Fiscal policy in a depressed economy.
Delong, J. Bradford ; Summers, Lawrence H.
ABSTRACT In a depressed economy, with short-term nominal interest
rates at their zero lower bound, ample cyclical unemployment, and excess
capacity, increased government purchases would be neither offset by the
monetary authority raising interest rates nor neutralized by supply-side
bottlenecks. Then even a small amount of hysteresis--even a small shadow
cast on future potential output by the cyclical downturn--means, by
simple arithmetic, that expansionary fiscal policy is likely to be
self-financing. Even if it is not, it is highly likely to pass the
sensible benefit-cost test of raising the present value of future
potential output. Thus, at the zero bound, where the central bank cannot
or will not but in any event does not perform its full role in
stabilization policy, fiscal policy has the stabilization policy mission
that others have convincingly argued it lacks in normal times. Whereas
many economists have assumed that the path of potential output is
invariant to even a deep and prolonged downturn, the available evidence
raises a strong fear that hysteresis is indeed a factor. Although
nothing in our analysis calls into question the importance of
sustainable fiscal policies, it strongly suggests the need for caution
regarding the pace of fiscal consolidation.
**********
This paper examines fiscal policy in the context of an economy
suffering, like the United States today, from protracted high
unemployment and output short of potential. We argue that although the
conventional wisdom articulated by John Taylor (2000) rejecting
discretionary fiscal policy is appropriate in normal times, such policy
has a major role to play in a severe downturn in the aftermath of a
financial crisis that carries interest rates down to the zero nominal
lower bound.
Our analysis reaches five conclusions about fiscal policy as a
stabilization tool in a depressed as opposed to a normal economy:
--The absence of supply constraints in the short term, together
with a binding zero lower bound on interest rates, means that the
Keynesian multiplier is likely to be substantially greater than the
relatively small value it is thought to have in normal times. This
multiplier may well be further magnified by an additional zero-bound
effect: the impact of economic expansion on expected inflation and hence
on real interest rates.
--At current and expected future real interest rates on government
borrowing, even a very modest amount of "hysteresis," through
which cyclical output shortfalls affect the economy's future
potential, has a substantial effect on estimates of the impact of
expansionary fiscal policy on the future debt burden. Although the data
are far from conclusive, a number of fragments of evidence suggest that
additional government spending that mitigates protracted output losses
raises potential future output, even if the spending policies are not
directly productive in themselves. (1)
--Policies of austerity may well be counterproductive even by the
yardstick of reducing the burden of financing the national debt in the
future. Austerity in a depressed economy can erode the long-run fiscal
balance. Stimulus can improve it. (2)
--Arguments that expansionary fiscal policy at the zero bound is
not self-financing and does not pass a benefit-cost test by raising the
present value of future potential output hinge on establishing one of
three conditions: that monetary policy offsets the demand effects of
fiscal policy even at the zero bound sufficiently that the multiplier is
near zero, or that future potential output is invariant to the size and
length of the downturn, or that interest rates are at or above
the range seen historically, at least in the United States.
--Only when a government must pay a substantial premium over the
social rate of time discount in order to borrow is the economy unlikely
to benefit from expansionary fiscal policy at the zero bound.
The paper is organized as follows. Section I presents a highly
stylized example making our basic point regarding self-financing fiscal
policy. It then lays out an analytical framework for assessing the
likelihood that expansionary fiscal policy will actually be
expansionary, and it identifies the parameters that are most important
in evaluating the impact of fiscal policy changes.
Two further sections examine evidence on the central parameters in
our framework: the fiscal multiplier and the extent of hysteresis. Both
must be greater than zero for our central point to hold, yet both are
subject to considerable uncertainty. Other key parameters are subject to
less uncertainty: estimates of the expected future growth rate of
potential output are tightly clustered; the financial market's
estimate of real Treasury borrowing rates far into the future is public
information.
Section II argues that the multiplier is context-dependent,
depending in particular on the reaction function of monetary policy. It
concludes that at moments like the present--when interest rates are
constrained by the zero bound, the output gap is large, and cyclical
unemployment is high--fiscal policy is likely to be more potent than
standard estimates suggest. This conclusion boosts the benefits of
expansionary fiscal policy in a depressed economy substantially, but,
importantly, it does not depend on the policy-relevant multiplier being
higher than standard estimates of the fiscal policy multiplier.
Section III examines the available evidence on the extent of
hysteresis. Financial crises and demand-induced recessions appear to
have an impact on potential output even after normal conditions are
restored. This makes it plausible that measures that mitigate their
effects would have long-run benefits. We find corroboration both in the
behavior of economic forecasters and in a number of fragments of
evidence on the effects of recessions.
Finally, section IV takes up issues relating to interest rates and
monetary policy. It argues that available evidence on central bank
behavior suggests that it is unlikely that, in a severely depressed
economy, expansionary fiscal policy will lead to an offsetting monetary
policy response. The section concludes with a discussion of policy
implications of the analysis for the United States and the world. An
appendix uses the framework laid out in section I to consider the
conditions under which expansionary policy is not self-financing but
nonetheless passes the benefit-cost test of raising the present value of
output--what we call the "extra-output benefit-cost test."
I. Self-Financing Fiscal Policy
Assume an economy in which output is well below its potential,
cyclical unemployment is elevated, supply constraints on short-run
demand are absent, conventional monetary policy is constrained by the
zero lower bound, and the central bank is either unable or unwilling to,
but in any case does not, provide additional stimulus through
quantitative easing or other means (an assumption we discuss further in
section IV). (3) A simple calculation then conveys the main message of
this paper: under these circumstances, a combination of real government
borrowing rates in the historical range, modestly positive fiscal
multiplier effects, and small hysteresis effects are together sufficient
to render fiscal expansion self-financing.
Imagine, for example, that in this demand-constrained economy the
fiscal multiplier is 1.5, the real annual interest rate on long-term
government debt is 1 percent, a $1 increase in GDP increases the net
tax-and-transfer fiscal balance by $0.33, and a $1 shortfall of GDP
below potential this year permanently reduces future potential GDP by
$0.01--that is, a hysteresis "shadow" on future potential
output of only 1 percent. Assume further that the government has the
power to undertake a transitory increase in spending and then reverse it
without any impact on the risk premium that it pays on its borrowing.
