The effects of quantitative easing on interest rates: channels and implications for policy.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind ; Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette
ABSTRACT We evaluate the effect of the Federal Reserve's
purchase of long-term Treasuries and other long-term bonds (QE1 in
2008-09 and QE2 in 2010-11) on interest rates. Using an event-study
methodology, we reach two main conclusions. First, it is inappropriate
to focus only on Treasury rates as a policy target, because quantitative
easing works through several channels that affect particular assets
differently. We find evidence for a signaling channel, a unique demand
for long-term safe assets, and an inflation channel for both QE1 and
QE2, and a mortgage-backed securities (MBS) prepayment channel and a
corporate bond default risk channel for QE! only. Second, effects on
particular assets depend critically on which assets are purchased. The
event study suggests that MBS purchases in QE1 were crucial for lowering
MBS yields as well as corporate credit risk and thus corporate yields
for QE1, and Treasuries-only purchases in QE2 had a disproportionate
effect on Treasuries and agency bonds relative to MBSs and corporate
bonds, with yields on the latter falling primarily through the
market's anticipation of lower future federal funds rates.
**********
The Federal Reserve has recently pursued the unconventional policy
of urchasing large quantities of long-term securities, including
Treasury securities, agency securities, and agency mortgage-backed
securities (MBS). The stated objective of this quantitative easing (QE)
is to reduce long-term interest rates in order to spur economic activity
(Dudley 2010). There is significant evidence that QE policies can alter
long-term interest rates. For example, Joseph Gagnon and others (2010)
present an event study of QE1 that documents large reductions in
interest rates on dates associated with positive QE announcements. Eric
Swanson (2011) presents confirming event-study evidence from the 1961
Operation Twist, where the Federal Reserve purchased a substantial
quantity of long-term Treasuries. Apart from the event-study evidence,
there are papers that look at lower-frequency variation in the supply of
long-term Treasuries and document its effects on interest rates (see,
for example, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen 2010). (1)
Although it is clear from this body of work that QE lowers medium-
and long-term interest rates, the channels through which this reduction
occurs are less clear. The main objective of this paper is to evaluate
these channels and their implications for policy. We review the
principal theoretical channels through which QE may operate. We then
examine the event-study evidence with an eye toward distinguishing among
these channels, studying a range of interest rates and drawing in
additional facts from various derivatives prices to help separate the
channels. We furthermore supplement previous work by adding evidence
from QE2 and evidence based on intraday data. Studying intraday data
allows us to document price reactions and trading volume in the minutes
after the main announcements, thus increasing confidence that any
effects documented in daily data are due to these announcements.
It is necessary to understand the channels of operation in order to
evaluate whether a given QE policy was successful. Here is an
illustration of this point: Using annual data back to 1919,
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) present evidence for a
channel whereby changes in long-term Treasury supply drive the safety
premiums on long-term assets with near-zero default risk. Our findings
in that paper suggest that QE policy that purchases very safe assets
such as Treasuries or agency bonds should work particularly to lower the
yields of bonds that are extremely safe, such as Treasuries, agency
bonds, and high-grade corporate bonds. But even if a policy affects
Treasury interest rates, such rates may not be the most policy-relevant
ones. A lot of economic activity is funded by debt that is not as free
of credit risk as Treasuries or other triple-A bonds. For example, about
40 percent of corporate bonds are rated Baa or lower (for which our
earlier work suggests that the demand for assets with near-zero default
risk does not apply). Similarly, MBSs issued to fund household mortgages
are less safe than Treasuries because of the substantial prepayment risk
involved. Whether yields on these less safe assets fall as much as those
on very safe assets depends on whether QE succeeds in lowering default
risk or the default risk premium (for corporate bonds) and the
prepayment risk premium (for MBSs).
One of the principal findings of this paper is that the large
reductions in mortgage rates due to QE1 appear to be driven partly by
the fact that QE1 involved large purchases of agency-backed MBSs (thus
reducing the price of mortgage-specific risk). In contrast, for QE2,
which involved only Treasury purchases, we find a substantial impact on
Treasury and agency bond rates, but smaller effects on MBS and corporate
rates. Furthermore, we find a substantial reduction in default risk or
the default risk premium for corporate bonds only for QE1, suggesting
that the MBS purchases in QE1 may also have helped drive down corporate
credit risk and thus corporate yields (possibly via the resulting
mortgage refinancing boom and its impact on the housing market and
consumer spending). The main effect on corporate bonds and MBSs in QE2
appears to have been through a signaling channel, whereby financial
markets interpreted QE as signaling lower federal funds rates going
forward. This finding for QE2 raises the question of whether the main
impact of a Treasuries-only QE may have been achievable with a statement
by the Federal Reserve committing to lower federal funds rates, that is,
without the Fed putting its balance sheet at risk in order to signal
lower future rates.
The next section of the paper lays out the channels through which
QE may be expected to operate. We then, in sections II and III, present
results of event studies of QE1 and QE2 to evaluate the channels. We
document that QE worked through several channels. First, a signaling
channel (reflecting the market inferring information from QE
announcements about future federal funds rates) significantly lowered
yields on all bonds, with the effects depending on bond maturity.
Second, the impact of QE on MBS rates was large when QE involved MBS
purchases, but not when it involved only Treasury purchases, indicating
that another main channel for QE1 was to affect the equilibrium price of
mortgage-specific risk. Third, default risk or the default risk premium
for corporate bonds fell for QE1 but not for QE2, contributing to lower
corporate rates. Fourth, yields on medium- and long-maturity safe bonds
fell because of a unique clientele for safe nominal assets, and Federal
Reserve purchases reduced the supply of such assets and hence increased
the equilibrium safety premium. Fifth, evidence from inflation swap
rates and Treasury inflation-protected securities (TIPS) shows that
expected inflation increased as a result of both QE1 and QE2, implying
larger reductions in real than in nominal rates. Section IV presents
regression analysis building on our previous work in Krishnamurthy and
Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) to provide estimates of the expected effects of
QE on interest rates via the safety channel. Section V concludes.
I. Channels
We begin by identifying and describing the various channels through
which QE might operate.
I.A. Signaling Channel
Gauti Eggertsson and Michael Woodford (2003) argue that
nontraditional monetary policy can have a beneficial effect in lowering
long-term bond yields only if such policy serves as a credible
commitment by the central bank to keep interest rates low even after the
economy recovers (that is, lower than what a Taylor rule may call for).
James Clouse and others (2000) argue that such a commitment can be
achieved when the central bank purchases a large quantity of
long-duration assets in QE. If the central bank later raises rates, it
takes a loss on these assets. To the extent that the central bank weighs
such losses in its objective function, purchasing long-term assets in QE
serves as a credible commitment to keep interest rates low. Furthermore,
some of the Federal Reserve's announcements regarding QE explicitly
contain discussion of its policy on future federal funds rates. Markets
may also infer that the Federal Reserve's willingness to undertake
an unconventional policy like QE indicates that it will be willing to
hold its policy rate low for an extended period.
The signaling channel affects all bond market interest rates (with
effects depending on bond maturity), since lower future federal funds
rates, via the expectations hypothesis, can be expected to affect all
interest rates. We examine this channel by measuring changes in the
prices of federal funds futures contracts, as a guide to market
expectations of future federal funds rates. (2) The signaling channel
should have a larger impact on intermediate-maturity than on
long-maturity rates, since the commitment to keep rates low lasts only
until the economy recovers and the Federal Reserve can sell the
accumulated assets.
I.B. Duration Risk Channel
Dimitri Vayanos and Jean-Luc Vila (2009) offer a theoretical model
for a duration risk channel. Their one-factor model produces a risk
premium that is approximately the product of the duration of the bond
and the price of duration risk, which in turn is a function of the
amount of duration risk borne by the marginal bond market investor and
this investor's risk aversion. By purchasing long-term Treasuries,
agency debt, or agency MBSs, policy can reduce the duration risk in the
hands of investors and thereby alter the yield curve, particularly
reducing long-maturity bond yields relative to short-maturity yields. To
deliver these results, the model departs from a frictionless asset
pricing model. The principal departures are the assumptions that there
is a subset of investors who have preferences for bonds of specific
maturities ("preferred-habitat demand") and another subset who
are arbitrageurs and who become the marginal investors for pricing
duration risk.
An important but subtle issue in using the model to think about QE
is whether the preferred-habitat demand applies narrowly to a particular
asset class (for example, only to the Treasury market) or broadly to all
fixed-income instruments. For example, if some investors have a special
demand for 10-year Treasuries, but not for 10-year corporate bonds (or
mortgages or bank loans), then the Federal Reserve's purchase of
10-year Treasuries can be expected to affect Treasury yields more than
corporate bond yields. Vayanos and Vila (2009) do not take a stand on
this issue. Robin Greenwood and Vayanos (2010) offer evidence for how a
change in the relative supply of long-term versus short-term Treasuries
affects the yield spread between them. This evidence also does not
settle the issue, because it focuses only on Treasury data.
Recent studies of QE have interpreted the model as being about the
broad fixed-income market (see Gagnon and others 2010), and that is how
we proceed. Under this interpretation, the duration risk channel makes
two principal predictions:
--QE decreases the yield on all long-term nominal assets, including
Treasuries, agency bonds, corporate bonds, and MBSs.
--The effects are larger for longer-duration assets.
I.C Liquidity Channel
The QE strategy involves purchasing long-term securities and paying
for them by increasing reserve balances. Reserve balances are a more
liquid asset than long-term securities. Thus, QE increases the liquidity
in the hands of investors and thereby decreases the liquidity premium on
the most liquid bonds.
It is important to emphasize that this channel implies an increase
in Treasury yields. That is, it is commonly thought that Treasury bonds
carry a liquidity price premium, and that this premium was high during
particularly severe periods of the crisis. An expansion in liquidity can
be expected to reduce such a liquidity premium and increase yields. This
channel thus predicts that
--QE raises yields on the most liquid assets, such as Treasuries,
relative to other, less liquid assets.
I.D. Safety Channel
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) offer evidence that
there are significant clienteles for long-term safe (that is,
near-zero-default-risk) assets, whose presence lowers the yields on such
assets. The evidence comes from relating the spread between Baa-rated
and Aaa-rated corporate bonds (or agency bonds) to variation in the
supply of long-term Treasuries, over the period from 1925 to 2008. In
that paper we report that when there are fewer long-term Treasuries in
the market, so that there are fewer long-term safe assets to meet
clientele demands, the spread between Baa and Aaa bonds rises. The
safety channel can be thought of as describing a preferred habitat of
investors, but applying only to the space of safe assets.
The increase in yield spreads between near-zero-default-risk assets
and riskier assets generated by the clientele demand for long-term safe
assets is not the same as the risk premium in a standard asset pricing
model; rather, it reflects a deviation from standard models. A simple
way to think about investor willingness to pay extra for assets with
very low default-risk is to plot an asset's price against its
expected default rate. Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) argue
that this curve is very steep for low default rates, with a slope that
flattens as the supply of Treasuries increases. Figure 1 illustrates the
distinction. The straight line represents the value of a risky bond as
determined in a consumption-based capital asset pricing model (C-CAPM).
As default risk rises, the price of the bond falls. The distance from
this line up to the lower of the two curves illustrates the safety
premium; for bonds that have very low default risk, the price rises as a
function of the safety of the bond, more so than in a standard C-CAPM
setting. The figure also illustrates the dependence of the safety
premium on the supply of long-term Treasuries. The distance from the
straight line to the upper curve represents the safety premium for a
smaller supply of safe assets. The clientele demand shifts the premium
upward because of a higher marginal willingness to pay for safety when
supply is lower. This dependence of the premium on the supply of
long-term Treasuries is how Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010)
distinguish a standard risk premium explanation of defaultable bond
pricing from an explanation based on clientele-driven demand for safety.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This same effect may be expected to play out in QE. However, there
is a subtle issue in thinking about different asset classes in QE:
Treasury and agency bonds are clearly safe in the sense of offering an
almost certain nominal payment (note that the government
"takeover" of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac was announced on
September 7, 2008, before QEI and QE2, making agency bonds particularly
safe during the period of QE1 and QE2); however, agency MBSs have
significant prepayment risk, which means that they may not meet
clientele safety demands. The safety channel thus predicts that
--QE involving Treasuries and agencies lowers the yields on very
safe assets such as Treasuries, agencies, and possibly high-grade
corporate bonds, relative to less safe assets such as lower-grade
corporate bonds or bonds with prepayment risk such as MBSs.
We expect Baa bonds to be the relevant cutoff for these safety
effects, for two reasons. First, such bonds are at the boundary between
investment-grade and non-investment-grade securities, so that if prices
are driven by clientele demands for safety, the Baa bond forms a natural
threshold. Second, and more rigorously, Francis Longstaff, Sanjay
Mithal, and Eric Neis (2005) use credit default swap data from March
2001 to October 2002 to show that the component of yield spreads that is
hard to explain by purely default risk information is about 50 basis
points (bp) for Aaa- and Aa-rated bonds and about 70 bp for lower-rated
bonds, suggesting that the cutoff for bonds whose yields are not
affected by safety premiums is somewhere around the A or Baa rating.
I.E. Prepayment Risk Premium Channel
QE1 involved the purchase of $1.25 trillion of agency MBSs. Xavier
Gabaix, Krishnamurthy, and Olivier Vigneron (2007) present theory and
evidence that mortgage prepayment risk carries a positive risk premium,
and that this premium depends on the quantity of prepayment risk borne
by mortgage investors. The theory requires that the MBS market is
segmented and that a class of arbitrageurs who operate predominantly in
the MBS market are the relevant investors in determining the pricing of
prepayment risk. This theory is similar to Vayanos and Vila's
(2009) explanation of the duration risk premium and more broadly fits
into theories of intermediary asset pricing (see He and Krishnamurthy
2010).
This channel is particularly about QE1 and its effects on MBS
yields, which reflect a prepayment risk premium:
--MBS purchases in QE1 lower MBS yields relative to other bond
market yields.
--No such effect should be present in QE2.
I.F. Default Risk Channel
Lower-grade bonds such as Baa bonds carry higher default risk than
Treasury bonds. QE may affect the quantity of such default risk as well
as its price (that is, the risk premium). If QE succeeds in stimulating
the economy, one can expect that the default risk of corporations will
fall, and hence Baa rates will fall. Moreover, some standard asset
pricing models predict that investor risk aversion will fall as the
economy recovers, implying a lower default risk premium. Finally,
extensions of the intermediary pricing arguments we have offered above
for pricing prepayment risk can imply that increasing financial health
or increasing capital in the intermediary sector can further lower the
default risk premium.
We use credit default swap (CDS) rates to evaluate the importance
of a default risk channel. A credit default swap is a financial
derivative used to hedge against default by a firm. The credit default
swap rate measures the percentage of face value that must be paid as an
annual insurance premium to insure against default on the bonds of a
given firm. A 5-year CDS is such an insurance contract that expires in 5
years, and a 10-year CDS is one that expires in 10 years. We use these
CDSs to infer default risk at different maturities.
I.G. Inflation Channel
To the extent that QE is expansionary, it increases inflation
expectations, and this can be expected to have an effect on interest
rates. In addition, some commentators have argued that QE may increase
tail risks surrounding inflation. (3) That is, in an environment where
investors are unsure about the effects of policy on inflation, policy
actions may lead to greater uncertainty over inflation outcomes. Others
have argued that aggressive policy decreases uncertainty about inflation
in the sense that it effectively combats the possibility of a
deflationary spiral. Ultimately, this is an issue that can only be
sorted out by data. We propose looking at the implied volatility on
interest rate options, since a rise in inflation uncertainty will
plausibly also lead to a rise in interest rate uncertainty and implied
volatility. The inflation channel thus predicts that
--QE increases the fixed rate on inflation swaps as well as
inflation expectations as measured by the difference between nominal
bond yields and TIPS yields.
--QE may increase or decrease interest rate uncertainty as measured
by the implied volatility on swaptions.
Two explanations are in order. First, a (zero-coupon) inflation
swap is a financial instrument used to hedge against a rise in
inflation. The swap is a contract between a fixed-rate payor and a
floating-rate payor that specifies a one-time exchange of cash at the
maturity of the contract. The floating-rate payor pays the realized
cumulative inflation, as measured using the consumer price index, over
the life of the swap. The fixed-rate payor makes a fixed payment indexed
by the fixed rate that is contracted at the initiation of the swap
agreement. In an efficient market, the fixed-rate payment thus measures
the expected inflation rate over the life of the swap.
Second, a swaption is a financial derivative on interest rates. The
buyer of a call swaption earns a profit when the interest rate rises
relative to the strike on the swaption. As with any option, following
the Black-Scholes model, the expected volatility of interest rates
enters as an important input for pricing the swaption. The implied
volatility is the expected volatility of interest rates as implied from
current market prices of swaptions.
I.H. Summary
The channels we have discussed and our empirical approach can be
summarized with a few equations. Suppose that we are interested in the
real yield on a T-year long-term, risky, illiquid asset such as a
corporate bond or an MBS. Denote this yield by [r.sub.risky, illiq,
long-term]. Also, denote the expected average interest rate over the
next T years on short-term safe and liquid nominal bonds as
E[[i.sub.safe, liq, short-term]], and the expected inflation rate over
the same period as [[pi].sup.e]. Then we can decompose the long-term
real yield as
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Each line in this equation reflects a channel we have discussed.
The first line gives the expectations hypothesis terms: the long-term
real yield reflects the expected average future real interest rate. The
signaling channel for QE may affect [r.sub.risky,illiq,long-term]
through the first line (via the term E[[i.sub.safe,liq,short-term]]).
