Central bank independence and inflation.
Acemoglu, Daron ; Johnson, Simon ; Querubin, Pablo 等
One of the most studied types of policy reform is the introduction
of CBI. Theoretical work in the early 1980s argued that when
unanticipated changes in monetary policy can reduce the rate of
unemployment, the government will be unable to commit to low inflation,
and consequently inflation will be suboptimally high. (36) Kenneth
Rogoff's proposed solution to this problem, namely, to delegate monetary policy to a conservative central banker, established a
theoretical rationale for creating independent central banks. (37)
A large number of empirical studies over the past fifteen years
have examined the impact of CBI on inflation, economic growth, and a
variety of other variables. (38) Some early studies used a measure of de
jure CBI (we describe the construction of the various measures of CBI
below) and exploited cross-sectional variation within OECD countries.
(39) Alberto Alesina and Lawrence Summers report a near perfect negative
correlation between inflation and de jure CBI. (40)
This de jure index of CBI was further developed by Alex Cukierman,
Steven Webb, and Bilin Neyapti and extended to seventy-two independent
countries over the period 1950-89. (41) Using their index in pooled
time-series and cross-sectional regressions, that study and another by
Cukierman show that the negative correlation between de jure CBI and
inflation does not hold for a cross section of developing countries,
although they confirm the earlier negative correlation for developed
countries. (42) They also show that their index of de facto CBI (based
on the turnover of central bank governors) is negatively correlated with
inflation in developing countries, but not significantly correlated with
inflation in developed countries. (43)
Nevertheless, other studies find very different results. Using
updated data, Christopher Crowe and Ellen Meade do not find the same
correlations. (44) Marta Campillo and Jeffrey Miron argue, as does
Thomas Oatley, that the correlation between de jure CBI and inflation is
not robust to the inclusion of various covariates, such as measures of
openness or the government deficit. (45) Oatley, Gabriel Mangano, James
Forder, and King Banaian, Richard Burdekin, and Thomas Willett also
document that the results depend on the subjectively coded details of
CBI measures and are not generally robust. (46)
Philip Keefer and David Stasavage, (47) in work related to this
paper, argue that CBI will be effective only if it cannot be reversed,
and that this will happen only if there are political checks and
balances. In their empirical work they interact a measure of checks and
balances from Thorsten Beck and coauthors with CBI and find that
introducing CBI increases inflation unless checks and balances are
sufficiently strong. (48) Their work, like much of the rest of this
literature, exploits only cross-sectional variation. This strategy makes
omitted-variable bias potentially quite severe, since the countries that
have introduced CBI typically have different macroeconomic equilibria
than the rest.
In contrast to almost all of this literature, we focus on
within-country variation. Although not a panacea against
omitted-variable bias, fixed-effects panel data regressions provide more
convincing and more relevant conditional correlations, focusing on
whether inflation declines following the introduction of CBI. Using such
regressions, we will show that the introduction of CBI appears to be
associated with declines in inflation in countries with intermediate
political constraints. The benefits of CBI in more developed economies
appear to be more limited. (49)
The Motivating Theory
In this section we use a simple model to clarify our approach to
the political economy of reform, and we derive hypotheses concerning the
circumstances under which CBI should have a significant impact on
inflation. Our purpose is not to contribute to the theoretical
literature on the political economy of reform, but rather to highlight
why specific institutional reforms might have different effects
depending on the constraints facing politicians. For this purpose we
choose the simplest model possible to communicate the major forces
rather than strive for generality. Our model is a simplified version
of--and a slight variant on--Gene Grossman and Elhanan Helpman's
model of lobbying. (50) In this model a single organized lobby tries to
convince a politician to choose distortionary policies, but underlying
constraints and reform of specific institutions relating to this policy
place limits on the lobby's influence on the politician and on
policy choices. We first use this model to highlight the interactions
between policy reform and constraints on politicians. We then use a
simple extension of the model to show how successful policy reform in
one sphere can lead to a deterioration in other dimensions of policy
(the seesaw effect).
Our framework is chosen both for its simplicity and to emphasize
the commonalities between CBI and other types of policy reform; it does
not do justice to some aspects of the macroeconomic equilibrium leading
to high inflation. For example, the time-inconsistency problems
emphasized by Robert Barro and David Gordon and by Rogoff are absent.
(51) We provide some justification for why we think these
time-inconsistency problems are not first-order in the context of high
inflation in developing countries. The war-of-attrition aspect of the
conflict over policy reform, emphasized by Alesina and Allan Drazen, is
also absent in our setup. (52) Although one could develop the same
general insights using a war-of-attrition model, we prefer to use our
simpler model to highlight the basic political economy factors affecting
the effectiveness of policy reforms.
Model and Main Result
The economy consists of three actors: the citizenry, a politician,
and an organized interest group or lobby. There is a single policy
variable [pi] [greater than or equal to] 0. To make the transition to
the empirical work easier, this policy can be thought of as inflation
policy, although nothing in this section depends on this interpretation.
In addition to policy [pi], the variable [rho] [member of] {0,
[[rho].sub.R]}, with [[rho].sub.R] > 0, denotes whether or not there
has been policy reform ([rho] = 0 if there has not) and parameterizes
its intensity (see below). The large group of citizens has preferences
given by
(1) u([pi]) = -[eta][pi],
where [eta] is a strictly positive constant. These preferences
imply that the political bliss point of the citizens (that is, their
most preferred policy) is [pi] = 0 (since [pi] [greater than or equal
to] 0 by assumption), and any increase in [pi] away from zero reduces
citizens' welfare. Thus [pi] should be thought of throughout as a
distortionary policy. We could also make u directly depend on whether
there has been policy reform, that is, on [rho]. This has no effect on
the major results we would like to emphasize. In addition, u is made
linear in [pi] only to simplify the exposition.
The second actor, the politician, has a utility function given by
(2) v([pi],[rho],t)= [lambda]u([pi]) + (1 - [lambda])t - [rho][pi].
Here t [greater than or equal to] 0 denotes a transfer from the
lobby, which might consist of explicit bribes or campaign contributions.
The variable [lambda] [member of] [0, 1] captures how much weight the
politician's utility function places on the welfare of the
citizens. We think of [lambda] as a measure of general institutional
constraints on the politician (such as those measured, in our empirical
work, by constraints on the executive or control of corruption). (53)
When [lambda] = 1, the politician must act as a perfect agent of the
citizens, perhaps because any deviation from the policies preferred by
the citizens will be punished by quick replacement. In contrast, when
[lambda] is close to zero, there are few constraints on the
politician's behavior, perhaps because he or she is not accountable
to the citizens or because politicians are difficult to replace using
elections or other means. In this case the politician can pursue with
impunity policies that increase the transfers he or she receives.
The other important feature of the preferences in equation 2 is the
dependence on [rho][pi]. This captures the idea that policy reform makes
distortionary policies more costly for the politician. For example, the
politician may find it more difficult to provide credit to favored firms
or groups, or to enact inflationary policies aimed at winning support.