Under these assumptions, the effect of an incremental $1 of
government spending is to increase current GDP by $1.50 and to raise the
debt by $0.50. The annual real debt service on this additional debt is
$0.005. The $1.50 increase in this year's GDP increases future
potential output by $0.015, which in turn augments future-period tax
revenue by $0.005, on the assumption that actual output averages to
potential output over the relevant future periods. Hence the fiscal
expansion is self-financing. In such a scenario, worries about the
adverse impact of fiscal stimulus on the government's long-run
budget are unwarranted, for there is no adverse impact.
This central point is made substantially stronger if one allows
for:
--underlying growth in the economy, so that the relevant fiscal
balance requirement is one of a stable debt-to-GDP ratio rather than a
stable real debt;
--increases in the future price level, as a result of the fiscal
expansion, that further reduce the real interest rate on accumulated and
newly issued debt; and
--the possibility that the additional government spending raises
future productivity, and thus future output, by increasing the
productive stocks of public infrastructure capital and private human
capital. (4)
This central point is a matter of arithmetic. It depends only on
the existence of a fiscal multiplier [mu] that is not near zero, the
existence of a plausible hysteresis shadow on future potential output,
low and unchanged government borrowing costs, and the assumption that a
temporary boost to government purchases is possible. If these four
assumptions are granted, the conclusion follows.
This section presents a reduced-form framework for assessing under
what conditions fiscal expansion is self-financing; the appendix
discusses the conditions under which, if fiscal expansion is not
self-financing, it nonetheless passes an extra-output benefit-cost test.
Our conclusions will apply to any underlying model that generates such a
reduced form.
A temporary boost to government purchases [DELTA]G boosts aggregate
demand through the short-term fiscal multiplier. More formally, an
increase in government spending for the present period only of [DELTA]G
percentage-point-of-potential-GDP-years is amplified by the
economy's short-term policy-relevant multiplier coefficient [mu],
reducing the output gap in the present period [Y.sub.n] ("n"
for "now") by an amount [DELTA][Y.sub.n], also measured in
percentage-point-years:
(1) [DELTA]][Y.sub.n] = [mu][DELTA]G.
We discuss in section II the value of [mu] in normal times and make
the crucial point that there is a strong likelihood that [mu] is now
above that value.
Financing this expansion of government purchases requires
increasing the national debt by an amount [DELTA]D, also measured in
percentage-point-of-potential-GDP-years. Given [mu] as before and
assuming a baseline marginal tax-and-transfer rate [tau], the required
increase in the national debt is then
(2) [DELTA]D : (1 - [mu][tau])[DELTA]G,
which is less than in the absence of the multiplier because higher
current output brings with it higher tax collections and thus an
immediate partial recapture of some of the costs of the fiscal
expansion.
If the economy's long-run growth rate is g and the real
government borrowing rate is r, (5) this additional debt [DELTA]D
imposes on the government an annual financing burden in percentage
points of a year's potential GDP of
(3) (r - g)[DELTA]D = (r - g)(1 - [mu][tau])[DELTA]G,
if it is to maintain a stable long-run debt-to-GDP ratio. In order
to maintain a stable debt-to-GDP ratio, the government must increase its
primary surplus by the difference between the growth rates of the debt
and of GDP times the increment to the debt. That is the left-hand side of equation 3. And the increment to the debt is simply (1 -
[mu][tau])[DELTA]G.
A depressed economy is one in which many workers are without
employment for an extended period. As a consequence, many see their
skills, the networks they use to match themselves with vacancies in the
labor market, and their morale all decay. A depressed economy is also
one in which investment is low, the capital stock is growing slowly if
at all, and entrepreneurial exploration is low, and it is certainly
possible that this deficit is not made up quickly. These factors may
well have an impact on future potential output.
Assume that in future periods production is determined by supply
and that there is no gap between real aggregate demand and potential
output. Then, in a typical future period, potential and actual output
<sub>Y</sub>f (where "f" stands for
"future") will be reduced by a hysteresis parameter [eta]
times the depth by which the economy is depressed in the present:
(4) [DELTA][Y.sub.f] = [eta]1[DELTA][Y.sub.n] = [eta][mu][DELTA]G.
The units of [eta] are inverse years: [eta] is the percent
reduction in the flow of future potential output per
percentage-point-year of the present-period output gap. We discuss the
mechanisms determining [eta] in section III.
A fiscal expansion undertaken to prevent hysteresis thus creates a
fiscal dividend: it raises future tax collections by an amount
(5) [tau][DELTA][Y.sub.f] = [tau][eta][mu][DELTA]G.
Equations 3 and 5 together imply that if
(6) (r - g)(l - [mu][tau]) - [eta][mu][tau] [less than or equal to]
0,
then at the margin, transitory expansionary fiscal policy is
self-financing. The boost to future potential output, and thus to future
net tax revenue, provided by shortening and lessening the current
downturn creates more public financial resources in the future than are
consumed by amortizing the additional debt incurred to finance the
transitory expansion. There is no cost to count against this benefit
from future fiscal expansion. This is the most important conclusion of
this paper.
Rearranging equation 6, we can show that this net future fiscal
dividend from the present-period fiscal expansion [DELTA]G arises as
long as r satisfies
(7) r [less than or equal to] g + [eta][mu][tau]/(1 - [mu][tau]).
As long as there is a short-term fiscal multiplier [mu], a
hysteresis shadow [eta], a tax-and-transfer share [tau], a real
government borrowing rate r, and a debt amortization equation
incorporating a trend growth rate g such that expression 7 holds, fiscal
expansion now improves the government's budget balance later. (6)
In this case, arguments that a depressed economy cannot afford fiscal
expansion now because the government dare not raise its debt have little
purchase. (7) And arguments that governments in such circumstances need
to demonstrate the credibility of their long-run fiscal strategy by
curbing spending today lack coherence, because cutting spending does not
improve but rather worsens the long-run fiscal picture.
For what values in the parameter space does expression 7 hold, if
we take the marginal tax rate [tau] and the expected rate of long-run
GDP growth g to be their consensus values? For the marginal net
tax-and-transfer share [tau], we assume the baseline value to be 0.333.
