the small net trend in output per hour (nonfarm business), which
would not be the case if nonfarm business hours (a narrower measure) are
correctly measured but employment is increasingly underestimated.
(24.) Focusing solely on demographic shifts ignores other potential
factors affecting labor force participation. One such factor is an
endogenous response to the stagnation of median real wages; however,
although the magnitude of the labor supply elasticity is debated, micro
studies generally suggest that it is small (see Saez, Slemrod, and
Giertz 2012, Chetty 2011, and Chetty and others forthcoming for
discussions). Another such factor is a possible trend increase in the
mismatch between worker skills and available jobs. For example, Goldin
and Katz (2008) point to a plateau in the supply of educated Americans
around 1980. Jaimovich and Siu (2012) present evidence that the trend
adjustments in employment occur mainly through permanent losses of
mid-skill jobs during and following recessions; this view of step-like
adjustments differs from our smooth trend. It goes beyond the scope of
this paper to examine these factors in any detail.
Table 1. Subsample R's of Regressions of Common Components on
Actual Data for Selected Macroeconomic Variables (a)
1959- 1984-
Series 2007Q3 2007Q3
GDP 0.73 0.62
Consumption (total) 0.63 0.45
Consumption (services) 0.35 0.22
Nonresidential fixed investment 0.63 0.57
Industrial production (total) 0.87 0.79
Industrial production (automobiles) 0.58 0.29
Nonfarm employment 0.92 0.91
Unemployment rate 0.84 0.75
Short-term unemployment rate 0.82 0.70
Long-term unemployment rate 0.61 0.58
Housing starts 0.59 0.39
OFHEO house price index 0.49 0.44
PCE inflation 0.51 0.54
PCE gas and energy inflation 0.37 0.48
Federal funds rate 0.44 0.34
Real monetary base 0.16 0.09
Real commercial and industrial loans 0.44 0.54
TED spread 0.54 0.02
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 0.48 0.48
S&P 500 index 0.72 0.69
VIX 0.47 0.50
SLOOS lending standards 0.60 0.18
Household net worth-disposable income ratio 0.16 0.14
Household liabilities 0.57 0.48
Computed over 15
quarters starting
at indicated
cyclical peak
Series 1960Q2 1969Q4 1973Q4
GDP 0.81 0.79 0.83
Consumption (total) 0.59 0.77 0.66
Consumption (services) 0.28 0.46 -0.06
Nonresidential fixed investment 0.64 0.77 0.90
Industrial production (total) 0.90 0.86 0.94
Industrial production (automobiles) 0.59 0.61 0.70
Nonfarm employment 0.93 0.94 0.93
Unemployment rate 0.77 0.88 0.95
Short-term unemployment rate 0.81 0.87 0.90
Long-term unemployment rate 0.55 0.62 0.68
Housing starts 0.27 0.59 0.83
OFHEO house price index n.a n.a n.a
PCE inflation 0.25 0.70 0.66
PCE gas and energy inflation -0.42 -1.69 -0.63
Federal funds rate -0.01 0.47 0.57
Real monetary base 0.18 0.39 0.22
Real commercial and industrial loans 0.48 0.47 0.55
TED spread n.a n.a 0.78
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread n.a n.a 0.89
S&P 500 index 0.75 0.68 0.89
VIX n.a 0.38 0.74
SLOOS lending standards n.a n.a 0.65
Household net worth-disposable income ratio -0.18 0.67 0.48
Household liabilities -0.19 0.73 0.90
Computed over 15
quarters starting
at indicated
cyclical peak
Series 1980Q1 1981Q3 1990Q3
GDP 0.79 0.85 0.73
Consumption (total) 0.82 0.72 0.74
Consumption (services) 0.62 0.47 0.47
Nonresidential fixed investment 0.58 0.57 0.50
Industrial production (total) 0.93 0.94 0.89
Industrial production (automobiles) 0.64 0.39 0.66
Nonfarm employment 0.95 0.98 0.93
Unemployment rate 0.91 0.88 0.76
Short-term unemployment rate 0.88 0.84 0.81
Long-term unemployment rate 0.74 0.71 0.44
Housing starts 0.79 0.76 0.62
OFHEO house price index 0.59 -0.01 0.60
PCE inflation 0.44 0.40 0.57
PCE gas and energy inflation 0.25 0.23 0.55
Federal funds rate 0.48 0.41 0.72
Real monetary base 0.65 0.59 -0.18
Real commercial and industrial loans -1.42 -1.07 0.70