Expected inflation can also be expected to affect long-term real rates.
The term in the second line reflects a duration risk premium that is a
function of duration and the price of duration risk, as explained above.
This decomposition is analogous to the textbook treatment of the CAPM,
where the return on a given asset is decomposed as the asset's beta
multiplied by the market risk premium. The term in the third line is the
illiquidity premium we have discussed, which is likewise related to an
asset's illiquidity multiplied by the market price of liquidity.
The next terms reflect the safety premium (the extra yield on the
nonsafe bond because it lacks the extreme safety of a Treasury bond), a
premium on default risk, and for the case of MBSs, a premium on
prepayment risk.
The equation makes clear that a given interest rate can be affected
by QE through a variety of channels. It is not possible to examine the
change in, say, the Treasury rate alone to conclude how much QE affects
interest rates more broadly, because different interest rates are
affected by QE in different ways.
Our main empirical methodology for examining the various channels
can be thought of as a difference-in-differences approach supplemented
with information from derivatives. For example, in asking whether there
is a liquidity channel that may affect interest rates, we consider the
yield spread between a long-term agency bond and a long-term Treasury
bond and measure how this yield spread changes over the relevant QE
event. The yield decomposition from equation 1 for each of these bonds
is identical, except for the term involving liquidity. That is, these
bonds have the same duration, safety, default risk, and so forth, but
the Treasury bond is more liquid than the agency bond. Thus, the
difference in yield changes between these bonds isolates a liquidity
channel. We examine how this yield spread changes over the QE event
dates. We take this difference-in-differences approach in evaluating the
liquidity, safety, duration risk premium, and prepayment risk channels.
In addition, in some cases we use derivatives prices, which are affected
by only a single channel, to separate out the effect of a particular
channel. This is how we use the federal funds futures contracts, the CDS
rates, the inflation swap rates, and the implied volatility on interest
rate options.
II. Evidence from QE1
This section presents data from the QE1 event study and analyzes
the channels through which QE1 operated. All data used throughout the
paper are described in detail in the online data appendix. (4)
II.A. Event Study
Gagnon and others (2010) provide an event study of QEI based on the
announcements of long-term asset purchases by the Federal Reserve in the
period from late 2008 to 2009. QE1 included purchases of MBSs, Treasury
securities, and agency securities. Gagnon and others (2010) identify
eight event dates beginning with the November 25, 2008, announcement of
the Federal Reserve's intent to purchase $500 billion of agency
MBSs and $100 billion of agency debt and continuing into the fall of
2009. We focus on the first five of these event dates (November 25,
December 1, and December 16, 2008, and January 28 and March 18, 2009),
leaving out three later event dates on which only small yield changes
occurred.
There was considerable turmoil in financial markets from the fall
of 2008 to the spring of 2009, which makes inference from an event study
somewhat tricky. Some of the assets we consider, such as corporate bonds
and CDSs, are less liquid than Treasuries. During a period of low
liquidity, the prices of such assets may react slowly to an
announcement. We deal with this issue by presenting 2-day changes for
all assets (from the day before to the day after the announcement). In
the data, for high-liquidity assets such as Treasuries, 2-day changes
are almost the same as 1-day changes. For low-liquidity assets, the
2-day changes are almost always larger than the 1-day changes.
The second issue that arises is that we cannot be sure that the
identified events are in fact important events, or the dominant events
for the identified event day. That is, other significant economic news
arrives during the period and potentially creates measurement error
problems for the event study. To increase our confidence that the QE1
announcements were the dominant news on the five event dates we study,
we graph intraday movements in Treasury yields and trading volume for
each of the QE1 event dates. Figure 2, which is based on data from BG
Cantor, plots data for the on-the-run 10-year Treasury bond at each
date. The yields graphed are minute-by-minute averages, and trading
volumes are total volume by minute. The vertical lines indicate the
minutes of the announcements, defined as the minute of the first article
covering the announcement in Factiva. These graphs show that the events
identify significant movements in Treasury yields and Treasury trading
volume and that the announcements do appear to be the main piece of news
coming out on the event days, especially on December 1, 2008, December
16, 2008, and March 18, 2009. For November 25, 2008, and January 28,
2009, the trading volume graphs also suggest that the announcements are
the main events, but the evidence from the yield graphs for those days
is more mixed.
Although it is likely that these five dates are the most relevant
event dates, it is possible that there are other "true" event
dates that we have omitted. How does focusing on too limited a set of
event dates affect inference? For the objective of analyzing through
which channels QE operates, omitting true event dates reduces the power
of our tests but does not lead to any biases (whereas including
irrelevant dates could distort inference about the channels). (5) For
estimating the overall effect of QE, omitting potentially relevant dates
could lead to an upward or a downward bias, depending on how the events
on the omitted dates affected the market's perception of the
probability or the magnitude of QE.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Table 1 presents data on 2-day changes in Treasury, (noncallable)
agency, and agency MBS yields around the main event-study dates,
spanning the period from November 25, 2008 (the 2-day change from
November 24 to November 26), to March 18, 2009 (the 2-day change from
March 17 to March 19). Over this period it became evident from
announcements by the Federal Reserve that the government intended to
purchase a large quantity of long-term securities. Across the five event
dates, interest rates on long-term bonds fell across the board,
consistent with a contraction-of-supply effect. We now consider the
channels through which the supply effect may have worked.
In all the tables in this paper we provide tests of the statistical
significance of the interest rate changes or changes in derivatives
prices, focusing on the total change shown in the last row of each table
(for QE1 and QE2 separately). Specifically, we test whether changes on
QE announcement days differ from changes on other days. To do this, we
regress the daily changes for the variable in question on six dummies: a
dummy for whether there was a QE1 announcement on this day, a dummy for
whether there was a QE1 announcement on the previous day, a dummy for
whether there was a QE2 announcement on this day, a dummy for whether
there was a QE2 announcement on the previous day, a dummy for whether
there was a QE3 announcement on this day, and a dummy for whether there
was a QE3 announcement on the previous day. By "QE3" we refer
to the Federal Reserve' s announcement in its Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) statement on September 21, 2011; this event happened
after the Brookings Panel conference at which this paper was presented,
but we analyze it briefly below. This regression is estimated on daily
data from the start of 2008 to the end of the third quarter of 2011,
using ordinary least squares estimation but with robust standard errors
to account for heteroskedasticity. F tests for the QE dummy coefficients
being zero are then used to assess statistical significance. When
testing for statistical significance of 2-day changes, the F test is a
test of whether the sum of the coefficient on the QE dummy (QE1 or QE2)
and the coefficient on the dummy for a QE announcement (QE1 or QE2) on
the previous day is equal to zero. When testing for statistical
significance of 2-day changes in CDS rates, we follow a slightly
different approach, described below, because of the way our CDS rate
changes are constructed.
II.B. Signaling Channel
Figure 3 graphs the yields on the monthly federal funds futures
contract, for contract maturities from March 2009 to October 2010. The
preannouncement average yield curve is computed on the day before each
of the five QE1 events and then averaged across these dates. The
postannouncement average yield curve is computed likewise based on the
five days after the QE1 event dates. Dividing the downward shift from
the pre- to the postannouncement average yield curve by the slope of the
initial average yield curve, and multiplying the result by the number of
event dates, indicates how much the policy shifted the rate cycle
forward in time. Evaluating the forward shift at the point and slope of
the March 2010 contract, we find that the total effect of the five QE
announcements is to shift anticipated rate increases later by 6.3
months. This effect is consistent with an effect through the signaling
channel whereby the Federal Reserve's portfolio purchases (as well
as direct indications of the stance of policy in the relevant Fed
announcements) signal a commitment to keep the federal funds rate low.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Table 2 reports the 1- and 2-day changes in the yields of the
3rd-month, 6th-month, 12th-month, and 24th-month futures contracts
across the five event dates. We aggregate by, for example, the 3rd month
rather than a given contract month (for example, March), because it is
more natural to think of the information in each QE announcement as
concerning how long from today rates will be held low (on the other
hand, for plotting a yield curve it is more natural to hold the contract
month fixed, as we did in figure 3). For two of the four federal funds
futures contracts, the 2-day changes for QE1 announcement dates are
significantly more negative than on other days. The 2-day decrease in
the 24th-month contract is 40 bp.
How much of an effect can the signaling channel have on longer-term
rates? The difficulty in assessing this effect is that we cannot
precisely measure changes in the expected future federal funds rate for
horizons over 2 years, because federal funds futures contracts do not
exist for those horizons. An upper bound on the signaling effect can be
found by extrapolating the 40-bp fall in the 24th-month contract to all
horizons. This is an upper bound because it is clear that at longer
horizons, market expectations should reflect a normalization of the
current, accommodative Federal Reserve policy, so that signaling should
not have any effect on rates at those horizons. Nevertheless, with the
40-bp number, equation 1 predicts that rates at all horizons fall by 40
bp.
A second approach to estimating the signaling effect is to build on
the observation that QE shifted the path of anticipated rate hikes by
about 6 months. Signaling affects long-term rates by changing the
expectations term in equation 1, E[[i.sub.safe,liq,short-term]].
Consider the expectations term for a T-year bond:
E[[i.sub.safe,liq,short-term]] = 1 / T
[[integral].sup.T.sub.t=0][i.sup.ff.sub.t]dt,
where [i.sup.ff.sub.t] is the expected federal funds rate t years
from today. Let [i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior] denote the path described by the
federal funds rate as expected by the market before the QE
announcements. Suppose that QE policy then signals that the rate is
going to be held at [i.sup.ff.sub.0,prior] for the next X months and
thereafter follow the path indicated by [i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior] (such
that the rate at time t with the policy in place is what the rate would
have been X months earlier absent the policy). That is, QE simply shifts
an anticipated rate hike cycle later by X months. Then the decrease in
the expectations term for a T-year bond is
[DELTA]E[[i.sub.safe,liq,short-term]] = 1 / T
[[integral].sup.T.sub.t=T-X/12]([i.sup.ff.sub.0,prior] -
[i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior])dt
The first point to note from this equation is that it indicates
that the signaling effect is decreasing in maturity (that is, T). Here
is a rough check on how large the signaling effect can be. Suppose that
[i.sup.ff.sub.0,prior] is zero, which is as low as the federal funds
rate fell over this period. Consider the [i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior] term
next. The 2-year federal funds futures contract, which is the longest
contract traded, indicated a yield as high as 1.8 percent over the
period from November 2008 to March 2009. But expected federal funds
rates out to, say, 10 years are likely to be much higher than that. Over
the QE1 period the yield curve between 10 and 30 years was relatively
fiat, with Treasury rates at 10 and 30 years as high as almost 4
percent. Thus, consider a value of [i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior] of 4 percent
to get an upper bound on this signaling effect. Then the change for a
10-year bond is 20 bp, and that for a 30-year bond is about 7 bp. At the
5-year horizon, given the slope of the yield curve,
[i.sup.ff.sub.t,prior] is lower than 4 percent. We use 3 percent, which
is based on computing average forward rates between years 4 and 7 using
the 3- and 7-year Treasury yields, implying a signaling effect of 30 bp
for the 5-year horizon. Our two ways of computing the signaling effect
indicate moves in the range of 20 to 40 bp out to 10 years. This effect
potentially explains the moves in the CDS-adjusted Baa rates (in table 3
below) of 41 bp (long) and 25 bp (intermediate). It can also help
explain the fall in the 1-year Treasury yield of 25 bp.
On the other hand, longer-term rates move much more substantially
than shorter-term rates. Yields on longer-term Treasuries and agencies
fall 73 to 200 bp, much more than the 1-year yield. For the corporate
bonds in table 3 below, however, there is no apparent maturity effect
(for a given ratings category). Thus, to understand the more substantial
movements of long-term rates, we need to look to other channels and, in
particular, the safety and prepayment risk channels.
II.C. Duration Risk Channel
Consistent with the duration risk hypothesis, the yields of many
longer-term bonds in table 1 fall more than the yields of
shorter-maturity bonds. The exceptions here are the 30-year Treasury and
agency bonds, whose yields fall less than those of the 10-year bonds.
Note that because mortgages amortize and carry prepayment risk, the
duration on the 30-year MBS is around 7 years and is thus more
comparable to that of a 10-year than that of a 30-year Treasury or
agency bond. The MBS duration is from Bloomberg and calculated based on
the coupon rates of the MBS series and the fact that the MBSs amortize
and may prepay.
There is other evidence that the duration risk channel cannot
explain. There are dramatic differences in the yield changes across the
different asset classes. Agency bonds, for example, experience the
largest fall in yields. The duration risk channel cannot speak to these
effects, as it predicts only effects that depend on bond maturity.
The corporate bond data also cannot be explained by the duration
risk channel. Table 3 presents data on corporate bond yields of
intermediate (around 4 years) and long (around 10 years) duration, as
well as on these same yields with the impact of changes in CDS rates
taken out (the durations for the corporate series are obtained from
Datastream). We adjust the yield changes using CDS changes to remove any
effects due to a changing default risk premium, thereby isolating
duration risk premium effects.
We construct CDS rate changes by rating category as follows. We
obtain company-level CDS rates from Credit Market Analysis via
Datastream. We classify companies into ratings categories based on the
value-weighted average rating of the company's senior debt with
remaining maturity above 1 year, using bond information from the Mergent
Fixed Investment Securities Database (FISD) and the Trade Reporting and
Compliance Engine (TRACE) of the Financial Industry Regulatory
Authority. For each QE date, we then calculate the company-level CDS
rate change and the value-weighted average of these changes by ratings
category, with weights based on the company's senior debt with
remaining maturity above 1 year (weights are calculated based on market
values on the day before the event day). (6) The reason for calculating
company-level CDS changes and then averaging across companies (call this
"method 1"), as opposed to calculating average CDS rates
across companies and then the change over time in the averages
("method 2"), is that we have CDS data for only a subset of
companies: between 362 and 378 for each QE1 date (and around 338 for the
two main QE2 dates we study below). This is likely many fewer than the
number of companies for which bond yields are included in the corporate
bond indexes from Barclays that we use. Therefore, if we used method 2,
the CDS calculations for a given ratings category would be fairly
sensitive to whether a particular company's bonds are down- or
upgraded on a given day (and more so than the bond yield indexes). We
avoid this problem by using method 1, since a given time change is then
calculated using CDS rates for a fixed set of companies.
A side effect of using method 1 is that the sum of two daily CDS
changes for a given ratings category (each of which averages 1-day
changes across companies) will not equal the 2-day CDS change for this
category (calculated by averaging 2-day changes across companies).
Therefore, to assess the statistical significance of 2-day CDS changes
for a given ratings category, we estimate a regression where the
dependent variable is the 2-day CDS change (from date t - 1 to t + 1)
and the independent variables are a dummy for whether day t is a QE1
announcement day and a dummy for whether day t is a QE2 announcement
day. To keep statistical inference simple, we use data for every second
day only (as opposed to using overlapping 2-day changes). We make sure
that all QE announcement dates are included: if a given QE date falls on
a date that would otherwise not be used, we include the QE date and drop
the day before and the day after the QE date. We have CDS data only up
to the end of the third quarter of 2010, so we estimate the regression
using data from the start of 2008 to the end of 2010Q3. We use the same
regression for 2-day changes when assessing the statistical significance
of 2-day yield changes adjusted for CDS changes.
The CDS adjustment makes a substantial difference in interpreting
the corporate bond evidence in terms of the duration risk channel. In
particular, there is a large fall in CDS rates for lower-grade bonds on
the event dates, suggesting that default risk or the default risk
premium fell substantially with QE, consistent with the default risk
channel (we discuss this further below). Given the CDS adjustment, the
change in the yield of the Baa bond can be fully accounted for by the
signaling channel. Moreover, there is no apparent pattern across long
and intermediate maturities in the changes in CDS-adjusted corporate
bond yields. These observations suggest that we need to look to other
channels to understand the effects of QE.
II.D. Liquidity Channel
The most liquid assets in table 1 are the Treasury bonds. The
liquidity channel predicts that their yields should increase with QE,
relative to the yields on less liquid bonds. Consistent with this,
Treasury yields fall much less than the yields on agency bonds, which
are less liquid. That is, the agency-Treasury spread falls with QE. For
example, the 10-year spread falls by 200 - 107 = 93 basis points. This
is a relevant comparison because 10-year agencies and Treasuries have
similar default risk (especially since the government placed Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac into conservatorship in September 2008) and are duration
matched. Thus, this spread isolates a liquidity premium. Consistent with
the liquidity channel, the equilibrium price premium (yield discount)
for liquidity falls substantially in economic terms. To test whether
agency yield changes are statistically significantly larger than
Treasury yield changes on the QE1 dates, we use the difference between
agency yield changes and Treasury yield changes as the dependent
variable in the regression described in section II.A. We find that this
is the case, at the 5 percent level, for all maturities shown (3, 5, 10,
and 30 years).
II.E. Safety Channel
The noncallable agency bonds will be particularly sensitive to the
safety effect. These bonds are not as liquid as the Treasury bonds but
are almost as safe. Of the channels we have laid out, (nominal) agency
bond yields are mainly affected via the signaling channel, the duration
risk premium channel, and the safety channel. We have argued that the
duration risk premium channel is not substantial, and that the signaling
channel accounts for at most a 40-bp decline in yields on QE1 dates. The
fall in 10-year agency yields is 200 bp, the largest effect in table 1.