For g, the long-term growth rate of real potential GDP, we take the
Congressional Budget Office's current estimate of 2.5 percent per
year. This leaves [mu] and [eta]--the fiscal multiplier and the
hysteresis coefficient that captures the shadow cast by the downturn on
the long run--as variable parameters. We take the plausible range for
[mu] in a severely depressed economy at the zero lower bound to be
between zero and 2.5, and the plausible range for [eta] to be between
zero and 0.2. Table 1 summarizes the framework parameters and their
base-case values.
When calibrating [eta], it is probably best to consider it as a
"permanent equivalent" concept. Short-term Keynesian effects
die out in less than 5 years; permanent effects are forever. In a
growing economy, permanent effects are thus capitalized at a multiple of
1/(r - g), which for plausible borrowing rates and social rates of time
discount r, and plausible growth rates g, can be a very large factor.
However, many plausible channels through which a deep and prolonged
downturn casts a shadow on future potential output produce not permanent
but rather persistent effects: they last for one generation, but not for
three.
We therefore consider [eta] to be the size of the persistent
effects of a downturn on potential output in a permanent-equivalent
metric: that is, we correct for the fact that these effects are long-run
but not truly permanent, and hence should be capitalized not at a factor
1/(r - g) but rather at [1 - [(1 - r + g).sup.T]]/(r - g), where T
captures the length of the persistent but not truly permanent effects.
Table 2 reports critical Treasury borrowing rates below which
expansionary fiscal policy is self-financing (expression 7 holds) for
various values of [eta] and [mu]. For example, for a multiplier [mu] of
1.5 and a hysteresis parameter [eta] of 0.10, the second term on the
fight-hand side of expression 7 is 10 percent per year. This means that
if the spread between the real Treasury borrowing rate r and the real
growth rate of GDP g is less than 10 percentage points per year, fiscal
expansion today improves rather than degrades the long-term budget
balance of the government. Given our assumption that g = 2.5 percent,
that implies a real Treasury borrowing rate of 17.5 percent per year or
less.
For [mu] of 1.0 and [eta] of 0.1, the second term on the right-hand
side of expression 7 is about 5 percent per year. In this case, if the
spread between r and g is less than about 5 percentage points, fiscal
expansion today improves rather than degrades the long-term budget
balance of the government. That implies a real Treasury borrowing rate
of about 7.5 percent per year or less.
For [mu] of 0.5 and [eta] of 0.05, the second term on the right in
expression 7 is about 1 percent per year. In this case, if the spread
between r and g is less than about 1 percentage point, fiscal expansion
today improves rather than degrades the long-term budget balance of the
government. That implies a real Treasury borrowing rate of about 3.5
percent per year or less.
How credible is the claim that the Treasury's borrowing rates
will stay below the relevant value in table 2, and thus that
expansionary fiscal policy would be self-financing? Since January 1997
the interest rates on Treasury inflation-protected securities (TIPS)
provide a direct, market-based measure of the real rate at which the
Treasury can borrow. For earlier periods, subtracting a measure of the
inflation rate from nominal interest rates provides a proxy. Figure 1
plots, in addition to the yield on 10-year TIPS, two such proxies: the
yield on 10-year nominal Treasuries minus expected inflation from the
University of Michigan Survey, and the same 10-year nominal yield minus
the previous year's core inflation rate. These two measures do not
markedly or persistently diverge from the TIPS rate over the period for
which the latter is available. The expectations-based measure shows a
somewhat higher mean value and more variability, but since the Volcker
disinflation of the early 1980s it has tracked or undershot the current
value of inflation.
The multiplier [mu] has to be low and the hysteresis parameter
[eta] almost negligible for the critical interest rate r to lie above
the range of real interest rates on Treasury debt seen in the historical
record. At a real interest rate of 5 percent per year, expansionary
fiscal policy is self-financing for [mu] = 2.5 as long as [eta] >
0.005; it is self-financing for [mu] = 1.5 as long as [eta] > 0.025;
it is self-financing for [mu] = 1.0 as long as [eta] > 0.050; and it
is self-financing for [mu] = 0.5 as long as [eta] > 0.125. The case
for expansionary U.S. fiscal policy imposing any significant budgetary
cost thus appears to rest on a claim that p is significantly less than
1.0, or that [eta] is significantly less than 0.05.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Moreover, current and expected future interest rates today are much
lower than in the historical post-World War II experience, and
today's long-term Treasury rates indicate that r is expected to
stay extraordinarily low for a generation. As of June 1, 2012, the 10-
and 30-year nominal Treasury rates were 1.47 and 2.53 percent per year,
respectively; the 10- and 30-year TIPS rates were -0.59 and +0.36
percent per year, respectively--and many market observers see TIPS rates
as elevated today because of perceived lack of liquidity. If there is no
expected term premium--if the expectations theory of the term structure
holds--then financial markets currently anticipate that the short-term
nominal Treasury rate will average less than 1.47 percent per year over
the next l0 years, and less than 2.53 percent per year over the next 30
years. These are extraordinarily low rates. At an expected annual
inflation rate of 2.0 percent and an expected real annual GDP growth
rate of 2.5 percent, 1 percent of GDP worth of debt borrowed now and
funded for 30 years with no nominal amortization raises the debt-to-GDP
ratio a generation hence by only 0.55 percentage point. Assuming log
utility and a zero rate of pure time preference, public spending that
has a current-dollar benefit-cost ratio of only 0.55 is worth
undertaking today as long as it can be funded with 30-year Treasuries.
Moreover, it is extremely unlikely that the expectations theory of
the term structure holds without any term premium driving a wedge
between expected future short-term rates and the current 30-year
Treasury bond rate. If the past generation's detailed
investigations into financial markets have taught us anything, it is
that a great many risks that do not have a clear correlation with the
marginal utility of aggregate consumption are nevertheless priced,
indeed priced substantially. The risk that the value of one's
long-term bonds will be eroded by inflation has been priced in the past
through a considerable term premium relative to the expectations
hypothesis of the term structure. It is hard to see any reason for this
historical correlation to fail to hold in the future. This means that
the arithmetic of government spending now is even more favorable, for
markets do not anticipate a return of interest rates to their postwar
norm for at least a generation.