TED spread 0.74 0.70 -0.05
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 0.11 0.49 0.12
S&P 500 index 0.62 0.65 0.37
VIX -0.78 -0.69 0.40
SLOOS lending standards 0.79 0.67 0.55
Household net worth-disposable income ratio 0.78 0.06 0.28
Household liabilities 0.76 0.70 0.79
Computed over
15 quarters
starting at
indicated
cyclical peak
Series 2001Q1 2007Q4
GDP 0.64 0.64
Consumption (total) 0.02 0.57
Consumption (services) -0.25 0.84
Nonresidential fixed investment 0.69 0.86
Industrial production (total) 0.76 0.95
Industrial production (automobiles) 0.13 0.57
Nonfarm employment 0.91 0.96
Unemployment rate 0.79 0.89
Short-term unemployment rate 0.75 0.78
Long-term unemployment rate 0.51 0.64
Housing starts 0.29 0.53
OFHEO house price index 0.42 0.57
PCE inflation 0.56 0.82
PCE gas and energy inflation 0.48 0.71
Federal funds rate 0.14 -1.51
Real monetary base -0.35 -0.03
Real commercial and industrial loans 0.62 0.46
TED spread -0.04 0.76
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 0.65 n.a
S&P 500 index 0.81 0.89
VIX 0.75 0.89
SLOOS lending standards -1.49 0.47
Household net worth-disposable income ratio -0.46 0.51
Household liabilities 0.18 0.77
Source: Authors' calculations; see the notes to figure 1 and the
online appendix for further details.
(a.) Common components are calculated using the six static factors
from the DFM estimated using quarterly data over 1959Q1-2007Q3;
predicted values are the "old model/old factors" values computed
as described in footnote 7 in the text. All entries are 1 minus
the ratio of the sum of squared prediction errors to the sum of
squares of the observed variable (see footnote 10). "n.a."
indicates that the regression was not performed because data for
that series were not available for the indicated period. All
series are transformed and detrended as described in sections
1.13 and LC and in the online appendix
Table 2. Subsample [R.sup.2] of the Common Component Regressions by
Category (a)
[R.sup.2]
1959- 1984-
Series category N 2007Q3 2007Q3
National income and product 21 0.56 0.43
accounts
Industrial production 13 0.72 0.60
Employment and unemployment 46 0.62 0.50
Housing starts 8 0.37 0.21
Inventories, orders, and sales 8 0.54 0.35
Prices 39 0.15 0.05
Earnings and productivity 13 0.37 0.29
Interest rates 18 0.40 0.30
Money and credit 12 0.44 0.26
Stock prices and wealth 11 0.47 0.52
Housing prices 3 0.67 0.67
Exchange rates 6 0.56 0.66
Other 2 0.42 0.42
[R.sup.2]
Computed over 15 quarters starting
at indicated cyclical peak
Series category 1960Q2 1969Q4 1973Q4 1980Q1
National income and product 0.56 0.46 0.62 0.66
accounts
Industrial production 0.78 0.77 0.86 0.86
Employment and unemployment 0.64 0.68 0.76 0.76
Housing starts 0.09 0.26 0.54 0.46
Inventories, orders, and sales 0.39 0.69 0.72 0.73
Prices 0.00 0.15 0.37 0.18
Earnings and productivity 0.52 0.38 0.35 0.30
Interest rates -0.07 0.39 0.30 0.50
Money and credit 0.22 0.47 0.55 0.65
Stock prices and wealth 0.00 0.67 0.74 0.62
Housing prices n.a n.a n.a 0.59
Exchange rates -2.64 0.47 0.64 0.48
Other -0.40 0.15 0.87 0.89
[R.sup.2]
Computed over 15 quarters starting
at indicated cyclical peak
Series category 1981Q3 1990Q3 2001Q1 2007Q4
National income and product 0.59 0.64 0.49 0.65
accounts
Industrial production 0.80 0.66 0.61 0.80
Employment and unemployment 0.81 0.61 0.63 0.78
Housing starts 0.54 0.44 -0.16 0.27
Inventories, orders, and sales 0.68 0.66 0.43 0.64
Prices 0.08 0.03 0.14 0.13
Earnings and productivity -0.03 0.32 0.36 -0.11
Interest rates 0.44 0.29 0.07 -0.50
Money and credit 0.63 0.40 0.06 -0.37
Stock prices and wealth 0.50 0.37 0.31 0.77
Housing prices -0.01 0.60 0.72 0.57
Exchange rates 0.66 0.75 0.72 0.60
Other 0.89 0.48 -0.60 0.31
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Based on the six-factor DFM estimated over 1959Q1-2007Q3.