All else equal, this will discourage the use of distortionary policies
by the politician. Making the use of such policies more costly for the
politician is not the only way to model the effects of policy reform.
(54) An alternative would be to model policy reform as introducing a
hard constraint, for example imposing [pi] [less than or equal to]
[bar.[pi]] for some upper bound on policy [bar.[pi]]. This is not a
useful modeling strategy for understanding policy reform in societies
with weak institutions, however, because such hard constraints would
leave no room for pursuing distortionary policies after the reform,
whereas our focus is on whether reform will prevent politicians from
choosing distortionary policies.
The third actor is an organized lobby, which benefits from [pi].
Suppose that the utility of the lobby is given by
(3) w([pi],t) = [alpha][pi] - [beta]/2 [[pi].sup.2] - t,
where [alpha] and [beta] are strictly positive constants. The
quadratic form is again assumed for convenience, as is the specification
that these preferences do not directly depend on [rho]. These
assumptions also have no effect on the qualitative results. These
preferences immediately imply that the lobby's political bliss
point is
[[pi].sup.*] [equivalent to] [alpha]/[beta] > 0,
and so the lobby will try, using the only instrument available to
it for this purpose, the transfer t, to shift policy toward higher
levels of [pi] than preferred by the citizens. Examples of policies for
which citizens and lobbies have conflicting preferences include
industrial policy, tariffs, and agricultural subsidies. Inflation is
another potential example, since it is often used as a means of
generating funds (for example, through the inflation tax) for
redistribution to politically powerful groups, such as public sector
employees or companies receiving procurements or industrial subsidies,
at the expense of the citizens at large; inflation may also result from
the use of government credits for favored firms.
Although there are three actors in all, the citizens are passive,
and the main interactions are between the lobby and the politician. We
model this game as follows:
--The parameter [lambda] and the reform variable [rho] are given.
--The lobby makes an offer ([??], [??]) to the politician. As in
Grossman and Helpman's model, this implies that if the politician
accepts the transfer [??], he or she has to implement policy [??]. This
is presumably supported by a continuation game with repeated
interactions, but as in much of the literature, to simplify the analysis
we do not model these.
--The politician chooses policy [??]. If [??] = [??], the
politician also receives transfer [??]. Otherwise, the politician
receives t = 0.
This is a simple game, and we characterize its subgame perfect
equilibrium, as is usually done, by backward induction. In the last
stage of the game, the politician will choose whichever policy maximizes
his or her utility. Clearly, this will be either [??] = [??], so that
the politician receives the transfer [??], obtaining a utility
[lambda]u([??]) + (1 - [lambda])[??] - [rho][??], or [??] = 0, in which
case the politician receives zero transfers and obtains utility
[lambda]u(0).
Therefore we can summarize the best response of the politician as
follows: (55)
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
If the lobby wishes to have its own policy preferences implemented,
it must satisfy this incentive compatibility constraint (or respect the
fact that the politician will play a best response in the last stage).
This implies that when the lobby wishes to see implemented a policy
close to its own preferences, it must choose ([??], [??]) as a solution
to the following program:
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] subject to
equation 4.
Let the solution to this maximization problem give the lobby
utility [??]. Since ([??] = 0, [??] = 0) is a feasible strategy, we must
have [??] [greater than or equal to] 0. Moreover, it is also evident
that this problem will lead to a solution with [??] > 0, when [??]
> 0, and [??] > 0 will be chosen if and only if the solution to
expression 5 also involves [??] > 0.
We next characterize the solution to this problem. The incentive
compatibility constraint of the politician (equation 4) requires that if
[??] > 0, then
[??] = [[lambda][eta] + [rho]/1 - [lambda]] [??].
Substituting this into the objective function of the lobby
(equation 3), we have the problem faced by the lobby expressed as
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
whenever it wants to implement policy [??] > 0. Inspection of
this maximization problem establishes our first result:
Result 1. If [lambda] [greater than or equal to] [bar.[lambda]]
[equivalent to] [alpha]/([alpha] + [eta]), then the lobby prefers not to
have an influence on policy regardless of whether [rho] = 0 or [rho] =
[[rho].sub.R].
This result follows immediately, since when [lambda] [greater than
or equal to] [??], the utility-maximizing policy for the lobby is to
choose [??] = 0. Since [lambda] corresponds to a measure of the quality
of constraints on the politician, this result suggests that when these
constraints are sufficiently strong, the political system will generate
a policy choice that is not distortionary, regardless of whether there
has been reform or not. In terms of our empirical work below, this
result suggests that in societies that place significant constraints on
politicians, reform should have relatively small effects. This can be
understood by considering the example of inflation: although CBI might
limit inflation in well-governed societies, one would not expect a very
large decline in inflation to result from implementing CBI, since these
societies would not have chosen highly distortionary policies to start
with.
More generally, the solution to the lobby's maximization
problem in expression 6, and thus the (subgame perfect) equilibrium
level of policy, is given by
(7) [??] = max {1/[beta]([alpha] - [lambda][eta] + [rho]/1 -
[lambda]); 0}.
This equation shows that the sensitivity of equilibrium policy [??]
to [rho] (policy reform) will be lower, the lower is [lambda].
Intuitively, when there are no checks on the politician in power, the
politician will do whatever maximizes his or her utility, and this will
involve maximizing the transfers the politician receives. Consequently,
transfers can outweigh the costs that policy reform imposes on the
politician's use of distortionary policies. In terms of the
inflation example, the politician in power can exert pressure or use
other means to force the central bank to increase the money supply and
inflation, even if choosing high inflation might have become more
difficult or costly. (56) Interpreted differently, equation 7 suggests
that in societies with low [lambda], de jure reform may not translate
into de facto reform, because despite the greater cost of [pi] to the
politician, the political equilibrium will induce him or her to choose
policies not so different from those before the reform.
The following result now readily follows from equation 7:
Result 2. Suppose that [lambda] < [bar.[lambda]]. Then a reform
that increases [rho] from 0 to [[rho].sub.R] will reduce [??]. Moreover,
for [lambda] < [alpha] - [[rho].sub.R]/[eta] + [alpha], the greater
the decline following policy reform.
This result therefore implies that when constraints are not so
strong as to have avoided the use of distortionary policies in the first
place, policy reform might be effective. How effective it will be is a
function of the constraints on the politician. The greater is [lambda],
the more transfers are necessary for the politician to adopt the
distortionary policy after reform, and thus the lower will be the
equilibrium distortionary policies following reform.
Putting these two results together, we conclude:
Result 3. Policy reform will have the largest effect on
distortionary policies in societies with intermediate levels of
constraints on politicians, and it will have no or only limited effects
in societies with the strongest and the weakest constraints.
In the empirical work that follows, we investigate whether the
effects of CBI reform on inflation are consistent with the predictions
in Result 3.