At this point a very natural question arises: if interest rates on
Treasury debt are usually (except in the early 1980s) sufficiently low
to allow the government to borrow, spend, and end up with no net
increase in its debt burden, why not do so always? The principal reason
is that it cannot do so in normal times. A multiplier [mu] of even 1 is,
as we discuss in section II, likely to be unusual. It is likely to
prevail only when the zero lower bound on short-term interest rates is
binding and cyclical unemployment is substantial. At other, normal
times, la is likely to be much smaller than 1. When interest rates are
away from their zero bound, when the output gap is small, or when high
unemployment is not cyclical but structural, then either bottlenecks or
monetary policy offset make it unlikely that fiscal expansion will
impart any significant boost to real GDP. When that is so, there is no
stabilization policy case for expansionary fiscal policy.
Note that the arithmetic of table 2 does not hinge on the economy
being close to the edge of or in the range of dynamic inefficiency. The
key interest rate in table 2 is r, and here it matters that r is the
real interest rate on government borrowing and not the private marginal
product of capital, the real social rate of time discount, or the rate
of return on public capital. (8)
The conclusion that fiscal expansion may be self-financing is at
least partially a point about the attractiveness of Treasury debt to
investors (see Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen 2012). If government
debt is sufficiently attractive as a safe savings vehicle, and if there
are at least minor counterhysteresis benefits from expansionary fiscal
policy, then there need be no net financing burden of extra government
purchases on taxpayers. Thus, the government can borrow, spend to boost
the economy, use the extra taxes from a more prosperous economy to
amortize part of its debt, refinance the debt and so push out the time
horizon at which it is to be retired, and, as that horizon is extended,
watch the debt-to-GDP ratio fall indefinitely. This would not be
possible if Treasury debt were unattractive, because this would drive a
wedge between the rate at which the Treasury can borrow and the rate of
time discount.
The idea that, for some range of plausible parameter values,
expansionary fiscal policy is self-financing means that for a wider
range of parameter values, expansionary fiscal policy passes sensible
benefit-cost tests. The benefits from such policy are, as before, the
current-period boost to production and income from higher demand, and
future-period boosts to potential output from the smaller shadow cast on
future growth by a shorter and shallower downturn. The costs are the
drag on future output produced by the higher taxes needed to amortize
the debt incurred to finance the fiscal expansion. If fiscal expansion
is self-financing, there are no costs, only benefits. And if fiscal
expansion is nearly self-financing, then the increase in taxes needed to
amortize the debt will be small, and so will the costs. The appendix
details the arithmetic of such an extra-output benefit-cost calculation.
II. The Value of the Multiplier
Valerie Ramey (2011) surveys estimates of the fiscal multiplier and
classifies them into four groups: estimates from structural models,
estimates from exogenous aggregate shocks (relying largely on increases
in military spending associated with wars), estimates from structural
vector autoregression models (VARs), and "local multiplier"
estimates. (9) She concludes (pp. 680-81) that
the range of plausible estimates for the multiplier in the case of
a temporary increase in government spending that is deficit
financed is probably 0.8 to 1.5.... If the increase is undertaken
during a severe recession, the estimates are likely to be at the
upper bound of this range. It should be understood, however, that
there is significant uncertainty involved in these estimates.
Reasonable people could argue that the multiplier is 0.5 or 2.0....
Christina Romer (2011) also surveys multiplier estimates. She
summarizes the evidence as suggesting a somewhat higher central tendency
for estimates of the government purchases multiplier slightly above 1.5.
She stresses a strong presumption that econometric estimates are likely
to be lower than the constant-monetary-and-financial-conditions
multiplier, which as we argue below is itself a lower bound to the
current policy-relevant multiplier. As Romer (p. 11) states, concurring with Emi Nakamura and Jon Steinsson (2011): "In the situation like
the one we are facing now, where monetary policy is constrained by the
fact that interest rates are already close to zero, the aggregate impact
of an increase in government spending may be quite a bit larger than the
cross-sectional effect."
The International Monetary Fund (IMF 2009) finds a government
purchases multiplier in a broad range of post-World War II experiences
similar to Romer's central estimate. Alan Auerbach and Yurii
Gorodnichenko (forthcoming) attempt to distinguish the multiplier in
normal times from that which prevails when the economy suffers from
slack aggregate demand. They estimate a multiplier of around 0.5 for
normal times and around 2.5 when the economy is depressed. (10) IMF
(2010) concludes that the multiplier at the zero lower bound is more
than twice what it is in normal times.
To summarize: the range of current multiplier estimates extends
from Ramey's lowest for which "reasonable people could
argue," 0.5, up to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko's estimate of
2.5, which applies when GDP is below potential such that increases in
nominal spending are highly likely to show up primarily as increases in
real GDP. However, it is far from clear that these estimates or the
methodologies that generate them shed sufficient light on the fiscal
multiplier concept relevant for our framework in section I. At present
in the United States, not only is GDP below potential, but the zero
lower bound constrains interest rates, and substantial frictions
interfere with the functioning of credit markets. These features were
seldom present during the periods and in the countries for which these
multipliers were estimated.
We can use Ramey's categorization to rehearse some of the
potential problems with applying these multiplier estimates from the
literature to a depressed economy. First, structural model estimates are
only as good as the identification of the structural model. Second,
estimates based on changes in military spending will underestimate the
impact of fiscal policy in a context like the present, to the extent
that spending increases are associated with tax increases and Ricardian
equivalence does not hold in full, or to the extent that supply
constraints associated either with the rapid shift of production,
heedless of efficiency, from civilian to military uses found in an
emergency military mobilization, or with a high rate of resource
utilization, slow output growth. Third, the identification of exogenous
fiscal shocks using time-series techniques seems to us problematic: it
is often difficult to identify historical events in the narrative or
contemporary notes that expectations have shifted in those quarters in
which time-series techniques identify "shocks" orthogonal to
an information set consisting of a few lagged values.