This suggests that the impact via the safety channel on agency and
Treasury yields is one of the dominant effects for QE1, at least 160 bp
for the 10-year bonds. (7) To test whether agency yield changes are
statistically significantly larger on the QE1 dates than the signaling
channel predicts, we use the difference between agency yield changes and
changes in the 24th-month federal funds futures contract yield as the
dependent variable in the regression described in section II.A, and we
find that this is the case, at the 5 percent level, for all maturities
shown (3, 5, 10, and 30 years).
As we have just noted, the yields on Treasuries fall less than
those on agencies because the liquidity effect runs counter to the
safety effect, but the safety effect itself should affect Treasuries and
agencies about equally.
The corporate bond evidence is also consistent with a safety
effect. The CDS-adjusted yields on Aaa bonds, which are close to default
free, fall much more than the CDS-adjusted yields on Baa or B bonds. The
Aa and A bonds are also affected by the safety effect, but by a smaller
amount, as the safety channel predicts. There is close to no effect on
the non-investment-grade bonds? Finally, since agencies are safer than
Aaa corporate bonds, the safety channel prediction that yields on the
former will fall more than those on the latter is also confirmed in the
data.
II.F. Prepayment Risk Channel
Agency MBS yields fall by 107 bp for 30-year bonds and 88 bp for
15-year bonds (table 1). There are two ways to interpret this evidence.
It could be due to a safety effect: the government guarantee behind
these MBSs may be worth a lot to investors, so that these securities
carry a safety premium. The safety premium then rises, as it does for
the agency bonds, decreasing agency MBS yields. On the other hand, the
agency MBSs carry significant prepayment risk and are unlikely to be
viewed as safe in the same way as agency bonds or Treasuries (where
"safety" means the almost complete certainty of nominal
repayment at known dates). We think that a more likely explanation is
market segmentation effects as in Gabaix, Krishnamurthy, and Vigneron
(2007). The government's purchase of MBSs reduces the prepayment
risk in the hands of investors, and thereby reduces MBS yields. The
effect is larger for the 30-year than for the 15-year MBSs because the
longer-term bonds carry more prepayment risk. (9)
Importantly, Andreas Fuster and Paul Willen (2010) show that the
large reductions in agency MBS rates around November 25, 2008, were
quickly followed by reductions in mortgage rates offered by mortgage
lenders to households.
II.G. Default Risk Channel
We noted earlier from table 3 that QE appears to reduce default
risk or the default risk premium, which particularly affects the
interest rates on lower-grade corporate bonds. The table shows that the
CDS rates of the Aaa firms do not change appreciably with QE. There is a
clear pattern across the ratings, going from Aaa to B, whereby firms
with higher credit risk experience the largest fall in CDS rates. In
terms of statistical significance, 2-day changes in CDS rates are
significantly more negative around QE1 announcement days than on other
days for four of the six ratings categories. This evidence suggests that
QE had a significant effect on yields through changes in default risk or
the
default risk premium.
II.H. Inflation Channel
The above analysis focuses on nominal interest rates (in
particular, on the effects on various nominal rates relative to the
nominal signaling channel benchmark). To assess effects on real rates,
one needs information about the impact of QE1 on inflation expectations.
Table 4 presents the relevant data.
The first four columns in the table report results for inflation
swaps. For example, the column labeled "10-year" shows the
change in the fixed rate on the 10-year zero-coupon inflation swap, a
market-based measure of expected inflation over the next 10 years (see
Fleckenstein, Longstaff, and Lustig 2010 for information on the
inflation swap market). These data suggest that inflation expectations
increased by between 35 and 96 bp, depending on maturity.
The next three columns present data on TIPS yields. We compare
these yield changes with those for nominal bonds to evaluate the change
in inflation expectations. Given the evidence of the existence of a
significant liquidity premium on Treasuries, it is inappropriate to
compare TIPS with nominal Treasuries. If investors' demand for
safety does not apply to inflation-adjusted safe bonds such as TIPS,
then the appropriate nominal benchmark is the CDS-adjusted Baa bond. On
the other hand, if long-term safety demand also encompasses TIPS, then
it is more appropriate to use the CDS-adjusted Aaa bond as the
benchmark. We are unaware of any definitive evidence that settles the
issue. From table 3, the CDS-adjusted yield on long-maturity Aaa bonds
falls by 70 bp, while that for intermediate-maturity Aaa bonds falls by
82 bp; the corresponding numbers for Baa bonds are 41 and 25 bp.
Matching the 70-bp change for the long-maturity Aaa bonds and the 41-bp
change in the long-maturity Baa bonds to the 187-bp change in the
10-year TIPS, we find that inflation expectations increased by 117 or
146 bp, respectively, at the 10-year horizon. (Both are significant at
the 1 percent level, using the same regression to test significance as
used for 2-day CDS changes.) At the 5-year horizon, based on the 82-bp
change in the CDS-adjusted intermediate-maturity Aaa bond, the 25-bp
change in the corresponding Baa bond, and the 160-bp change in the TIPS,
we find that inflation expectations increased by 78 or 135 bp (the first
is not significant and the second is significant at the 5 percent
level). Benchmarking to the Aaa bond produces results more similar to
those from the inflation swaps.
Together these two sets of data suggest that the impact of Federal
Reserve purchases of long-term assets on expected inflation was large
and positive.
We also evaluate the inflation uncertainty channel. The last column
in table 4 reports data on implied volatilities from interest rate
swaptions (options to enter into an interest rate swap), as measured
using the Barclays implied volatility index. The underlying maturity for
the swap ranges from 1 year to 30 years, involving options that expire
from 3 months to 20 years. The index is based on the weighted average of
implied volatilities across the different swaptions.
Average volatility by this measure over the QE1 time period is 104
bp, so the fall of 38 bp is substantial. Thus, it appears that QE1
reduced rather than increased inflation uncertainty.
The other explanation for this fall in volatility is segmented
markets effects. MBSs have an embedded interest rate option that is
often hedged by investors in the swaption market. Since QE1 involved the
purchase of MBSs, investors' demand for swaptions fell, and hence
the implied volatility of swaptions fell. This explanation is often the
one given by practitioners for changes in swaption-implied volatilities.
Notice, however, that volatility is essentially unchanged on the first
QE1 event date, which is the event that drives the largest changes in
MBS yields. This could indicate that the segmented markets effects are
not important, with volatility instead being driven by the inflation
uncertainty channel.
I1.1. Summary
QE1 significantly reduced yields on intermediate- and long-maturity
bonds. There is evidence that this decrease in yields, particularly on
the intermediate-maturity bonds, occurred via the signaling channel,
with effects on 5- to 10-year bonds ranging from 20 to 40 bp. A
preferred habitat for long-term safe assets, including Treasuries,
agencies, and highly rated corporate bonds, appears to have generated a
large impact of QE1 on the yields on these bonds, with effects as large
as 160 bp for 10-year agency and Treasury bonds. For riskier bonds such
as lower-grade corporate bonds and MBSs, QE1 had effects through a
reduction in default risk or the default risk premium and a reduced
prepayment risk premium. The 10-year CDS rates on Baa corporate bonds
fell by 40 bp on the QE1 dates. These effects on CDS rates and MBS
pricing could be due to reductions in risk borne by the financial
sector, consistent with limited intermediary capital models, or due to
impacts via a mortgage refinancing boom and its impact on the housing
market and consumer spending. We find little evidence of effects via the
duration risk premium channel. Finally, there is evidence that QE
substantially increased inflation expectations but reduced inflation
uncertainty. The increase in expected inflation was large: 10-year
expected inflation was up between 96 and 146 bp, depending on the
estimation approach used, implying that real interest rates fell
dramatically for a wide variety of borrowers.
Finally, note that these effects are all sizable and probably much
more than one should expect in general. The period from November 2008 to
March 2009 was an unusual time of financial crisis in which the demand
for safe assets was heightened, segmented markets effects were apparent
across many markets, and intermediaries suffered from serious financing
problems. In such an environment, supply changes should be expected to
have a large effect on interest rates.
III. Evidence from QE2
This section presents data from the QE2 event study and analyzes
the channels through which QE2 operated.
III.A. Event Study
We perform an event study of QE2 similar to that of QE1. There are
two relevant sets of events in QE2. First, in its August 10, 2010,
statement, the FOMC announced, "The Committee will keep constant
the Federal Reserve's holdings of securities at their current level
by reinvesting principal payments from agency debt and agency
mortgage-backed securities in longer-term Treasury securities."
Before this announcement, market expectations were that the Federal
Reserve would let its MBS portfolio run off, (10) thereby reducing
reserve balances in the system and allowing the Fed to exit from its
nontraditional monetary policies. Thus, the announcement of the Federal
Reserve's intent to continue QE revised market expectations.
Moreover, the announcement indicated that QE would shift toward
longer-term Treasuries, and not agencies or agency MBSs as in QE1. As a
back-of-the-envelope computation, suppose that the prepayment rate for
the next year on $1.1 trillion of MBSs was 20 percent. (11) Based on
this, the announcement indicated that the Federal Reserve intended to
purchase $220 billion [$1.1 trillion x 0.2] of Treasuries over the next
year, $176 billion [$1.1 trillion x (1 - 0.2) x 0.2] over the subsequent
year, and so on. It is unclear from the announcement how long the
Federal Reserve expected to keep the reinvestment strategy in place.
The September 21, 2010, FOMC announcement reiterates this message:
"The Committee also will maintain its existing policy of
reinvesting principal payments from its securities holdings."
The second type of information for QE2 pertains to the Federal
Reserve's intent to expand its purchases of long-term Treasury
securities. The fourth paragraph of the September 21 FOMC statement
says, "The Committee will continue to monitor the economic outlook
and financial developments and is prepared to provide additional
accommodation if needed to support the economic recovery" (emphasis
added).
This paragraph includes new language relative to the corresponding
paragraph in the August 10, 2010, FOMC statement, which read, "The
Committee will continue to monitor the economic outlook and financial
developments and will employ its policy tools as necessary to promote
economic recovery and price stability." The new language in the
September 21 statement follows the third paragraph of that statement in
which the FOMC reiterates its intention to maintain its target for the
federal funds rate and reiterates its policy of reinvesting principal
payments from its securities holdings. The new language was read by many
market participants as indicating new stimulus by the Federal Reserve,
and particularly an expansion of its purchases of long-term Treasuries.
For example, Goldman Sachs economists, in their market commentary on
September 21, 2010, refer to this language and conclude that the Federal
Reserve intended to purchase up to $1 trillion of Treasuries. (12)
The following announcement from the November 3, 2010, FOMC
statement makes such an intention explicit: "The Committee will
maintain its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments from its
securities holdings. In addition, the Committee intends to purchase a
further $600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities by the end of
the second quarter of 2011."
The November 3 announcement was widely anticipated. A Wall Street
Journal survey of private sector economists in early October 2010 found
that they expected the Federal Reserve to purchase about $750 billion in
QE2. (13) We have noted above the expectation, as of September 21, 2010,
by Goldman Sachs economists of $1 trillion of purchases. Based on this,
one would expect the November 3 announcement to have little effect.
(Estimates in the press varied widely, but the actual number of $600
billion was within the range of numbers commonly mentioned.)
Figure 4 presents intraday data on the 10-year Treasury bond yield
around the announcement times of the above FOMC statements. The August
10 announcement appears to have contained significant news for the
Treasury market, reducing the yield in a manner that suggests that
market expectations regarding QE were revised upward. The reaction to
the September 21 announcement is qualitatively similar. After the
November 3 announcement, Treasury yields increased but then fell
somewhat. This reaction suggests that markets may have priced in more
than a $600 billion QE announcement.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
In our event study, we aggregate across the August 10 and September
21 events, which seem clearly to be driven by upward revisions in QE
expectations. We do not add in the change from the November 3
announcement, as it is unclear whether only the increase in yields after
that announcement or also the subsequent decrease was due to QE2.
(Furthermore, the large 2-day reaction to the November 3 announcement
may not have been due to QE2, since a lot of it happened the morning of
November 4, around the time new numbers were released for jobless claims
and productivity.) As noted in section II.A, given our objective of
understanding the channels of QE, it is important to focus on events
that we can be sure are relevant to QE.
Additionally, we present information for both 1-day changes and
2-day changes, but we focus on the 1-day changes in our discussion. The
reason is that market liquidity had normalized by the fall of 2010, and
looking at the 2-day changes would therefore likely add noise to the
data.
III.B. Analysis
Table 5 provides data on the changes in Treasury, agency, and
agency MBS yields over the event dates. Table 6 provides data on changes
in corporate bond yields, CDS rates, and CDS-adjusted corporate yields.
The effects of QE2 on yields are consistently much smaller than the
effects found for QE1. This could be partially due to omission of
relevant additional event dates for QE2. We considered various
additional events (for example, speeches by Federal Reserve officials)
but, using intraday Treasury yield data, did not find any days with
dramatic Treasury yield declines right around the events. This does not
mean that considering only a few QE2 event dates captures all of the
impact of QE2, but only that the market may have updated its perceptions
about QE2 not only on Federal Reserve announcement dates but also on
dates of bad economic news. Decomposing the yield impact of, for
example, a GDP announcement into its "standard effects" and
its indirect effect due to its impact on the likelihood of QE is
difficult, and we do not pursue it.
The fact that the effects of QE2 are fairly small makes it more
difficult to discern all of the various channels involved in QE2 than in
QE1. That said, we offer some conclusions regarding the channels:
--There is significant evidence of the signaling channel. The
12th-month federal funds futures contract (table 2) falls by 4 bp. The
24th-month contract falls by 11 bp. Extrapolating out from this
24th-month contract suggests that we can explain moves in longer-term
rates of up to 11 bp following our first approach outlined in our
discussion of signaling for QE1. Turning to our second approach, we show
in figure 5 the average pre- and post-QE2 yield curves from the federal
funds futures contracts. The graph suggests a shift forward in time of
the anticipated rate hike cycle. We can again estimate how large this
shift is. Because the slope of the futures curve from figure 5 is not
constant, the computation is sensitive to exactly which point one uses
to evaluate the time shift. Using the slope and vertical shift at July
2012, we estimate that the time shift is 3.2 months, whereas using the
slope and vertical shift at July 2011, we estimate it at 2.1 months. The
latter implies a fall in 5-year rates of 11 bp, a fall in 10-year rates
of 7 bp, and a fall in 30-year rates of 2 bp. A time shift of 3.2 months
implies a fall in 5-year rates of 16 bp, a fall in 10-year rates of 11
bp, and a fall in 30-year rates of 4 bp. The fall of 16 bp in the 5-year
rate from this computation is too large relative to the 11-bp upper
bound from our first approach, suggesting that the computation at 2.1
months is more plausible.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
These numbers appear to be in line with the CDS-adjusted corporate
bond yield changes as well as the agency MBS yield changes. Note also
that the intermediate-term corporate rates (those for bonds of about 4
years' duration) in table 6 fall more than the long-term rates (10
years' duration) and that the 15-year agency MBS yields (3
years' duration) in table 5 fall more than the 30-year yields (7
years' duration). Both moves are consistent with the signaling
channel. Thus, the signaling channel can plausibly explain all of the
movements in the corporate bond rates and the agency MBS yields. The
only exceptions are the long-term Ba and B categories, where the CDS
rates appear to rise sharply with no corresponding effects on bond
yields. We are unsure of what is driving the divergence between CDS
rates and bond yields for these categories.
--Given that MBS yield changes are fully accounted for by the
signaling channel, there is no evidence of a prepayment risk channel for
QE2. This is as would be expected given that QE2 did not involve MBS
purchases. Similarly, there does not appear to be a substantial duration
risk premium channel. Given that the size of the signaling channel is
roughly the same as the decline in the CDS-adjusted corporate rates,
there is no additional yield decline to be explained by a duration risk
premium reduction.
--There is evidence for a safety channel. Yields on 10-year agency
and Treasury bonds, both of which have near-zero default risk, fall more
than the CDS-adjusted corporate bond yields. With a signaling effect for
10-year bonds of between 7 and 11 bp, and a fall in 10-year Treasury and
agency bond yields of 17 to 18 bp, the safety effect is between 6 and 11
bp for the 10-year agency bonds and Treasuries.
--There does not appear to be a liquidity channel. Treasury and
agency yields fall by nearly the same amounts, so that their spread,
which we use to measure liquidity, appears unchanged. This result is
plausible because liquidity premiums in bond markets were quite low in
late 2010, as market liquidity conditions had normalized. Consider the
following data (as of August 10, 2010):
Yield (basis points)
Tier 1 nonfinancial
Maturity Treasury bill commercial paper
1 week 13 20
1 month 15 19
3 months 15 27
The yield discount on the more liquid 1-week bill relative to the
1-month bill is only 2 bp, and the yield discount on the more liquid
3-month bill relative to 3-month commercial paper is only 12 bp. The
latter premium also reflects some credit risk and tax effects. Part of
the reason why liquidity premiums are so low is that government policy
had already provided a large supply of liquid assets to the private
sector. The Federal Reserve had already increased bank reserves
substantially. At the end of the third quarter of 2008, reserve balances
totaled $222 billion. At the end of the second quarter of 2010, reserve
balances totaled $973 billion, and the government increased the supply
of Treasury bills from $1,484 billion to $1,777 billion over this same
period. (14) These arguments suggest that the effects on liquidity
premiums should be negligible via the liquidity channel.
--There is no evidence for a credit risk channel as CDS rates rise,
especially for lower-grade bonds. This may indicate that QE2 (unlike
QE1) did not have a substantial stimulating effect on the economy. It is
possible that CDS rates rose (rather than simply remained unchanged)
because the market inferred from the Federal Reserve's decision to
pursue QE2 that the economy was in worse shape than previously thought.