Entries are the median of the R's of the common component,
computed for the series in the row category over the indicated
period, where the R' is computed as described in the notes to
table 1. "n.a." indicates that the regression was not performed
because data for that series were not available for the indicated
period.
Table 3. Tests of Absence of a Break in Factor Loadings
Percent of series in the
category for which the
hypothesis of a break at
2007Q4 is rejected at the
5 percent level (a)
Series category N 1959-2007Q3 1984Q1-2007Q3
National income and product 21 0 0
accounts
Industrial production 13 0 0
Employment and unemployment 46 15 15
Housing starts 8 25 13
Inventories, orders, and sales 8 13 13
Prices 39 26 23
Earnings and productivity 13 15 8
Interest rates 18 0 11
Money and credit 12 42 17
Stock prices and wealth 11 18 0
Housing prices 3 33 33
Exchange rates 6 0 0
Other 2 0 0
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) The Andrews (2003) end-of-sample stability test is used to
test the hypothesis of stability of the factor loadings. The
statistic tests the null hypothesis of constant factor loadings
against the alternative of a break in the final 15 quarters
(2007Q4-2011Q2) relative to the value of the factor loading
estimated over the indicated period.
Table 4. Standard Deviations of Four-Quarter Growth Rates of
Major Activity Variables (a)
Standard deviation of series
Series 1959-83 1984-2004 2005-11 (b)
GDP 2.6 1.6 2.8
Consumption 2.1 1.3 2.3
Investment 11.4 8.5 15.3
Industrial production (total) 5.2 3.1 6.4
Nonfarm employment 2.0 1.4 2.3
Change in unemployment rate (c) 1.1 0.8 1.5
Standard deviation of factor
component
Series 1959-83 1984-2004 2005-11 (b)
GDP 2.6 1.4 2.8
Consumption 2.1 1.2 2.4
Investment 10.5 6.8 11.4
Industrial production (total) 4.9 3.2 5.9
Nonfarm employment 1.9 1.3 2.5
Change in unemployment rate (c) 1.1 0.7 1.4
(a.) Entries are standard deviations of 4-quarter detrended
growth rates, except where noted otherwise, over the indicated
period. The first three columns report standard deviations of the
row series. and the second three columns report standard
deviations of the factor component of the row series.
(b.) Calculations go through the final quarter in the data set,
201 IQ2.
(c.) Entries refer to the 4-quarter detrended change in the
unemployment rate.
Table 5. Innovations to Factor Components of Selected Series,
2007Q1-2011Q2
Standard deviation units
Total
Quarter GDP consumption Investment Employment Productivity
2007Q1 -0.9 -1.3 -0.4 -0.7 -1.2
2007Q2 0.3 -0.2 0.5 -0.1 0.2
2007Q3 -0.3 -0.8 0.0 -0.7 0.0
2007Q4 -0.3 -1.3 0.1 0.3 -0.7
2008Q1 -0.3 -0.7 0.1 0.2 -0.4
2008Q2 -1.4 -2.1 -0.4 -1.1 -2.1
2008Q3 -1.7 -1.7 -1.0 -0.7 -1.4
2008Q4 1.0 2.1 -0.1 -0.4 4.6#
2009Q1 0.3 -2.7 2.3 0.9 -0.3
2009Q2 2.9 1.8 3.3# 3.8# 0.7
2009Q3 1.6 0.4 1.9 2.3 -0.6
2009Q4 -1.2 -0.9 -2.0 -2.1 -0.2
2010Q1 0.3 -0.1 0.6 0.5 0.0
2010Q2 0.7 0.3 0.7 0.3 1.3
2010Q3 0.8 -0.3 1.1 0.4 0.9