The Seesaw Effect
We now use the model from the previous subsection to illustrate the
seesaw effect, whereby successful policy reform might lead to a
deterioration in other dimensions of policy. To do this, we augment the
previous model with another policy dimension, denoted by [theta]
[greater than or equal to] 0, and modify citizen preferences to
u([pi], [theta]) = -[eta][pi] - [eta]'[theta],
where [eta]' is also a strictly positive constant. This
implies that [theta] is another distortionary policy, and thus the
political bliss point of the citizens now corresponds to [pi] = [theta]
= 0. In this instance policy reform is narrowly targeted at [pi] and
thus only makes policy [pi] more costly for the politician. Some
reforms, which involve the introduction of greater accountability for
politicians, would not fit this pattern. CBI reform is a natural
candidate in this context, since it is primarily focused on monetary
policy and inflation.
The preferences of the lobby are modified to
w([pi], t) = [alpha][pi] + [alpha]'[theta] - [beta]/2[([pi] +
[theta]).sup.2] - t,
with again [alpha]' > 0. The preferences of the politician
are unchanged. We again look for a subgame perfect equilibrium.
The politician will choose [??] and [??] greater than zero if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
By reasoning identical to that in the previous subsection, the
optimal policy-transfer combination for the lobby is then given by the
solution to the following maximization problem:
(8) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
To simplify the discussion, let us impose the following assumption:
(9) [eta]' > [eta] and [alpha]' < [alpha]
This assumption implies that policy [theta] is more costly for the
citizens and less beneficial for the lobby than policy [pi]. In view of
this, the following result is immediate:
Result 4. Suppose expression 9 holds and there has been no policy
reform; that is, [rho] = 0. Then [??] = 0.
Intuitively, it is more economical for the lobby to receive policy
favors through [pi], which is both more beneficial for the lobby and
less costly for the citizens. Consequently, policy [theta] will never be
used in equilibrium (either [pi] > 0 and [theta] = 0, or [pi] =
[theta] = 0). Result 4 is a consequence of the simplifying assumptions
made in this subsection; in particular, it depends on the assumption
that the two policies, [pi] and [theta], are perfect substitutes.
Without this assumption, both policies might be used simultaneously
before policy reform. Nevertheless, our main result, Result 5 below,
would continue to apply even when these policies are not perfect
substitutes.
Next suppose that policy reform is enacted, so that [rho] =
[[rho.sub.R] > 0. Our main result in this subsection is that
following such policy reform, it may become beneficial to use the
alternative distortionary policy [theta]. The following result
summarizes the conditions under which this will happen:
Result 5. Suppose expression 9 holds and consider policy reform
increasing [rho] from 0 to [[rho].sub.R]. If
(10) [alpha] - [lambda][eta] + [rho]/1 - [lambda] <
[alpha]' - [lambda][eta]'/1 - [lambda],
and if
[lambda] < [??] [equivalent to] [alpha]'/[alpha]' +
[eta]',
then the equilibrium following policy reform involves [??] = 0 and
[??]' = 1/[beta]([alpha]' - [lambda][eta]'/1 -
[lambda]) > 0.
This result follows readily from the maximization problem in
expression 8, combined with expressions 9 and 10. Note that those two
expressions are consistent with each other provided that [[rho].sub.R]
is sufficiently large--meaning that reform is effective in making policy
[pi] costly. Result 4 implies that before policy reform, the equilibrium
involves [??] = 0. Moreover, given expressions 9 and 10, before policy
reform the equilibrium involves [??] > 0. Consequently, policy reform
in this case creates a typical seesaw pattern: the policy that is
regulated with the reform is used less intensively (moving from [??]
> 0 to [??]' = 0), but at the same time the political process
generates rents for the still-powerful lobby by using an alternative
policy instrument more intensively (moving from [??] = 0 to [??]'
> 0). This result highlights that when the political-economic
interactions leading to distortionary policies remain unchanged, the
imposition of a (specific or narrowly targeted) policy reform might
change only the form of redistribution toward politically powerful
groups, rather than eliminate policy distortions entirely.
An interesting implication of the specific configuration of
parameters given by expressions 9 and 10 should also be noted: in the
case discussed in Result 5, policy reform makes both citizens and the
lobby worse off. Instead of redistribution being accomplished through
the less costly instrument, it now uses the more costly instrument. This
is not a general result: policy reform might improve the allocation of
resources despite the presence of seesaw-like effects. Nevertheless,
this result points out the potential pitfalls of specific policy reforms
in societies where constraints on politicians are absent and
political-economic interactions lead to dysfunctional policy choices.
Discussion
The model we have developed here is in the spirit of standard
approaches to redistributive politics. In particular, as noted above, it
does not include any element of time inconsistency. We do not believe
that time-inconsistency issues play a major role in understanding
high-inflation or hyperinflationary episodes in less developed
economies. Most instances of high inflation are instead directly related
to the inability of governments to fund their (often politically
motivated) expenditure through taxation and borrowing. Such policies are
much more likely to emerge when there is severe distributional conflict
that the political system is unable to resolve, or when politicians have
only limited instruments to use to distribute patronage. The increasing
inflation in Zimbabwe, depicted in figure 1, is an example: President
Mugabe turned to hyperinflation when he had no further resources left to
redistribute as patronage to the military and to his key supporters.
Finally, although we have followed Grossman and Helpman in setting
up the model with lobbies making offers to politicians, (57) the model
could be reformulated to allow politicians to make offers to lobbies or
interest groups without affecting any of the results. This reformulation
might be more in line with the political experiences of countries in
sub-Saharan Africa or Latin America, where interest groups are as likely
to be captured by politicians as vice versa. (58) For instance, in his
seminal study of economic policy in Ghana, Tony Killick notes that
President Kwame Nkrumah succeeded in capturing the lobbies, making them
dependent on him instead of himself on them. (59) Argentina under Juan
Peron illustrates the same pattern. (60) First as minister of labor and
then as president in the 1940s, Peron played an active role in creating
the interest groups that then constituted his support base. Certain
groups in society will have (political) resources that politicians need,
and politicians will offer them redistribution in exchange for this
support. The model above could be reformulated along these lines, so
that policy reform would represent an increase in the cost to
politicians of supplying policy favors to interest groups, possibly
because they now have to use patronage to control those who run the
independent central bank as well. Our major results, in particular
Results 3 and 5, would continue to apply in this modified setup.
Data Sources and Construction
Throughout the paper we focus on the post-Bretton Woods period
1972-2005. From 1946 until 1971, when the United States suspended the
convertibility of dollars to gold, countries under the Bretton Woods
system agreed to coordinate monetary policy in order to fix their
currencies with respect to gold. This naturally limited the discretion
that both governments and central banks enjoyed in managing their
monetary policies. This implies that the post-Bretton Woods era is a
natural period for us to focus on in analyzing the relationship between
CBI and inflation.
Several approaches have been used to measure CBI, and some
controversy surrounds the advantages and disadvantages of each. (61) The
key question centers around whether one should use de jure measures,
which capture how much independence the central bank has under the law,
or de facto measures, which correspond to how much independence the
central bank has in practice. Another distinction that has been made is
between goal independence, in which the central bank is able to
determine its own objectives, and operational independence, in which it
does not set its own goals but is free to achieve any goal set for it
without interference.