--Table 7 provides data on inflation swaps and TIPS yields for the
event dates. Inflation expectations rise with QE2. The rate on the
10-year inflation swap rises by 5 bp, while that on the 30-year
inflation swap rises by 11 bp. The 10-year TIPS yield falls by 25 bp.
Comparing this number with the CDS-adjusted declines in yields on
long-term Aaa and Baa bonds implies that inflation expectations rise by
14 bp or 16 bp, respectively, at the 10-year horizon. The implied
volatility on swaptions falls by 3 bp, indicating a slight decrease in
inflation uncertainty.
III.C Summary and Discussion
The QE2 data suggest three primary channels for this
Treasuries-only policy. The signaling channel lowered yields on 5-year
bonds by 11 to 16 bp and on 10-year bonds by 7 to 11 bp, depending on
the estimation method used. The safety channel lowered yields on
low-default-risk 10-year bonds by an additional 6 to 11 bp. Furthermore,
there is significant evidence of an increase in inflation expectations
(5 to 16 bp over the 10-year horizon), suggesting that real interest
rates fell for all borrowers. The main effect on the nominal rates that
are most relevant for households and many corporations--mortgage rates
and rates on lower-grade corporate bonds--was thus through the signaling
and inflation channels, rather than from a portfolio balance effect via
the QE2 Treasury purchases.
Our finding that signaling played a primary role in QE2 is
consistent with the market's reaction to the August 9, 2011, FOMC
statement, which said that "the Committee currently anticipates
that economic conditions--including low rates of resource utilization
and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run--are likely to
warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least
through mid-2013." From August 8 to August 9, Treasury rates
declined by 12, 20, 20, and 12 bp at maturities of 3, 5, 10, and 30
years, respectively. An important question is thus whether the Federal
Reserve could have achieved the signaling and inflation impact on yields
seen in the Treasuries-only policy of QE2 from a commitment like that in
the August 9, 2011, statement, and thus without taking on additional
balance sheet risk.
It is also interesting to contrast the channels in the QE2 policy
with those in the QE1 policy, and to consider the Federal Reserve's
QE3 action on September 21, 2011, in this light. We find that the main
channel in lowering MBS rates (and thus household mortgage rates) and
corporate borrowing rates in QE1 is a portfolio balance effect via the
MBS purchases during a time of market stress (and its associated effects
on the housing market and the real economy). We also find a smaller, but
still sizable, signaling effect in QE1. The QE2 channel for MBS and
corporate borrowing rates appears to be entirely through the signaling
effects. QE3 involves both purchases of long-dated Treasuries (funded by
corresponding sales of shorter-maturity Treasuries) as well as
investments in agency MBSs. The two relevant parts of the September 21,
2011, FOMC statement are the following: "The Committee intends to
purchase, by the end of June 2012, $400 billion of Treasury securities
with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years and to sell an equal
amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 3 years or
less," and "the Committee will now reinvest principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities
in agency mortgage-backed securities."
Our analysis of QE1 and QE2 suggests that the impact of QE3 on MBS
and corporate borrowing rates should occur through a signaling effect
and a portfolio balance effect based on the MBS purchases. The latter
effect should be smaller than during QE1, because market conditions were
less stressed in September 2011 than in late 2008 and early 2009, and
MBS purchases were larger in QE1 than in QE3.
From September 20 to September 21, 2011, long-term interest rates
decline substantially and across the board. The largest decline, 23 bp,
is in the 30-year MBS (as previously, this is based on averaging the
yields on current-coupon Fannie Mae, Ginnie Mae, and Freddie Mac
securities); the yield on the comparable-duration 10-year Treasury
declines by 7 bp, that on the 10-year agency by 2 bp, and long-term
corporate rates from the Aaa to the Baa category by between 15 and 17
bp. These moves are plausibly affected by an MBS risk premium channel,
with attendant effects for corporate borrowing rates, as in QE1. On the
other hand, the market responses differ in three other ways from those
following QE1. First, the federal funds futures contract barely moves
(the 24th-month contract fails by 1 bp), suggesting a negligible
signaling channel. It is possible that the August 9, 2011, statement
reduced the amount of room remaining for rate reductions via the
signaling channel. Second, default risk rises, with 10-year
investment-grade CDS rates rising by 9 bp and high-yield CDS rates
rising by 1 bp. (We do not have firm-level CDS data for the QE3 period.
The CDS numbers reported are based on data from Markit obtained via
Datastream.) The rise in perceived default risk despite an observed
decrease in corporate bond yields is unlike what happened in QE1 and is
puzzling to us. One possible answer is that other news affecting
financial markets that day also moved asset prices. When we look at
intraday asset price changes, we find that Treasury and MBS rates
decline sharply within minutes after the announcement. That same day the
S&P 500 index declines by around 3 percent, but the bulk of this
decline occurs a full hour after the FOMC announcement. Thus, it is
possible that bad news affected the market later in the day, driving up
CDS rates and driving down all yields. We do not have intraday data on
corporate bond yields and CDS rates with which to evaluate this
hypothesis. Finally, unlike in both QE1 and QE2, inflation expectations
measured from inflation swaps are down 8 bp at the 30-year horizon and 4
bp at the 10-year horizon. It is possible that since QE3 involved no
change in the monetary base, markets perceived the operation not to be
inflationary. Moreover, both the increased default risk and the decrease
in inflation expectations could be driven by the markets updating their
odds of a slowdown in economic growth. (15)
IV. Regression Analysis of the Safety Channel
The event-study evidence is useful in identifying channels for QE.
Although it provides guidance on the magnitudes of the effects through
QE, it is hard to interpret the numbers precisely, because event-study
measures are dependent on the dynamics of expectations through the
event. That is, the asset market reaction depends on the change in the
expectation of QE over the event. We have no direct way of precisely
measuring such a change, nor can we determine whether the event study is
likely to over- or understate the effects of QE. In addition, the QE1
event occurred in highly unusual market conditions, so that it is hard
to extrapolate numbers from that period to more normal conditions. As
such, it is valuable to find alternative approaches to estimating the
impact of QE. In this section we use regression analysis to provide such
estimates, focusing on the long-term safety channel.
IV.A. Regressions
We build on the regression analysis in Krishnamurthy and
Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) to estimate the effect of a purchase of
long-term securities via the safety channel. We focus on the safety
channel because it appears from the event studies to be a dominant
effect, and because long time series of historical data exist that allow
us to elaborate on this channel.
The regression approach we have taken in prior work can be
explained through figure 1. Consider the yield (or price) difference
between a low-default-risk bond, such as a Treasury bond, and a
Baa-rated bond. This yield difference includes both a default risk
premium due to standard risk considerations and a safety premium due to
clientele demands for particularly safe assets. We disentangle the
default risk and the safety premium by observing that the safety premium
is decreasing in the supply of safe assets, including Treasuries,
whereas the default risk component can be controlled for using empirical
default measures. The empirical approach is to regress the Baa-Treasury
spread on the supply of Treasuries as well as on standard measures of
default.
As we explain in Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010), the
Baa-Treasury spread reflects both a liquidity premium, since Treasuries
are much more liquid than corporate bonds, and a safety premium. The
Baa-Treasury spread is thus likely to overstate the safety premium. (16)
We therefore also consider the spread between Baa- and Aaa-rated
corporate bonds (as we did for QE). The coefficient from the Baa-Aaa
regression is a pure read on the safety premium, because Baa and Aaa
corporate bonds are equally illiquid. However, it is an underestimate of
the safety effect as may be reflected in Treasuries or agencies, because
although Aaa corporate bonds are safe, they still contain more default
risk than Treasuries or agencies. For example, Moody's reports that
over 10 years, the historical average default probability of a corporate
bond that is rated Aaa today is 1 percent (whereas it is likely close to
zero for Treasuries and around 8 percent for Baa bonds). We note that an
alternative spread to capture the price of long-term safety would be
that between Treasury yields and duration-matched federal funds futures
(following our approach to estimating the safety channel for QE, with
the exception that agency yields could not be used historically because
of their higher risk before the government takeover). However, data on
federal funds futures contracts are not available far enough back in
time to allow meaningful regressions in annual data.
In Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010), we mainly focus on
the effect of changes in the total supply of Treasuries, irrespective of
maturity, on bond yields. For evaluating QE, we are interested more in
asking how a change in the supply of long-term Treasuries (and agency
bonds) will affect yields. Accordingly, we construct a maturity-based
measure of debt supply as follows. For each Treasury issue in the Center
for Research in Security Prices' Monthly U.S. Treasury Database, we
compute the market value of that issue multiplied by the duration of the
issue divided by 10. (17) We normalize by 10 to express the supply
variable in "10-year equivalents." We then sum these values
across Treasury issues with remaining maturity of 2 years or more. We
denote the sum as LONG-SUPPLY. We also construct the (unweighted) market
value across all Treasury issues (TOTAL-SUPPLY), including those with a
remaining maturity of less than 2 years.
We then regress the spread between the Moody's Baa corporate
bond yield and the long-term Treasury yield (Baa-Treasury), or between
Moody's Baa and Aaa corporate bond yields, on ln(LONG-SUPPLY/ GDP)
instrumented by TOTAL-SUPPLY/GDP and squares and cubes of
TOTAL-SUPPLY/GDP. The regression includes as default controls stock
market volatility (the standard deviation of weekly stock returns over
the preceding year) and the slope of the yield curve (the 10-year
Treasury yield minus the 3-month yield). Data sources are as described
in detail in Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010). The regressions
are estimated via two-stage least squares, with standard errors adjusted
for an AR(1) correlation structure. It is important to instrument for
LONG-SUPPLY because the maturity structure of government debt is chosen
by the government in a way that could be correlated with spreads.
TOTAL-SUPPLY is strongly related to LONG-SUPPLY and is plausibly
exogenous to the safety premium. (See Krishnamurthy and
Vissing-Jorgensen 2010 for further details of the estimation method.)
The regressions are estimated using annual data from 1949 to 2008. The
regression is
[spread.sub.t] = [default controls.sub.t] + [beta]ln
([LONG-SUPPLY.sub.t]/[GDP.sub.t]) + [[epsilon].sub.t],
instrumented by TOTAL-SUPPLY/GDP and squares and cubes of
TOTAL-SUPPLY/GDP. The term [beta] In(LONG-SUPPLY/GDP) is the premium of
interest in this regression. We evaluate the effect of a QE by
evaluating this premium term at the pre-QE and post-QE values of
LONG-SUPPLY.
The resulting [beta] coefficient is -0.83 (t statistic = -5.83) for
the Baa-Treasury spread. For the Baa-Aaa spread, the coefficient is
-0.32 (t statistic = -3.02).
IV.B. Estimates for QE1
Gagnon and others (2010) report that, in 10-year equivalents, the
Federal Reserve had purchased $169 billion of Treasuries, $59 billion of
agency debt, and $573 billion of agency MBSs by February 1, 2010. The
Treasury purchases were complete at $300 billion, whereas $164 billion
of up to $200 billion of agency securities had been purchased. We scale
up the agency number to $59 billion x (200/164) = $72 billion of 10-year
equivalents.
Agency debt and Treasury debt are almost equally safe during the QE
period, whereas agency MBSs carry prepayment risk. Thus, if we consider
only the Treasuries and agencies purchased and ask what effect this will
have on the Baa-Aaa spread using the regression coefficient of -0.32, we
find that the effect is 4 bp (we also use the fact that at the end of
2008, before the QE purchases, LONG-SUPPLY equaled $1,983 billion and
GDP for 2008 was $14,291.5 billion). As we have noted, this is smaller
than the true safety effect, because Aaa corporate bonds are not as safe
as either agencies or Treasuries. As an upper bound, even if we use the
Baa-Treasury coefficient (which includes a liquidity premium), the
estimate is 11 bp. Although the event study may not identify the precise
economic impact of QE via the long-term safety channel, for reasons
discussed earlier, our regression estimates still appear quite small.
This suggests that had QE1 taken place at an "average" demand
for safety (as estimated by our regressions), its effects via the safety
channel would have been much smaller than what we observed.
IV.C Estimates for QE2
In QE2 the Federal Reserve announced that it would purchase $600
billion of Treasuries and roll over the maturing MBSs in its portfolio
into long-term Treasuries. We suggested earlier that the latter
translates to a purchase of $220 billion over the next year, and $176
billion for the following year, if the policy was kept in place. For the
sake of argument, let us suppose that the market expects the policy to
be in place for only one year; then the total effect is to purchase $820
billion of Treasuries.
An $820 billion Treasury purchase can have a large effect on safety
premiums. Moreover, QE2 occurred during more normalized market
conditions, so that estimates based on the -0.32 coefficient are likely
to be appropriate during this period. The $820 billion of Treasuries
translates to $511 billion of 10-year equivalents, based on the planned
maturity breakdown provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
(18) Based on these numbers, and using the -0.32 coefficient, we find
that QE2 should have increased the safety premium by 8 bp. Using the
upper-bound coefficient of -0.83, we estimate an effect of 20 bp. These
numbers are roughly comparable to the magnitude of the safety channel
for QE2 we estimated using the event-study approach.
V. Conclusion
We have documented that the Federal Reserve's purchases of
long-term Treasuries and other long-term bonds (QE1 in 2008-09 and QE2
in 2010-11) significantly lowered nominal interest rates on Treasuries,
agencies, corporate bonds, and MBSs, but with magnitudes that differed
across bond types, across maturities, and across QE1 and QE2. There are
several primary channels for these effects. Three of these were
operative in both QE1 and QE2, and the other three only in QE1. For both
QE1 and QE2 we find significant evidence for, first, a signaling channel
that drives down the yield on all bonds (with larger effects on
intermediate- than on long-term bonds); second, a long-term safety
channel through which yields on medium- and long-maturity safe bonds
fall because a unique clientele exists for extremely safe nominal
assets, and Federal Reserve purchases reduce the supply of such assets
and hence increase the equilibrium safety premium; and third, an
inflation channel, with evidence from both inflation swap rates and TIPS
showing that expected inflation increased, implying larger reductions in
real than in nominal rates. The three additional channels for QE1 are,
first, an MBS risk premium channel that lowers yields on MBSs (QE
affected MBS yields by more than the signaling effect for QE1 but not
for QE2, indicating that another main channel for QE is to affect the
equilibrium price of mortgage-specific risk if QE involves purchases of
MBSs); second, a default risk or default risk premium channel that
lowers yields on corporate bonds; and third, a liquidity channel through
which QE financed by reserves increases yields on the most liquid bonds
relative to less liquid bonds of similar duration. We find no evidence
for an impact of QE on the duration risk premium.
Our results have three main policy implications. First, it is
inappropriate for central banks to focus only on Treasury rates as a
policy target, because changes in Treasury rates are driven by safety
effects that do not carry over to mortgage and lower-grade corporate
borrowing rates. Second, the beneficial effects of QE for mortgage and
lower-grade corporate rates of the Federal Reserve's asset
purchases are highest when these purchases involve non-Treasury assets
such as MBSs. Last, a Treasuries-only policy such as QE2 has effects
primarily through a signaling channel, whereby the market lowers its
anticipation of future federal funds rates. An important question is
thus whether the Federal Reserve could have achieved the signaling
impact via a direct commitment as in the August 9,2011, FOMC statement,
and thus without taking on additional balance sheet risk.
The principal contribution of our work relative to other research
on QE in the United States (D'Amico and King 2010, Gagnon and
others 2010, and Hamilton and Wu 2010) is that by analyzing the
differential impact of QE on a host of interest rates and derivatives,
we shed light on the channels through which QE affects interest rates.
Although the prior literature does not discuss the channels for QE in as
much detail as we do, it points to the operation of QE through two
potential channels: the signaling channel as well as a "portfolio
balance channel." Brian Sack, executive vice president of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York's Markets Group, which oversees
open market operations, describes the portfolio balance channel as
follows:
By purchasing a particular asset, the Fed reduces the amount of the
security that the private sector holds, displacing some investors and
reducing the holdings of others. In order for investors to be willing to
make those adjustments, the expected return on the security has to fall.
Put differently, the purchases bid up the price of the asset and hence
lower its yield. These effects would be expected to spill over into
other assets that are similar in nature, to the extent that investors
are willing to substitute between the assets. These patterns describe
what researchers often refer to as the portfolio balance channel. (Sack
2009, emphasis added)
In thinking about the portfolio balance channel, it is key to
understand which assets are substitutes for those that the Federal
Reserve is purchasing. Compared with prior work, we have fleshed out the
portfolio balance channel in more detail. We have considered specific
finance theory-based versions of the portfolio balance channel, each of
which indicates how certain assets may substitute for others in terms of
their duration risk, prepayment risk, default risk, degree of extreme
safety, and liquidity. One portfolio balance channel that emerges as
substantial for both QE1 and QE2 works partially through a safety
channel affecting extremely safe long- and medium-term bonds. Investors
have a unique demand for low-default-risk assets of particular
maturities. When the Federal Reserve purchases a large quantity of such
assets, investors bid up the price on the remaining low-default-risk
assets, decreasing their yields. The safety channel highlights the
substitutability of assets within a (low) default-risk class. In other
words, the safety channel can be thought of as a preferred habitat for
particular maturities, but applying only to low-default-risk assets.