2010Q4 0.3 -0.6 0.6 0.0 0.0
2011Q1 0.4 -0.6 1.1 0.5 -0.6
2011Q2 -0.9 -0.8 -1.1 -1.3 -0.6
Standard deviation units
Housing Oil Federal TED Household
Quarter starts price funds rate spread VIX wealth
2007Q1 0.2 1.7 0.3 0.0 -0.6 0.0
2007Q2 0.8 1.1 0.5 -0.9 -1.4 0.8
2007Q3 -0.7 0.3 -0.6 0.7 1.2 -1.0
2007Q4 -1.3 1.3 0.4 0.4 0.5 -0.9
2008Q1 -1.3 0.2 -0.1 1.4 2.2 -2.0
2008Q2 1.0 3.4# 0.5 0.1 -0.4 -0.8
2008Q3 -3.5# -0.6 0.2 3.9# 2.9 -2.6
2008Q4 -8.3# -10.3# -2.5 7.7# 8.3# -4.1#
2009Q1 -4.7# 2.5 3.5# 4.0# 1.4 -3.3#
2009Q2 2.9 2.8 3.8# -3.0# -3.4# 1.2
2009Q3 4.8# 5.0# 1.5 -5.2# -3.5# 1.5
2009Q4 0.1 -0.4 -2.1 -1.7 -2.1 2.7
2010Q1 -0.5 0.3 1.2 0.9 0.0 -0.6
2010Q2 -2.4 -1.8 0.3 2.1 1.6 -1.2
2010Q3 -1.7 0.0 0.9 1.0 0.3 -0.7
2010Q4 0.6 1.7 0.8 -1.0 -1.8 0.8
2011Q1 1.5 2.8 1.2 -0.9 -0.8 -0.5
2011Q2 0.5 0.4 -1.5 -0.7 0.1 0.3
Sources: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Entries are the standardized innovations in the factor
component of each series, computed relative to the six factors;
series are standardized by dividing by the standard deviation of
the 1959-2007Q3 factor component innovations for that series.
Standardized innovations equal to or exceeding 3 in absolute
value are italicized.
Note: Standardized innovations equal to or exceeding 3 in absolute
value are indicated with #.
Table 6. Subsample R's of Regressions Evaluating the Factor
Component of GDP Growth Associated with Individual Identified
Shocks (a)
F 1959- 1984-
Structural shock and instrument statistic (b) 2007Q3 2007Q3
Oil shock
Hamilton 2.9 0.18 0.01
Kilian 1.1 0.08 -0.03
Ramey-Vine 1.8 0.14 -0.04
Monetan, policy shock
Romer-Romer 4.5 0.23 -0.16
Smets-Wouters 9.0 0.18 -0.01
Sims-Zha 6.5 0.19 -0.30
Gurkaynak-Sack-Swanson 0.6 0.12 -0.07
Productivity shock
Fernald TFP 14.5 0.29 0.14
Gali long-run output per hour NA 0.07 0.02
Smets-Wouters 7.0 0.20 -0.04
Uncertainty shock
Bloom financial uncertainty (VIX) 43.2 0.08 0.03
Baker-Bloom-Davis policy 12.5 0.11 0.02
uncertainty
Liquidity-financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 4.5 0.12 -0.09
TED spread 12.3 0.18 -0.08
Bassett and others bank loan 4.4 0.11 0.04
supply
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending 0.5 0.21 -0.06
Fisher-Peters spending 1.3 0.23 0.04
Romer-Romer tax 0.5 0.16 -0.20
Principal components of
uncertainty and credit spread
shocks
First principal component NA 0.14 -0.03
Second principal component NA 0.19 0.07
Computed over 15 quarters starting
at indicated cyclical peak
Structural shock and instrument 1969Q4 1973Q4 1980Q1 1981Q3
Oil shock
Hamilton 0.26 0.49 0.10 0.11
Kilian 0.15 0.10 0.20 0.24
Ramey-Vine 0.27 0.24 0.38 0.49
Monetan, policy shock
Romer-Romer 0.35 0.31 0.57 0.57
Smets-Wouters 0.24 0.25 0.32 0.23
Sims-Zha 0.29 0.44 0.54 0.51
Gurkaynak-Sack-Swanson 0.07 0.39 0.26 0.26
Productivity shock
Fernald TFP 0.39 0.08 0.31 0.28
Gali long-run output per hour 0.12 0.06 0.10 0.05
Smets-Wouters 0.35 0.39 0.18 0.17
Uncertainty shock