Vittorio Grilli, Donato Masciandaro, and Guido Tabellini developed
an index based on work by Hans Aufricht that emphasizes political
independence, as measured by the procedures regarding the appointment of
the central bank board, the relationship between the bank and the
government in the formulation of monetary policy, and the formal
responsibilities of the bank. (62) They also measured economic
independence, which focuses on whether or not the central bank must
finance government debt. The current state of the art of measurement of
de jure CBI stems from Cukierman and his collaborators, (63) who
constructed an index of de jure CBI for seventy-two countries over the
period 1950-89, coding the variable for each of four ten-year periods,
with the index remaining constant within a given period. Their index is
a weighted average of sixteen different central bank characteristics.
(64)
Each of the above indices has various drawbacks. Mangano argues
that both the choice of criteria in the different indices and the
interpretation of laws involve significant subjectivity. (65) It appears
that these indices do not capture de jure CBI only but are, at least in
part, informative about how monetary policy is being conducted in
practice. Our focus on policy reform makes it important that we focus on
de jure CBI. A related problem is that most existing work reports values
for CBI indices computed at a specific point in time. However,
within-country variation is essential for our empirical strategy based
on panel fixed-effects regressions. (66)
To overcome these problems, we measure de jure CBI by a dummy
variable that takes a value of one in every year after a major reform to
the constitution or the central bank law leading to increased
independence, and zero elsewhere. The advantage of this measure is that
it does not incorporate information on the de facto conduct of monetary
policy. A drawback is that this measure assumes that CBI increases by
the same magnitude in every country following a reform, which we know is
not true, because reforms in different countries have introduced
different levels of independence. Nevertheless, it captures in a simple
way the effect of central bank reform and changes in de jure CBI.
Our main sample consists of fifty-two countries for which
information on changes in central bank legislation was reported by Luis
Jacome and Francisco Vasquez, and by Simone Polillo and Mauro Guillen.
(67) We exclude all former socialist countries, because data for these
countries before CBI are limited, and many enacted CBI at the same time
as many other reforms associated with the transition from planned to
market economies. We also exclude Africa, since central bank reforms in
these countries are hard to identify and interpret, and in most cases
their reforms have fallen short of creating truly independent central
banks. (68)
Our sample does, however, include almost every OECD and Latin
American country and a sample of thirteen Asian countries. (69) To
construct our CBI dummy for Latin American countries, we used the dates
of major central bank reforms provided by Jacome and Vasquez. (70) For
the remaining countries the CBI dummy takes a value equal to one
starting in the year in which the Cukierman index constructed by Polillo
and Guillen increases. (71) Moreover, for every country we used
information from Marco Arnone and coauthors, (72) who report the years
of major central bank reforms, to verify that a major reform did take
place in the year in which the index constructed by Polillo and Guillen
increases. Whenever there was disagreement between the two sources, we
consulted additional sources (such as the central bank's website)
to identify the year in which the most substantial reform toward CBI (if
any) took place. Similarly, for countries for which the index
constructed by Polillo and Guillen did not increase between 1989 and
2000, we used Arnone and coauthors and other sources to explore whether
a central bank reform took place after 2000. A list of the countries
included in our sample and the details of the coding, including the laws
that have amended central bank charters, as well as additional sources
used, can be found in the online appendix. Most central bank reforms in
these countries took place during the 1990s.
We also examined the impact of CBI on the forty of these fifty-two
countries whose degree of CBI changed over our sample period. Focusing
on this sample enables us to obtain identification from differences in
the timing of CBI; the countries in this sample might also be more
homogeneous, since all have undergone the same policy reform.
Although we believe our CBI dummy provides a transparent way of
investigating the relationship between CBI and inflation, we also study
the robustness of our results by using the Cukierman index. Since these
data are not in the form of an annual time series, and earlier data
exhibit almost no variation, we take the value of the index in 1989 and
assume that this value holds for all pre-CBI periods. We then use the
2003 value from Crowe and Meade for all post-CBI periods. (73)
Our main measure of political institutions is constraints on the
executive, from the Polity IV dataset, which codes the extent of
constitutional limits on the exercise of arbitrary power by the
executive. (74) The Polity dataset reports a qualitative score between 1
and 7 for every independent country. We computed the average of the
constraints on the executive variable for the period 1972-2004 and then
classified each country in our sample according to whether it has weak,
medium, or strong constraints on the executive. (75) Countries within
one standard deviation of the sample mean for the constraints measure
were assigned to the medium-constraints category, and the rest were
assigned to either the strong-constraints or the weak-constraints group.
Figure 3 shows the distribution of average constraints on the executive
for our sample as well as the cutoffs for the different categories.
Appendix table A1 shows the category in which each country was
classified. The weak- and medium-constraints countries are found mainly
in Asia and Latin America; most OECD countries are in the
strong-constraints category.
To verify that our results are not driven by the specific cutoffs
used in creating the weak-, medium-, and strong-constraints groups, we
also look at the interaction of a quadratic function of the average
constraints on the executive with the CBI dummy. We show that the
results obtained using this approach are similar to those estimated
using the dummies for weak, medium, and strong constraints.
In addition, we check the robustness of our results using different
measures of institutions. In particular, we use the rule-of-law and the
control-of-corruption indices constructed by Daniel Kaufmann, Aart
Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi for the period 1996-2005. (76) These
indices are reported on a scale from -2.5 to 2.5 and are based on
subjective perceptions reported by experts from the public sector, the
private sector, and nongovernmental organizations. (77) The
classification of countries on these variables, following the same
one-standard-deviation rule described above, is reported in appendix
table A1. Broadly speaking, the classifications under the three
institutional variables are similar. The most notable exception is
Singapore, which is classified as having weak constraints on the
executive, but strong institutions in terms of both the rule-of-law and
control-of-corruption indices.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Our main dependent variable, inflation, was obtained from the
International Financial Statistics (IFS) of the International Monetary
Fund and is defined as the annual percentage change in the consumer
price index. (78) Figures B1, B2, and B3 in appendix B plot the
inflation data over time as well as the date of CBI for all the
countries in our sample. Figure B1 focuses on the eight countries
categorized as having weak constraints on the executive, figure B2 on
the twenty-five medium-constraints countries, and figure B3 on the
nineteen countries with strong constraints. To isolate changes in
inflation in individual countries, in all three figures the average of
normalized world inflation is subtracted from each country's
normalized inflation rate; thus a value of zero indicates that the
country's inflation rate is at the world average. (79)
Figure B1 presents a mixed picture with respect to the association
between inflation and CBI in countries with the weakest constraints. In
China and Guyana a decline in inflation is seen following the
introduction of CBI, whereas in Guatemala and Nepal inflation drifts
upward over time, and the introduction of CBI in 2002 in both countries
appears to have had no effect on this process. Figure B2 shows several
cases of significant disinflation concurrent with the introduction of
CBI. This happens in Colombia and Argentina, as discussed in the
introduction, but it also seems to occur in Turkey and Uruguay. In a
number of countries, such as Bolivia, Chile, and Greece, inflation
starts declining before CBI. Finally, figure B3 shows no case where CBI
is followed by a large fall in inflation.