Most promising are the estimates of "local multipliers"
made by Nakamura and Steinsson (2011) and an increasing number of
others. They examine differences in government spending across regions
and identify a multiplier holding monetary and financial conditions
constant. This literature appears to be coalescing around an estimate
for such a multiplier of 1.5, although with substantial imprecision.
(11)
The principal issue in linking these estimated multipliers to the
reduced-form fiscal multiplier relevant for the framework of section I
is whether and to what extent the monetary policy reaction function in
normal times differs from that in a depressed economy. Indeed, our
suspicion is that much of the substantial variation over the past 80
years in the judgments of American economists, at least, about
discretionary fiscal policy reflects changes in the nature of this
function, and thus in the monetary-and-financial-conditions curve that
underlies their analyses. As views of the likely slope of this function
(depicted as the MP curve in figures 2 through 4 below) have changed,
views of the efficacy of fiscal expansion in a depression have changed
as well.
From the time of Keynes' General Theory to the 1960s, the
default assumption was that interest rates would remain constant as
fiscal policy changed, because the central bank and the fiscal authority
would cooperate to support aggregate demand: fiscal expansion would be
accompanied by monetary policy accommodation that produced not crowding
out but crowding in. With the changes in macroeconomic thinking and the
inflationary experience of the 1970s, the natural assumption in the
United States came to be that the Federal Reserve was managing aggregate
demand. Thus, changes in fiscal policy, just like changes in private
investment demand, would be offset as the Federal Reserve pursued the
appropriate balance between inflation and investment. Today, however, at
least until the economy exits from the zero lower bound or cyclical
unemployment drops substantially, the economy is once again in a regime
in which real interest rate movements amplify rather than offset the
effects of fiscal stimulus.
Consider a central bank that includes both inflation and output in
its objective function, in an economy that is well modeled by the
neo-Hicksian framework of Romer (2000). In such an economy, output Y and
the real interest rate charged to firms [r.sup.f] are jointly determined
by an IS saving-investment condition and an MP monetary policy reaction
function. Assume that real aggregate demand is a function of the fiscal
policy impetus [DELTA]G, the constant-monetary-and-financial-conditions
multiplier [mu], and [r.sup.f]. An increase in government purchases in
the current period from baseline, [DELTA]G, would then, all else equal,
raise current-period output relative to baseline according to the IS
condition:
(8) [DELTA]Y = -[alpha]([DELTA][r.sup.f]) + [mu][DELTA]G.
However, if the monetary authority responds to this expansionary
fiscal policy by raising [r.sup.f] or allowing it to rise, according to
the following MP function,
(9) [DELTA][r.sup.f] = (1/[gamma]) [DELTA]Y,
then the reduced-form relationship between the fiscal expansion and
the resulting difference in output from baseline is
(10) [DELTA]Y = [gamma] / ([gamma] + [alpha]) - [mu][DELTA]G.
Thus, an estimate of the multiplier over a period during which the
monetary policy reaction function is characterized by a particular
[gamma] will give not the constant-monetary-and-financial-conditions
multiplier [mu], but rather
(11) [mu]' = [gamma] / ([gamma] + [alpha]) [mu].
What value of [gamma] will an optimizing central bank pick for its
reaction function if, like the Federal Reserve from the end of the 1970s
to the mid-2000s, it is focused on its price stability mission? The
central bank will have a view about what level of Y is best suited to
advance that mission over the long term. That level of Y will not be
much altered by the stance of fiscal policy. The implication then is
that the central bank will pick a value of [gamma] very close to zero,
and the MP curve will be nearly vertical. Whatever shocks shift the IS
curve, whether fiscal policy or other factors, will then affect interest
rates but will affect the level of output little if at all. Thus, in
normal times the policy-relevant reduced-form multiplier [mu]' is
likely to be small. Figure 2 illustrates this monetary offset of the
fiscal expansion in normal times.
The situation is different when the economy is at the zero bound,
precisely because the fiscal expansion [DELTA]G then extends the set of
economic outcomes [PI] attainable through monetary policy in a manner
that provides access to superior outcomes previously unreachable. At the
zero bound, the central bank is setting the short-term safe nominal
interest rate i that it controls at zero. It would not respond to fiscal
policy that boosts output by raising the short-term nominal interest
rate to offset its effects, for that level of output is a previously
unreachable superior outcome.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
If the long-term rate to firms [r.sup.f] were at a constant premium
to the short-term safe nominal interest rate i, then at the zero bound
the monetary policy reaction function would set a constant real rate.
The MP curve would be flat, and the parameter [alpha] in equation 8
would be zero. And as in figure 3, the policy-relevant reduced-form
multiplier would equal the constant-monetary-and-financial-conditions
multiplier: [mu]' = [mu].
In reality, however, there is slippage between i and [r.sup.f]. The
relationship between them is
(12) [r.sup.f] = [pi] + [sigma].
In words, the relevant real interest rate is equal to the
short-term safe rate, minus inflation, plus a spread [sigma]--which
itself has duration, risk, and default components. The inflation rate
will be increasing in output: more demand both raises the chances that
producers will increase prices and increases how much they will raise
them. (12) The interest rate spread [sigma], in contrast, may well be a
decreasing function of output: a more prosperous economy is one with
fewer defaults, and the price of bearing risk is lower because there is
less risk in the economy. (13)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Thus, instead of an MP curve in which increases in GDP are
associated with increases in [r.sup.f], and instead of a flat MP curve,
a depressed economy at the zero bound is likely to see the following
relationship between interest rates and the state of the economy:
(13) [DELTA][r.sup.f] = -[delta][DELTA]Y.
The multiplier estimated in that case, and the one relevant for the
reduced-form framework of sections I and II, will be neither the
(relatively small) normal-times reduced-form multiplier [mu]' nor
the constant-monetary-and-financial-conditions multiplier [mu], but
rather
(14) [[mu].sup.*] = [mu] / (1 - [alpha][delta])'
and the ratio of this policy-relevant multiplier at the zero bound
to the normal-times multiplier will be [[mu].sup.*]/[mu]' = [1 +
([alpha]/[gamma])]/(1 - [alpha][delta]).
Figure 4 illustrates this difference between the (small) multiplier
likely to be seen in normal times and the multiplier relevant at the
zero bound.