Bloom financial uncertainty (VIX) 0.12 0.16 0.18 0.31
Baker-Bloom-Davis policy 0.15 0.40 0.15 0.14
uncertainty
Liquidity-financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 0.17 0.21 0.25 0.38
TED spread 0.28 0.45 0.31 0.21
Bassett and others bank loan 0.20 0.25 0.13 0.31
supply
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending 0.36 0.35 0.50 0.55
Fisher-Peters spending 0.27 0.02 0.32 0.36
Romer-Romer tax 0.21 0.25 0.36 0.31
Principal components of
uncertainty and credit spread
shocks
First principal component 0.21 0.36 0.25 0.26
Second principal component 0.17 0.49 0.31 0.40
Computed over 15 quarters
starting at indicated
cyclical peak
Structural shock and instrument 1990Q3 2001Q1 2007Q4
Oil shock
Hamilton 0.23 -0.55 -0.14
Kilian -0.03 -0.26 0.37
Ramey-Vine 0.20 0.40 0.23
Monetan, policy shock
Romer-Romer 0.16 0.08 0.26
Smets-Wouters 0.37 0.16 0.46
Sims-Zha -0.01 0.03 0.03
Gurkaynak-Sack-Swanson 0.00 -0.05 0.34
Productivity shock
Fernald TFP 0.33 -0.42 -0.14
Gali long-run output per hour 0.00 -0.11 -0.04
Smets-Wouters -0.05 -0.36 -0.17
Uncertainty shock
Bloom financial uncertainty (VIX) 0.22 0.23 0.34
Baker-Bloom-Davis policy 0.48 0.15 0.62
uncertainty
Liquidity-financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 0.07 0.30 0.57
TED spread 0.21 0.30 0.38
Bassett and others bank loan 0.27 0.45 0.41
supply
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending 0.06 0.01 0.19
Fisher-Peters spending 0.41 -0.06 0.09
Romer-Romer tax 0.08 -0.38 -0.02
Principal components of
uncertainty and credit spread
shocks
First principal component 0.30 0.23 0.48
Second principal component 0.38 0.32 0.54
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Structural shocks are computed using the full-sample
six-factor DFM and the indicated instrument, as described in sections
III.A and III.B of the text. [R.sup.2]s are for the contribution
of the indicated shock to the variation in GDP growth, computed
over the indicated subsample, as described in footnote 19. NA =
not applicable.
(b.) Non-HAC F statistic from the regression of the indicated
instrument on the six factor innovations.
Table 7. Correlations among Estimated Structural Shocks
[O.sub.H] [O.sub.K] [O.sub.RV]
[O.sub.H] 1.00#
[O.sub.K] 0.42# 1.00#
[O.sub.RV] 0.15# 0.60# 1.00#
[M.sub.RR] 0.37 0.65 * 0.77 *
[O.sub.SW] 0.09 0.11 0.39
[O.sub.MZ] 0.33 0.35 0.68
[O.sub.GSS] 0.44 -0.12 -0.08
[P.sub.F] -0.64 * 0.30 0.24
[P.sub.G] -0.40 0.34 0.01
[P.sub.SW] -0.91 * -0.03 0.00
[U.sub.B] -0.37 -0.37 -0.58
[U.sub.BBD] 0.10 0.11 -0.37
[L.sub.GZ] -0.20 -0.42 -0.51
[L.sub.TED] -0.09 0.01 -0.05
[L.sub.BCDZ] 0.04 0.22 0.79 *
[F.sub.R] -0.17 -0.64 * -0.77*
[F.sub.FP] 0.04 -0.21 -0.35
[F.sub.RR] 0.20 0.15 0.30
[M.sub.RR] [M.sub.SW] [M.sub.SZ] M.sub.GSS]
[O.sub.H]
[O.sub.K]
[O.sub.RV]
[M.sub.RR] 1.00#
[O.sub.SW] 0.09# 1.00#
[O.sub.MZ] 0.93# 0.16# 1.00#
[O.sub.GSS] 0.24# 0.43# 0.39# 1.00#
[P.sub.F] 0.20 -0.09 0.06 -0.57
[P.sub.G] -0.30 0.36 -0.S3 -0.37