This channel differs from the duration risk channel. Under the duration
risk channel, in which the key dimension of substitutability is duration
risk, QE has an effect on long-term rates by reducing the duration risk
held by investors, and thereby reducing the term premium on longer-term
assets. When the Federal Reserve removes duration from the portfolios of
investors, they substitute by purchasing other long-duration assets to
make up for the lost duration. Longer-duration assets, which substitute
better for the removed duration than do short-duration assets, fall the
most in yield. We do not find support for the operation of the duration
risk channel. Instead, the role of duration appears to be through a
preferred-habitat demand for particular maturities.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank Jack Bao, Olivier Blanchard, Greg Duffee,
Charlie Evans, Ester Faia, Simon Gilchrist, Robin Greenwood, Thomas
Philippon, Monika Piazzesi, Tsutomu Watanabe, the editors, and
participants at seminars and conferences at Brookings, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, the European Central Bank, the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, Princeton University, Northwestern University, the Centro de
Estudios Monetarios y Financieros (Madrid), the University of
Pennsylvania (Wharton), the Society for Economic Dynamics, the National
Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute, the Napa Conference on
Financial Markets Research, the European Finance Association, the
University of Miami, the Bank of England, Stanford University, and the
University of California, Berkeley, for their suggestions. We thank
Kevin Crotty and Juan Mendez for research assistance. The authors
declare no relevant conflicts of interest.
References
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. "Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to
the Congress." Testimony before the Committee on Housing, Banking,
and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, Washington (July 21).
Bernanke, Ben S., Vincent R. Reinhart, and Brian P. Sack. 2004.
"Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical
Assessment." BPEA, no. 2: 1-78.
Clouse, James, Dale Henderson, Athanasios Orphanides, David Small,
and Peter Tinsley. 2000. "Monetary Policy When the Nominal
Short-Term Interest Rate Is Zero." Topics in Macroeconomics 3, no.
1, article 12.
D'Amico, Stefania, and Thomas B. King. 2010. "Flow and
Stock Effects of Large-Scale Treasury Purchases." Finance and
Economics Discussion Series no. 2010-52. Washington: Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System (September).
Dudley, William C. 2010. "The Outlook, Policy Choices and Our
Mandate." Remarks at the Society of American Business Editors and
Writers Fall Conference, City University of New York.
Eggertsson, Gauti, and Michael Woodford. 2003. "The Zero Bound
on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy." BPEA, no. 1:
139-233.
Fleckenstein, Matthias, Francis A. Longstaff, and Hanno Lustig.
2010. "Why Does the Treasury Issue TIPS? The TIPS-Treasury Bond
Puzzle." Working paper. University of California, Los Angeles.
Fuster, Andreas, and Paul S. Willen. 2010. "$1.25 Trillion Is
Still Real Money: Some Facts about the Effects of the Federal
Reserve's Mortgage Market Investments." Working paper. Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston.
Gabaix, Xavier, Arvind Krishnamurthy, and Olivier Vigneron. 2007.
"Limits of Arbitrage: Theory and Evidence from the Mortgage-Backed
Securities Market." Journal of Finance 62, no. 2: 557-95.
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack.
2010. "Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They
Work?" Staff Report no. 441. Federal Reserve Bank of New York
(March).
Greenwood, Robin, and Dimitri Vayanos. 2010. "Bond Supply and
Excess Bond Return." Working paper. London School of Economics.
Hamilton, James D., and Jing Wu. 2010. "The Effectiveness of
Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound
Environment." Working paper. University of California, San Diego.
He, Zhiguo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 2010. "Intermediary
Asset Pricing." Working paper. Northwestern University.
Joyce, Michael, Ana Lasaosa, Ibrahim Stevens, and Matthew Tong.
2010. "The Financial Market Impact of Quantitative Easing."
Working Paper no. 393. London: Bank of England.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen. 2010.
"The Aggregate Demand for Treasury Debt." Working paper.
Northwestern University.
Longstaff, Francis A., Sanjay Mithal, and Eric Neis. 2005.
"Corporate Yields Spreads: Default Risk or Liquidity? New Evidence
from the Credit-Default Swap Market." Journal of Finance 60, no. 5:
2213-54.
Piazzesi, Monika, and Eric T. Swanson. 2008. "Futures Prices
as Risk-Adjusted Forecasts of Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary
Economics 55, no. 4: 677-91.
Sack, Brian. 2009. "The Fed's Expanded Balance
Sheet." Remarks at the Money Marketeers of New York University, New
York (December 9). www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/2009/sac091202.html.
Swanson, Eric. 2011. "Let's Twist Again: A High-Frequency
Event-Study Analysis of Operation Twist and Its Implications for
QE2." BPEA (Spring): 151-88.
Vayanos, Dimitri, and Jean-Luc Vila. 2009. "A Preferred
Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates." Working
paper. Financial Markets Group, London School of Economics.
Wright, Jonathan. 2011. "What Does Monetary Policy Do to
Long-Term Interest Rates at the Zero Lower Bound?" Working paper.
Johns Hopkins University.
ARVIND KRISHNAMURTHY
Northwestern University
ANNETTE VISSING-JORGENSEN
Northwestern University
(1.) Other papers in the literature that have examined Treasury
supply and bond yields include Bernanke, Reinhart, and Sack (2004),
Greenwood and Vayanos (2010), D'Amico and King (2010), Hamilton and
Wu (2010), and Wright (2011).
(2.) Piazzesi and Swanson (2008) show that these futures prices
reflect a risk premium, in addition to such expectations. If short-term
rates are low and employment growth is strong, the risk premium is
smaller. To the extent that this risk premium is reduced by QE, our
estimates of the signaling effect are too large. It is difficult to
assess whether changes in short-term rates or employment growth due to
QE have the same effect as non-policy-related changes in these
variables, so we do not attempt to quantify any such bias.
(3.) See Charles Calomiris and Ellis Tallman, "In Fed's
Monetary Targeting, Two Tails Are Better than One," Bloomberg
Business Week, November 17, 2010 (www.businessweek.com/
investor/content/nov2010/pi20101117_644007.htm).
(4.) Online appendixes for all papers in this volume may be
accessed at the Brookings Papers website,
www.brookings.edu/economics/bpea.aspx, under "Past Editions."
(5.) We thank Gabriel Chodorow-Reich for clarifying this point.
(6.) We drop CDS rates for AIG, the large insurance firm in which
the U.S. government intervened in September 2008. According to our
calculations, this firm is the largest in ratings category Baa by market
value of bonds outstanding and has a very high CDS rate increase on our
last QE1 date. With AIG included, the 2-day CDS changes for category Baa
(summed across the five QE1 dates) are 32 bp rather than 40 bp at the
10-year horizon and 37 bp rather than 51 bp at the 5-year horizon. We
are not sure whether AIG is still included in the Barclays bond indexes
during this period, given the government's intervention in this
firm.
(7.) When inferring the size of the safety channel from a
comparison of agency yield changes and changes in federal funds futures,
we are implicitly assuming that neither is affected by changes in the
overall supply of liquidity in QE1. This is plausible if the following
assumptions hold: that agencies are not (to a substantial extent) valued
for their liquidity and do not change in price in response to a change
in the supply of liquidity; that the federal funds futures we use are
sufficiently far out in the future not to be affected by the high price
of liquidity in the fall of 2008; and that the market expects any
liquidity injected by QE1 to be withdrawn by the time of the federal
funds futures contract used. The last two assumptions are plausible
given that we focus on 24th-month federal funds futures.
(8.) The anomalously large moves in the CDS rates for the B
category appear to be partly driven by Ford Motor Company bonds, perhaps
related to news about the auto bailouts. If we drop Ford from the
tabulation, the 5-year and 10-year CDS rates fall by 435 bp and 496 bp,
respectively.
(9.) The fall in MBS yields may be driven by both a reduction in
prepayment risk and a reduction in the risk premium required to bear
prepayment risk. This is similar to the effects on corporate bond
yields, where reductions in both default risk and the default risk
premium play a role. We have looked at the option-adjusted spreads on
MBSs, which remove the prepayment risk effects using a model, and find
that these spreads fall, suggesting that the prepayment risk premium
fell.
(10.) See Federal Reserve Board Chairman Ben Bernanke's
Monetary Policy Report to Congress on July 21, 2010, discussing the
"normalization" of monetary policy. The issue is also
highlighted in Bernanke's testimony on March 25, 2010, on the
Federal Reserve's exit strategy.
(11.) The Federal Reserve's holdings of MBSs were $1,118
billion on August 4, 2010, and $897 billion on August 3, 2011 (according
to the H4 report of the Federal Reserve), for an annualized decline of
19.7 percent.
(12.) "FOMC Rate Decision--Fed Signals Willingness to Ease
Further if Growth or Inflation Continue to Disappoint," Goldman
Sachs newsletter, New York, September 21, 2010.
(13.) Jon Hilsenrath and Jonathan Cheng, "Fed Gears Up for
Stimulus," Wall Street Journal, October 26, 2010.
(14.) Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States,
table L. 109 (depository institution reserves), and U.S. Treasury,
Monthly Statement of the Public Debt of the United States, various
issues.
(15.) Another interesting case study for QE is that of the United
Kingdom in 2009-10, examined by Joyce and others (2010). Like QE2 in the
United States, QE in the United Kingdom during this period consisted of
purchases of long-term government bonds, totaling 200 billion [pounds
sterling] in the U.K. case. Joyce and others (2010) document that QE led
to large reductions in government bond yields, smaller effects on
investment-grade bonds, and more erratic effects on non-investment-grade
corporate bonds. They find quite small effects on derivatives measures
of future policy rates (to capture the signaling effects). The authors
do not consider the effects on MBS rates, CDS rates, or expected
inflation. It would be interesting to revisit the U.K. QE evidence
explicitly in the framework of our channels approach. Regarding our
long-term safety channel, a few observations from the U.K. experience
are striking. Joyce and others (2010, chart 7) find that on the first QE
event date, yields on gilts (government bonds) moved dramatically out to
a maturity of 15 years, with sharply smaller effects on yields just
longer than the 15-year maturity, suggesting that the market did not
expect bonds beyond that maturity to be purchased. On the second QE
event date, the Bank of England announced that the maturities purchased
would be 5 to 25 years. On that date, yields on bonds from 15 to 25
years' maturity declined sharply more than yields on bonds between
5 and 15 years, and yields on bonds just above 5 years declined much
more than yields on bonds just below 5 years. This suggests the presence
of investors with preferred-habitat demand for very safe bonds of
particular maturities, and the absence of sufficient arbitrage activity
from other investors to smooth out the impact of announced gilt
purchases across the yield curve.
(16.) Note that, as discussed above, in QE the liquidity effect of
changes in Treasury supply works to increase Treasury yields relative to
yields on less liquid assets, because the QE Treasury purchases were
financed by reserves and thus represented an increase in the supply of
liquidity. In general, however, a reduction in the supply of Treasuries
available to investors will not be associated with a change in reserves
and will thus reduce the supply of liquidity and reduce Treasury yields
relative to yields on less liquid assets such as corporate bonds.
(17.) We use monthly data on prices and bond yields from the CRSP
Monthly U.S. Treasury Database to empirically construct the derivative
of price with respect to yield (see the online data appendix). The
derivative is then used to compute the duration.
(18.) Federal Reserve Bank of New York, "FAQs: Purchases of
Longer-Term Treasury Securities"
(www.newyorkfed.org/markets/opolicy/operating_policy_101103.html).
Comments and Discussion
COMMENT BY SIMON GILCHRIST Overall this is an excellent paper.
Arvind Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen consider the economic
effect of large-scale asset purchases (LSAPs) by the Federal Reserve for
a rich variety of fixed-income assets. They do so by extending previous
research in this area to consider the announcement effect of LSAP
programs on changes in yields on a broad array of securities. The
organizing principle of the paper is that the effects of LSAP
announcements can be decomposed into the various channels emphasized in
the asset pricing literature, such as the duration, liquidity, safe
haven, and default risk channels, while also accounting for the effect
that such announcements may have on expectations of both inflation and
the course of monetary policy.
The paper is carefully written and the analyses are well executed.
The principal findings are persuasive, namely, that LSAP announcements
primarily work through a combination of forces that include monetary
announcement effects, increased inflation expectations, reductions in
overall credit risk, and an effect that works through the safe haven
channel (what the authors call the "safety channel")
emphasized in the authors' previous research. The paper also
includes a useful analysis of intraday movements in Treasury yields and
volumes during announcement days, providing readers with greater
confidence that the event-study methodology commonly employed in this
literature is sound.
The paper emphasizes that the QE1 announcements worked in part
because they included mortgage-backed securities and, by reducing the
risk premiums associated with prepayment risk, likely benefited the
financial intermediaries holding such assets and increased the overall
willingness to lend in the mortgage market. More generally, according to
the intermediary asset pricing theories emphasized by Tobias Adrian,
Emanuel Moench, and Hyun Song Shin (2010) and by Zhiguo He and
Krishnamurthy (2010), to the extent that LSAPs work through intermediary
balance sheets, they may influence the prices of a variety of assets in
which such intermediaries specialize. These include securities related
to mortgage lending activity and possibly fixed-income securities of the
nonfinancial sector.
This suggests that a potentially important channel through which
LSAPs influence economic activity is their effect on the aggregate
balance sheet of the financial intermediary sector. To the extent that
LSAPs improve financial intermediary balance sheets, one would expect
LSAP announcements to have a significant impact on CDS rates of
financial intermediaries (that is, spreads on credit default swaps on
securities issued by those intermediaries). In my comments below, I
therefore focus on this issue. Following the authors' overall
methodology, I consider the effect of LSAP announcements on the CDS
rates of large financial holding companies. Along the way, I propose a
few adjustments to the methodology used in this literature, stemming
from current research by myself and Egon Zakrajsek (Gilchrist and
Zakrajsek 2011) that was in part prompted by my opportunity to discuss
this paper. In particular, I examine the residual effect of changes in
asset prices on Treasury rates, after controlling for the relationship
prevailing on nonannouncement days. I argue that such a procedure
provides an alternative way of understanding the economic forces at work
through LSAPs. I also propose an instrumental variables procedure to
quantify the effect of LSAPs on asset prices. This procedure estimates
the effect of a movement in Treasury yields engineered by LSAP
announcements on the yields of alternative assets such as CDSs. To the
extent that some QE announcements have more of an impact on Treasury
yields than others, this methodology provides an overall metric for
assessing the extent to which movements in Treasury yields can influence
alternative asset classes via the announcement mechanism.
To analyze the effect of LSAP announcements on the CDS rates of
financial intermediaries, I concentrate on the rates of 5-year CDSs for
the top five U.S. financial holding companies: Bank of America,
Citigroup, Goldman Sachs, JP Morgan Chase, and Morgan Stanley. The data
are the same as those used in Gilchrist and Zakrajsek (2011) and come
from Markit. The sample covers the 925 trading days from January 2008
through October 2011.
Figure 1 plots the median 5-year CDS rate for the above five
companies and the median rate for a group of other large bank holding
companies. The figure shows that the perceived default risk of financial
intermediaries started to rise before the onset of the recession in late
2007. This rise coincides with the initial decline in housing prices
that occurred that year. CDS rates peaked during the financial turmoil
of late 2008 and subsided somewhat thereafter. Owing to the exposure of
large financial holding companies to sovereign risk in Europe, their
perceived default risk has now risen to levels comparable to those seen
during the depth of the financial crisis.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 2 provides a snapshot of movements in CDS rates in a 20-day
window around the LSAP announcement dates identified by the authors as
associated with QE1. The data are normalized to zero on the day before
the announcement date and thus plot deviations from this point for each
of the five dates, along with the average deviation that occurs over the
window. The top and bottom panels show the median change in 5-year CDS
rates for the five largest bank holding companies and for the other bank
holding companies, respectively. On average, there is no noticeable
effect on CDS rates for either group around announcement days.
Furthermore, with the exception of the December 16 announcement, CDS
rates tend to either rise or show no response. CDS rates for the top
five financial holding companies do fall substantially in the 2-day
window following the December 16 announcement. This date is unusual,
however, because that announcement also led to an increase in Treasury
yields rather than a decrease.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
I now consider these results more formally by using regression
analysis to study the effect of LSAP announcements on default risk for
the five largest financial holding companies. Following the analysis of
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen, I begin by considering the effect
of both the current and the 1-day-lagged LSAP announcements on the 1-day
change in the 5-year CDS rate of these five financial holding companies.
I aggregate LSAP announcements into the 5 days that correspond to QE1,
the first 2 days of QE2, and the more recent announcement that
constitutes QE3.
Table 1 shows the results of this regression analysis for each of
the top five financial holding companies. The table reports estimated
coefficient values for the current and lagged effects of the
announcement for QE1, QE2, and QE3, along with the standard errors of
the coefficients. I also report the adjusted [R.sup.2] of the regression
and the probability value associated with the F test that the sum of
contemporaneous and lagged announcement coefficients is equal to zero
for each LSAP program.
The results provide statistical confirmation of the findings
displayed in figure 2. There is no statistically significant effect of
the LSAP announcements on the 5-year CDS rates of these companies for
either QE1 or QE2. The effect of the QE1 announcements is negative but
quantitatively small: the median impact across the five companies is -3
basis points. The effect of the QE2 announcements is positive and not as
trivial in magnitude: the median impact is +11 basis points. Finally,
the effect of the QE3 announcement is positive and large: the median
impact is +52 basis points. This last finding appears consistent with
the authors' conjecture that other news events may have
contaminated the results for the QE3 announcement. It may also reflect
the market's reassessment of the economic outlook given the
announced size of the program.