Comparison of figures B1 and B2 shows that in contrast to our
theoretical model, inflation is generally higher in medium-constraints
countries than in weak-constraints countries. We do not have an
explanation for this pattern. It may reflect the fact that in countries
with weak constraints, politicians have access to other instruments for
achieving their political objectives and do not need to rely primarily
on monetary policy, which may be a relatively blunt instrument for
achieving clientelistic objectives or self-enrichment.
Our data on government expenditure as a percentage of GDP were
obtained from the International Monetary Fund's Worm Economic
Outlook. (80) In our robustness checks we also use additional
macroeconomic variables to control for other time-varying determinants
of inflation. We use the logarithm of GDP per capita (in constant
prices, using the chain series from the Penn World Tables 6.2). Also, to
control for the extent to which fixed exchange rate regimes might have
provided an anchor for inflation and limited the discretionary use of
monetary policy, we use an index of exchange rate flexibility
constructed by Carmen Reinhart and Rogoff. (81) This index takes values
between one and six, with higher values corresponding to more-flexible
exchange rate regimes. The index is reported on an annual basis and
covers the period 1972-2001.
Central Bank Independence and Inflation
In this section we present our main empirical results concerning
the relationship between CBI and inflation. Throughout, the
left-hand-side variable is defined as
(11) [y.sub.c,t] = [inflation.sub.c,t]/1 + [inflation.sub.c,t],
where [inflation.sub.c,t] denotes the inflation rate (for example,
0.1 for 10 percent inflation) for country c in year t. This
transformation is useful, since otherwise hyperinflationary episodes
entirely dominate the analysis. An alternative would have been to use
the logarithm of inflation, but this is not possible when there are
cases of zero inflation. Moreover, using logarithms would shift the
outlier problem to cases in which inflation is very low. With a slight
abuse of terminology, we refer to [y.sub.c,t] as inflation rather than
as normalized inflation.
It should be noted throughout that changes in CBI are neither
randomly assigned nor exogenous, so the empirical work we present here
is intended to uncover robust correlations between central banking
reform and contemporaneous or subsequent declines in inflation. As noted
in the introduction, CBI is often adopted as part of a package of
anti-inflation policies, and this can be seen in figures B1 and B2 in
appendix B, which reveal a number of instances in which inflation starts
declining a few years before CBI. This is indicative of a pattern in
which other anti-inflation measures are adopted simultaneously with or
just before the introduction of CBI.
The Main Effect of Central Bank Independence on Inflation
Our general estimating equation for the results reported in table 1
is
(12) [y.sub.c,t] = [k.summation over (j=1)] [[zeta].sub.j]
[y.sub.c,t-j] + [[phi].sub.0] [x.sub.c,t] + [k.summation over (j=1)]
[[phi].sub.j] [x.sub.c,t-j] + [[delta].sub.c] + [[omega].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.c,t].
Here the first summation includes lags of inflation and helps us
control for potential serial correlation in this variable. The variable
of interest is the dummy for CBI, described in the previous section and
denoted by [x.sub.c,t]. Since CBI may have delayed effects, we sometimes
also control for lags of CBI, as shown by the second summation. For
simplicity, the same number of lags is used for inflation as for CBI. In
addition, all regressions include [[delta].sub.c], which stands for a
full set of country dummies, and [[omega].sub.t], which is a full set of
year dummies. The error term [[epsilon].sub.c,t] captures all omitted
influences. Since CBI is not randomly assigned, this disturbance term
may be correlated with some of the right-hand-side variables. It is
therefore important to interpret the estimates we report as conditional
correlations rather than causal effects, [[epsilon].sub.c,t] may also
have residual serial correlation, and to control for this we report
throughout standard errors that are fully robust for arbitrary serial
correlation at the country level (that is, clustered at the country
level). (82)
Columns 1-1 through 1-3 of table 1 examine the whole sample of
countries. Columns 1-4 through 1-6 repeat the same regressions but focus
on the sample of countries that changed their CBI during the sample
period, and thus rely only on differences in the timing of CBI to
identify its effect on inflation. Column 1-1 includes only the
contemporaneous CBI dummy, [x.sub.c,t]. The estimate of [[phi].sub.0] is
-0.036, with a (robust) standard error of 0.034. Thus, in this first
specification, the effect of CBI on inflation is negative, but this
effect is not statistically significant at the 10 percent level, and the
coefficient is rather small. This estimate implies that CBI is
associated with a reduction in the annual inflation rate by 9 percentage
points at the sample mean inflation rate of 58 percent. (83)
The specification in column 1-1 does not control for persistence in
inflation, however. Since inflation is a highly serially correlated
variable, doing so can have major effects on the estimates. Column 1-2
therefore includes five lags of inflation but still includes only the
contemporaneous CBI dummy. When these lags are included, one can
distinguish between the short- and the long-run effects of CBI. The
short-run effect is still given by
[[phi].sub.0], whereas the long-run effect is [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Column 1-2 reports both of these effects, together with the p-value
for the statistical significance of the long-run effect. It shows that
neither the short-run nor the long-run effect is significant. For
example, the long-run effect is about double the impact of CBI on
inflation suggested in column 1-1, but it falls short of conventional
levels of significance (p = 0.13). The lags of inflation themselves are
highly significant. The results in the first two columns therefore show
that despite the preponderance of theory and some evidence that CBI is
important in practice, in this broad sample of countries the effect of
CBI on inflation is modest and not statistically significant.
Column 1-3 also includes the five lags of the CBI dummy. In this
case, however, the long-run effect is given by [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. In this specification the short-run effect
is -0.031 (suggesting that CBI decreases inflation by 8 percentage
points) and is again insignificant. The long-run effect is estimated to
be -0.087 (suggesting that CBI decreases inflation by 22 percentage
points) but is also insignificant.
Column 1-4 reestimates the basic model reported in column 1-1 using
the smaller subsample of countries that underwent a change in CBI. The
estimated effect is now -0.063, with a standard error of 0.030, and is
thus now significant, as are the results in columns 1-5 and 1-6, which
repeat the regressions in columns 1-2 and 1-3, respectively, using the
smaller subsample. Both the short- and the long-run effects are
negative, and the estimated effects are larger. The basic finding of
table 1, then, is of some weak evidence that CBI does reduce inflation,
especially when one looks only at the sample of countries that changed
their CBI over the period.
Central Bank Independence, Political Constraints, and Inflation
Why does CBI not have a quantitatively more significant effect on
inflation? The answer we will propose is based on our motivating theory,
namely, that CBI will have a strong effect on inflation only in
societies with intermediate levels of constraints on politicians. Let
[S.sub.c], [M.sub.c], and [W.sub.c] be dummy variables denoting a
strong-, a medium-, or a weak-constraints country, respectively.