Whereas the MP curve in normal times is steeply sloped upward,
causing virtually all of any increase in output through fiscal expansion
to be offset by a rise in [r.sup.f]; the MP curve relevant for a
depressed economy at the zero bound slopes downward: the stronger the
economy, the lower is the real cost of capital to firms seeking to
borrow.
A situation in which fiscal expansion is accompanied not by higher
but rather by lower real interest rates for firms fits a scenario often
mentioned by observers but rarely modeled: that of "pump
priming," a term popularized by Jacob Viner and Lauchlin Currie during the New Deal of the 1930s (Jones 1978). The claim is that private
spending will flood into the marketplace and boost demand, once initial
government purchases have restored the normal channels of enterprise.
Note that the presence of an exceptionally accommodative monetary
reaction function at the zero bound raises the possibility that an
increase in government purchases might under some circumstances be
self-financing even without any hysteresis at all. At a marginal
tax-and-transfer share [tau] of 1/3, a depressed-economy policy-relevant
Keynesian multiplier [[mu].sup.*] of 1.5 would mean that the rise in the
national debt [DELTA]D is only half as large as the spending from an
expansionary fiscal boost [DELTA]G. A [[mu].sup.*] of 3 would mean that
fiscal policy becomes self-financing through demand channels without
resort to supply-side hysteresis. Back in 1977, Walter Heller, who had
served as chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers during the
Kennedy and Johnson administrations, testified before the Joint Economic
Committee of Congress that reduced real interest rates brought about by
monetary accommodation had raised the policy-relevant multiplier
applicable to the 1964 Kennedy-Johnson tax cut enough to put it on the
edge of self-financing. As Bruce Bartlett (2003, p. 5) quotes Heller:
What happened to the tax cut in 1965 is difficult to pin down, but
insofar as we are able to isolate it, it did seem to have a
tremendously stimulative effect, a multiplied effect on the
economy. It was the major factor that led to our running a $3
billion surplus by the middle of 1965, before escalation in Vietnam
struck us. It was a $12 billion tax cut, which would be about $33
or $34 billion in today's terms. And within 1 year the revenues
into the Federal Treasury were already above what they had been
before the tax cut.... Did it pay for itself in increased
revenues? I think the evidence is very strong that it did....
From early in the Kennedy administration through the end of 1964,
the proxy for the real annual rate on 10-year Treasuries calculated by
subtracting the subsequent year's inflation from the nominal rate
was around 3 percent; thereafter it dropped rapidly to around 1.5
percent. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) was more cautious than
Heller, concluding that between "25% and 75%" (Bartlett 2005,
p. 5) of the static 2-year debt increase from the tax cut had been
offset by the boost to output and thus to tax revenue that it had
delivered.
The argument that normal-times policy-relevant fiscal multipliers
should be presumed to be very small can be made more general. Optimizing
central banks will be expected to offset shifts in discretionary fiscal
policy--and thus lead to multiplier estimates near zero--under
relatively unrestrictive conditions. Consider a government choosing
monetary policy so as to achieve the best economic outcome from the set
of outcomes attainable by policy [PI]. A change in fiscal policy from
baseline would change the relationship between monetary policy and the
economic outcome. But unless the change in fiscal policy opens up access
to an outcome not in the set [PI] that is superior, or eliminates access
to the best economic outcome in [PI], the government will shift its
monetary policy so that it still picks the same economic outcome. It
will thus engage in full monetary offset.
Note that for this point to hold, the choice of monetary policy m
and the choice of fiscal policy g cannot themselves be part of the
outcome the government values. A central bank that values a smooth path
for interest rates (as did the pre-1979 Federal Reserve) or has
preferences about the size of its balance sheet (as did the Federal
Reserve under Paul Volcker) will not engage in full monetary offset.
Monetary and fiscal policy must enter into the central bank's
objective only through their effects on economic outcomes for full
monetary offset to hold.
For these reasons it is difficult, for us at least, to consider the
empirical evidence on multipliers without reaching the conclusion that
the base-case multiplier of 1.0 of section I is likely to be an
underestimate, and perhaps a substantial underestimate, of the
policy-relevant multiplier in excess-capacity economies at the zero
bound like the United States today.
III. Hysteresis
As Edmund Phelps (1972) was the first to point out, there are
reasons for believing that recessions impose costs even after they end,
and that a "high-pressure economy" (Arthur Okun's term
for one continuously operating at potential) has continuing benefits. It
is not easy to quantify these "hysteresis effects," in part
because the factors that cause a downturn may continue to have an impact
once the downturn has ended, which is difficult to disentangle from the
hysteresis effect. In this section we survey some of the evidence in an
effort to come to a plausible view about our reduced-form framework
parameter [eta], the impact of a 1-percentage-point shortfall of GDP
below potential for 1 year on the subsequent path of potential output.
It would indeed be surprising if downturns did not cast a shadow
over future economic activity. A host of mechanisms have been suggested,
including reduced labor force attachment on the part of the long-term
unemployed, scarring effects on young workers who have trouble beginning
their careers, reductions in government physical and human capital
investments as social insurance expenditures make prior claims on
limited public financial resources, reduced investment in both in
research and development and in physical capital, reduced
experimentation with business models and informational spillovers, and
changes in managerial attitudes.
Bottom-up evidence on hysteresis is provided by Kim Clark and
Summers (1982), who documented substantial persistence in
individuals' labor supply decisions and found that past work
experience was a key determinant of current employment status. They
concluded that this persistence of labor supply decisions meant that the
hypothesis of a "natural" or non-accelerating-inflation rate
of unemployment (NAIRU), as a medium-run proposition, was false. Steven
Davis and Till yon Wachter (2011) find that workers who lose their jobs
when unemployment is high lose an extra amount, relative to when
unemployment is low, equal to the present value of an extra 1.5 years of
earnings in their subsequent careers--a 7.5 percent reduction in
permanent earnings. At a typical average unemployment duration of 17
weeks, the aggregate demand shock associated with such a loss of
employment amounts to a third of a year's earnings. This suggests a
contribution to the [eta] parameter of 0.225 (0.075 / 0.333) from the
labor side alone, and that only if the average duration of unemployment
rapidly returns to normal levels. (14)
In addition to these effects on the labor side, the past several
years have seen substantial shortfalls in both public and private
investment. Government nondefense capital formation in the United States
is already 0.4 percentage point below its early-2008 peak as a share of
potential GDP, and cuts continue. Private gross investment is still 3.5
percentage points of potential GDP below its precrisis level and has
been depressed for 4 years.