To further investigate why the LSAP programs had either zero or a
positive effect on the CDS rates of these companies, I first consider
the effect of changes in Treasury rates on the 5-year CDS rate on
nonannouncement days. I regress the 1-day change in the 5-year CDS rate
of financial holding companies on the 1-day change in the 5-year
Treasury yield, using the full sample but dropping days on which LSAP
announcements occurred. Regressions are again estimated for each
financial holding company separately. The results, reported in table 2,
highlight a strong negative relationship between changes in Treasury
rates and changes in the CDS rates of the five companies over this
period. Although the coefficients vary across companies, the effect is
always statistically significant and economically large: a
1-percentage-point reduction in the 5-year Treasury rate implies an
increase in CDS rates of between about 40 and 140 basis points. These
results are highly robust to using either the 1-year or the 10-year
Treasury rate instead of the 5-year Treasury rate (results not shown).
This negative relationship between the CDS rates of financial
holding companies and the level of interest rates is consistent with the
notion that financial intermediaries experience a decline in net income
in the short run when interest rates fall. Such an effect is well
documented in recent work by William English, Skander Van den Heuvel,
and Zakrajsek (2011), who consider the effect of surprise movements in
interest rates on the net income and stock market values of financial
intermediaries during the pre-crisis period. According to their
analysis, a reduction in the overall level of Treasury rates reduces
these intermediaries' net income in the short run. It also leads to
an expansion of their assets over time, which eventually produces a
small positive long-run effect on their net income. The long-run
expansionary effect implies that a reduction in Treasury rates has a
positive effect on these companies' stock market value. Thus, in
normal times, one would expect that a reduction in Treasury rates
represents good news for financial firms and should lead to both an
increase in their stock market values and a reduction in their default
risk as measured by CDS spreads.
During a financial crisis, however, it is unlikely that the
expansion option has much value. Thus, one possible explanation for the
systematically negative relationship between financial sector CDS rates
and Treasury rates documented in table 2 is that the negative effect on
net income in the short run raised the default probability of financial
firms during the crisis period.
To the extent that the relationship between changes in Treasury
rates and changes in the CDS rates of financial holding companies is
causal (I return to this issue below), it is reasonable to consider
whether LSAP announcements have an effect on the default risk of the
same financial holding companies once one controls for the usual
relationship between CDS rates and Treasury rates that occurs throughout
this period. Accordingly, for each financial holding company, I
construct the estimated residual ([[epsilon].sub.t.cds] =
[DELTA][CDS.sub.5yr] - [[??].sub.0] - [[??].sub.1]
[DELTA][Treas.sub.5yr]) implied by the regression estimated in table 2.
I then regress this residual on a set of indicator variables for LSAP
announcement dates. For simplicity, I consider only the contemporaneous
effect of the 1-day announcement on the contemporaneous residual,
omitting the lagged effects reported in table 1. (I obtain similar
results, not shown, when allowing for lagged announcement effects.)
The results, reported in table 3, show that QE1 announcements have
a negative effect on the CDS residuals for all of the five large
financial holding companies except Citigroup. For the four other
companies, the announcements imply an average reduction in
[[epsilon].sub.t.cds] that varies between -9 and -34 basis points. This
effect is statistically significant at the 5 percent level or greater
for all four firms. For Citigroup, the QE1 announcement effect is
statistically indistinguishable from zero. The effect of QE2 is both
economically small and statistically insignificant for all financial
holding companies. As in the levels regressions reported in table 1, the
effect of the QE3 announcement is again positive, large, and
statistically significant for all the financial holding companies except
Morgan Stanley. Overall, these results suggest that the QE1
announcements had a strong negative impact on the default risk of large
financial holding companies, once one controls for the overall negative
relationship between CDS rates and the level of interest rates
prevailing during this period.
Regressing CDS rates or the CDS residual on LSAP announcement days
provides an indication of whether LSAP announcements influenced the
default risk of financial holding companies, but it does not directly
determine how much CDS rates respond to a given movement in Treasury
yields that is engineered by LSAP announcements. Understanding this
quantitative mechanism is particularly important given that different
programs affected Treasury rates differently. To consider the
quantitative relationship between financial intermediary default risk
and Treasury yields, I therefore turn to an instrumental variables
regression. I regress the contemporaneous residual [[epsilon].sub.t,cds]
on the contemporaneous change in the 5-year Treasury rate, using the QE
announcements as instruments. Here I include three sets of instruments:
the indicators for whether there was an LSAP announcement associated
with each of the three QE episodes. This procedure is equivalent to
regressing the change in the 5-year Treasury rate on QE1, QE2, and QE3
announcements, obtaining the fitted value, and then regressing the CDS
residual on this fitted value. The results of this equation, estimated
for each financial holding company using two-stage least squares, are
reported in table 4. Small-sample, robust standard errors are reported
along with the [R.sup.2] from the second-stage regression.
The results in table 4 imply that the predicted changes in the
5-year Treasury yield owing to LSAP announcements have a significant
effect on [[epsilon].sub.t.cds], the residual default risk of large
financial holding companies. In particular, calculating the median
effect across the five banks, I find that a 1-percentage-point decrease
in the 5-year Treasury rate due to an LSAP announcement implies an
83-basis-point reduction in the 5-year CDS rate residual. The estimated
effect varies from a low of 56 basis points for Bank of America to a
high of 181 basis points for Morgan Stanley. In all cases the
coefficient on the 5-year Treasury rate is statistically significant at
the 5 percent level or greater.
In summary, the regressions imply that the effect of LSAP
announcements on the default risk of the top five financial holding
companies is zero for QE1 announcements, slightly positive for QE2
announcements, and positive and statistically significant for the QE3
announcement. These estimates combine two effects: an effect operating
through the average relationship between CDS rates and Treasury rates
during the financial crisis, and the additional effect of the QE
announcement itself. Controlling for the former, I find a strong
positive relationship between changes in Treasury rates engineered by
LSAP announcements and the default risk of large financial holding
companies.
As discussed above, one interpretation of these results is that
during the financial crisis, a reduction in Treasury yields had negative
consequences for the net income of financial firms. The decline in net
income caused their CDS rates to rise. Following LSAP announcements,
this negative effect was offset by an additional positive effect
specific to the LSAP program. This may be due to the fact that LSAP
purchases include mortgage-backed securities and other assets that are
specific to financial sector balance sheets. It may also be due to the
fact that the LSAPs reduced overall default risk in the economy, which
is positively reflected in the CDS rates of financial intermediaries,
once one controls for the negative effect of changes in the level of
interest rates on financial sector default risk that was prevalent
during this period.
An alternative interpretation, however, is that the negative
relationship between the CDS rates of financial holding companies and
Treasury rates largely reflects a flight-to-quality mechanism. In this
view, both Treasury rates and CDS rates respond simultaneously to
economic events that trigger a flight to the safer asset: CDS rates rise
while Treasury rates fall. In this view the negative relationship is not
due to one acting on the other, but rather reflects broader asset
pricing forces at work during the financial crisis. Roughly speaking, on
nonannouncement days, shocks that trigger a flight to quality
predominate, and the negative relationship is observed. On announcement
days, however, these shocks are likely less relevant or nonexistent.
Under this interpretation, a regression of the CDS rates on LSAP
announcements provides the correct gauge of the effect of LSAP programs
on financial intermediary default risk, and one would therefore conclude
that LSAP announcements had no direct effect on reducing that risk.
Assessing the extent to which either of these views provides a coherent
explanation for the lack of direct evidence linking LSAP announcements
to changes in the default risk of financial intermediaries requires
further detailed investigation.
REFERENCES FOR THE GILCHRIST COMMENT
Adrian, Tobias, Emanuel Moench, and Hyun Song Shin. 2010.
"Financial Intermediation, Asset Prices, and Macroeconomic
Dynamics." Staff Reports no. 422. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
(January).
English, William, Skander Van den Heuvel, and Egon Zakrajsek. 2011.
"Interest Rate Risk and Bank Equity Valuations." Working
paper. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve.
Gilchrist, Simon, and Egon Zakrajsek. 2011. "The Effects of
Large Scale Asset Purchases on Financial Sector Risk." Working
paper. Boston University.
He, Zhiguo, and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 2010. "Intermediary
Asset Pricing." Working paper. Northwestern University.
Table 1. Regressions Estimating the Effect of LSAP Announcements on
5-Year CDS Rates of Large Financial Holding Companies (a)
Company
Bank of Goldman
Announcement America Citigroup Sachs
QE1, current effect -0.02 0.00 -0.02
(0.05) (0.08) (0.08)
QE1, 1-day-lagged effect -0.01 -0.02 -0.01
(0.05) (0.08) (0.08)
QE2, current effect 0.03 0.02 0.04
(0.07) (0.13) (0.13)
QE2, 1-day-lagged effect 0.07 0.12 0.09
(0.07) (0.13) (0.13)
QE3, current effect 0.42 0.32 0.30
(0.11) (0.18) (0.18)
QE3, 1-day-lagged effect 0.28 0.18 0.22
(0.11) (0.18) (0.18)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.02 0.00 0.00
observations = 925)
Probability that the sum
of the announcement
effects = 0
QE1 0.54 0.88 0.80
QE2 0.38 0.48 0.51
QE3 0.00 0.06 0.00
Company
JP
Morgan Morgan
Announcement Chase Stanley
QE1, current effect -0.02 -0.07
(0.03) (0.19)
QE1, 1-day-lagged effect -0.03 0.00
(0.03) (0.19)
QE2, current effect 0.03 0.00
(0.05) (0.30)
QE2, 1-day-lagged effect 0.07 0.08
(0.05) (0.30)
QE3, current effect 0.15 0.84
(0.07) (0.42)
QE3, 1-day-lagged effect 0.13 0.51
(0.07) (0.42)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.01 0.00
observations = 925)
Probability that the sum
of the announcement
effects = 0
QE1 0.20 0.66
QE2 0.18 0.84
QE3 0.00 0.16
Sources: Author's regressions.
(a.) Standard errors are in parentheses.
Table 2. Regressions Estimating the Effect of Changes in Treasury
Yields on CDS Rates of Large Financial Holding Companies,
Company
JP
Independent Bank of Goldman Morgan Morgan
variable America Citigroup Sachs Chase Stanley
Change in 5-year -0.41 -0.82 -0.74 -0.35 -1.41
Treasury yield (0.04) (0.08) (0.08) (0.03) (0.17)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.09 0.11 0.09 0.15 0.07
observations =
917)
Source: Author's regressions.
(a.) Standard errors are in parentheses.
Table 3. Regressions Estimating the Effect of LSAP Announcements
on CDS Residuals (a)
Company
Bank of Goldman
Announcement America Citigroup Sachs
QE 1, current effect -0.10 0.00 -0.16
(0.05) (0.08) (0.08)
QE2, current effect -0.01 0.02 -0.02
(0.07) (0.13) (0.12)
QE3, current effect 0.43 0.32 0.31
(0.10) (0.18) (0.17)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.09 0.00 0.06
observations = 925)
Company
JP
Morgan Morgan
Announcement Chase Stanley
QE 1, current effect -0.09 -0.34
(0.03) (0.18)
QE2, current effect 0.00 -0.11
(0.04) (0.29)
QE3, current effect 0.16 0.34
(0.06) (0.40)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.02 0.07
observations = 925)
Source: Author's regressions.
(a.) Standard errors are in parentheses.
Table 4. Instrumental Variables Regressions of CDS Residuals on
the Change in the Year Treasury Yield (a)
Company
Bank of Goldman
Independent variable America Citigroup Sachs
Change in 5-year 0.56 0.84 0.83
Treasury yield (0.25) (0.22) (0.24)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.09 0.11 0.09
observations = 925)
Company
JP
Morgan Morgan
Independent variable Chase Stanley
Change in 5-year 0.83 1.81
Treasury yield (0.24) (0.44)
[R.sup.2] (no. of 0.15 0.07
observations = 925)
Source: Author's regressions.
(a.) Standard errors are in parentheses.
COMMENT BY
THOMAS PHILIPPON There was a time when macroeconomic textbooks used
only one interest rate. The focus on one rate rested on the idea of
integrated financial markets and constant relative risks. In such a
world, monetary policy needed only to ensure price stability, not
financial stability. On the empirical side, much work was done to
demonstrate the impact of monetary policy on inflation and output (see,
for example, the classic contribution of Romer and Romer 2004).
The crisis that started in 2007 has shown that financial markets
can quickly become segmented and has forced us to rethink the role of
monetary policy. This excellent contribution by Arvind Krishnamurthy and
Annette Vissing-Jorgensen provides the evidence that is needed to test
the next generation of macrofinance models. Their paper leads us to
think about exactly which markets are segmented and why this matters for
policy.
The two main contributions of the paper are, first, the use of
intraday data to improve identification, and second, the study of a
large set of yields and spreads in an effort to understand the channels
through which unconventional monetary policy affects the economy. I
personally find the expression "quantitative easing" (QE)
confusing, but given its widespread use, I will stick to it and refer to
QE1 and QE2. I will focus on three issues:
--why one might not expect a duration risk channel to have been
operating in the circumstances of late 2008 and early 2009
--why the credit risk channel matters so much for firms and for
households, and
--why it is hard to identify liquidity and safety effects in the
case of agency bonds.
I will conclude with a brief discussion of policy implications.
THE DURATION RISK CHANNEL (OR LACK THEREOF) An interesting finding
of the paper is that a reduction in duration risk does not seem to play
an important role in the transmission mechanism of QE. One possible
interpretation is that the duration risk premium was small during the
financial crisis. This would be consistent with standard theory if
investors in 2008 were more worded about demand shocks (that is, debt
deflation) than about supply shocks (from oil or technology). To see
why, start from the standard bond pricing formula. The price
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] at time t of a
zero-coupon bond with maturity [tau] solves the following recursive
equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [m.sub.t+1] is the one-period pricing kernel (between t and t
+ 1), and the terminal condition [p.sup.(0)] = 1. For [tau] = 1 the
definition of the short-term rate becomes [e.sup.-r,t] =
[E.sub.t][[m.sub.t+1]]. For [tau] = 2 it is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The yield curve slopes upward if long-term bonds are riskier than
short-term bonds. This depends on the covariance between m and the
future short-term rate. Bad news corresponds to high values of m. If the
Federal Reserve increases the short-term rate in response to bad news,
then coy, [[m.sup.t+1]; [e.sup.-r,t+1] ] < 0, the price of the 2-year
bond is reduced, and the yield curve slopes upward (for more on this,
see Piazzesi and Schneider 2006).
Since the Federal Reserve increases the short-term rate in response
to inflation, the question boils down to the following: is inflation bad
news or good news? In normal times, one would expect inflation to be
mostly bad news (oil price shocks, negative productivity shocks, and the
like). But in the circumstances of 2008-09, one might conjecture that
investors were mostly worried about deflation triggered by a credit
crunch (Midrigan and Philippon 2010, Eggertsson and Krugman 2011). In
this case inflation would actually be good news, and long-term bonds
would provide a hedge against deflation risk.
It follows that if deflation risk dominates, one should not expect
a significant duration risk premium. This might explain why the authors
do not find that QE affected the economy by reducing duration risk.
CREDIT RISK The authors find remarkably strong effects of QE
announcements on credit risk. At the corporate level, credit spreads are
a key driver of corporate investment (Philippon 2009, Gilchrist and
Zakrajsek 2011). My figure 1, taken from Philippon (2009), illustrates
this point. It shows the investment rate (capital expenditure divided by
the capital stock) and a measure of Tobin's q constructed from bond
prices.
A simple back-of-the-envelope calculation will be useful here.
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen find that QE1 lowered the spread on
5-year CDSs of Baa-rated borrowers by 51 basis points (bp). From the
calibration in Philippon (2009), this implies an increase in the
investment rate of about 50 bp. Since I/K is 0.1, this means that
investment increased by about 5 percent thanks to QE1. Seen in this
light, QE1 appears to have been an unmitigated success.
Credit risk also matters for households. This recession was unique
in the sense that household balance sheets were severely affected,
whereas corporate balance sheets remained relatively strong. Consider
the yields on asset-backed securities (ABSs) collateralized by consumer
credit (for example, credit card ABSs). The declines in yield for these
securities were significant for QE1 (60 bp), but not for QE2 (3 bp). (1)
For QE1 the impacts fall in between that on Treasury and that on agency
yields. For QE2 the impact is essentially nil.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
AGENCY BONDS AND THE LIQUIDITY CHANNELS For QE1 the authors find
that 10-year agency yields fall by 200 bp, a large number. By
comparison, 10-year Treasury yields fall by about 100 bp, and the
signaling channel explains about 40 bp of the change in Treasury yields.
The authors compare agency yields with Treasury yields in order to
isolate a liquidity channel, and agency yields with prices on 2-year
federal funds futures to isolate a safety channel.
The issue is how much one can learn from these comparisons. Their
validity relies on agency bonds being as free of credit risk as Treasury
bonds. However, the view in the finance industry is not as clear-cut as
the authors'. For instance, Fidelity Investments describes agency
bonds to its investors as follows: "[Government-sponsored
enterprise] and agency bonds generally offer yields slightly higher than
U.S. Treasuries ... their credit risk does not have the unconditional
backing of the U.S. government." (2) If this is typical of views in
the industry, it does not seem that investors expect agency bonds to be
free of credit risk. A move by the Federal Reserve to buy large
quantities of agency bonds would therefore be expected to lower the
perceived credit risk. As a consequence, the authors probably
overestimate the size of the safety and liquidity channels. That said,
however, it seems unlikely that changes in perceived credit risk could
explain a relative move of 100 basis points. It seems clear that
liquidity issues were significant, but perhaps not quite as large as the
authors' calculations suggest.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS There should be no doubt that
this paper provides a fantastic set of stylized facts for future
research in macroeconomics and finance. It also provides an insightful
discussion of the various channels through which unconventional monetary
policy can affect the economy.