Including interactions with these dummies, the general estimating
equation becomes
(13) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
This equation implies that [[phi].sup.S.sub.0] measures the
short-run effect of CBI on countries with strong constraints on the
executive, whereas with the full set of lags included,
[long-run effect.sup.S] = [k.summation over
(j=0)][[phi].sup.S.sub.j]/1 - [k.summation over (j=1)][[zeta].sub.j]
corresponds to the long-run effect for these countries. The
short-run and the long-run effects for medium- and weak-constraints
countries are defined analogously. Equation 13 also includes a vector of
country- and time-varying covariates [Z.sub.c,t] (with a vector of
coefficients denoted by v). These covariates will be included in the
robustness checks reported in table 7.
Table 2 reports the results of estimating equation 13 on our base
sample, with constraints measured in terms of the average constraints on
the executive from the Polity IV data as described above. The first
three columns use data for the whole sample. Column 2-1 is again the
most parsimonious specification, omitting any lags of inflation or of
the CBI dummy. The estimates suggest that CBI has no effect on inflation
in weak- and strong-constraints countries but has a marginally
significant effect of -0.071 (standard error of 0.044) in the sample of
medium-constraints countries. This effect is twice the size of the
estimate in column 1-1, showing that almost all of the effect in table 1
is due to the impact of CBI on inflation in countries with intermediate
constraints. Moreover, the p-values at the bottom of the table indicate
that we can reject the null hypothesis that the impact of CBI in the
medium-constraints group is equal to that in the weak- or the
strong-constraints groups.
Column 2-2 shows similar results when the lags of inflation are
included, and again the effect of CBI on inflation is statistically
significant at about the 7 percent level. However, in this case, even
though the long-run effect in the medium-constraints group is almost
twice as large as for the weak-constraints group, we can no longer
reject the null hypothesis that they are equal. (But we continue to
reject the null hypothesis that the effect is the same in strong- as in
medium-constraints countries.)
Column 2-3 reports the specification that includes the lags of CBI
as well as the lags of inflation. Now the long-run effect in the sample
of countries with intermediate constraints is larger, at -0.125, and is
significant at about the 6 percent level. The effects in countries with
strong or weak constraints continue to be insignificant. In this
specification we can reject at the 10 percent level the null hypothesis
that the effect of CBI is the same in the medium- and weak-constraints
countries (and we continue to reject, at the 1 percent level, the null
hypothesis that it is the same in the strong- and medium-constraints
countries).
Columns 2-4 through 2-6 estimate the same models for the sample of
countries that experienced a change in CBI. The effects of CBI in the
medium-constraints countries are now quantitatively larger and more
significant. The short-run effect in column 2-4, -0.097, is significant
and implies that CBI is associated with a decline in inflation of 24
percentage points for this group of countries, (84) We continue to
reject the null hypotheses that this effect is the same as that for
strong- or weak-constraints countries. In columns 2-5 and 2-6, once we
include lags of the CBI dummy and inflation, the short-run effect
becomes smaller and less significant, but the long-run effects are
statistically and economically significant. For example, the effect in
column 2-6, -0.196, implies that CBI reduces inflation by 49 percentage
points. As in the first three columns, there is no evidence that CBI
influences inflation in countries with strong constraints. However, the
results reported in these columns show some evidence that CBI might have
a negative long-run effect on inflation in weak-constraints countries,
although this effect is smaller than that for medium-constraints
countries.
We conclude from this evidence that the conditional correlations
between the introduction of CBI and changes in inflation are broadly
consistent with the ideas suggested in the theoretical discussion above.
In particular, CBI appears to be followed by a decline in inflation in
countries with intermediate constraints on politicians, but there is no
evidence of a negative effect of CBI on inflation in strong-constraints
countries. In weak-constraints countries there is typically no effect of
CBI on inflation, although some specifications show negative but
(usually) less significant effects. Although we can reject the null
hypothesis that the effect of CBI on inflation differs between strong-
and medium-constraints countries, we can reject the same hypothesis in
only some of the specifications for medium- and weak-constraints
countries.
Robustness
Tables 3 through 7 investigate the robustness of the results in
tables 1 and 2. Table 3 replicates columns 2-1, 2-3, 2-4, and 2-6 of
table 2 but replaces the Polity IV executive constraints measure with
the rule-of-law and control-of-corruption indices constructed by
Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi. (85) The results in columns 3-1 through
3-4, based on the full sample, are similar to those in columns 1-1
through 1-3 of table 1 and do not show statistically significant effects
of CBI. The results in columns 3-5 through 3-8, which focus on the
sample of countries that experienced a change in CBI, are more
encouraging. They are broadly similar to those in columns 2-4 through
2-6 of table 2. Columns 3-5 and 3-7 show evidence of a statistically
significant short-run effect of CBI on inflation only in countries with
institutions of medium strength, whether using the rule-of-law index
(column 3-5) or the control-of-corruption index (column 3-7). These
coefficients are similar in magnitude to those reported in column 2-4 of
table 2. Columns 3-6 and 3-8, on the other hand, show evidence of a
negative and statistically significant long-run effect of CBI on
inflation in both the medium- and the weak-institutions countries. These
results again show that the effects in the medium- and
strong-institutions countries are statistically different, but we cannot
reject the null hypothesis that the effects in the weak- and the
medium-institutions countries are equal. Overall, the results using the
alternative measures of institutions are generally consistent with those
reported in table 2, although with these measures the differences
between the weak and the medium categories are less pronounced.
An econometric problem in the estimation of equation 13 is that it
includes both fixed effects and lagged dependent variables. In the
presence of the latter, the key regressor [x.sub.c,t] (and its lags)
will be mechanically correlated with [[epsilon].sub.c,s] for s < t,
so that the standard fixed-effects estimator, used in table 2, is
inconsistent. (86) However, it can be shown that the fixed-effects
estimator becomes consistent as the number of time periods in the sample
increases (that is, as T [right arrow] [infinity]). Even though our
sample covers a relatively large number of time periods, this source of
inconsistency might still be important depending on how close to a unit
root the inflation dynamics are. The most common way of ensuring
consistency in this case is to use the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator developed by Manuel Arellano and Stephen Bond. (87) This
involves differencing equation 13 to eliminate fixed effects, so that we
have
(14) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and then using lags of [y.sub.c,t] and [x.sub.c,t] to instrument
for the differenced terms (here [DELTA][y.sub.c,t] = [y.sub.c,t] -
[y.sub.c,t-1] and so on). These lags will be valid instruments to solve
the endogeneity problem resulting from the mechanical correlation
between [x.sub.c,t] and the error term if there is no additional serial
correlation in [[epsilon].sub.c,t] (so that there is no second-order
serial correlation in [DELTA][[epsilon].sub.c,t]), which can be tested.