The natural way to calibrate these effects on the investment side
to the current downturn is to say that a 20-percentage-point-year
cumulative shortfall from potential GDP has carried with it a relative
decline in the capital stock equal to 14 percentage points (3.5
percentage points x 4 years) of annual potential GDP. At a marginal
product of capital of 10 percent per year, that implies a 1.3 percent
reduction in potential output and an investment-side contribution to
[eta] of 0.13; at a marginal product of capital of 5 percent per year,
it implies a 0.65 percent reduction in potential output and an
investment-side contribution to [eta] of 0.065.
In the standard Solow growth model, the shortfall in private
investment generated by the financial crisis and the recession will
eventually be made up as the economy reconverges to its steady-state
capital-to-output ratio. Long-term-unemployed workers who become
discouraged and drop out of the labor force will reach retirement age
within several decades. The long-run effects of a long, deep downturn on
potential output are thus much more plausibly viewed as persistent than
as truly permanent. The 1/e time of convergence to the steady-state
capital-to-output ratio is on the order of 33 years. The average time to
retirement of labor force dropouts is likely to be somewhat less. Thus,
permanent-equivalent measures of the persistent effects of downturns on
future potential output will be somewhat smaller. Even so, the bottom-up
evidence of persistent effects of downturns on potential output
indicates a value for [eta] that is at or above the top of the range
considered in section I.
Top-down evidence for hysteresis in Europe was provided by Olivier
Blanchard and Summers (1986). Reacting to increases in the unemployment
rate in Western Europe from the 1970s to the mid-1980s, they argued that
hysteresis links between the short-run cycle and the long-run trend were
key: that increases in unemployment from recessions "have a direct
impact on the 'natural' rate of unemployment" around
which an economy would oscillate. Others had argued that Western
Europe's persistently high unemployment was primarily due to
rigidities in labor markets (high minimum wages, high firing costs, and
the like). Laurence Ball (1997), however, suggested that the link
between labor market rigidities and the transformation of cyclical into
structural unemployment in Western Europe in the 1980s had been
overdrawn. In his estimation, "countries with larger decreases in
inflation and longer disinflationary periods have larger rises in the
NAIRU. [Measured] imperfections in the labor market [had] little direct
relation to change in the NAIRU," (15) with the possible exception
of an interaction between the generosity of the unemployment insurance
system and the depth of the downturn.
Ball's (1997) attribution of cross-national variation in
changes in the NAIRU in the 1980s and 1990s to inadequate stabilization
policy in some countries that allowed cyclical unemployment to turn
structural has striking implications. He finds that in countries that
pursue long, slow rather than short, sharp disinflations--with an active
pursuit of disinflation on the order of 4 years--effectively all of the
cyclical decline in employment becomes a permanent decline. Four
percentage-point-years of a negative shock thus produces a 1 percent
fall in potential output, for an [eta] of 0.25.
Findings similar to those of Ball (1997) are reported in IMF
(2009), which examines the effects of demand shocks produced by
financial crises at a 7-year horizon. In that study of the aftermath of
88 financial crises in the past two generations, each output decline of
1 percent of GDP in the short-run response to a financial crisis is
associated on average with a 1 percent shortfall of GDP from its
precrisis trend. If the "short run" during which output is
depressed because of inadequate demand is 3 years, this result is
consistent with an [eta] of 0.33. (16)
A second form of top-down evidence is provided by professional
economic forecasters. As a group, they do not appear to hold to the
position that the current economic downturn will have no or small
effects on the growth path of U.S. potential output. Instead, their
recent revisions of their projections for the next decade implicitly
incorporate very substantial hysteresis effects. To take one prominent
example: between January 2007 and January 2009, as the economy slid into
its deep, financial crisis-driven recession, the CBO marked down its
estimate of potential GDP for the end of 2017 by 4.2 percent (figure 5).
The CBO took some heart from the end of the recession in late 2009, and
in its January 2010 forecast revision it raised its estimate of
end-of-2017 potential GDP by 0.4 percent. Then, over the next 2 years to
January 2012, the CBO--in near lockstep with private
forecasters--lowered its forecast of end-of-2017 potential GDP by an
additional 3 percent. Thus, as of the beginning of 2012, the CBO had
marked down its estimate of potential GDP 5 years hence by a cumulative
6.8 percentage points. Were that markdown to be interpreted as the
result simply of the 20-percentage-point-year output gap to the present,
it would correspond to an [eta] of 0.34. Even if that markdown were
based on a belief that the economy has so far experienced only half of
the cumulative gap relative to potential output that will ultimately
result from this episode, that would correspond to an [eta] of 0.17.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
It is possible that these revisions reflect not a belief in
hysteresis but merely the recognition that previous forecasts of
potential output were too high. However, an elementary signal extraction
point rebuts this interpretation. When observing a noisy series that has
a permanent component, an observation lower than the current estimate of
the permanent component leads a rational forecaster to reduce his or her
estimate of that permanent component. However, one should not reduce
one's estimate of potential output if
lower-than-previously-expected levels of production are associated with
lower-than-previously-expected levels of inflation. Estimates of
potential output are conceptually based not on quantities alone, but on
quantities and prices. Typically, the bad news that leads to a marking
down of potential output is not news that output is lower than, but
rather news that output and inflation together are above, their
anticipated co-movement line. Such news is not in evidence.
Blanchard and Summers's (1986) line of thought was that
significant hysteresis was a uniquely European phenomenon. Their model
carried the implication that the United States was likely to be largely
immune from permanent labor-side effects of what was originally
transitory cyclical unemployment. (17) They stressed the
"insider-outsider" wage-bargaining theory of hysteresis:
workers who lose their jobs no longer vote in union elections, and so
union leaders no longer take their interests into account in
negotiations, focusing instead on higher wages and better working
conditions for those still employed. Since union strength and legal
obligations on employers to bargain were much weaker in the United
States than in Europe, insider-outsider dynamics generated by formal
labor market institutions seemed to give the United States little to
fear.