On the policy side, one naturally needs to acknowledge that not
enough is yet known to make clear recommendations. Suppose, for
instance, that QE works mainly by avoiding a disastrous debt deflation
spiral, with massive defaults by consumers and firms. In that case one
can almost think of QE as moving the economy away from a bad
equilibrium. One would certainly expect all risks and liquidity premiums
to be globally affected, even if the main channel is, say, credit risk.
The point here is that, in general equilibrium, there might not be clear
distinctions between the various channels that the authors consider.
This is also important when comparing QE1 and QE2. Figure 2 shows
the full daily series from January 2007 to September 2011 of the
consumer credit ABS yields discussed earlier. The periods surrounding
QE1 and QE2 are highlighted. It is clear that QE1 took place at a time
of extremely high and volatile yields, probably reflecting acute
concerns about consumer credit risk. If the main effect of QE is to save
the economy from a bad equilibrium, it seems that QE2 had no chance to
have worked as well as QE1, not because QE2 failed to target
mortgage-backed securities, but rather because the world does not need
to be saved every year.
REFERENCES FOR THE PHILIPPON COMMENT
Eggertsson, Gauti, and Paul Krugman. 2011. "Debt,
Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo
Approach." Working paper. Princeton University.
Gilchrist, Simon, and Egon Zakrajsek. Forthcoming. "Credit
Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations." American Economic Review.
Midrigan, Virgiliu, and Thomas Philippon. 2010. "Household
Leverage and the Recession." Working Paper no. 16965. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Philippon, Thomas. 2009. "The Bond Market's q."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124:1011-56.
Piazzesi, Monika, and Martin Schneider. 2006. "Equilibrium
Yield Curves." In NBER Macroeconomic Annual, edited by Daron
Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff, and Michael Woodford. MIT Press.
Romer, David, and Christina Romer. 2004. "A New Measure of
Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications." American Economic
Review 94, no. 4: 1055-84.
(1.) I thank the authors for providing the data. The ABS series is
from Barclays (obtained via Datastream) and has a duration of 3 to 4
years.
(2.) Fidelity.com, "Agency Bonds"
(www.fidelity.com/bonds/agency-bonds), under "Features &
Benefits."
GENERAL DISCUSSION Robert Shiller wondered how to interpret the
results of the event study given the newness and uniqueness of QE2. Most
event studies examine types of events that have occurred repeatedly over
decades, and they largely measure the reaction of intraday traders to an
event. These traders, he argued, act not on their own beliefs about the
ultimate meaning of the new information, but rather on their guess as to
how other investors will react. These guesses might be very unstable
when a new kind of event occurs. Shiller thought it would be interesting
to conduct a meta-analysis of event studies to see how often the results
of the first 10 or so events of each kind are borne out by later
evidence.
Having worked in investment banking for some 20 years, Douglas
Elliott found the paper's results quite plausible, but he agreed
with Shiller that it is difficult to interpret yield movements generated
primarily by intraday trading. Noting the authors' result that
B-rated credit default swap rates fell a cumulative 768 basis points in
the event windows considered for QE1, while Ba-rated corporate bond
credit default swap rates fell only 84 basis points, Elliott doubted
that the large difference could be fully attributed to the default risk
channel, as the authors suggested.
Finally, Elliott agreed with Thomas Philippon that markets do not
see agency bonds as having the same minimal credit risk as Treasuries.
However, he did not think the difference in risks was large enough to
change the paper's conclusions significantly. Annette
Vissing-Jorgensen responded that the agencies had been taken under
conservatorship by the federal government in September 2008. One might
argue that this rescue was not credible, but, unfortunately, she and
Krishnamurthy could not test how markets interpreted the intervention,
because credit default swaps on the agencies had ceased trading.
Edward Lazear thought that to understand the effects of QE1 and
QE2, it was important to take into account heterogeneity in the
preferences and valuations of individual market participants, rather
than assume that market participants all react in the same way. In
general, he proposed, if an asset is price elastic, then people value
that asset similarly, whereas if it is price inelastic, valuations are
more heterogeneous. Similarly, if the price effect of an announcement is
large, it is likely that people are interpreting that announcement
similarly, whereas if it is small, interpretations are likely to be
varied. He suspected that heterogeneity in valuations was greater for
QE1 because it happened sooner after the height of the financial crisis,
before markets had had much time to recover.
Robert Hall proposed that the authors consider the reaction of the
Treasury to QE1 and QE2 in assessing the effects of the Federal
Reserve's actions. The Treasury does not treat the choice of
maturity of the securities it issues as a policy variable, he argued. If
it did, it would copy the Federal Reserve and issue more short-term and
less long-term debt. Instead, the Treasury has lengthened the maturity
of its debt issuance in recent years. The Treasury is influenced, to
some extent, by an advisory committee of securities dealers, whose
interests may not coincide with those of the Fed.
Vissing-Jorgensen responded that the Treasury's offsetting
actions did not compromise the integrity of the event study because the
Treasury did not make announcements about plans to lengthen the maturity
of its debt on the same days as the Federal Reserve's announcements
related to QE2. For judging the longer-term net impact of QE2, however,
she agreed that the Treasury's reaction was important.
David Wessel found it interesting that the Treasury has been
lengthening the maturity of its debt at a time when the Federal Reserve
has been going in the opposite direction. As he understood it, the
maturity of Treasury debt issuances was also an issue during Operation
Twist in the 1960s, when the Federal Reserve supposedly was coordinating
with the Treasury. The current Treasury was emphatic that it was not
linking its actions to the Federal Reserve's, and Wessel wondered
whether it would continue to lengthen the maturity of its debt--which is
currently above average--if the Federal Reserve announced a new
Operation Twist. He also wondered whether it made any sense for the
Federal Reserve to contemplate a repeat of Operation Twist, which only
reduces duration risk, given the paper's result that duration risk
is unimportant.
Michael Woodford thought it incorrect to characterize the
paper's event-study effects as those of "quantitative
easing" per se. When the term was originally introduced during
discussions of the Bank of Japan's policies in the late 1990s and
early 2000s, it referred specifically to the idea of stimulating the
economy through growth in the base money supply by increasing the size
of the central bank's balance sheet, even in the absence of any
effect on short-term interest rates. In contrast, the paper found that
the effects of QE2 stemmed more from the change in relative supplies of
safe and risky assets than from growth in the monetary base. The
importance of the asset mix channel suggested to Woodford that the
Treasury should complement the Federal Reserve's actions by
introducing its own policies that shift the relative supply of safe and
risky assets.
Woodford also commented on the signaling channel: although the
paper suggested that the Federal Reserve's announcements of asset
purchases had signaling effects, he did not think that these
announcements were, in general, a good way to achieve such effects. The
effect of asset purchases on the future path of interest rates and of
inflation is highly context dependent, and so the signal sent by the
announcement is subject to uncertainty and varies with outside
conditions. Announcements about policy targets and commitments to future
policies, as opposed to announcements about asset purchases, have
clearer implications for the future path of interest rates and therefore
are likely to have more reliable signaling effects.
Randall Kroszner cautioned that the efficacy of the signaling
effect did not give central banks the opportunity to affect markets just
by making announcements about policy without following through on their
commitments. Such a plan could only work once before costing the central
bank all of its credibility.
Frederic Mishkin agreed with Woodford that quantitative easing by
the usual definition--that is, balance sheet expansion--was not the key
feature of the recent interventions by the Federal Reserve. He thought
that the signaling effects of the interventions were much more
important, and he noted that Chairman Bernanke had repeatedly said that
the Federal Reserve was engaging in credit easing, not quantitative
easing. Mishkin thought a key conclusion of the paper was that actions
in credit markets, and signaling in particular, had a much greater
impact than balance sheet expansion. He cited the related example of the
Bank of Japan's balance sheet expansions in the early to mid-2000s,
which, he argued, had not worked to lower Japanese interest rates. The
reason, in his view, was that the Bank of Japan had simultaneously
expressed its wish to raise interest rates toward normal levels, and
this signal overrode whatever effect the quantitative easing might have
had on yields.
Finally, Mishkin offered the caveat that for a signal to be
credible, the central bank issuing it must do something that is costly.
He saw the Federal Reserve's recent move as politically very
costly--for example, it had led to strident criticism from some of the
current candidates in the 2012 presidential race--which led him to
wonder whether the Federal Reserve could find a way of making its
signals credible without expanding its balance sheet.
Woodford agreed that the issue of whether balance sheet changes or
other Federal Reserve actions could actually make its signals more
credible was important, but it was not clear to him that its recent
actions had added credibility to a signal, or that they were even meant
to do so. In fact, before QE2, the Federal Open Market Committee had
considered an alternative option of providing more clarity about future
policy targets--in other words, more direct signaling. He thought the
committee had ultimately opted for asset purchases specifically because
they would have their own, real effects that did not require the Federal
Reserve to discuss their implications for future policy.
Ricardo Reis worried that the discussion about signaling overlooked
the fact that a single balance sheet change could be interpreted as a
signal of different, and sometimes contradictory, intentions. For
instance, when the Federal Reserve decides to accumulate long-term
bonds, in some circumstances that could be seen as trying to help lift
the economy out of a liquidity trap and raise inflation. Alternatively,
if observers think the Federal Reserve is worried about its accounting
capital (whether or not that is the case), then long-term bond
accumulation could be seen as a signal that it will pursue lower
inflation, since higher inflation would result in large capital losses
for the Fed. Because asset purchases can be interpreted in these
different ways, Reis argued, for signaling to be most effective, the
Federal Reserve should opt for explicit interest rate or price-level
targets.
Joseph Gagnon said he had considered doing an event study on QE2
and had concluded that it would be impossible; he therefore
congratulated the authors for conducting this study and managing to
obtain some sensible results. However, he was concerned that the study
omitted a number of dates on which yields seemed to have moved
substantially in response to related events. For example, yields fell
following a July 29 speech by St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank President
James Bullard and an early August speech by the former secretary of the
Federal Open Market Committee, Vincent Reinhart. Chairman
Bernanke's speech at Jackson Hole on August 26 also attracted a lot
of attention and could have affected yields. Beyond these dates, there
were many others on which journalists attributed yield movements to
changing views about the likelihood of QE2. Without attributing too much
importance to these claims, Gagnon argued, one must still accept that,
unlike with QE1, investors had a long time to speculate about the
likelihood of the Federal Reserve pursuing QE2 and react accordingly. In
the event, when QE2 was actually announced, it seemed that investors had
overreacted to the possibility of QE2, and over the next couple of weeks
their expectations unwound. Although the authors' results turned
out to be close to what Gagnon would have predicted given the size of
QE2 and estimates of the effects of previous similar events, the number
of dates with sizable yield moves that were excluded from the sample led
him to question the credibility of their findings.
David Wessel shared Gagnon's concern about the limited number
of dates included in the study, particularly because nowadays the press
frequently reports news about possible future actions of the Federal
Reserve. For example, Wessel's colleague at the Wall Street
Journal, Jon Hilsenrath, had recently written a story asserting that the
Federal Reserve would probably move to reinvest in mortgage markets.
Wessel seconded the point that investors saw Bernanke's Jackson
Hole speech as a significant signal.
Vissing-Jorgensen responded that she and Krishnamurthy had, in
fact, looked at intraday data for a number of other possible QE2-related
events, including Bernanke's Jackson Hole speech. Within minutes of
that speech, yields actually rose, whereas for some other speeches,
yields did not move much within that time frame. Moreover, she was not
sure how to interpret the reaction to the Jackson Hole speech, since it
essentially only reviewed a list of advantages and disadvantages of QE.
Gagnon was also hesitant to draw any conclusions about the impact
of QE2 on mortgage-backed securities from the one-day movement of their
yields on the two event days examined in the study. In his own research
he had found this market to be quirky and slow to react: during QE1, it
had been the only market in which actual asset purchases by the Federal
Reserve moved yields even when those purchases had been announced in
advance. In the markets for Treasuries and agency bonds, yields moved on
the days the Federal Reserve announced its asset purchase plans, but not
on the days when they were executed, presumably because those purchases
had already been fully incorporated into investors' expectations.
Finally, Gagnon questioned the conclusion that the most important
channel of QE2 was a pure safety effect. The authors had come to this
conclusion by arguing that high-grade corporate bonds are, in terms of
safety, the most similar to Treasuries, and during QE2 their yields fell
more than those of other, less safe assets. But if the term-length
channel was unimportant, Gagnon asked, why did Treasury bond yields fall
more than Treasury bill yields during QE2? After all, the only
difference between these assets is their term length.
Vissing-Jorgensen said she and Krishnamurthy did not disagree with
Gagnon that there was a term effect: intermediate- and long-term yields
did move much more than Treasury bill yields. Where she and
Krishnamurthy disagreed was in interpreting this effect as a duration
risk premium. Instead, she thought the term effect should be thought of
as revealing a preferred habitat demand for medium- to long-term assets.
The distinction was important, she felt, because if there is a pure
duration risk premium, buying any type of long-term assets will move all
long-term yields, whereas if the long-term preference is specific to
safe assets, then buying long-term Treasuries will disproportionately
move Treasury yields.
Randall Kroszner thought that to understand the kinds of policies
undertaken by the Federal Reserve, it was important to consider the
impact of the tail risk, since it could affect assets in ways not fully
understood and which could be nonlinear. Kroszner was also struck by the
fact that QE had led to an increase in inflation expectations, but a
reduction in interest rate volatility, since usually interest rate
volatility rises with inflation expectations. He thought this unusual
pattern suggested that the intervention did have the effect of reducing
tail risk.
Kroszner also responded to Gilchrist's comment about the
impact of the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) on financial markets.
He thought that the date of the bill's passage, October 3, 2008,
was not as significant as October 14, the date on which Treasury
Secretary Henry Paulson and President Bush announced that TARP would
feature an injection of capital into financial institutions and a
liquidity guarantee program. This announcement had a large impact on
market expectations.
William Brainard suggested that the authors look further into the
role of reserves in the liquidity channel. He thought it important to
distinguish between different types of reserves, for example between
excess reserves and reserves that correspond to increases in the
liabilities of institutions, to understand how they affect liquidity and
the price of liquidity.
Michael Kiley pointed out that the persistence of the effects of
the Federal Reserve's policy interventions mattered hugely in
determining its impacts. He cited a policy brief written by Jeffrey
Fuhrer and Giovanni Olivei at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, which
estimated that Federal Reserve asset purchases that led to a
100-basis-point reduction in 10-year Treasury yields for two years would
raise GDP growth by about 2.5 percentage points. He wondered how
confident one could be in the persistence of the effects measured over
the two-day horizons in the event study, and he thought it might be
worthwhile to investigate how that persistence might differ across the
signaling, safety, liquidity, and duration channels.
Ricardo Reis proposed organizing QE2's channels of influence
into two categories: channels that basically amount to monetary
policy--that is, that affect the size of the money supply or
expectations thereof--and channels that concern the relative supply of
assets. Signaling about the future path of interest rates would fall
into the monetary policy category. Changes in duration risk and default
risk would fall into the category of relative asset supply channels.
Reis suggested conducting an event study of announcements by the
Treasury over the last 20 years in which it said it would lengthen or
shorten the maturity of the debt it issues. Since these actions affect
only the relative supply of assets, such a study could help separate the
effects of relative supply changes from those of monetary expansion.
Jon Hilsenrath highlighted another challenge of event studies,
which is that on several of the dates examined, the Federal Reserve
announced multiple policy changes at the same time. In March 2009, for
example, the Federal Reserve announced both its intention to keep the
federal funds rate low for an extended period and its plans to extend
its asset purchases. It was unclear to what extent any market reaction
was to the low-interest-rate commitment and to what extent it was a
reaction to the asset purchase announcement. More recently, the Federal
Reserve had announced that it would commit to keeping rates low through
mid-2013, but also that it was prepared to take further action. Again,
was the market response to that announcement more a response to the
low-interest-rate commitment or to the possibility of a new policy
intervention?
Vissing-Jorgensen accepted Hilsenrath's point and clarified
that the signaling effects she and Krishnamurthy were trying to measure
could stem from the Federal Reserve's announcements about the
federal funds rate, in addition to any signaling effect of QE.
Arvind Krishnamurthy agreed with Mishkin that it was correct to
think of QE1 as credit easing, and not quantitative easing. His own
prior was that financial intermediaries' response to QE1 played a
significant role in causing yields to fall. He was therefore surprised
by Gilchrist's data showing that rates on credit default swaps
traded by financial institutions did not change significantly on QE1
event days, since that indicated that QE1 did not have a significant
impact on those institutions. This suggested to Krishnamurthy that the
channels of credit easing in QE1 required further investigation.
Certainly, he thought, if purchases of mortgage-backed securities are
affecting their yields, then the risk premium on those securities must
be changing. For that to be possible, markets must be segmented or
somewhat dysfunctional, which was what had led him to suspect that
financial intermediaries were important. Perhaps, however, the effects
of QE1 could be operating through some other channel, such as
Lazear's hypothesis about heterogeneity in valuations and low
elasticity of demand for assets.
Krishnamurthy agreed with Woodford that the signaling effects of
QE2 were more important than the asset purchases themselves.
Specifically, it was the market's interpretation of the Federal
Reserve's actions and its commitment to a future policy path that
mattered. Risk premiums are not changing. So, in considering a possible
Operation Twist, the evidence from QE2 indicated that changing the
maturity structure of debt, in itself, would not have an effect on broad
corporate rates, except through signaling.