Table 4 reports the results of estimating equation 14 on the same
samples and specifications as in columns 2-2, 2-3, 2-5, and 2-6 of table
2. (Here and throughout the rest of the paper, [S.sub.c], [M.sub.c], and
[W.sub.c] are again based on the Polity IV executive constraints
variable.) The results are similar to those of table 2. In particular,
the interactions between the medium-constraints dummy and CBI are still
negative, and the estimates are almost all statistically more
significant than in table 2. There is no evidence of a negative effect
of CBI on inflation in strong-constraints countries. The results in
table 4 also show some evidence of a negative effect of CBI in
weak-constraints countries once we focus on the sample of countries that
changed their CBI, in columns 4-3 and 4-4. Nevertheless, these results
should be interpreted with caution: although the tests for serial
correlation cannot reject the null hypothesis of no second-order
correlation in the differenced residuals, the Sargan overidentification
tests reject the null hypothesis in all columns, which implies that
different lags estimate different magnitudes for the coefficients of CBI
and lagged inflation (which is often a problem when using this GMM
procedure with large T).
Table 5 investigates an alternative to the use of the three dummy
variables [S.sub.c], [M.sub.c], and [W.sub.c] for strong-, medium-, and
weak-constraints countries to capture the nonlinear effects of this
variable, namely, the use of a quadratic term in the average of
constraints on the executive interacted with the CBI dummy. The
coefficients reported evaluate the quadratic at levels 1, 4, and 7 of
constraints on the executive. The results are broadly similar to those
in table 2. The short- and the long-run effects of CBI on inflation are
always negative and significant for countries with medium constraints.
There is no evidence of a significant effect of CBI in countries with
strong or weak constraints. However, we can reject the hypothesis that
the effects are equal only when comparing the strong- and the
medium-constraints groups. Overall, these results suggest that the
specific way of parameterizing the non-linearity in the exact cutoffs
between weak and medium, and medium and strong, constraints does not
matter greatly to our results.
Table 6 reports the results of a simple falsification exercise.
Each regression this time includes the interaction of each of the
executive constraints dummies with both the contemporaneous CBI and its
five-year lead. To the extent that inflation was already declining in
some countries before central bank reform, this lead variable will
capture the decline. When this is the case, we cannot have much
confidence that CBI is in fact a major factor in the decline in
inflation. The table shows that the contemporaneous effect of CBI in
countries with intermediate constraints is still significant. The
coefficient on the five-year lead is never negative for this group and
is typically very small. Hence the negative association between CBI and
inflation in this group of countries is not driven mainly by a secular
decline in inflation. For strong-constraints countries, the lead of CBI
is likewise never significant and is typically very small. For
weak-constraints countries there is some evidence of an upward trend in
inflation preceding CBI. This suggests that in some of these cases CBI
may have been introduced in the midst of episodes of particularly high
inflation.
Finally, table 7 reports results from a range of other robustness
checks. The top panel focuses on the full sample and reports results of
specifications corresponding to columns 2-1 and 2-3 in table 2. In the
bottom panel the sample is restricted to countries that changed their
CBI during the sample period, and specifications corresponding to
columns 2-4 and 2-6 of table 2 are reported. Columns 7-1 and 7-2 in both
panels report the robustness of the results to including potential
time-varying determinants of inflation. In particular, we include five
lags of the logarithm of GDP per capita and five lags of the exchange
rate flexibility index constructed by Reinhart and Rogoff, described
above. (88) Although the negative effect of CBI on inflation is not
significant in the full sample, the results in the bottom panel show a
pattern similar to that depicted in table 2, with a negative and
statistically significant long-run effect of CBI only in the group with
intermediate constraints on the executive. The results in columns 7-3
and 7-4 include a quadratic time trend interacted with regional dummies
to control for differing trends in inflation across world regions. These
additional controls have little effect on the estimates. In column 7-3
in the top panel, the estimate of the impact of CBI in
medium-constraints countries is -0.065, with a standard error of 0.044,
which is similar to that reported in column 2-1 of table 2. The long-run
effect in column 7-4, however, is smaller and less significant than that
in column 2-2. Nevertheless, the results in the bottom panel for columns
7-3 and 7-4 show that in the sample of countries that changed CBI, once
we control for differences in regional trends, the results are again
similar to those in table 2.
In columns 7-5 and 7-6 we exclude the Western European countries
from the sample entirely. This robustness check is motivated by the
concern that policy dynamics and the effect of CBI on inflation might be
different in Western Europe than in the rest of the world. The results,
however, are again similar to the baseline estimates.
Columns 7-7 and 7-8 include an additional dummy for the
introduction of the European Central Bank, or for the country in
question joining the European monetary union after the European Central
Bank was established. Again there is little change from the results in
table 2.
Finally, columns 7-9 and 7- 10 show the robustness of our results
to using the CBI index constructed by Cukierman rather than the CBI
dummy. Despite the concerns discussed above related to the coding and
interpretation of this index, it still constitutes a useful check on our
measure of CBI and on our results. The results using this index are
again similar to those reported in table 2: only the interaction between
the medium-constraints dummy and the Cukierman CBI index is negative and
statistically significant. (89) Interestingly, in columns 7-5 through
7-10 for both panels we can now reject at the 10 percent level the null
hypothesis that the effects in the intermediate-constraints group are
equal to those in the weak-constraints group as well as in the
strong-constraints group.
We also examined the robustness of the results reported in table 2
to the type of CBI that different countries implemented. To do this we
ran the same regressions as in table 2 but included a dummy for goal
independence of the CBI. This dummy takes a value of one for countries
where CBI reform defined inflation as the unique objective of monetary
policy, and zero elsewhere. This is a useful robustness check against
the possibility that CBI may have very different effects where the
central banker is truly conservative, with price stability the unique
objective (as with the German Bundesbank), than where CBI has multiple
objectives (as with the U.S. Federal Reserve). The results (not reported
here) using the goal independence dummy are analogous to those in table
2 and suggest a similar pattern, with a negative effect of goal
independence on inflation found only for countries with intermediate
constraints on the executive. We also briefly investigated whether
changes in the dynamics and persistence of inflation in the mid-1980s,
documented for example by Haroon Mumtaz and Paolo Surico and by James
Stock and Mark Watson, (90) might be responsible for our results. As a
crude control for this possibility, we interacted the lags of inflation
with a dummy for the period 1972-90 and a dummy for 1991-2005. The
results (again not reported here) exhibited a pattern similar to that in
table 2, with a negative effect of CBI found only in countries with
intermediate constraints on the executive, although the statistical
significance of some of the estimates became weaker.
The Seesaw Effect
Here we investigate the implications of CBI reform for other
dimensions of policy. In particular, we look at whether CBI is followed
by an increase in government expenditure as a percentage of GDP in
countries with intermediate political constraints. Our basic econometric
model is again equation 13, but now the dependent variable measures
fiscal policy. Table 8 reports the different effects of CBI in strong-,
medium-, and weak-constraints countries on government expenditure as a
percentage of GDP. No evidence is found that introducing CBI in
countries with strong or weak constraints has any impact on government
expenditure relative to GDP in either the short or the long run.