[P.sub.SW] -0.24 -0.07 -0.36 -0.S9
[U.sub.B] -0.39 0.30 -0.29 0.37
[U.sub.BBD] -0.17 0.45 -0.22 0.S7
[L.sub.GZ] -0.41 0.44 -0.24 0.34
[L.sub.TED] 0.03 0.73 * 0.10 0.48
[L.sub.BCDZ] 0.56 0.13 0.55 0.04
[F.sub.R] -0.84 * -0.32 -0.72 * -0.34
[F.sub.FP] -0.72 * 0.20 -0.78 * -0.03
[F.sub.RR] 0.77 * -0.10 0.88 0.37
[P.sub.F] [P.sub.G] [P.sub.SW]
[O.sub.H]
[O.sub.K]
[O.sub.RV]
[M.sub.RR]
[O.sub.SW]
[O.sub.MZ]
[O.sub.GSS]
[P.sub.F] 1.00#
[P.sub.G] 0.52# 1.00#
[P.sub.SW] 0.82# 0.68# 1.00#
[U.sub.B] 0.19 0.34 0.27
[U.sub.BBD] -0.06 0.4S -0.01
[L.sub.GZ] 0.07 0.24 0.08
[L.sub.TED] 0.21 0.37 0.09
[L.sub.BCDZ] -0.09 -0.28 -0.06
[F.sub.R] -0.17 -0.01 0.01
[F.sub.FP] -0.49 0.40 -0.02
[F.sub.RR] 0.18 -0.59 -0.28
[U.sub.B] [U.sub.BBD]
[O.sub.H]
[O.sub.K]
[O.sub.RV]
[M.sub.RR]
[O.sub.SW]
[O.sub.MZ]
[O.sub.GSS]
[P.sub.F]
[P.sub.G]
[P.sub.SW]
[U.sub.B] 1.00#
[U.sub.BBD] 0.78 * 1.00
[L.sub.GZ] 0.92 * 0.66 *
[L.sub.TED] 0.80 0.76 *
[L.sub.BCDZ] -0.69 * -0.54
[F.sub.R] 0.26 -0.08
[F.sub.FP] 0.03 0.25
[F.sub.RR] 0.01 -0.10
[L.sub.GZ] [L.sub.TED] [L.sub.BCDZ]
[O.sub.H]
[O.sub.K]
[O.sub.RV]
[M.sub.RR]
[O.sub.SW]
[O.sub.MZ]
[O.sub.GSS]
[P.sub.F]
[P.sub.G]
[P.sub.SW]
[U.sub.B]
[U.sub.BBD]
[L.sub.GZ] 1.00#
[L.sub.TED] 0.84# 1.00#
[L.sub.BCDZ] -0.73# -0.40 1.00#
[F.sub.R] 0.4 -0.13 -0.13
[F.sub.FP] 0.03 -0.12 -0.12
[F.sub.RR] 0.02 0.19 0.19
[F.sub.R] [F.sub.FP] [F.sub.RR]
[O.sub.H]
[O.sub.K]
[O.sub.RV]
[M.sub.RR]
[O.sub.SW]
[O.sub.MZ]
[O.sub.GSS]
[P.sub.F]
[P.sub.G]
[P.sub.SW]
[U.sub.B]
[U.sub.BBD]
[L.sub.GZ]
[L.sub.TED]
[L.sub.BCDZ]
[F.sub.R] 1.00#
[F.sub.FP] 0.38# 1.00#
[F.sub.RR] -0.45 -0.93# 1.00
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Entries are correlations between individually identified
shocks, computed over the full 1959-2011 Q2 sample. Shading
denotes correlations within categories of shocks; italicized
correlations are cross-category correlations exceeding 0.60 in
absolute value. Shocks are those listed in table 6, abbreviated
as follows:
Oil: [O.sub.H], Hamilton (1996,2003); [O.sub.RV], Kilian (2008a);
ORV, Ramey-Vine (2010)
Monetary policy: [M.sub.RR], Romer and Romer (2004); [M.sub.SW],
Smets and Wouters (2007); [M.sub.GSS], Sims and Zha (2006);
[M.sub.SZ], Giirkaynak, Sack, and Swanson (2005)
Productivity: [P.sub.P], Fernald (2009) TFP; [P.sub.G], Gali
(1999); [P.sub.SW] Smets and Wouters (2007)
Uncertainty: [U.sub.VIX], Bloom (2009) financial uncertainty;
[U.sub.BBD] Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012) policy uncertainty
Liquidity and financial risk: [L.sub.GX], Gilchrist and
Zakraj"sek (forthcoming) spread; [L.sub.TED], spread;
[L.sub.BCDZ], Bassett and others (2011) bank loan supply
Fiscal policy: [F.sub.R], Ramey (201la) spending; [F.sub.FP],
Fisher-Peters (2010) spending; [F.sub.RR], Romer-Romer (2010)
tax.
Note: Shading denotes correlations within categories of shocks is
indicated with #.
Note: Correlations indicated with * are cross-category correlations
exceeding 0.60 in absolute value.