Krishnamurthy gave an example of how communication alone was enough
to move interest rates, and that Treasury purchases were not necessary
to achieve results. When the Federal Reserve announced on August, 9,
2011, that it would keep rates low for an extended period, 3-year
Treasury rates fell 12 basis points, 5-year Treasury rates fell 20 basis
points, and 10-year Treasury rates fell 20 basis points--about the same
magnitude of effects he and Vissing-Jorgensen had found for QE2.
Finally, Krishnamurthy advised caution in interpreting changes in
Treasury yields: these changes are driven by liquidity and safety
effects that do not carry over to other asset classes. That meant that
even though QE2 had lowered Treasury rates by changing the supply of
Treasuries, those rate drops did not necessarily cause credit easing. To
determine whether credit easing had actually occurred, one must examine
changes in broader rates, such as mortgage rates and corporate bond
rates. He and Vissing-Jorgensen had done this and found that drops in
these broader rates seemed to correspond much more with the signaling
effects of QE2 than changes in Treasury rates caused by Treasury
purchases.
Table 1. Changes in Treasury, Agency, and Agency MBS Yields around
QE1 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Treasury yields
(constant maturity)
Date Event 30-year 10-year 5-year
Nov. 25, 2008 Initial announcement -24 -36 -23
Dec. 1, 2008 Bernanke speech -27 -25 -28
Dec. 16, 2008 FOMC statement -32 -33 -15
Jan. 28, 2009 FOMC statement 31 28 28
Mar. 18, 2009 FOMC statement -21 -41 -36
Sum of above five dates (c) -73 * -107 ** -74
Treasury yields
(constant maturity)
Date Event 3-year 1-year
Nov. 25, 2008 Initial announcement -15 -2
Dec. 1, 2008 Bernanke speech -15 -13
Dec. 16, 2008 FOMC statement -4 -5
Jan. 28, 2009 FOMC statement 19 4
Mar. 18, 2009 FOMC statement -24 -9
Sum of above five dates (c) -39 -25 **
Agency (Fannie Mae) yields
Date Event 30-year 10-year
Nov. 25, 2008 Initial announcement -57 -76
Dec. 1, 2008 Bernanke speech -52 -67
Dec. 16, 2008 FOMC statement -37 -39
Jan. 28, 2009 FOMC statement 33 28
Mar. 18, 2009 FOMC statement -31 -45
Sum of above five dates (c) -144 ** -200 ***
Agency (Fannie Mae) yields
Date Event 5-year 3-year
Nov. 25, 2008 Initial announcement -57 -42
Dec. 1, 2008 Bernanke speech -50 -33
Dec. 16, 2008 FOMC statement -26 -25
Jan. 28, 2009 FOMC statement 27 14
Mar. 18, 2009 FOMC statement -44 -35
Sum of above five dates (c) -150 *** -123 ***
Agency MBS
yields (b)
Date Event 30-year 15-year
Nov. 25, 2008 Initial announcement -72 -88
Dec. 1, 2008 Bernanke speech -14 12
Dec. 16, 2008 FOMC statement -26 -16
Jan. 28, 2009 FOMC statement 31 20
Mar. 18, 2009 FOMC statement -27 -16
Sum of above five dates (c) -107 * -88
Sources: FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; Bloomberg.
(a.) All changes are over 2 days, from the day before to the day
after the event. Asterisks denote statistical significance at the ***
I percent, ** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.
(b.) Averages across current-coupon Ginnie Mae, Fannie Mae, and
Freddie Mac MBSs.
(c.) May differ from the sum of the values reported for individual
dates because of rounding.
Table 2. Changes in Federal Funds Futures Yields around QE1 and QE2
Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Federal funds futures, contract maturity
Date (b) 3rd month 6th month 12th month 24th month
QE1 (c) -6 -5 -8 -16
Nov. 25, 2008 -6 -3 -7 -20
Dec. 1, 2008 -13 -15 -10 -11
Dec. 16, 2008 -1 -1 -1 19
Jan. 28, 2009 -2 -4 -8 -11
Mar. 18, 2009 -28 * -27 -33 ** -40
Sum (d)
QE2
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 0 0 -2 -3
Two-day change 0 0 -3 -8
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change 0 -1 -3 -8
Two-day change 0 -1 -3 -8
Sum (d)
One-day changes 0 *** -1 -4 *** -11 ***
Two-day changes 0 *** -1 -5 *** -16 ***
Source: Authors' calculations using Bloomberg data.
(a.) Asterisks denote statistical significance at the *** 1 percent,
** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.
(b.) See table 1 for descriptions of events on QE1 dates; QE2 dates
are those of FOMC statements regarding QE2.
(c.) All changes in yields for QE1 are 2-day changes, from the day
before to the day after the event.
(d.) Because our significance tests are based on comparing changes on
QE announcement days with changes on other days, changes on QE
announcement days of zero can be statistically significant. For the
3-month federal funds futures. changes on non-QE days were on average
slightly negative. Values may differ from the sum of the values
reported for individual dates because of rounding.
Table 3. Changes in Corporate Yields, Unadjusted and Adjusted by
Credit Default Swap Rates, around QE1 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Corporate yields
Long-term
Date (b) Aaa Aa A Baa Ba B
Nov. 25, 2008 -28 -18 -23 -19 -4 4
Dec. 1, 2008 -24 -24 -21 -17 -13 28
Dec. 16, 2008 -43 -37 -45 -39 1 -11
Jan. 28, 2009 34 17 17 14 -16 -25
Mar. 18, 2009 -16 -21 -21 -20 -28 -39
Sum (c) -77 -83 ** -93 ** -81 ** -60 ** -43
Credit default swap rates (d)
10-year maturity
Nov. 25, 2008 -1 10 -17 -13 -31 -798
Dec. 1, 2008 1 0 9 11 21 1
Dec. 16, 2008 -2 -8 -18 -17 -23 -308
Jan. 28, 2009 -3 -15 -6 -13 -26 -231
Mar. 18, 2009 -2 -1 0 -7 -18 -18
Sum (c) -7 *** -14 -32 -40 * -78 * -1,354 **
Adjusted corporate yield (c)
Long-term
Nov. 25, 2008 -27 -28 -6 -6 27 802
Dec. 1, 2008 -25 -24 -30 -28 -34 27
Dec. 16, 2008 -41 -29 -27 -22 24 297
Jan. 28, 2009 37 32 23 27 10 206
Mar. 18, 2009 -14 -20 -21 -13 -10 -21
Sum (c) -70 -69 -61 -41 18 1,311 **
Corporate yields
Intermediate-term
Date (b) Aaa Aa A Bun Ba B
Nov. 25, 2008 -17 -15 -18 -18 1 -47
Dec. 1, 2008 -21 -15 -18 -8 -5 6
Dec. 16, 2008 -19 -21 -24 -27 -28 -42
Jan. 28, 2009 12 8 7 3 -32 -25
Mar. 18, 2009 -43 -50 -39 -26 -18 -22
Sum (c) -88 ** -93 ** -92 ** -76 ** -82 *** -130 ***
Credit default swap rates (d)
5-year maturity
Nov. 25, 2008 -1 -6 -20 -18 -32 -573
Dec. 1, 2008 1 3 13 7 28 33
Dec. 16, 2008 -2 -15 -20 -21 -40 -172
Jan. 28, 2009 -3 -7 -9 -11 -27 -255
Mar. 18, 2009 -2 8 2 -8 -27 -25
Sum (c) -6 *** -17 -33 -51 ** -98 * -991 **
Adjusted corporate yield (c)
Intermediate-term
Nov. 25, 2008 -16 -9 2 0 33 526
Dec. 1, 2008 -22 -18 -31 -15 -33 -27
Dec. 16, 2008 -17 -6 -4 -6 12 130
Jan. 28, 2009 15 15 16 14 -5 230
Mar. 18, 2009 -41 -58 -41 -18 9 3
Sum (c) -82 * -76 -59 -25 16 861 **
Sources: Authors' calculations using data from Barclays, Credit
Market Analysis (CMA), the Mergent Fixed Investment Securities
Database (FISD), and the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine
(TRACE) of the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority.
(a.) All changes are over 2 days, from the day before to the day
after the event. Asterisks denote statistical significance at the ***
1 percent, ** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.
(b.) See table 1 for descriptions of the events on these dates.
(c.) May differ from the sun? of the values reported for individual
dates because of rounding.
(d.) Constructed using CMA data and ratings from Men: changes are
value-weighted averages using information on issue sizes from FISD
and prices from TRACE.
(e.) Change in the unadjusted corporate yield minus the change in the
corresponding CDS rate.
Table 4. Changes in Inflation Swap Rates, TIPS Yields, and
Implied Interest Rate Volatility around QE1 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Inflation swap rates
Date (b) 30-year 10-year 5-year 1-year
No v. 25, 2008 1 -6 -28 48
Dec. 1, 2008 15 27 12 -40
Dec.16, 2008 4 37 35 -17
Jan. 28, 2009 14 15 -6 5
Mar. 18, 2009 2 22 24 45
Sum (e) 35 ** 96 ** 38 41
TIPS real yield (constant
maturity) Implied
interest rate
Date (b) 20-year 10-year 5-year volatility (c)
No v. 25, 2008 -22 -43 5 1
Dec. 1, 2008 -38 -34 -52 (d) -7
Dec.16, 2008 -45 -57 -83 -20
Jan. 28, 2009 15 6 13 0
Mar. 18, 2009 -45 -59 -43 -11
Sum (e) -135 *** -187 *** -160 ** -38 ***
Sources: FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; Bloomberg.
(a.) All changes are over 2 days, from the day before to the day
after the event. Asterisks denote statistical significance at the
*** 1 percent, ** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.
(b.) See table 1 for descriptions of the events on these dates.
(c.) Volatility implied from swaptions as measured using the
Barclays implied volatility index.
(d.) The constant-maturity TIPS data from FRED indicate that the
5-year TIPS fell by 244 by around this event. We think this is a
data error. Using data from FRED on the 5-year and 10-year
underlying TIPS with remaining maturities near 5 years around QE1
(the 5-year TIPS maturing April 15, 2013, and the 10-year TIPS
maturing January 15, 2014), we found yield changes of -58 by and
-46 bp, respectively. The value reported in the table is the
average of these changes.
(e.) May differ from the sum of the values reported for individual
dates because of rounding.
Table 5. Changes in Treasury, Agency, and Agency MBS Yields around
QE2 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Treasury yields (constant maturity)
Date 30-year 10-year 5-year 3-year 1-year
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -1 -7 -8 -3 -1
Two-day change -8 -14 -10 -3 -1
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -11 -9 -5 0
Two-day change -13 -16 -10 -5 -1
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 16 4 -4 -2 0
Two-day change 11 -10 -11 -6 -1
Sum of Aug. 10 and
Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change -9 * -18 *** -17 *** -8 *** -1
Two-day change -21 *** -30 *** -20 *** -8 *** -2
Agency (Fannie Mae) yields
Date 30-year 10-year 5-year 3-year
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -2 -7 -8 -4
Two-day change -8 -13 -9 -7
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -11 -9 -6
Two-day change -14 -16 -10 -6
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 13 5 -5 -3
Two-day change 4 -10 -14 -8
Sum of Aug. 10 and
Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change -9 ** -17 *** -17 *** -10 ***
Two-day change -22 *** -29 *** -20 *** -13 ***
Agency MBS
yields (a)
Date 30-year 15-year
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -1 -4
Two-day change -4 -8
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -8
Two-day change -4 -5
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change -4 -4
Two-day change -10 -9
Sum of Aug. 10 and
Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change -9 * -12 ***
Two-day change -8 -13 **
Sources: FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; Bloomberg.
(a.) Dates are those of FOMC statements regarding QE2. Asterisks
denote statistical significance at the *** 1 percent, ** 5
percent, and * 10 percent level.
(b.) Averages across current-coupon Ginnie Mae, Fannie Mae, and
Freddie Mac MBSs.
(c.) May differ from the sum of the values reported for
individual dates because of rounding.
Table 6. Changes in Corporate Yields, Unadjusted and Adjusted
by Credit Default Swap Rates, around QE2 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Corporate yields
Long-term
Date Aaa Aa A
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 0 3 1
Two-day change -10 -5 -7
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -9 -9 -9
Two-day change -13 -12 -13
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 10 11 12
Two-day change 5 2 4
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 211
One-day change -9 -6 -8
Two-day change -23 *** -17 * -20 ***
Credit default swap rates (c)
10-year maturity
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -1 5 2
Two-day change 0 10 7
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change 2 -3 0
Two-day change 3 0 2
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change 2 2 2
Two-day change 3 10 10 **
Adjusted corporate yields
Long-term
Date Aaa Aa A
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 1 -2 -1
Two-day change -10 -15 -14
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -11 -6 -9
Two-day change -16 -12 -15
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change -11 -8 ** -10 *
Two-day change -26 *** -27 *** -30 ***
Basis points
Corporate yields
Long-term
Date Baa Ba B
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 1 -3 -9
Two-day change -7 -3 -5
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -7 2
Two-day change -11 -15 1
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 9 28 -1
Two-day change -1 22 -10
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 211
One-day change -7 -10 *** -7
Two-day change -18 ** -18 *** -4
Credit default swap rates (c)
10-year maturity
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 2 4 4
Two-day change 7 16 23
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change 0 2 4
Two-day change 2 9 8
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change 2 6 8
Two-day change 8 * 25 *** 31
Adjusted corporate yields
Long-term
Date Ban Ba B
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -1 -7 -13
Two-day change -14 -19 -28
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -9 -2
Two-day change -13 -24 -7
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change -9 -16 *** -15
Two-day change -26 *** -43 *** -35
Basis points
Corporate yields
Intermediate-term
Date Aaa Aa A
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -4 -2 -2
Two-day change -8 -5 -6
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -9 -9 -10
Two-day change -10 -8 -10
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change -2 -2 -1
Two-day change -10 -11 -13
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 211
One-day change -13 *** -11 ** -12 **
Two-day change -18 *** -13 ** -16 **
Credit default swap rates (c)
5-year maturity
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 1 5 3
Two-day change 1 15 7
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -1 -1 0
Two-day change 1 3 3
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change 0 4 3
Two-day change 2 * 18 * 10 **
Adjusted corporate yields
Intermediate-term
Date Aaa Aa A
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -5 -7 -5
Two-day change -9 -20 -13
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -8 -8 -10
Two-day change -I1 -11 -13
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change -13 *** -15 *** -15 ***
Two-day change -20 *** -31 *** -26 ***
Basis points
Corporate yields
Date Baa Ba B
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -3 0 6
Two-day change -6 9 23
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -10 -4 -3
Two-day change -11 -3 2
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change -1 -1 -5
Two-day change -14 -12 -18
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 211
One-day change -13 ** -4 3 **
Two-day change -17 *** 6 25
Credit default swap rates (c)
5-year maturity
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 4 5 9
Two-day change 9 20 26
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change 0 4 4
Two-day change 4 11 12
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change 4 9 13
Two-day change 13 *** 31 *** 38
Adjusted corporate yields
Intermediate-term
Date Baa Ba B
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -7 -5 -3
Two-day change -15 -11 -3
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -10 -8 -7
Two-day change -15 -14 -10
Sum of Aug. 10
and Sep. 21 (b)
One-day change -17 *** -13 *** -10
Two-day change -30 *** -25 *** -13
Sources: Authors' calculations using data from Barclays, Credit
Market Analysis (CMA), the Mergent Fixed Investment Securities
Database (FISD), and the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine
(TRACE) of the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority.
(a.) Dates are those of FOMC statements regarding QE2. Asterisks
denote statistical significance at the *** 1 percent, ** 5 percent,
and * 10 percent level.
(b.) May differ from the sum of the values reported for individual
dates because of rounding.
(c.) Constructed using CMA data and ratings from FISD; changes are
value-weighted averages using information on issue sizes from FISD
and prices from TRACE. Data for the November 3 event are
unavailable.
(d.) Change in the unadjusted corporate yield minus the change in the
corresponding CDS rate.
Table 7. Changes in Inflation Swap Rates, TIPS Yields, and Implied
Interest Rate Volatility around QE2 Event Dates (a)
Basis points
Inflation swaps
Date 30-year 10-year 5-year 1-year
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change 5 -1 -3 0
Two-day change -2 0 -3 -4
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change 6 6 6 -1
Two-day change 6 4 7 9
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 6 -3 2 1
Two-day change 1 -11 4 14
Sum of Aug. 10 and Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change 11 *** 5 3 -1
Two-day change 4 4 4 5
TIPS real yield
(constant maturity)
Date 20-year 10-year 5-year
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -7 -9 -8
Two-day change -5 -9 -5
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -13 -16 -14
Two-day change -18 -20 -18
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change 8 1 -6
Two-day change 12 -5 -14
Sum of Aug. 10 and Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change -20 *** -25 *** -22 ***
Two-day change -23 *** -29 *** -23 ***
Implied
interest rate
Date volatility (b)
Aug. 10, 2010
One-day change -2
Two-day change -3
Sep. 21, 2010
One-day change -1
Two-day change -2
Nov. 3, 2010
One-day change -2
Two-day change -3
Sum of Aug. 10 and Sep. 21 (c)
One-day change -3 ***
Two-day change -5 ***
Sources: FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; Bloomberg.
(a.) Dates are those of FOMC statements regarding QE2. Asterisks
denote statistical significance at the *** 1 percent, ** 5 percent,
and * 10 percent level.
(b.) Volatility implied from swaptions as measured using the Barclays
implied volatility index.
(c.) May differ from the sum of the values reported for individual
dates because of rounding.