However, in medium-constraints countries, where CBI was found above to
be associated with declines in inflation, CBI also appears to be
associated with increases in government expenditure. Both the short- and
the long-run effects are positive for these countries in all
specifications, and in columns 8-2, 8-3, and 8-5 these effects are
statistically significant. In column 2 the estimated [[phi].sup.M.sub.0]
is 0.011, with a standard error of 0.004, which suggests an immediate
increase in government expenditure equivalent to just above 1 percent of
GDP. The long-run effect of 0.050 is also significant and corresponds to
a 5-percent-of-GDP increase in government expenditure in the long run in
medium-constraints countries that have introduced CBI.
Table 9 shows that the broad pattern is similar when we use the
Arellano-Bond GMM estimator as in table 4. In this case the evidence
consistent with the seesaw effect is somewhat stronger, although now we
also find some positive long-run effect of CBI on government expenditure
in weak-constraints countries (see, for example, column 9-2). Finally,
table 10 reports results of a falsification exercise similar to that in
table 6. Here we again include a five-year lead of the CBI dummy to
check whether the estimates in table 8 might be capturing a secular
upward trend in government expenditure in countries with intermediate
constraints. The results show no evidence of such a pattern. The
interaction between the medium-constraints dummy and the five-year lead
of the CBI dummy is never significantly different from zero.
We also investigated whether CBI is associated with a change in the
government budget balance (again measured as a fraction of GDP). These
results (not reported here) reveal no significant effect. One reason
might be that governments in medium-constraints countries, which do show
a significant increase in spending, may have also raised revenue.
Alternatively, government balances may have improved automatically
because these governments held nominal debt and benefited from the
decline in interest rates associated with reduced inflation.
Counteracting this, however, they are also likely to have experienced a
reduction in the inflation tax.
We conclude that there is some suggestive evidence consistent with
the seesaw pattern, in that in some of the cases where CBI reduces
inflation, there may also be an increase in government expenditure as a
share of GDP. Nevertheless, this result is not always robust, and
further investigation is necessary before reaching a firm conclusion.
Conclusions
We have argued that in order to understand when policy reform will
be effective, one must understand the political context that leads to
distortionary policies in the first place. Although such a claim would
seem natural to those steeped in the study of political economy, it
appears not to have influenced either the design of policy reform in the
past or the recent wave of revisionist research on the failures of
reform. Rather, scholars have taken some recent instances of failure to
imply that the reforms themselves were misconceived because of
second-best problems. We believe that a much more fruitful approach is
to study the political economy constraints that interact with both the
implementation and the effects of reform.
To develop this perspective, we constructed a simple political
economy model of policy distortions and showed that when such
distortions arise as a result of the political equilibrium, strong
forces exerted by those actors initially benefiting from the distortions
may negate the effects of the reform. The model illustrates in a simple
way that both the extent of distortionary policy and the effects of
reform will generally depend on political institutions, for example on
various measures of the constraints on political officeholders. The
first major insight of the model is that policy reform may not be
effective when constraints are so weak that reform can be undermined, or
when constraints are sufficiently strong that policy is unlikely to have
been highly distortionary to start with. Rather, it is at intermediate
values of constraints that policy reform might be most effective. The
second important lesson from the model is that with multiple policy
instruments, reform may lead to a seesaw effect, whereby effective or
partially effective reform in one dimension leads to more-intensive use
of other distortionary instruments.
The paper also provides empirical evidence consistent with these
patterns in the context of CBI. Our evidence suggests that CBI is
associated with significant declines in inflation in countries with
medium constraints, but with no decline, or smaller declines, in
countries with strong or weak constraints. There is also some evidence
that, consistent with the seesaw effect, countries where CBI is
associated with reduced inflation also experience an increase in
government expenditure. This might partly reflect the use of an
alternative policy instrument to achieve goals that high inflation was
previously being used for.
Do these results imply that policy reform can never work? We do not
think this is the correct conclusion, for two reasons. First, our
evidence is consistent with the view that targeted reforms, such as
anti-inflation programs and CBI, can be effective. Second, the evidence
is difficult to reconcile with a naive approach that assumes that
politicians adopt reforms for well-meaning reasons or because they have
decided that their old policies were inappropriate. In this light, if
reforms fail to be fully effective, it must be at least partly because
of the constraints imposed by existing political economy factors. In
particular, when reforms are promoted by international organizations and
imposed on reluctant leaders, they are less likely to be effective or,
at the very least, need to be designed much more carefully to ensure
their effectiveness. Otherwise our model and the empirical results
suggest that de jure reform may not translate into de facto reform, and
when it does, other dimensions of policy may deteriorate.
The general message of our paper is that the analysis of policy
reform should start with an understanding of the political economy
constraints that lead to distortionary policies in the first place. This
type of political economy analysis might ultimately be useful both in
predicting when reforms are likely to be effective and in understanding
how reforms can be better designed to reduce the risk of backlash.
Although we are currently too far from a satisfactory theoretical or
empirical understanding to be able to design policy reforms that are
robust to such challenges, this paper and others in this vein should
help make the case that an analysis of the political economic roots of
distortionary policies must be part of any debate on the effectiveness
and design of reforms.
Table A1. Classification of Countries by Strength
of Executive Constraints and Institutions
Coding bused Coding Coding based
on executive based on on control of
Country constraints (a) rule of law (b) corruption (b)
Argentina Medium Medium Medium
Australia Strong Strong Strong
Austria Strong Strong Strong
Belgium Strong Medium Medium
Bolivia Medium Medium Weak
Brazil Medium Medium Medium
Canada Strong Strong Strong
Chile Medium Medium Medium
China Weak Medium Medium
Colombia Medium Weak Medium
Costa Rica Strong Medium Medium
Denmark Strong Strong Strong
Dominican Republic Medium Weak Medium
Ecuador Medium Weak Weak
El Salvador Medium Weak Medium
Finland Strong Strong Strong
France Medium Medium Medium
Germany Strong Strong Strong
Greece Medium Medium Medium
Guatemala Weak Weak Weak
Guyana Weak Medium Medium
Honduras Medium Weak Weak
India Medium Medium Medium
Indonesia Weak Weak Weak
Ireland Strong Strong Medium
Israel Strong Medium Medium
Italy Strong Medium Medium
Japan Strong Medium Medium
Korea Medium Medium Medium
Malaysia Medium Medium Medium
Mexico Medium Medium Medium
Mongolia Medium Medium Medium
Nepal Weak Medium Medium
Netherlands Strong Strong Strong
New Zealand Strong Strong Strong
Nicaragua Medium Weak Weak
Norway Strong Strong Strong
Pakistan Medium Weak Weak
Paraguay Weak Weak Weak
Peru Medium Weak Medium
Philippines Medium Medium Medium
Portugal Medium Medium Medium
Qatar Weak Medium Medium
Singapore Weak Strong Strong
Spain Medium Medium Medium
Sweden Strong Strong Strong
Switzerland Strong Strong Strong
Turkey Medium Medium Medium
United Kingdom Strong Strong Strong
United States Strong Strong Medium
Uruguay Medium Medium Medium
Venezuela Medium Weak Weak
Sources: Authors' determinations based on sources indicated.
(a.) From Polity IV dataset.
(b.) From Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2007) data.
APPENDIX A
[FIGURE B1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE B2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE B3 OMITTED]