Table 8. Contributions of Identified Shocks to Cumulative
Post-2007Q4 Growth of GDP and Employment
Cumulative percentage change
in detrended GDP (a)
2007Q4- 2007Q4- 2007Q4-
Shock and instrument 2008Q3 2009Q2 2011Q2
Actual outcome -2.8 -8.7 -8.2
Factor component -4.0 -9.2 -6.0
Oil shock
Hamilton -1.0 -0.8 -0.8
Kilian -1.0 -2.1 -0.6
Ramey-Vine -l.4 -1.6 0.7
Monetary policy shock
Romer-Romer -1.1 -1.6 0.1
Smets-Wouters -0.4 -3.7 -5.0
Sims-Zha -0.3 -0.1 -0.1
GSS -0.8 -3.2 -4.3
Productivity shock
Fernald -0.7 0.0 1.4
Gali 0.4 0.3 1.1
Smets-Wouters -0.5 -0.1 0.6
Uncertainty shock
Financial uncertainty (VIX) -1.0 -4.1 0.2
Political uncertainty (BBD) -2.3 -5.8 -4.8
Liquidity/financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread -1.5 -6.3 -1.2
TED spread -1.2 -5.6 -4.9
Bassett and others bank loan -2.0 -3.2 0.1
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending -1.6 -1.6 -1.0
Fisher-Peters spending -0.3 -0.3 0.3
Romer-Romer tax 0.2 0.3 -0.2
Principal components of uncertainty
and credit spread shocks
First principal component -1.5 -6.2 -3.4
Second principal component -2.3 -7.6 -5.4
Cumulative percentage
change in detrended
payroll employment (a)
2007Q4- 2007Q4- 2007Q4-
Shock and instrument 2008Q3 2009Q2 2011Q2
Actual outcome -1.4 -6.2 -7.4
Factor component -2.1 -7.3 -8.9
Oil shock
Hamilton -0.4 -1.1 -1.0
Kilian -0.5 -1.7 -1.2
Ramey-Vine -1.1 -2.1 0.2
Monetary policy shock
Romer-Romer -0.7 -2.l 0.4
Smets-Wouters -0.5 -2.5 -6.2
Sims-Zha -0.5 -1.0 0.3
GSS 0.0 -1.0 -3.8
Productivity shock
Fernald -0.1 0.1 0.9
Gali 0.0 -0.6 -0.9
Smets-Wouters 0.2 -0.1 0.4
Uncertainty shock
Financial uncertainty (VIX) -0.9 -3.7 -2.2
Political uncertainty (BBD) -1.6 -4.6 -6.8
Liquidity/financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread -0.8 -4.6 -3.5
TED spread -0.8 -3.7 -6.8
Bassett and others bank loan -1.5 -3.5 -1.1
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending -0.9 -1.6 -0.5
Fisher-Peters spending -0.2 -0.7 0.3
Romer-Romer tax 0.2 0.0 0.3
Principal components of uncertainty
and credit spread shocks
First principal component -1.0 -4.5 -5.8
Second principal component -1.5 -5.8 -8.4
2009Q2 forecast
growth in factor
component,
2009Q2-2011Q2 (b)
Shock and instrument GDP Employment
Actual outcome
Factor component
Oil shock
Hamilton 1.8 1.0
Kilian 1.3 0.3
Ramey-Vine 1.5 1.2
Monetary policy shock
Romer-Romer 1.4 1.2
Smets-Wouters -0.6 -3.3
Sims-Zha 0.4 0.8
GSS -1.3 -2.7
Productivity shock
Fernald 0.2 0.2
Gali 1.0 0.5
Smets-Wouters 0.9 0.7
Uncertainty shock
Financial uncertainty (VIX) 3.5 0.6
Political uncertainty (BBD) 1.4 -2.0
Liquidity/financial risk shock
Gilchrist-Zakrajsek spread 3.6 -0.4
TED spread 0.8 -3.2
Bassett and others bank loan 2.7 1.3
Fiscal policy shock
Ramey spending 0.3 0.1
Fisher-Peters spending 0.4 0.5
Romer-Romer tax -0.1 0.3
Principal components of uncertainty
and credit spread shocks
First principal component 2.4 -1.8
Second principal component 2.7 -2.5
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Each entry after the top panel is the contribution of the
indicated shock to cumulative growth in GDP or employment over
the indicated period, computed as described in footnote 19 in the
text.
(b.) Implied forecasts of GDP or employment growth from 2009Q2 to
2011Q2, constructed in 2009Q2 associated with the indicated
shock.