However, the labor market dynamics of the past two and a half years
raise the possibility that the United States is not so immune after all
from the considerations raised by Blanchard and Summers (1986). Rather,
a transformation of cyclical into structural unemployment may be under
way in the United States today, as the pace of real GDP growth during
the current recovery is no greater than the precrisis trend growth rate
of potential output, so that the output gap remains large.
Here it is worth noting the divergence between the behavior of the
measured U.S. unemployment rate and the behavior of the measured U.S.
adult employment-to-population ratio over the past two and a half years.
From the late-2009 peak in the unemployment rate until April 2012, the
civilian employment-to-population ratio fell by only 0.1 percentage
point, the civilian adult labor force participation rate by a more
substantial 1.4 percentage points, and the unemployment rate by an even
larger 1.9 percentage points, from 10.0 percent to 8.1 percent (figure
6).
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Such a divergence between the unemployment rate and the
employment-to-population ratio is unprecedented in the United States.
The years immediately following the 1970, 1975, and 1982 unemployment
rate peaks saw strong recovery in the labor force participation rate,
and the 1992 and 2003 unemployment rate peaks were followed by
effectively flat labor force participation rates and very slow eventual
recoveries. Only after the 2009 unemployment rate peak has the civilian
labor force participation rate continued to decline, and indeed to
decline by enough to offset the effects of the falling unemployment
rate, leaving the employment-to-population ratio virtually unchanged
from the low point reached at the end of the recession (figure 7).
Since the late 1990s, the retirement of many members of the
baby-boom generation has led to lower employment-to-population ratios
for a given unemployment rate. But this is a slow-moving generational
trend, amounting to a fall in labor force participation on the order of
0.05 percentage point per year. The total reduction in labor force
participation since the end of the recession is thus an order of
magnitude too large to be attributed to this phenomenon alone. (18)
Moreover, there are counteracting pressures stemming from the financial
crisis that should tend to raise labor force participation: one would
expect many middle-aged Americans whose wealth (housing or financial, or
both) has been reduced by the crisis to delay retirement. Indeed, there
are signs of such a wealth effect at work in the increasing employment
of those past retirement age since 2007.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Consider a counterfactual in which the unemployment rate had
followed its actual trend but the labor force participation rate had
remained at its same level between October 2009 and April 2012, rather
than falling by 1.4 percentage points in those 30 months as it did. The
supply of workers in America today is 2.2 percent lower than in that
counterfactual baseline. Under the assumption that potential output
scales one for one with the labor force, such a reduction in labor
supply implies a 2.2 percent reduction in potential output. Assuming
instead a potential-output production function with a labor share of
0.65, the reduction in potential output would be 1.4 percent.
From the start of 2008 through the end of 2011, the cumulative
shortfall of real GDP from the Congressional Budget Office's
potential GDP series amounted to 20.5-percentage-point-years. Under the
assumption that potential output scales one for one with the labor
force, dividing 2.2 percent by 20.5-percentage-point-years yields an
[eta] of 0.107; assuming instead that potential output scales with a
labor share of 0.65 gives an [eta] of 0.07. Moreover, this calculation
assumes that the NAIRU has remained unchanged over the past 5 years.
Christina Romer (2012) documents, however, that the NAIRU estimates of
the CBO, the Federal Open Market Committee, and the Survey of
Professional Forecasters have been raised since 2007 by 0.8, 0,7, and
1.2 percentage points, respectively. (19) A counterfactual in which the
NAIRU had remained at its 2007 rate would produce a potential labor
force at full employment 3.0 percent larger than the current situation,
which would imply correspondingly higher values of [eta].
The U.S. economy in the aftermath of the 2008-09 crisis thus
appears not to be repeating the exceptional rapid rebound that used to
distinguish it from the sclerotic Western Europe analyzed by Blanchard
and Summers (1986). Instead it seems to be following much more closely
the typical post--financial crisis pattern found by IMF (2009). In their
sample, 7 years after the crisis, real GDP on average was some 10
percent below its precrisis trend. (20) Both the capital stock and
employment were substantially depressed below their precrisis trends,
with shortfalls relative to previous trends in total factor productivity
as well. In particular, IMF (2009, pp. 4-5) found:
--There was, on average, no recovery to trend from the level
relative to trend of the short-run output decline: "the path of
output tends to be depressed substantially and persistently ... with no
rebound on average to the precrisis trend."
--Crises that did not generate large output declines in the short
run tended not to generate large shortfalls relative to trend at the
7-year horizon: "what happens to short-run output is also a good
predictor of the medium-term outcome."
--The economies that did approach their precrisis trend growth path
in recovery tended to be those that had applied substantial
macroeconomic stimulus immediately after the crisis: "although
post-crisis output dynamics are hard to predict, the evidence suggests
that economies that apply counter-cyclical fiscal and monetary stimulus
in the short run after the crisis tend to have smaller output
losses" relative to trend at the 7-year horizon.
The historical evidence on the existence of hysteresis is thinner
than one would wish, as is inevitable when one is attempting to
generalize from a few previous episodes. Thus, any conclusions must be
weak and tentative. The question of how large a shadow is cast on future
potential output by a deep cyclical downturn rests on a few historical
cases: the experience of the United States and Western Europe in the
Great Depression, the long Western European downturn of the late 1970s
and the 1980s (comparing both Europe with the United States and the
European countries with each other), and Japan's "lost
decades" starting in the 1990s. In the United States, moreover, the
Great Depression was followed by the great boom of total mobilization for World War II, so that if the Great Depression did cast a shadow, it
was erased by the war.
Perhaps the recent departure of the unemployment rate and the labor
force participation rate from their earlier historical pattern of
co-movement will turn out to be a transitory cyclical anomaly. Perhaps
in the next few years the economy will quickly rebound to its pre-2008
path of potential output growth. But our reading of the remaining
cases--the experience of Western Europe since the late 1970s and Japan
during the 1990s and after--provide strong reason to presume that
hysteresis effects on the order of those in table 2 are more likely than
not to be a reality. In that case the standard call for further research
in this area becomes urgent.