Table 9. Predicted and Actual Cumulative Growth of Output, Employment,
and Productivity Following a Cyclical Trough (a)
Percent
Cumulative growth of common component
(or actual) over 8 quarters following
trough
Non farm Output per hour
Trough Source GDP employment (nonfarm business)
1961Q1 Cyclical 1.1 -1.0 2.0
Trend 7.5 4.9 4.8
Total 8.7 4.0 6.8
1970Q4 Cyclical 2.4 0.0 2.6
Trend 6.9 4.7 4.0
Total 9.3 4.6 6.6
1975Q1 Cyclical 3.3 -1.8 5.4
Trend 6.6 4.5 3.7
Total 9.9 2.7 9.1
1980Q3 Cyclical 1.1 -1.5 2.9
Trend 6.3 4.2 3.5
Total 7.5 2.7 6.4
1982Q4 Cyclical 5.0 1.1 4.3
Trend 6.2 4.1 3.5
Total 11.2 5.2 7.8
1991Q1 Cyclical 0.8 -1.6 2.5
Trend 5.9 3.3 3.8
Total 6.7 1.6 6.3
2001Q4 Cyclical 2.9 0.5 2.6
Trend 5.1 2.1 4.3
Total 8.0 2.6 6.9
2009Q2 Cyclical 2.4 -3.1 6.3
Trend 4.4 1.2 4.5
Total 6.8 -1.9 10.8
Averages
1960-82 Cyclical 3.0 -0.4 3.6
Trend 6.8 4.5 4.0
Total 9.8 4.1 7.6
Actual (a) 11.0 5.9 7.3
1960-2001 Cyclical 2.6 -0.5 3.2
Trend 6.4 3.9 4.0
Total 9.0 3.5 7.3
Actual (a) 9.2 4.0 7.2
Differences
2009Q2 minus Cyclical -0.6 -2.7 2.7
average, 1960-82 Trend -2.4 -3.3 0.5
Total -3.0 -6.0 3.2
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Entries are cumulative predicted growth rates of the common
component (or the actual value) of the indicated series, computed
using the factors at the trough and the DFM estimated through
2007Q3. Predicted paths are decomposed into the detrended
cyclical component (the contribution of the factors at the
trough) and the trend growth rate.
(b.) Excludes the post-1980Q3 recovery because the next recession
commenced within the 8-quarter window used in this table.
Table 10. Contributions of Trend Productivity, Labor Force, and
Population to Trend GDP Growth Rate (a)
Trend growth rate (a)
(percent per year)
Series and component 1965 1985 2005
GDP 3.7 3.1 2.5
GDP-employment ratio 1.6 1.3 1.5
Employment-population ratio 0.3 0.4 -0.2
Population 1.7 1.4 1.1
GDP-employment ratio 1.6 1.3 1.5
Ratio of GDP to NFB output -0.2 -0.3 -0.2
Ratio of NFB output to NFB hours 2.3 1.8 2.2
Ratio of NFB hours to NFB -0.4 -0.3 -0.2
employment
Ratio of NFB employment to total 0.0 0.1 -0.3
nonfarm employment
Employment-population ratio 0.3 0.4 -0.2
Employment as share of labor force 0.0 0.1 0.0
Labor force as share of population 0.3 0.4 -0.1
Labor force share of population 0.3 0.4 -0.1
Female 0.5 0.4 0.0
Male -0.2 -0.1 -0.2
Labor force 2.0 1.7 0.9
Female (prime-age) 0.7 0.8 0.3
Male (prime-age) 0.4 0.6 0.2
Female (non-prime-age) 0.5 0.2 0.2
Male (non-prime-age) 0.4 0.1 0.2
Difference 2005
minus 1965 (c)
Series and component (percentage points)
GDP -1.2
GDP-employment ratio -0.1
Employment-population ratio -0.5
Population -0.6
GDP-employment ratio -0.1
Ratio of GDP to NFB output 0.0
Ratio of NFB output to NFB hours -0.1
Ratio of NFB hours to NFB 0.2
employment
Ratio of NFB employment to total -0.3
nonfarm employment
Employment-population ratio -0.5
Employment as share of labor force 0.0
Labor force as share of population -0.5
Labor force share of population -0.5
Female -0.5
Male 0.1
Labor force -1.1
Female (prime-age) -0.4
Male (prime-age) -0.2
Female (non-prime-age) -0.3
Male (non-prime-age) -0.2
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Growth rates and differences for components may not sum to
those for totals because of rounding. Standard errors for the
estimated trends range from 0.1 for the labor force variables to
0.5 for GDP; for details see the online appendix. NFB = nonfarm
business.
(b.) Each entry is the growth in the trend component of the
indicated series in the indicated year, computed as described in
section I.C.
(c.) Difference between 2005 and 1965 trend values.